2016-29483

[Federal Register Volume 81, Number 251 (Friday, December 30, 2016)]

[Proposed Rules]

[Pages 96704-96990]

From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]

[FR Doc No: 2016-29483]

[[Page 96703]]

Vol. 81

Friday,

No. 251

December 30, 2016

Part III

Book 2 of 2 Books

Pages 96703-97110

Commodity Futures Trading Commission

-----------------------------------------------------------------------

17 CFR Parts 1, 15, 17, et al.

Position Limits for Derivatives; Proposed Rule

Federal Register / Vol. 81 , No. 251 / Friday, December 30, 2016 /

Proposed Rules

[[Page 96704]]

-----------------------------------------------------------------------

COMMODITY FUTURES TRADING COMMISSION

17 CFR Parts 1, 15, 17, 19, 37, 38, 140, 150 and 151

RIN 3038-AD99

Position Limits for Derivatives

AGENCY: Commodity Futures Trading Commission.

ACTION: Reproposal.

-----------------------------------------------------------------------

SUMMARY: The Commodity Futures Trading Commission (``Commission'' or

``CFTC'') is reproposing rules to amend part 150 of the Commission's

regulations concerning speculative position limits to conform to the

Wall Street Transparency and Accountability Act of 2010 (``Dodd-Frank

Act'') amendments to the Commodity Exchange Act (``CEA'' or ``Act'').

The reproposal would establish speculative position limits for 25

exempt and agricultural commodity futures and option contracts, and

physical commodity swaps that are ``economically equivalent'' to such

contracts (as such term is used in section 4a(a)(5) of the CEA). In

connection with establishing these limits, the Commission is

reproposing to update some relevant definitions; revise the exemptions

from speculative position limits, including for bona fide hedging; and

extend and update reporting requirements for persons claiming exemption

from these limits. The Commission is also reproposing appendices to

part 150 that would provide guidance on risk management exemptions for

commodity derivative contracts in excluded commodities permitted under

the revised definition of bona fide hedging position; list core

referenced futures contracts and commodities that would be

substantially the same as a commodity underlying a core referenced

futures contract for purposes of the definition of location basis

contract; describe and analyze fourteen fact patterns that would

satisfy the reproposed definition of bona fide hedging position; and

present the reproposed speculative position limit levels in tabular

form. In addition, the Commission proposes to update certain of its

rules, guidance and acceptable practices for compliance with Designated

Contract Market (``DCM'') core principle 5 and Swap Execution Facility

(``SEF'') core principle 6 in respect of exchange-set speculative

position limits and position accountability levels. Furthermore, the

Commission is reproposing processes for DCMs and SEFs to recognize

certain positions in commodity derivative contracts as non-enumerated

bona fide hedges or enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedges, as well

as to exempt from position limits certain spread positions, in each

case subject to Commission review. Separately, the Commission is

reproposing to delay for DCMs and SEFs that lack access to sufficient

swap position information the requirement to establish and monitor

position limits on swaps.

DATES: Comments must be received on or before February 28, 2017.

ADDRESSES: You may submit comments, identified by RIN number 3038-AD99,

by any of the following methods:

CFTC Web site: http://comments.cftc.gov;

Mail: Secretary of the Commission, Commodity Futures

Trading Commission, Three Lafayette Centre, 1155 21st Street NW.,

Washington, DC 20581;

Hand delivery/courier: Same as Mail, above.

Federal eRulemaking Portal: http://www.regulations.gov.

Follow instructions for submitting comments.

All comments must be submitted in English, or if not, accompanied

by an English translation. Comments will be posted as received to

http://www.cftc.gov. You should submit only information that you wish

to make available publicly. If you wish the Commission to consider

information that may be exempt from disclosure under the Freedom of

Information Act, a petition for confidential treatment of the exempt

information may be submitted according to the procedures established in

CFTC regulations at 17 CFR part 145.

The Commission reserves the right, but shall have no obligation, to

review, pre-screen, filter, redact, refuse or remove any or all of your

submission from http://www.cftc.gov that it may deem to be

inappropriate for publication, such as obscene language. All

submissions that have been redacted or removed that contain comments on

the merits of the rulemaking will be retained in the public comment

file and will be considered as required under the Administrative

Procedure Act and other applicable laws, and may be accessible under

the Freedom of Information Act.

FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Stephen Sherrod, Senior Economist,

(202) 418-5452, [email protected], Riva Spear Adriance, Senior Special

Counsel, (202) 418-5494, [email protected], Hannah Ropp, Surveillance

Analyst, 202-418-5228, [email protected], or Steven Benton, Industry

Economist, (202) 418-5617, [email protected], Division of Market

Oversight; or Lee Ann Duffy, Assistant General Counsel, 202-418-6763,

[email protected], Office of General Counsel, in each case at the

Commodity Futures Trading Commission, Three Lafayette Centre, 1155 21st

Street NW., Washington, DC 20581.

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:

Table of Contents

I. Background

A. Introduction

B. The Commission Construes CEA Section 4a(a) To Mandate That

the Commission Impose Position Limits

C. Necessity Finding

II. Proposed Compliance Date

III. Reproposed Rules

A. Sec. 150.1--Definitions

B. Sec. 150.2--Position limits

C. Sec. 150.3--Exemptions

D. Sec. 150.5--Exchange-set speculative position limits and

Parts 37 and 38

E. Part 19--Reports by persons holding bona fide hedging

positions pursuant to Sec. 150.1 of this chapter and by merchants

and dealers in cotton

F. Sec. 150.7--Reporting requirements for anticipatory hedging

positions

G. Sec. 150.9--Process for recognition of positions as non-

enumerated bona fide hedging positions

H. Sec. 150.10--Process for designated contract market or swap

execution facility exemption from position limits for certain spread

positions

I. Sec. 150.11--Process for recognition of positions as bona

fide hedging positions for unfilled anticipated requirements, unsold

anticipated production, anticipated royalties, anticipated services

contract payments or receipts, or anticipatory cross-commodity hedge

positions

J. Miscellaneous regulatory amendments

1. Proposed Sec. 150.6--Ongoing responsibility of DCMs and SEFs

2. Proposed Sec. 150.8--Severability

3. Part 15--Reports--General provisions

4. Part 17--Reports by reporting markets, futures commission

merchants, clearing members, and foreign brokers

5. Part 151--Position limits for futures and swaps, Commission

Regulation 1.47 and Commission Regulation 1.48--Removal

IV. Related Matters

A. Cost-Benefit Considerations

B. Paperwork Reduction Act

C. Regulatory Flexibility Act

V. Appendices

A. Appendix A--Review of Economic Studies

B. Appendix B--List of Comment Letters Cited in this Rulemaking

I. Background

A. Introduction

The Commission has long established and enforced speculative

position limits for futures and options contracts on various

agricultural commodities as authorized by the Commodity Exchange

[[Page 96705]]

Act (``CEA'').\1\ The part 150 position limits regime \2\ generally

includes three components: (1) The level of the limits, which set a

threshold that restricts the number of speculative positions that a

person may hold in the spot-month, individual month, and all months

combined,\3\ (2) exemptions for positions that constitute bona fide

hedging transactions and certain other types of transactions,\4\ and

(3) rules to determine which accounts and positions a person must

aggregate for the purpose of determining compliance with the position

limit levels.\5\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1\ 7 U.S.C. 1 et seq.

\2\ See 17 CFR part 150. Part 150 of the Commission's

regulations establishes federal position limits (that is, position

limits established by the Commission, as opposed to exchange-set

limits) on certain enumerated agricultural contracts; the listed

commodities are referred to as enumerated agricultural commodities.

The position limits on these agricultural contracts are referred to

as ``legacy'' limits because these contracts on agricultural

commodities have been subject to federal position limits for

decades. See also Position Limits for Derivatives, 78 FR 75680 at

75723, n. 370 and accompanying text (Dec. 12, 2013) (``December 2013

Position Limits Proposal'').

\3\ See 17 CFR 150.2.

\4\ See 17 CFR 150.3.

\5\ See 17 CFR 150.4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In late 2013, the CFTC proposed to amend its part 150 regulations

governing speculative position limits.\6\ These proposed amendments

were intended to conform the requirements of part 150 to particular

changes to the CEA introduced by the Wall Street Transparency and

Accountability Act of 2010 (''Dodd-Frank Act'').\7\ The proposed

amendments included the adoption of federal position limits for 28

exempt and agricultural commodity futures and option contracts and

swaps that are ``economically equivalent'' to such contracts.\8\ In

addition, the Commission proposed to require that DCMs and SEFs that

are trading facilities (collectively, ``exchanges'') establish

exchange-set limits on such futures, options and swaps contracts.\9\

Further, the Commission proposed to (i) revise the definition of bona

fide hedging position (which includes a general definition with

requirements applicable to all hedges, as well as an enumerated list of

bona fide hedges),\10\ (ii) revise the process for market participants

to request recognition of certain types of positions as bona fide

hedges, including anticipatory hedges and hedges not specifically

enumerated in the proposed bona fide hedging definition; \11\ and (iii)

revise the exemptions from position limits for transactions normally

known to the trade as spreads.\12\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\6\ See generally December 2013 Positions Limits Proposal. In

the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission proposed

to amend its position limits to also encompass 28 exempt and

agricultural commodity futures and options contracts and the

physical commodity swaps that are economically equivalent to such

contracts.

\7\ The Commission previously had issued proposed and final

rules in 2011 to implement the provisions of the Dodd-Frank Act

regarding position limits and the bona fide hedge definition.

Position Limits for Derivatives, 76 FR 4752 (Jan. 26, 2011);

Position Limits for Futures and Swaps, 76 FR 71626 (Nov. 18, 2011).

A September 28, 2012 order of the U.S. District Court for the

District of Columbia vacated the November 18, 2011 rule, with the

exception of the rule's amendments to 17 CFR 150.2. International

Swaps and Derivatives Association v. United States Commodity Futures

Trading Commission, 887 F. Supp. 2d 259 (D.D.C. 2012). See generally

the materials and links on the Commission's Web site at http://www.cftc.gov/LawRegulation/DoddFrankAct/Rulemakings/DF_26_PosLimits/index.htm. The Commission issued the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, among other reasons, to respond to the District Court's

decision in ISDA v. CFTC. See generally the materials and links on

the Commission's Web site at http://www.cftc.gov/LawRegulation/DoddFrankAct/Rulemakings/PositionLimitsforDerivatives/index.htm.

\8\ See CEA section 4a(a)(5), 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(5) (providing that

the Commission establish limits on economically equivalent

contracts); CEA section 4a(a)(6), 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(6) (directing the

Commission to establish aggregate position limits on futures,

options, economically equivalent swaps, and certain foreign board of

trade contracts in agricultural and exempt commodities

(collectively, ``referenced contracts'')). See December 2013

Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75825. Under the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal, ``referenced contracts'' would have been

defined as futures, options, economically equivalent swaps, and

certain foreign board of trade contracts, in physical commodities,

and been subject to the proposed federal position limits. The

Commission proposed that federal position limits would apply to

referenced contracts, whether futures or swaps, regardless of where

the futures or swaps positions were established. See December 2013

Positions Limits Proposal, at 78 FR 75826 (proposed Sec. 150.2).

\9\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75754-

8. Consistent with DCM Core Principle 5 and SEF Core Principle 6,

the Commission proposed at Sec. 150.5(a)(1) that for any commodity

derivative contract that is subject to a speculative position limit

under Sec. 150.2, a DCM or SEF that is a trading facility shall set

a speculative position limit no higher than the level specified in

Sec. 150.2.

\10\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75706-

11, 75713-18.

\11\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75718.

\12\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75735-

6. CEA section 4a(a)(1), 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(1), permits the Commission

to exempt transactions normally known to the trade as ``spreads''

from federal position limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

On June 13, 2016, the Commission published a supplemental proposal

to its December 2013 Position Limits rulemaking.\13\ The supplemental

proposal included revisions and additions to regulations and guidance

proposed in 2013 concerning speculative position limits in response to

comments received on that proposal, and alternative processes for DCMs

and SEFs to recognize certain positions in commodity derivative

contracts as non-enumerated bona fide hedges or enumerated anticipatory

bona fide hedges, as well as to exempt from federal position limits

certain spread positions, in each case subject to Commission review. In

this regard, under the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal,

certain of the regulations proposed in 2013 regarding exemptions from

federal position limits and exchange-set position limits would be

amended to take into account the alternative processes. In connection

with those proposed changes, the Commission proposed to further amend

certain relevant definitions, including to clearly define the general

definition of bona fide hedging for physical commodities under the

standards in CEA section 4a(c). Separately, the Commission proposed to

delay for DCMs and SEFs that lack access to sufficient swap position

information the requirement to establish and monitor position limits on

swaps at this time.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\13\ Position Limits for Derivatives: Certain Exemptions and

Guidance, 81 FR 38458 (June 13, 2016) (``2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After review of the comments responding to both the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal and the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, the Commission, in consideration of those comments, is now

issuing a reproposal (``Reproposal''). The Commission invites comments

on all aspects of this Reproposal.

B. The Commission Preliminarily Construes CEA Section 4a(a) To Mandate

That the Commission Impose Position Limits

1. Introduction

a. The History of Position Limits and the 2011 Position Limits Rule

As part of the Dodd-Frank Act, Congress amended the CEA's position

limits provision, which since 1936 has authorized the Commission (and

its predecessor) to impose limits on speculative positions to prevent

the harms caused by excessive speculation. Prior to the Dodd-Frank Act,

CEA section 4a(a) stated that for the purpose of diminishing,

eliminating or preventing specified burdens on interstate commerce, the

Commission shall, from time to time, after due notice and an

opportunity for hearing, by rule, regulation, or order, proclaim and

fix such limits on the amounts of trading which may be done or

positions which may be held by any person under contracts of sale of

such commodity for future delivery on or subject to the rules of any

contract market as the Commission finds are necessary to

[[Page 96706]]

diminish, eliminate, or prevent such burden.\14\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\14\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a) (2006).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the Dodd-Frank Act, Congress renumbered a modified version of

CEA section 4a(a) as section 4a(a)(1) and added, among other

provisions, CEA section 4a(a)(2), captioned ``Establishment of

Limitations,'' which provides that in accordance with the standards set

forth in CEA section 4a(a)(1), the Commission shall establish limits on

the amount of positions, as appropriate, other than bona fide hedge

positions, that may be held by any person. CEA section 4a(a)(2) further

provides that for exempt commodities (energy and metals), the limits

required under CEA section 4a(a)(2) shall be established within 180

days after the date of the enactment of CEA section 4a(a)(2); for

agricultural commodities, the limits required under CEA section

4a(a)(2) shall be established within 270 days after the date of the

enactment of CEA section 4a(a)(2).\15\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\15\ CEA section 4a(a)(2); 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(2). The Commission

notes that it uses the defined term ``bona fide hedging position''

throughout part 150, rather than ``bona fide hedge positions'' found

in CEA section 4a(a)(2). CEA section 4a(c)(1) uses the term ``bona

fide hedging transactions or positions'' and CEA section 4a(c)(2)

uses the term ``bona fide hedging transaction or position.'' The

Commission interprets all of these terms to mean the same. It should

be noted that the Commission previously imposed transaction volume

limits on ``the amounts of trading which may be done'' as authorized

by CEA section 4a(a)(1), but removed those transaction volume

limits. Elimination of Daily Speculative Trading Limits, 44 FR 7124,

7127 (Feb. 6, 1979).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

These and other changes to CEA section 4a(a) are described in more

detail below.

Pursuant to these amendments, the Commission adopted a position

limits rule in 2011 (``2011 Position Limits Rule'') in a new part

151.\16\ In the 2011 Position Limits Rule, the Commission imposed, in

new part 151, speculative limits in the spot-month and non-spot-months

on 28 physical commodity derivatives ``of particular significance to

interstate commerce.'' \17\ Under the 2011 Position Limits Rule, part

151 used formulas for calculating limit levels that are similar to the

formulas used to calculate previous Commission- and exchange-set

position limits.\18\ The 2011 Position Limits Rule contained provisions

in part 151 that implemented the statutory exemption for bona fide

hedging.\19\ It also provided account aggregation standards to

determine which positions to attribute to a particular market

participant.\20\ Because it interpreted the Dodd-Frank Act as mandating

position limits, the Commission did not make an independent threshold

determination that position limits are necessary to accomplish the

purposes set forth in the statute. The Commission explained:

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\16\ Position Limits for Futures and Swaps, 76 FR 71626 (Nov.

18, 2011). As finalized, part 151 replaced part 150.

\17\ Id. at 71665; see also id at 716629-30.

\18\ Id. at 71632-33 (transition), 71668-70 (spot-month limit),

71671 (non-spot month limit).

\19\ Id. at 71643-51.

\20\ Id. at 71651-55. A central feature of any position limits

regime is determining which positions to attribute to a particular

trader. The CEA requires the Commission to attribute to a person all

positions that the person holds or trades, as well as positions held

or traded by anyone else that such person directly or indirectly

controls. 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(1). This is referred to as account

aggregation. In addition to account aggregation, Congress required

the Commission to set limits on all derivative positions in the same

underlying commodity that a trader may hold or control across all

derivative exchanges. 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(6). The Commission refers to

this as position aggregation.

Congress directed the Commission to impose position limits and to do

so expeditiously. Section 4a(a)(2)(B) states that the limits for

physical commodity futures and options contracts ``shall'' be

established within the specified timeframes, and section 4a(a)(2)(5)

states that the limits for economically equivalent swaps ``shall''

be established concurrently with the limits required by section

4a(a)(2). The congressional directive that the Commission set

position limits is further reflected in the repeated references to

the limits ``required'' under section 4a(a)(2)(A).\21\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\21\ Position Limits for Futures and Swaps, 76 FR at 71626-628.

ISDA and SIFMA sued the Commission to vacate part 151 on the basis

(among others) that, in their view, CEA section 4a(a) clearly required

the Commission to make an antecedent necessity finding.

b. The District Court Opinion

As set forth in the Commission's December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal,\22\ the district court in ISDA v. CFTC found that, on one

hand, CEA section 4a(a)(1) ``unambiguously requires that, prior to

imposing position limits, the Commission find that position limits are

necessary to `diminish, eliminate, or prevent' the burden described in

[CEA section 4a(a)(1)].'' \23\ On the other hand, the court found that

the Dodd-Frank Act amendments to CEA section 4a(a) rendered section

4a(a)(1) ambiguous with respect to whether such findings are required

for the position limits described in CEA section 4a(a)(2)--futures

contracts, options, and certain swaps on agricultural and exempt

commodities.\24\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\22\ International Swaps and Derivatives Ass'n v. United States

Commodity Futures Trading Comm'n, 887 F. Supp. 2d 259 (D.D.C. 2012).

\23\ Id. at 270.

\24\ Id. at 281.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The court's determination in ISDA v. CFTC that CEA sections

4a(a)(1) and (2), read together, are ambiguous focused on the opening

phrase of subsection (A)--``[i]n accordance with the standards set

forth in [CEA section 4a(a)(1)].'' The court held that the term

``standards'' in CEA section 4a(a)(2) was ambiguous as to whether it

referred to the requirement in CEA section 4a(a)(1) that the Commission

impose position limits only ``as [it] finds are necessary to diminish,

eliminate, or prevent'' an unnecessary burden on interstate

commerce.\25\ If not, ``standards'' would refer to the aggregation and

flexibility standards stated in CEA section 4a(a)(1) by which position

limits are to be implemented. Accordingly, the court rejected both (1)

the Commission's contention that CEA section 4a(a) as a whole

unambiguously mandated the imposition of position limits without the

Commission finding independently that they are necessary; and (2) the

plaintiffs' contention that CEA section 4a(a) unambiguously required

the Commission to make such findings before the imposition of position

limits.\26\ The court stated that because the Commission had

incorrectly found CEA section 4a(a) unambiguous, it could not defer to

any interpretation by the Commission to resolve the section's

ambiguity. As the court observed, the D.C. Circuit has held that ``

`deference to an agency's interpretation of a statute is not

appropriate when the agency wrongly believes that interpretation is

compelled by Congress.' '' \27\ The court further held that, pursuant

to the law of the D.C. Circuit, it was required to remand the matter to

the Commission so that it could ``fill in the gaps and resolve the

ambiguities.'' \28\ The court instructed that the Commission must apply

its experience and expertise and cautioned that, in resolving the

ambiguity in CEA section 4a(a), `` `it is incumbent upon the agency not

to rest simply on its parsing of the statutory language.' '' \29\ The

Commission does not rest simply on parsing the statutory language, but

any interpretation necessarily begins with the text, which is described

in the next section.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\25\ 887 F. Supp. 2d at 274-76.

\26\ 887 F. Supp. 2d at 279-80.

\27\ Id. at 280-82, quoting Peter Pan Bus Lines, Inc. v. Fed.

Motor Carrier Safety Admin., 471 F.3d 1350, 1354 (D.C. Cir. 2006).

\28\ 887 F. Supp. 2d at 282.

\29\ Id. at n.7, quoting PDK Labs. Inc. v. DEA, 362 F.3d 786,

797 (D.C. Cir. 2004).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. The Statutory Framework for Position Limits

Before the Dodd-Frank Act, what was then CEA section 4a(a)

authorized the

[[Page 96707]]

Commission to set limits on futures for any exchange-traded contract

for future delivery of any commodity ``as the Commission finds are

necessary to diminish, eliminate, or prevent [the] burden'' of

``[e]xcessive speculation'' ``causing sudden or unreasonable

fluctuations or unwarranted changes in the price of such commodity.'' 7

U.S.C. 6a(a) (2009 Supp.).\30\ CEA section 4a(a) also required the

Commission to follow certain criteria for aggregating limits once it

made that determination. And the Commission was authorized to impose

limits flexibly, depending on the commodity, delivery month, and other

factors.\31\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\30\ Under the heading of ``Burden on interstate commerce;

trading or position limits,'' 7 U.S.C. 6a(a) (2006) provided that

excessive speculation in any commodity under contracts of sale of

such commodity for future delivery made on or subject to the rules

of contract markets or derivatives transaction execution facilities,

or on electronic trading facilities with respect to a significant

price discovery contract causing sudden or unreasonable fluctuations

or unwarranted changes in the price of such commodity, is an undue

and unnecessary burden on interstate commerce in such commodity.

Title 7 U.S.C. 6a(a) (2006) further provided that for the purpose of

diminishing, eliminating, or preventing such burden, the Commission

shall, from time to time, after due notice and opportunity for

hearing, by rule, regulation, or order, proclaim and fix such limits

on the amounts of trading which may be done or positions which may

be held by any person under contracts of sale of such commodity for

future delivery on or subject to the rules of any contract market or

derivatives transaction execution facility, or on an electronic

trading facility with respect to a significant price discovery

contract, as the Commission finds are necessary to diminish,

eliminate, or prevent such burden. Additionally, 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)

(2006) stated that in determining whether any person has exceeded

such limits, the positions held and trading done by any persons

directly or indirectly controlled by such person shall be included

with the positions held and trading done by such person; and

further, such limits upon positions and trading shall apply to

positions held by, and trading done by, two or more persons acting

pursuant to an expressed or implied agreement or understanding, the

same as if the positions were held by, or the trading were done by,

a single person. Title 7 U.S.C. 6a(a) (2006) further stated that

nothing in that section shall be construed to prohibit the

Commission from fixing different trading or position limits for

different commodities, markets, futures, or delivery months, or for

different number of days remaining until the last day of trading in

a contract, or different trading limits for buying and selling

operations, or different limits for the purposes of paragraphs (1)

and (2) of subsection (b) of this section, or from exempting

transactions normally known to the trade as ``spreads'' or

``straddles'' or ``arbitrage'' or from fixing limits applying to

such transactions or positions different from limits fixed for other

transactions or positions. Moreover, 7 U.S.C. 6a(a) (2006) defined

the word ``arbitrage'' in domestic markets to mean the same as a

``spread'' or ``straddle.'' It also authorized the Commission to

define the term ``international arbitrage.'' 7 U.S.C. 6a(a) (2006).

\31\ There were four other subsections of CEA section 4a: CEA

section 4a(b), which made it unlawful for a person to hold positions

in excess of Commission-set limits; CEA section 4a(c), which

exempted positions held under an exemption for bona fide hedges, CEA

section 4a(d), which exempted positions held by or on behalf of the

United States, and CEA section 4a(e), which authorized exchanges to

set limits so long as they were not higher than Commission-set

limits and made it unlawful for any person to hold limits in excess

of exchange-set limits. (Exchange-set limits are also addressed

elsewhere in the CEA. E.g., 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(5)).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The 2010 Dodd-Frank Act amendments to CEA section 4a(a)

significantly expanded and altered it. The entirety of pre-Dodd-Frank

CEA section 4a(a) became CEA section 4a(a)(1). Congress added six new

subsections to CEA section 4a(a)--sections 4a(a)(2) through (7). And,

outside of section 4a(a), Congress imposed a requirement that the

Commission study the new limits it imposed and provide Congress with a

report on their effects within one year of their imposition.\32\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\32\ 15 U.S.C. 8307(a). Some parts of pre Dodd-Frank CEA

sections 4a(a) and 4a(b)-(e) were also amended by the Dodd-Frank

Act. CEA section 4a(a) is now CEA section 4a(a)(1) and was modified

primarily to add swaps, CEA section 4a(b) updates the names of

applicable exchanges, and CEA section 4a(c) requires the Commission

to promulgate a rule in accordance with a narrowed definition of

bona fide hedging position as an exemption from position limits. 7

U.S.C. 6a(a)(1), 6a(b)-(e).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The primary change at issue here was the addition of new CEA

section 4a(a)(2), which addresses position limits on a specific class

of commodity contracts, ``physical commodities other than excluded

commodities'':

CEA section 4a(a)(2)(A) provides that in accordance with the

standards set forth in CEA section 4a(a)(1), with respect to physical

commodities other than excluded commodities, the Commission shall

establish limits on the amount of positions, as appropriate, other than

bona fide hedge positions, that may be held by any person with respect

to contracts of sale for future delivery or with respect to options on

the contracts.

CEA section 4a(a)(2)(B), in turn, provides that the limits

``required'' under CEA section 4a(a)(2)(A) ``shall be established

within 180 days after the date of enactment of this paragraph'' for

``agricultural commodities'' (such as wheat or corn) and ``within 270

days after the date of the enactment of this paragraph'' for ``exempt

commodities'' (which include energy-related commodities like oil, as

well as metals).\33\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\33\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(2)(B)(i) and (ii).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The other new subsections of CEA section 4a(a) delineate the types

of physical commodity derivatives to which the new limits apply, set

forth criteria for the Commission to consider in determining the levels

of the required limits, require the Commission to aggregate the limits

across exchanges for equivalent derivatives, require the Commission to

impose limits on swaps that are economically equivalent to the physical

commodity futures and options subject to CEA section 4a(a)(2), and

permit the Commission to grant exemptions from the position limits it

must impose under the provision:

Section 4a(a)(3) guides the Commission in setting

appropriate limit levels by providing that the Commission shall

consider whether the limit levels: (i) Diminish, eliminate, or prevent

excessive speculation; (ii) deter and prevent market manipulation,

squeezes, and corners; (iii) ensure sufficient market liquidity for

bona fide hedgers; and (iv) ensure that the price discovery function of

the underlying market is not disrupted;

Section 4a(a)(4) sets forth criteria for determining which

swaps perform a significant price discovery function for purposes of

the position limits provisions;

Section 4a(a)(5) requires the Commission to concurrently

impose appropriate limit levels on physical commodity swaps that are

economically equivalent to the futures and options for which limits are

required;

Section 4a(a)(6) requires the Commission to apply the

required position limits on an aggregate basis to contracts based on

the same underlying commodity across all exchanges; and

Section a(a)(7) authorizes the Commission to grant

exemptions from the position limits it imposes.\34\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\34\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(3)-(7).

In a separate Dodd-Frank Act provision, Congress required that the

Commission, in consultation with exchanges, ``shall conduct a study of

the effects (if any) of the position limits imposed'' under CEA section

4a(a)(2), that ``[w]ithin twelve months after the imposition of

position limits'' the Commission ``shall'' submit a report of the

results of the study to Congress, and that Congress ``shall'' hold

hearings within 30 days of receipt of the report regarding its

findings.\35\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\35\ 15 U.S.C. 8307(a).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. The Commission's Experience With Position Limits

As explained in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

position limits have a long history as a tool to prevent unwarranted

price movement and volatility, including but not limited to price

swings caused by market manipulation.\36\ Physical commodities

underlying futures contracts are, by definition, in finite supply, and

so it is

[[Page 96708]]

possible to amass or dissipate an extremely large position in such a

way as to interfere with the normal forces of supply and demand.

Speculators (who have no commercial use for the underlying commodity)

are considered differently from hedgers (who use commodity derivatives

to hedge commercial risk). Speculators have been considered a greater

source of risk because their trading is unconnected with underlying

commercial activity, whereas a hedger's trading is calibrated to other

business needs. In various statutory enactments, Congress has

recognized both the utility of position limits and the need to treat

speculators differently from hedgers.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\36\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75685.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Congress began regulating commodity derivatives in 1917, when

Congress enacted emergency legislation to stabilize the U.S. grain

markets during the First World War by suspending wheat futures and

securing ``a voluntary limitation'' of 500,000 bushels on trading in

corn futures.\37\ In 1922 Congress enacted the Grain Futures Act, in

which it noted that ``sudden or unreasonable fluctuations in the prices

of commodity futures . . . frequently occur as a result of speculation,

manipulation, or control . . . .'' \38\ In 1936, Congress strengthened

the government's authority by providing for limits on speculative

trading in commodity derivatives when it enacted the CEA. The CEA

authorized the CFTC's predecessor, the Commodity Exchange Commission

(CEC), to establish limits on speculative trading. Since that time, the

Commission has been establishing or authorizing position limits for the

past 80 years. As discussed in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal and prior rulemakings, this history includes setting position

limits beginning in 1938; overseeing exchange-set limits beginning in

the 1960s; promulgating a rule in 1981, later directly ratified by

Congress, mandating that exchanges set limits for all commodity futures

for which there were no limits; allowing exchanges, in the 1990s, to

set position accountability levels for certain financial contracts,

such as futures and options on foreign currencies and other financial

instruments with high degrees of stability; \39\ and later expanding

exchange limits or accountability requirements to significant price

discovery contracts traded on exempt commercial markets.\40\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\37\ Frank M. Surface, The Grain Trade During the World War, at

224 (Macmilliam 1928).

\38\ Grain Futures Act of 1922, ch. 369 at section 3, 342 Stat.

998, 999 (1922), codified at 7 U.S.C. 5 (1925-26).

\39\ See Speculative Position Limits--Exemptions From Commission

Rule 1.61; Chicago Mercantile Exchange Proposed Amendments to Rules

3902.D, 5001.E, 3010.F, 3012.F, 3013.F, 3015.F, 4604, and Deletion

of Rules 3902.F, 5001.G, 3010.H., 3012.M, 3013.H, and 3015.H, 56 FR

51687 (Oct. 15, 1991) (providing notice of proposed exchange rule

changes; request for comments). The Government, either through

Congress, CEC or the Commission, has maintained position limits on

various agricultural commodities since 1917.

\40\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75681-85;

Significant Price Discovery Contracts on Exempt Commercial Markets,

74 FR 12178 (March 23, 2009).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As addressed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, two

aspects of the Commission's experience are particularly important to

the Commission's interpretation of the Dodd-Frank Act amendments to CEA

section 4a. The first is the Commission's experience with the time

required to make necessity findings before setting limits, which

relates to the time limits contained in CEA section 4a(a)(2)(B). The

second is the Commission's experience in rulemaking requiring exchanges

to set limits in accordance with certain ``standards,'' the term the

district court found ambiguous.

a. Time to Establish Position Limits

Based on its experience administering position limits, the

Commission preliminarily concludes (as stated preliminarily in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal) that Congress could not have

contemplated that, as a prerequisite to imposing limits, the Commission

would first make antecedent commodity-by-commodity necessity

determinations in the 180-270 day time frame within which CEA section

4a(a)(2)(B) states that limits ``required under subparagraph

[4a(a)(2(A)] shall be established.'' \41\ As described in the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, for 45 years after passage of the CEA,

the Commission's predecessor agency made findings of necessity in its

rulemakings establishing position limits.\42\ During that period, the

Commission had jurisdiction over only a limited number of agricultural

commodities. In orders issued by the Commodity Exchange Commission

between 1940 and 1956 establishing position limits, the CEC stated that

the limits it was imposing in each were necessary. Each of those orders

involved no more than a small number of commodities. But it took the

CEC many months to make those findings. For example, in 1938, the CEC

imposed position limits on six grain products.\43\ Proceedings leading

up to the establishment of the limits commenced more than 13 months

earlier, when the CEC issued a notice of hearing regarding the

limits.\44\ Similarly, in September 1939, the CEC issued a Notice of

Hearing with respect to position limits for cotton, but it was not

until August 1940 that the CEC finally promulgated such limits.\45\ And

the CEC began the process of imposing limits on soybeans and eggs in

January 1951, but did not complete the process until more than seven

months later.\46\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\41\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75682-83

(citing 887 F. Supp. 2d at 273).

\42\ 887 F. Supp. 2d at 269.

\43\ See In the Matter of Limits on Position and Daily Trading

in Wheat, Corn, Oats, Barley, Rye, and Flaxseed, for Future Delivery

Findings of Fact, Conclusions, and Order, 3 FR 3145, Dec. 24, 1938.

\44\ See 2 FR 2460, Nov. 12, 1937.

\45\ See Limitation on Buying or Selling of Cotton Notice of

Hearing, 4 FR 3903, Sep. 14, 1939; Part 150--Orders of the Commodity

Exchange Commission Findings of Fact, Conclusions, and Order In the

Matter of Limits on Position and Daily Trading in Cotton for Future

Delivery, 5 FR 3198, Aug. 28, 1940.

\46\ See Handling of Anti-Hog-Cholera Serum and Hog-Cholera

Virus; Notice of Proposed Rule Making 16 FR 321, Jan. 12, 1951;

Limits on Position and Daily Trading in Eggs for Future Delivery, 16

FR 8106, Aug. 16, 1951; see also Limits on Positions and Daily

Trading in Cottonseed Oil, Soybean Oil, and Lard for Future

Delivery, 17 FR 6055, Jul. 4, 1952 (providing notice of a hearing

regarding proposed position limits for cottonseed oil, soybean oil,

and lard); Limits on Position and Daily Trading in Cottonseed Oil

for Future Delivery, 18 FR 443, Jan. 22, 1953 (giving orders setting

limits for cottonseed oil, soybean oil, and lard); Limits on

Position and Daily Trading in Onions for Future Delivery; Notice of

Hearing, 21 FR 1838, Mar. 24, 1956 (conveying notice of a hearing

regarding proposed position limits for onions), Limits on Position

and Daily Trading in Onions for Future Delivery, 21 FR 5575, Jul.

25, 1956 (providing order setting position limits for onions).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the Commission's experience (including the experience of its

predecessor agency), it generally took many months to make a necessity

finding with respect to one commodity. The process of making the sort

of necessity findings that plaintiffs in ISDA v. SIFMA urged with

respect to all agricultural commodities and all exempt commodities (and

that some commenters urge) would be far more lengthy than the time

allowed by CEA section 4a(a)(3), i.e., 180 or 270 days from enactment

of the Dodd-Frank Act.\47\ Because of the stringent time limits in CEA

section 4a(a)(2)(B), the Commission concludes that Congress did not

intend for the Commission to delay the imposition of limits until it

first made antecedent, contract-by-contract necessity findings.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\47\ Although the Commission did not meet these deadlines in its

first position limits rulemaking, it completed the task (in which

the Commission received and addressed more than 15,000 comments) as

expeditiously as possible under the circumstances.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96709]]

b. Prior Rulemaking Requiring Exchanges to Set Limits

The CFTC's preliminary interpretation of the statute is also based

in part on its promulgation of a rule in 1981 requiring exchanges to

impose limits on all contracts that did not already have limits. In

that rulemaking, the Commission, acting expressly pursuant to, inter

alia, what was then CEA section 4a(1) (predecessor to CEA section

4a(a)(1)), adopted what was then 17 CFR 1.61.\48\ This rule required

exchanges to set speculative position limits ``for each separate type

of contract for which delivery months are listed to trade'' on any DCM,

including ``contracts for future delivery of any commodity subject to

the rules of such contract market.'' \49\ The Commission explained that

this action would ``close the existing regulatory gap whereby some but

not all contract markets [we]re subject to a specified speculative

position limit.'' \50\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\48\ Establishment of Speculative Position Limits, 46 FR 50938,

50944-45, Oct. 16, 1981. The rule adopted in 1981 tracked, in

significant part, the language of CEA section 4a(1). Compare 17 CFR

1.61(a)(1) (1982) with 7 U.S.C. 6a(1) (1976).

\49\ Establishment of Speculative Position Limits, 46 FR at

50945.

\50\ Id. at 50939; see also id. at 50938 (``to ensure that each

futures and options contract traded on a designated contract market

will be subject to speculative position limits'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Like the Dodd-Frank Act, the 1981 final rule established (and the

rule release described) that such limits ``shall'' be established

according to what the Commission termed ``standards.'' \51\ As used in

the 1981 final rule and release, ``standards'' meant the criteria for

determining how the required limits would be set.\52\ ``Standards'' did

not include the antecedent ``necessity'' determination of whether to

order limits at all. The Commission had already made the antecedent

judgment in the rule that ``speculative limits are appropriate for all

contract markets irrespective of the characteristics of the underlying

market.'' \53\ The Commission further concluded that, with respect to

any particular market, the ``existence of historical trading data''

showing excessive speculation or other burdens on that market is not

``an essential prerequisite to the establishment of a speculative

limit.'' \54\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\51\ Compare id. at 50941-42, 50945 with 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(2)(A).

\52\ Establishment of Speculative Position Limits, 46 FR 50941-

42, 50945.

\53\ Id. at 50941-42 (preamble), 50945 (text of Sec.

1.61(a)(2)).

\54\ The Commission believes it likely that, given the

prophylactic purposes articulated in current CEA section

4a(a)(1)(A), a similar view of position limits underpins CEA section

4a(a)(2)(A).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission thus directed the exchanges to set limits for all

futures contracts ``pursuant to the . . . standards of rule 1.61,''

without requiring that the exchanges first make a finding of

necessity.\55\ And rule 1.61 incorporated the ``standards'' from then-

CEA-section 4a(1)--an ``Aggregation Standard'' (46 FR at 50943) for

applying the limits to positions both held and controlled by a trader,

and a flexibility standard allowing the exchanges to set ``different

and separate position limits for different types of futures contracts,

or for different delivery months, or from exempting positions which are

normally known in the trade as `spreads, straddles or arbitrage' or

from fixing limits which apply to such positions which are different

from limits fixed for other positions.'' \56\ Because the Commission

had already made the antecedent necessity findings, it imposed tight

deadlines for the exchanges to establish the limits. It is,

accordingly, reasonable to believe that Congress would have structured

CEA section 4a(a) similarly, by first making the antecedent necessity

determination on its own,\57\ then directing the Commission to impose

the limits without making an independent determination of necessity,

and then using the term ``standards'' just as the Commission did in

1981 to refer to aggregation and flexibility rather than necessity for

the required limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\55\ Establishment of Speculative Position Limits. 46 FR at

50942.

\56\ Id. at 50945 (Sec. 1.61(a)). Compare 7 U.S.C. 6a(1)

(1976).

\57\ As discussed in further detail regarding congressional

investigations, below, it is especially reasonable to infer that

Congress had in fact made such a determination based on the

congressional investigations that preceded these Dodd-Frank Act

amendments. The fact that the Commission already had the clear

authority to impose limits when it deemed them necessary bolsters

this inference, because there was no need for these Dodd-Frank Act

amendments to the position limits statute unless Congress, based on

its own determination of necessity, sought to direct the Commission

to impose limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Indeed, legislative history shows reason to believe that Congress'

choice of the word ``standards'' to refer to aggregation and

flexibility alone was purposeful and intended it to mean the same thing

it did in the Commission's 1981 rule.\58\ The language that ultimately

became section 737 of the Dodd-Frank Act, amending CEA section 4a(a),

originated in substantially final form in H.R. 977, introduced by

Representative Peterson, who was then Chairman of the House Agriculture

Committee and who would ultimately be a member of the Dodd-Frank Act

conference committee.\59\ In important respects, the language of H.R.

977 resembles the language the Commission used in 1981, suggesting that

the regulation's text may have influenced the statutory text. Like the

Commission's 1981 rule, H.R. 977 states that there ``shall'' be

position limits in accordance with the ``standards'' identified in CEA

section 4a(a).\60\ This language was included in CEA section 4a(a)(2)

as adopted. Also like the 1981 rule, H.R. 977 established (and the

Dodd-Frank Act ultimately adopted) a ``good faith'' exception for

positions acquired prior to the effective date of the mandated

limits.\61\ The committee report accompanying H.R. 977 described it as

``Mandat[ing] the CFTC to set speculative position limits'' and the

section-by-section analysis stated that the legislation ``requires the

CFTC to set appropriate position limits for all physical commodities

other than excluded commodities.'' \62\ This closely resembles the

omnibus prophylactic approach the Commission took in 1981, when the

Commission required the establishment of position limits on all futures

contracts according to ``standards'' it borrowed from CEA section

4a(1). The Commission views the history and interplay of the 1981 rule

and Dodd-Frank Act section 737 as further evidence that Congress

intended to follow much the same approach as the Commission did in

1981, mandating position limits as to all physical commodities.\63\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\58\ The relevant broader legislative history is discussed in

depth, below.

\59\ H.R. 977, 11th Cong. (2009).

\60\ 7 U.S.C. 6.

\61\ Compare H.R. 977, 11th Cong. (2009) with Establishment of

Speculative Position Limits, 46 FR at 50944.

\62\ H.Rept. 111-385, at 15, 19 (Dec. 19, 2009).

\63\ See Union Carbide Corp. & Subsidiaries v. Comm'r of

Internal Revenue, 697 F.3d 104, 109 (2d Cir. 2012) (explaining that

when an agency must resolve a statutory ambiguity, to do so ``with

the aid of reliable legislative history is rational and prudent''

(quoting Robert A. Katzman, Madison Lecture: Statutes, 87 N.Y.U. L.

Rev. 637, 659 (2012)).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

There is further evidence based on the 1981 rulemaking that

Congress would have found the across-the-board prophylactic approach

attractive. In 1983, when enacting the Futures Trading Act of 19982,

Public Law 97-444, 96 Stat. 2294 (1983), Congress was aware that the

Commission had ``promulgated a final rule requiring exchanges to submit

speculative position limit proposals for Commission approval for all

futures contracts traded as of that date.'' \64\ Presented with

competing industry and Commission proposals to amend the position

limits statute, Congress elected to amend the

[[Page 96710]]

CEA ``to clarify and strengthen the Commission's authority in this

area,'' including authorizing the Commission to prosecute violations of

exchange-set limits as if they were violations of the CEA.\65\ Thus, by

granting the Commission explicit authority to enforce the Commission-

mandated exchange-set limits, Congress in effect ratified the 1981

rule, finding it reasonable to impose position limits on an across-the

board basis, rather than following a commodity-by-commodity

determination. This contributes to the Commission's judgment that

Congress reasonably could have followed a similar approach here and,

for the reasons given elsewhere, likely did.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\64\ S. Rep. No. 97-384, at 44 (1982).

\65\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

c. Comments \66\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\66\ A list is provided below in Section V, Appendix B, of the

full names, abbreviations, dates and comment letter numbers for all

comment letters cited in this rulemaking. The Commission notes that

many commenters submitted more than one comment letter.

Additionally, all comment letters that pertain to the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal and the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, including non-substantive comment letters, are contained

in the rulemaking comment file and are available through the

Commission's Web site at http://comments.cftc.gov/PublicComments/CommentList.aspx?id=1708. A search can be done online for a

particular comment letters by inserting the specific comment letter

number in the address in place of the hash tags in the following web

address: http://comments.cftc.gov/PublicComments/ViewComment.aspx?id=#####&SearchText.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

i. Commission's Experience: No commenter disputed the depth or

breadth of the Commission's experience and expertise with position

limits.\67\ Most, if not all, commenters, many of them exchanges,

traders, and other market participants who have been subject to a long-

standing federal and exchange-set limit regime, implicitly or

explicitly agreed that at least spot-month position limits continue to

be essential to prevent manipulation and excessive volatility and thus

serve the public interest.\68\ One commenter acknowledged that only the

Commission can impose and monitor limits across exchanges.\69\ Another

opined that only the Commission could impose limits without any

conflicts of interest due to the exchanges' imperative to maximize

trading volume in order to maximize profit.\70\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\67\ One commenter questioned whether the Commission's

experience was even relevant. This commenter asserted that the

statute clearly and unambiguously does not mandate imposition of

position limits, and therefore no consideration or deference to the

Commission's experience is appropriate. CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 7.

But the district court disagreed and directed the Commission to

employ its experience in resolving the ambiguities in the statute.

887 F. Supp. 2d at 270, 280-82. In any event, for the reasons

discussed, the Commission's reading is, at a minimum, reasonable.

\68\ E.g., CL-CME-59718 at 2; see also CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 3,

27-32, App. A at 11, App. B at 6 (arguing for alternatives to limits

outside the spot month).

\69\ CL-CME-59718 at 18.

\70\ CL-CMOC-60400 at 3; and CL-Public Citizen-60390 at 2-3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Time to Establish Limits: No commenters disputed the fact that

it took many months for the Commission to make a necessity

determination before establishing limits. Some commenters agreed with

the determinations the Commission preliminarily drew from its

experience.\71\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\71\ E.g., CL-A4A-59714 at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters asserted that the Commission's reliance on the

timelines to support its view ignores other qualifying language in the

statute, such as the terms ``necessary'' and ``appropriate.'' \72\ The

Commission disagrees, because its interpretation of the statute

considers the relevant provisions as an integrated whole, which is

required in interpreting any statute. Under this approach, it is

appropriate to give consideration to the import of the tight statutory

deadlines in light of the Commission's experience that it could not

possibly comply with if it had to make necessity findings as it has in

the past. These comments fail to take these considerations into

account. The Commission addresses the language relied upon by these

commenters, infra, in its discussion of the text of the statute.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\72\ CL-CME-59718 at 7; and CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 9, n. 32

(asserting that deadlines are no excuse for the Commission to be

``arbitrary'' or ``sloppy.'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

CME also contended that the 180- and 270-day time limits were a

difficulty manufactured by the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

itself. According to CME, the Commission could instead expedite the

process for setting limits by utilizing its exchanges and others to

determine whether position limits are necessary and appropriate for a

particular commodity and, if so, the appropriate types and levels of

limits and related exemptions.\73\ While this is a plausible approach

to generating necessity findings, the Commission views it unlikely that

Congress had this approach in mind. The provisions at issue make no

mention of exchange-set limits or necessity findings. CME also gave no

reason to believe that commodity-by-commodity necessity findings could

be made by the exchanges within the prescribed 180/270 day limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\73\ CL-CME-59718 at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iii. 1981 Rulemaking: Some commenters disagreed with the

Commission's consideration of the 1981 Rule. CME commented that the

1981 Rule is inapposite because there the Commission was requiring DCMs

to impose position limits based on an ``antecedent judgment'' that

limits were necessary and appropriate; a necessity finding was not

required there.\74\ The Commission believes that CME's observation is

consistent with its interpretation. In the 1981 rule, the Commission

made an antecedent judgment on an across-the-board basis that position

limits were necessary, and the exchanges then set them according to

specific standards. Here, Congress has made the antecedent judgment on

an across-the-board basis that position limits are necessary for

physical commodities (i.e., commodities other than excluded

commodities), and ordered the Commission to set them according to the

same types of standards referenced in the 1981 rule. This supports,

rather than undermines, the Commission's interpretation that the

``standards'' in CEA section 4a(a)(1), referred to in CEA section

4a(a)(2) as added by the Dodd-Frank Act, are the flexibility and

aggregation standards, much as they were in the 1981 rulemaking

interpreting CEA section 4a(a)(1).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\74\ Id. at 9-10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters contended that the Commission's reliance on the

1981 rulemaking ignores that the CFTC then imposed limits only after a

fact-intensive inquiry into the characteristics of individual contracts

markets to determine the limits most appropriate for individual

contract markets.\75\ However, the Commission has taken those inquiries

into account. The Commission believes these inquiries are significant

because while the Commission performed such investigation for some

markets, it did not do so for all markets ultimately within the scope

of the rule. The 1981 Rule directed exchanges to impose limits on all

futures contracts for which exchanges had not already imposed limits.

For example, citing a then-recent disruption in the silver market, the

Commission directed that position limits be imposed prophylactically

for all futures and options contracts.\76\ It further directed the

exchanges to consider the characteristics of particular contracts and

markets in determining how to set limits (the standards, limit

[[Page 96711]]

levels and so on) but not whether to do so.\77\ It specifically

rejected commenters' concerns that position limits would not be

beneficial for all contracts, finding, after ``considerable years of

Federal and contract market regulatory experience,'' that ``the

capacity of any contract market . . . is not unlimited,'' and there was

no need to evaluate the particulars of whether any contract would

benefit from position limits.\78\ The Dodd-Frank Act amendments

unfolded in an analogous fashion. Prior to the Dodd-Frank Act, Congress

conducted studies of some, but not all, markets in physical

commodities. This history suggests that Congress extrapolated from the

conclusions reached in those studies to determine that position limits

were necessary for all physical commodities other than excluded

commodities.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\75\ CL-AMG-59709 at 4, n. 8; and CL-CME-59718 at 15-16.

\76\ Establishment of Speculative Position Limits, 46 FR at

50940-41 (Oct. 16, 1981).

\77\ Id.

\78\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ISDA and SIFMA asserted that the Commission's reliance on the 1981

rulemaking is unavailing because (1) it cannot alter the Commission's

statutory burdens with respect to imposing position limits; and (2) it

was never adopted by Congress.\79\ The first of these comments begs the

question, i.e., what is ``the statutory burden'' intended in the text

of CEA sections 4a(a)(1) and (2), read as a whole and considered in

context to resolve the ambiguity found by the district court. As to the

second comment, the Commission does not contend that Congress adopted

the 1981 rule. Rather, it is relevant because the language the district

court found ambiguous in the Dodd-Frank Act amendments to CEA section

4a(a) resembles the language of the 1981 rule, and some of the context

is parallel. The relevance of this rulemaking is supported by the fact

that Congress did ratify it the following year, when it amended the CEA

by granting the Commission the authority to enforce the position limits

set by the exchanges, reinforcing that as a historical matter Congress

had approved an omnibus prophylactic approach as reasonable. That

Congress had approved of such an approach before and then used language

in the Dodd-Frank Act that closely resembles the very language the

Commission used when it mandated that omnibus approach is another

factor that weighs on the side of interpreting the statutory ambiguity

to find a mandate to impose physical commodity positon limits.\80\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\79\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 9.

\80\ CFTC v. Schor, 478 U.S. 833, 846 (1986).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Finally, several commenters asserted that the Commission cannot

consider the 1981 rulemaking because the Commission later allowed

exchanges to set position accountability levels in lieu of limits for

some commodities and contracts.\81\ Those later exemptions do not,

however, alter the language or import of the 1981 rule, which directed

the exchanges to impose limits in accordance with ``standards'' that

did not include a necessity finding. The 1981 rulemaking is the last

time the Commission definitively addressed and identified the

``standards'' in CEA section 4a(a)(1) for imposing across-the-board,

prophylactic position limits in a manner akin to the Dodd-Frank Act

amendments. That other approaches intervened is not inconsistent with

the inference that Congress was influenced by the 1981 rulemaking in

the Dodd-Frank Act amendments.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\81\ E.g., CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 9; and CL-AMG-59709 at 4, n.8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

4. Legislative History of the Dodd-Frank Act Amendments to Position

Limits Statute

As discussed in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission has also considered the legislative history of the Dodd-

Frank Act amendments.\82\ That history contains further indication that

Congress intended to mandate the imposition of limits for physical

commodity derivatives without requiring the Commission to make

antecedent necessity findings, and did not intend the term

``standards'' to include such a finding.\83\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\82\ Union Carbide Corp. & Subsidiaries v. Comm'r of Internal

Revenue, 697 F.3d 104, 109 (2d Cir. 2012) (explaining that when an

agency must resolve a statutory ambiguity, to do so ``with the aid

of reliable legislative history is rational and prudent'' (quoting

Robert A. Katzman, Madison Lecture: Statutes, 87 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 637,

659 (2012)).

\83\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75682,

75684-85.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission's preliminary interpretation of CEA section 4a(a)(2)

is based in part on congressional concerns that arose, and

congressional actions taken, before the passage of the Dodd-Frank Act

amendments.\84\ During the 1990s, the Commission began permitting

exchanges to experiment with an alternative to position limits--

position accountability, which allowed a trader to hold large positions

subject to reporting requirements and gave the exchange the right to

order the trader to hold or reduce its position.\85\ Then, in the

Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000 (``CFMA''),\86\ Congress

expressly authorized the use of position accountability as an

alternative means to limit speculative positions.\87\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\84\ Id. at 75682.

\85\ Federal Speculative Position Limits for Referenced Energy

Contracts and Associated Regulations, 75 FR 4144, 4147 (Jan. 26,

2010); Revision of Federal Speculative Position Limits and

Associated Rules, 64 FR 24038, 24048-49 (May 5, 1999).

\86\ Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000, Public Law

106-554, 114 Stat. 2763 (Dec. 21, 2000).

\87\ 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(3) (2009).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Following this experiment with position accountability, Congress

became concerned about fluctuations in commodity prices. In the late

1990s and 2000s, Congress conducted several investigations that

concluded that excessive speculation accounted for significant

volatility and price increases in physical commodity markets. For

example, a congressional investigation determined that prices of crude

oil had risen precipitously and that ``[t]he traditional forces of

supply and demand cannot fully account for these increases.'' \88\ The

investigation found evidence suggesting that speculation was

responsible for an increase of as much as $20-25 per barrel of crude

oil, which was then at $70.\89\ Subsequently, Congress found similar

price volatility stemming from excessive speculation in the natural gas

market.\90\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\88\ The Role of Market Speculation in Rising Oil and Gas

Prices: A Need to Put the Cop Back on the Beat, Staff Report,

Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations of the Senate Committee on

Homeland Security and Governmental Affairs, U.S. Senate, S. Prt. No.

109-65 at 1 (June 27, 2006).

\89\ Id. at 12; see also Excessive Speculation in the Natural

Gas Market, Staff Report, Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations

of the Senate Committee on Homeland Security and Governmental

Affairs, U.S. Senate at 1 (June 25, 2007), available at http://www.levin.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/supporting/2007/PSI.Amaranth.062507.pdf (last visited Mar. 18, 2013) (``Gas

Report'').

\90\ Gas Report at 1-2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

These investigations appear to have informed the drafting of the

Dodd-Frank Act. During hearings prior to the passage of the Dodd-Frank

Act, Senator Carl Levin, then-Chair of the Senate Permanent

Subcommittee on Investigations that had conducted them, urged passage

to ensure ``a cop on the beat in all commodity markets where U.S.

commodities are traded . . . that can enforce the law to prevent

excessive speculation and market manipulation.'' \91\ In addition,

Congress viewed the nearly $600 trillion little-regulated swaps market

as a ``major contributor to the financial crisis'' because excessive

risk taking, hidden leverage, and under collateralization in that

market created a systemic risk of harm to the entire financial

system.\92\ As Senator Cantwell and others explained, it was imperative

that the CFTC have the ability to regulate swaps through

[[Page 96712]]

``position limits,'' ``exchange trading,'' and ``public transparency''

to avoid a recurrence of the instability that rippled through the

entire financial system in 2008.\93\ And in the House of

Representatives, Representative Collin Peterson, then-Chairman of the

House Committee on Agriculture and author of an amendment strengthening

the position limits provision as discussed below, reminded his

colleagues that his committee's own ``in-depth review of derivative

markets began when we experienced significant price volatility in

energy futures markets due to excessive speculation--first with natural

gas and then with crude oil. We all remember when we had $147 oil. . .

. This conference report [now] includes the tools we authorized and the

direction to the CFTC to mitigate outrageous price spikes we saw 2

years ago.'' \94\ Congress's focus in its investigations on excessive

speculation involving physical commodities is reflected in the scope of

the Dodd-Frank Act's position limits amendment: It applies only to

physical commodities.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\91\ 156 Cong. Record S. 4064 (daily ed. May 20, 2010).

\92\ S. Rep. 111-176, at 29 (2010).

\93\ See, e.g., 156 Cong. Rec. S 2676-78, S 2698-99, S 3606-07,

S 3966, S 5919 (daily ed. April 27, May 12, 19, July 15, 2010

(providing statements of Senators Cantwell, Feinstein, Lincoln)).

\94\ 156 Cong. Rec. H5245 (daily ed. June 30, 2010) (emphasis

added).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The evolution of the position limits provision in the bills before

Congress from permissive to mandatory supports a preliminary

determination that Congress intended to do something more than continue

the long-standing statutory regime giving the Commission discretionary

authority to impose limits.\95\ As initially introduced, the House bill

that became the Dodd-Frank Act provided the Commission with

discretionary authority to issue position limits, stating that the

Commission ``may'' impose them.\96\ However, the House replaced the

word ``may'' with the word ``shall,'' suggesting a specific judgment

that the limits should be mandatory, not discretionary. The House also

added other language militating in favor of interpreting CEA section

4a(a)(2) as a mandate. In two new subsections, it set the tight

deadlines described above.\97\ After changing ``may'' to ``shall,'' the

House further amended the bill to refer in one instance to the limits

for agricultural and exempt commodities as ``required.'' \98\ And only

after the language had changed from permissive to mandatory, the House

added the requirement that the Commission conduct studies on the

``effects (if any) of position limits imposed'' \99\ to determine if

the required position limits were harming U.S. markets.\100\

Underscoring its intent to amend the bill to include a mandate, the

House Report accompanying the House Bill stated that it ``required''

the Commission to impose limits.\101\ The Conference Committee adopted

the House bill's amended provisions on position limits and then

strengthened them even further by referring to the position limits as

``required'' an additional three times, bringing the total to four

times in the final legislation the number of references in statutory

text to position limits as ``required.'' \102\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\95\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75684-85.

\96\ Initially, the House used the word ``may'' to permit the

Commission to impose aggregate positions on contracts based upon the

same underlying commodity. See H.R. 4173, 11th Cong. 3113(a)(2)

(providing the version introduced in the House, Dec. 2, 2009)

(``Introduced Bill''); see also Brief of Senator Levin et al as

Amicus Curiae at 10-11, ISDA v. CFTC, no. 12-5362 (D.C. Cir. Apr.

22, 2013), Document No. 1432046 (hereafter ``Levine Br.'').

\97\ Levin Br. at 11 (citing H.R. 4173, 111th Cong.

3113(a)(5)(2), (7) (as passed by the House Dec. 11, 2009)

(``Engrossed Bill'')).

\98\ Id. at 12. (citing Engrossed Bill at 3113(a)(5)(3)).

\99\ 15 U.S.C. 8307; Engrossed Bill at 3005(a).

\100\ See Levin Br. at 13-17; see also DVD: October 21, 2009

Business Meeting (House Agriculture Committee 2009), ISDA v. CFTC,

Dkt. 37-2 Exh. B (Apr. 13, 2012) at 59:55-1:02:18.

\101\ Levin Br. at 23 (citing H.R. Rep. No. 111-373 at 11

(2009)).

\102\ Levin Br. at 17-18.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. Comments

A number of commenters generally supported or opposed the

Commission's consideration of Congressional investigations and the

textual strengthening of the Dodd-Frank bill. The Commission addresses

specific comments below.

i. Congressional Investigations: Several commenters agreed that the

Congressional investigations, hearings and reports support the view

that Congress decided to mandate position limits.\103\ They pointed out

that Congress's investigations followed amendments in 2000 to the CEA

as part of the CFMA that exempted swaps and energy derivatives from

position limits and expressly authorized exchanges to impose position

accountability levels in lieu of limits.\104\ According to the

Commodity Markets Oversight Coalition (``CMOC''), ``witnesses confirmed

[at those hearings] that the erosion of the position limits regime was

a leading cause in market instability and wild price swings.'' \105\

Senator Levin, who presided over the investigations, commented that

those investigations, conducted from 2002 onwards, ``into how our

commodity markets function, focusing in particular on the role of

excessive speculation on commodity prices'' ``have demonstrated that

the failure to impose and enforce effective position limits have led to

greater speculation and increased price volatility in U.S. commodity

markets.'' \106\ According to Senator Levin, the investigations

``provide[d] strong support for the Dodd-Frank decision to require the

Commission to impose position limits on all types of commodity futures,

swaps, and options.'' \107\ Senator Levin also stated that the harms of

excessive speculation continue to be felt in the absence of the

mandated limits. He cited recent actions by federal regulators to stop

manipulation in energy markets, and opined that the continuing problems

in the absence of the mandated limits only reinforce the reasonableness

of the Commission's view that Congress intended to mandate position

limits as a prophylactic measure.\108\ Senator Levin's point was echoed

by Public Citizen, a consumer advocacy organization, and Airlines for

America, a trade association for the U.S. scheduled airline

industry.\109\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\103\ CL-CMOC-59720 at 2; CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 2-5; and CL-

A4A-59686 at 2-3.

\104\ CL-IECA-59964 at 2; CL-A4A-59686 at 2; and CL-Public

Citizen-59648 at 2-3.

\105\ CL-CMOC-59720 at 2.

\106\ CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 3-4.

\107\ Id.

\108\ Id. at 2.

\109\ CL-Public Citizen-59648 at 2-3, and CL-A4A-59686 at 1-2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Other commenters disagreed with the Commission's preliminary

determination that the Congressional investigations indicate that

Congress intended to mandate limits. CME asserted that the

investigations do not in themselves demonstrate that Congress required

the CFTC to impose position limits as recommended even if those

investigations suggest that excessive speculation poses a burden on

interstate commerce in certain physical commodity markets.\110\ Citadel

questioned whether the cited reports could be ``broadly indicative of

Congressional intent,'' or could ``redefine statutory language that has

existed for nearly eight decades.'' \111\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\110\ CL-CME-59718 at 8. CME also asserted that the

Congressional investigation into excessive speculation in natural

gas futures focused more on the fact that position accountability

rules for exchange-traded natural gas futures were not in place for

``look-alike'' natural gas swaps traded ``over the counter,''

permitting regulatory arbitrage.

\111\ CL-Citadel-59717 at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

But the Commission is not relying solely on these reports. The

question, rather, is whether these Congressional

[[Page 96713]]

investigations and findings of excessive speculation and price

volatility in energy markets, conducted and issued when the Commission

was authorized but not required by law to impose limits, may be one

indication, among others, that Congress sought to do something more

with the Dodd-Frank Act amendments than to maintain the statutory

status quo for futures on physical commodities. In the Commission's

preliminary view, it is more plausible, based on these investigations,

that Congress sought to do something more--to require that the

Commission impose limits for the covered commodities without having to

first find that they are necessary to prevent excessive speculation.

Contrary to Citadel's comment, the Commission is not relying on the

investigations and reports to redefine statutory language that has

existed for nearly eight decades. Rather, the Commission believes that

the investigations favor the conclusion that Congress added CEA section

4a(a)(2) to the pre-existing language in order to strengthen the long-

standing position limits regime for a category of commodity

derivatives--physical commodities--that Congress's investigations

revealed to be vulnerable to substantial price fluctuations.

ii. Evolution of the Dodd-Frank Bill: Several commenters agreed

with the Commission's preliminary determination that the strengthening

of the position limits language in the Dodd-Frank bill evinces

Congress' intent to mandate limits.\112\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\112\ CL-Public Citizen-59648 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

CME and MFA disagreed; while they do not directly address this

point, they believed that the strengthening of the language in the

Dodd-Frank bills does not indicate that Congress intended to de-couple

the enacted directive to impose position limits from the necessity

finding of CEA section 4a(a)(1).\113\ The Commission, however,

preliminarily considers this the most plausible interpretation. The

evolution of the bill from one stating the Commission ``may'' impose

position limits to include statements that the Commission ``shall''

impose them, that they are ``required,'' and that the Commission shall

study their effects indicates intentional progressive refinement from a

bill that would continue the status quo for futures to one that added

special nondiscretionary requirements for a category of commodities.

This legislative evolution also supports the conclusion ``standards''

does not include an antecedent necessity finding.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\113\ CL-CME-59718 at 2, 5-12 (maintaining statutory language

requires necessity finding); and CL-MFA-59606 at 9 (citing S. Rept.

111-176 (Apr. 30, 2010, which states ``[t]his section authorizes the

CFTC to establish aggregate position limits. . . .'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

5. The Commission Preliminarily Interprets the Text of CEA Section

4a(a) as an Integrated Whole, In Light of Its Experience and Expertise.

In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

discussed how its interpretation of the text of CEA section 4a(a),

considered as an integrated whole, is consistent with and supports its

conclusions based on experience and expertise. As discussed, the

ambiguity is the meaning of CEA section 4a(a)(2)'s statement that the

Commission ``shall'' establish limits on physical commodities other

than excluded commodities ``[i]n accordance with the standards'' set

forth in CEA section 4a(a)(1). If ``standards'' includes a necessity

finding, then a necessity finding is required before limits can be

imposed on agricultural and exempt commodities. If not, the Commission

must impose limits for that subset of commodity derivatives. In the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission resolved the

ambiguity by preliminarily determining that the reference in CEA

section 4a(a)(2) to the ``standards'' in pre-Dodd-Frank section

4a(a)(1) refers to the criteria in CEA section 4a(a)(1) for how the

required limits are to be set and not the antecedent finding whether

limits are even necessary. The Commission explained that, in its

preliminary view, ``standards'' refers to, in CEA section 4a(a)(1),

only the following two provisions. First, the limits must account for

situations in which one person controls another or two persons act in

concert, by aggregating those positions as if the trading were done by

one person acting alone (aggregation). The second ``standard'' in CEA

section 4a(a)(1) states that the limits may be different for different

commodities, markets, delivery months, etc. (flexibility).

The Commission reasoned that this construction of ``standards''

seemed most consistent with the Commission's experience and history

administering position limits. It also seemed most consistent with the

text of CEA section 4a(a)(2), the rest of CEA section 4a(a), and the

Act as a whole. The Dodd-Frank Act amendments to CEA section 4a(a)

largely re-shape CEA section 4a(a) by adding a new, detailed, and

comprehensive section 4a(a)(2) that applies only to a subset of the

derivatives regulated by the Commission--physical commodities like

wheat, oil, and gold--and not intangible commodities like interest

rates. Amended CEA section 4a(a) repeatedly uses the word ``shall'' and

refers to the new limits as ``required,'' differentiating it from the

text that existed before the Dodd-Frank Act.\114\ Never before in the

Commission's experience had Congress set deadlines on action for

position limits by a date certain, much less the short time provided in

CEA section 4a(a)(2)(B).\115\ Nor, in the Commission's experience, had

Congress required a report by a given date or committed itself to hold

hearings on the report within 30 days thereafter.\116\ The Commission

preliminarily concluded that, considered as a whole in light of this

experience, these provisions evince a Congressional mandate that the

Commission impose limits on physical commodities, that it do so

quickly, that it impose limit levels in accordance with certain

requirements, and that it study the effectiveness of the limits after

imposing them and then report to Congress.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\114\ E.g., CEA sections 4a(a)(2)(A) (providing that the

Commission ``shall'' set the limits); 4a(a)(2)(B) (referring twice

to the ``limits required'' and directing that they ``shall'' be

established by a time certain); 4a(a)(3)(referring to the limits

``required'' under subparagraph (A)); 4a(a)(5)(stating that the

Commission ``shall'' concurrently establish limits on economically

equivalent contracts).

\115\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(2(B).

\116\ 15 U.S.C. 8307.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

By the same token, the Commission preliminarily determined that

interpreting CEA section 4a(a)(2) as it proposed to do would not render

superfluous the necessity finding requirement in CEA section 4a(a)

because that section still applies to the non-physical (excluded)

commodity derivatives that are not subject to CEA section 4a(a)(2). Nor

would it nullify other parts of CEA section 4a(a), as those are

unaffected by this reading.

The Commission received a number of comments on its discussion of

the interplay between the statute's text and the Commission's

experience and expertise. The Commission has considered them carefully,

but is not thus far persuaded. The Commission preliminarily believes

that it is a reasonable interpretation of the text of the statute

considered as an integrated whole and viewed through the lens of the

Commission's experience and expertise, that Congress mandated that the

Commission establish position limits for physical commodities. It is

also reasonable to construe the reference to ``standards'' as an

instruction to the Commission to apply the flexibility and aggregation

standards set forth in CEA section 4a(a)(1), just as the Commission

instructed the exchanges to impose

[[Page 96714]]

omnibus limits in 1981. And it is at least reasonable to conclude that

Congress, in directing the Commission to impose the ``required'' limits

on extremely tight deadlines, did not intend the Commission to

independently make an antecedent finding that any given position limit

for physical commodities is ``necessary''--a finding that would take

many months for each individual physical commodity contract.

a. Comments

Several commenters disputed the Commission's interpretation, based

on its experience and expertise, that CEA section 4a(a)(2) is a mandate

for prophylactic limits based on their view that the statute

unambiguously requires the Commission to promulgate position limits

only after making a necessity finding, and only ``as appropriate.''

\117\ But in ISDA v. SIFMA, the district court held that the statute

was ambiguous in this respect, and the Commission here is following the

court's direction to apply its experience and expertise to resolve the

ambiguity. This is consistent with a commenter's statement that ``the

meshing of the Dodd-Frank Act into the CEA may have created some

ambiguity from a technical drafting/wording standpoint.'' \118\

Nevertheless, the Commission addresses these textual arguments to show

that its preliminary interpretation is, at a minimum, a permissible

one.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\117\ CL-CME-59718 at 11; CL-MFA-59606. at 9; etc. But see,

e.g., CL-A4A-59714 at 2-3 (noting that notwithstanding the

``meshing'' problems, ``it is clear that the Commission's

interpretation is reasonable and fully supported by the context in

which the Dodd-Frank Act was passed, its legislative history, and

the many other factors identified in the NPRM''); CL-AFR-59685 at 1;

CL-Public Citizen-60390 at 2; CL-Public Citizen-59648 at 2; CL-Sen.

Levin-59637 at 4; and CL-CMOC-59720 at 2-3.

\118\ CL-A4A-59714 at 2-3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The commenters that disagreed with the Commission's preliminary

conclusion argued that the Commission: (i) Erred in determining that

the reference to ``standards'' in CEA section 4a(a)(2) does not include

the necessity finding in CEA section 4a(a)(1); (ii) failed to consider

other provisions that show Congress intended to require the Commission

to make antecedent findings; and (iii) incorrectly determined that its

interpretation is the only way to give effect to CEA section 4a(a)(2).

i. Meaning of Standards: Several commenters asserted that the

language: ``[in] accordance with the standards set forth in paragraph

(1)'' in section 4a(a)(2) must include the phrase ``as the Commission

finds are necessary to diminish, eliminate, or prevent [the burden on

interstate commerce]'' in CEA section 4a(a)(1).\119\ They believed that

the Commission's contrary interpretation constitutes an implied repeal

of the necessity finding language.\120\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\119\ See, e.g., CL-CME-59718 at 12-13; CL-Citadel-59717 at 3-4;

CL-AMG-59709 at 3; CL-MFA-59606 at 9-10; CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 5-7;

CL-IECAssn-59679 at 3-4; and CL-FIA-59595 at 6-7.

\120\ CL-CME-59718 at 2, 12 (citing Hunter v. FERC, 711 F.3d 155

(D.C. Cir. 2013)).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission disagrees that this constitutes an implied repeal.

First, CEA section 4a(a)(2) applies only to physical commodities, not

other commodities. Accordingly, the requirement of a necessity finding

in section 4a(a)(1) still applies to a broad swath of commodity

derivatives. Second, there is no implied repeal even in part, because

the Commission is interpreting express language--the term

``standards.'' The Commission must bring its experience to bear when

interpreting the ambiguity in the new provision, and the Commission

preliminarily believes that the statute, read in light of the

Commission's experience administering position limits and making

necessity findings, is more reasonably read as an express limited

exception, for physical commodities futures and economically equivalent

swaps, to the preexisting authorization in CEA section 4a(a)(1) for the

Commission to impose limits when it finds them necessary.

ii. Other Limiting Language: Some commenters pointed to a number of

terms and provisions that they say support the notion that the

Commission must make antecedent findings before imposing any limits

under new CEA section 4a(a)(2).

First, some commenters asserted that the term ``as appropriate'' in

CEA sections 4a(a)(3) (factors that the ``Commission, ``as

appropriate'' must consider when it ``shall set limits'') and

4a(a)(5)(A) (providing that Commission ``shall'' ``as appropriate''

establish limits on swaps that are economically equivalent to physical

commodity futures and options) require the Commission to make

antecedent findings that the limits required under CEA section 4a(a)(2)

are appropriate before it may impose them.\121\ The district court

found these words to be ambiguous. In the court's view, they could

refer to the Commission's obligation to impose limits (i.e., the

Commission shall, ``as appropriate,'' impose limits), or to the level

of the limits the Commission is to impose.\122\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\121\ See, e.g., CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 5, 7-8 (citing CEA

section 4a(a)(5) as authorizing aggregate position limits ``as

appropriate'' for swaps that are economically equivalent to DCM

futures and options and CEA section 4a(a)(3), which directs the

Commission to set position limits as appropriate and to the maximum

extent practicable, in its discretion: (i) To diminish, eliminate,

or prevent excessive speculation; (ii) to deter and prevent market

manipulation, squeezes, and corners; (iii) to ensure sufficient

market liquidity for bona fide hedgers; and (iv) to ensure that the

price discovery function of the underlying market is not

disrupted.).

\122\ 887 F.Supp. 2d at 278; December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, 78 FR at 75685, n. 59.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission preliminarily believes that when these words are

considered in the context of CEA section 4a(a)(2)-(7) as a whole,

including the multiple uses of the new terms ``shall'' and ``required''

and the historically unique stringent time limits for imposing the

covered limits and post-imposition study requirement, it is more

reasonable to interpret these words as referring to the level of

limits, i.e., the Commission must set physical commodity limits at an

appropriate level, and not to require the Commission to first determine

whether the required limits are appropriate before it may even impose

them.\123\ In other words, while Congress made the threshold decision

to impose position limits on physical commodity futures and options and

economically equivalent swaps, Congress at the same time delegated to

the Commission the task of setting the limits at levels that would

maximize Congress' objectives.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\123\ CEA section 4a(a)(2)(A) provides that the Commission

``shall'' establish limits; CEA section 4a(a)(2)(B) refers multiple

times to the ``required'' limits in (A) that ``shall'' be

established within 180 or 270 days of enactment of Dodd-Frank; and

CEA section 4a(a)(2)(C) provides that ``[i]n establishing the limits

required'' the Commission shall ``strive to ensure'' that trading on

foreign boards of trade for commodities that have limits will be

subject to ``comparable limits,'' thereby assuming that limits must

be established and requiring that they be set at levels in

accordance with particular considerations. CEA section 4a(a)(3)

contains ``specific limitations'' on the ``required'' limits which

are most reasonably understood to be considerations for the

Commission for the levels of limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some commenters claimed that other parts of CEA section 4a(a)(2)

undermine the Commission's determination. First, CEA section 4a(2)(C)

states that the ``[g]oal . . . [i]n establishing the limits required''

is to ``strive to ensure'' that trading on foreign boards of trade

(``FBOTs'') for commodities that have limits will be subject to

``comparable limits.'' It goes on to state that for ``any limits to be

imposed'' the Commission will strive to ensure that they not shift

trading overseas. Commenters argue that ``any limits to be imposed''

under CEA section 4a(a)(2)(A) implies that limits might not be imposed

under that section. However, in the context discussed and in view of

the reference in that section to position limits

[[Page 96715]]

``required,'' the reference to ``any limits to be imposed'' refers

again to the levels or other standards applied. That is, whatever the

contours the Commission chooses for the required limits, they must meet

the goal set forth in that section.

Second, CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B) states certain factors that the

Commission must consider in setting limits under CEA section

4a(a)(2).\124\ The Commission sees no inconsistency with mandatory

position limits--the Commission must consider these factors in setting

the appropriate levels and other contours. Indeed, CEA section

4a(a)(3)(B) applies by its own terms to ``establishing the limits

required in paragraph (2).'' Moreover, consideration of these factors

under CEA section 4a(a)(3) is not mandatory, as some commenters

suggest,\125\ but rather to be made ``in [the Commission's]

discretion.'' \126\ In the Commission's preliminary view, there is thus

nothing in these provisions at odds with the Commission's

interpretation that it is required by CEA section 4a(a)(2)(A) to impose

limits on a subset of commodities without making antecedent findings

whether they should be imposed, particularly when the language at issue

is construed, as it should be, with other terms in CEA section

4a(a)(2)-(7), discussed above, that use mandatory language and impose

time limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\124\ See, e.g., CL-CME-59718 at 11, 13-17, and CL-FIA-59595 at

5-6.

\125\ See, e.g., CL-AMG-59709 at 3; and CL-CME-59718 at 13-17.

\126\ CEA section 4a(a)(3), 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(3).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some commenters stated that two pre-Dodd Frank Act provisions in

CEA section 4a undermine the Commission's interpretation. The first is

CEA section 4a(e),which states, ``if the Commission shall have fixed

limits . . . for any contract . . . , then the limits'' imposed by

DCMs, SEFs or other trading facilities ``shall not be higher than the

limits fixed by Commission.'' \127\ According to a commenter, the ``if/

then'' formulation suggests position limits should not be presupposed

for any contract.\128\ The Commission sees the provision differently.

CEA section 4a(a)(2) applies only to a subset of futures contracts--

contracts in physical commodities. For other commodities, position

limits remain subject to the Commission's determination of necessity,

and the ``if/then'' formulation applies and remains logical. There is,

accordingly, no inconsistency.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\127\ CEA section 4a(e), 7 U.S.C. 6a(e).

\128\ CL-CME-59718 at 10 (citing CEA section 4a(e)).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The second pre-Dodd Frank Act provision the commenters mentioned is

CEA section 5(d)(5); \129\ it gives the exchanges discretionary

authority to impose position limits on all commodity derivatives ``as

is necessary and appropriate.'' \130\ There is, however, no

inconsistency. Exchanges retain the discretionary authority to set

position limits for the many commodities not covered by CEA section

4a(a)(2), and they retain the discretion to impose position limits for

physical commodities, so long as the limits are no higher than federal

position limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\129\ 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(5).

\130\ CL-CME-59718 at 11 (citing 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(5)).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some commenters cited other language in CEA section 5(d)(5) to

support their assertion that, notwithstanding the Dodd-Frank Act

amendments discussed above requiring the Commission to impose limits,

the Commission retains and should exercise its discretion to impose

position accountability levels in lieu of limits or delegate that

authority exchanges to do so. CEA section 5(d)(5) authorizes exchanges

to adopt ``position limitations or position accountability'' levels in

order to reduce the threat of manipulation and congestion. These

commenters also pointed out that the Commission has previously endorsed

accountability levels for exchanges in lieu of limits.\131\ Other

commenters disagree. They asserted that, given what they interpret as a

mandate in CEA section 4a(a)(2) for the Commission to impose position

limits for physical commodities, it would be inappropriate for the

Commission to consider imposing position accountability levels instead

for those commodities, or to allow exchanges to do so.\132\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\131\ CL-CME-59718 at 10; CL-AMG-59709 5-6; CL-FIA-59595 at 12-

13; CL-FIA-60392 at 4-6, 8 (asserting that under the Commission's

general rulemaking authority in CEA section 8a(5), 7 U.S.C. 12a(5),

``the Commission has the power to adopt, as part of an

accountability regime, a rule pursuant to which it or a DCM could

direct a market participant to reduce speculative positions above an

accountability limit because that authority is `reasonably necessary

to effectuate' a position accountability rule,'' and observing that

the Commission previously determined in rulemakings that exchange-

set accountability levels represent an alternative means to limit

excessive speculation); CL-FIA-60303 at 3-4; CL-DBCS-59569 at 4; CL-

MFA-60385 at 7-8, 10-14; and CL-Olam-59658 at 1-2 (declaring that

the Commission can and should permit exchanges to administer

position accountability levels in lieu of Commission-set limits

under CEA section 4a(a)(2)).

\132\ CL-Public Citizen-60390 at 3-4 (noting other concerns with

exchange set limits or accountability levels); CL-IECA 60389 at 3-4

(asserting that the Commission should not cede its authority to

exchanges); CL-AFR-60953 at 4; CL-A4A-59686 at 2-3; CL-IECA-59671 at

2; and CL-CMOC-59720 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission agrees with the latter group of commenters and finds

the former reading strained. CEA section 4a(a)(2) makes no mention of

position accountability levels. Regardless whether pre-Dodd Frank

section 5(d)(5) allows exchanges to set accountability levels in lieu

of limits where the Commission has not set limits, and regardless

whether the Commission has in the past endorsed exchange-set position

accountability levels in lieu of limits, CEA section 4a(a)(2) does not

mention that tool. If anything, reference to accountability levels

elsewhere in the CEA shows that Congress understands that exchanges

have used position accountability, but made no reference to it in

amended CEA section 4a(a).

iii. Avoiding Surplusage or Nullity: Several commenters took issue

with the Commission's preliminary determination that its interpretation

is necessary in order to avoid rendering CEA section 4a(a)(2)(A)

surplusage. These commenters suggested that reading the term

``standards'' in CEA section 4a(a)(2)(A) to include the antecedent

necessity finding in CEA section 4a(a)(1) will not render CEA section

4a(a)(2) surplusage because if the Commission finds a position limit is

``necessary'' and ``appropriate,'' it now must impose one (as opposed

to pre-Dodd-Frank, when the Commission had authority but not a mandate

under CEA section 4a(a) to impose limits).\133\ The Commission finds

this reading highly unlikely. There is no history of the Commission

determining that limits are necessary and appropriate, but then

declining to impose them. Nor is it reasonable to expect that the

Commission might do so. Indeed, historically necessity findings were

made only in connection with establishing limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\133\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 5; and CL-MFA-59606 at 9-10. The

District Court expressed the same concern. 887 F. Supp. 2d at 274-

75.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Furthermore, if Congress had still wanted to leave it to the

Commission to ultimately decide whether a limit was necessary, there is

no reason for it to have also set tight deadlines, repeat multiple

times that the limits are ``required,'' and direct the agency to

conduct a study after the limits were imposed. In other words,

requiring the Commission to make an antecedent necessity finding would

render many of the Dodd-Frank Act amendments superfluous. For example,

if the Commission determined limits were not necessary then, contrary

to CEA section 4a(a)(2), no limits were in fact ``required,'' no limits

needed to be imposed by the deadlines, and no study

[[Page 96716]]

needed to be conducted. But none of these provisions were phrased in

conditional terms (e.g., if the Commission finds a limit necessary,

then it shall . . . ). Had Congress wanted the Commission to continue

to be the decisionmaker regarding the need for limits, it could have

expressed that view in countless ways that would not strain the

statutory language in this way.

CME contended that the Commission's position--that requiring a

necessity finding would essentially give the Commission the same

permissive authority it had before the Dodd-Frank Act amendments--is

``short-sighted'' because other provisions of CEA section 4a(a) ``would

still have practical significance.'' In support of this view, CME

stated that new CEA sections 4a(a)(2)(C) and 4(a)(3)(B) have

significance even if the Commission is required to make a necessity

finding because they ``set forth safeguards that the CFTC must balance

when it establishes limits'' after ``the CFTC finds that such limits

are necessary.'' The Commission preliminarily believes it unlikely that

Congress would have intended that. On CME's reading, the statute would

place additional requirements to constrain the Commission's preexisting

authority. Given the background for the amendments, particularly the

studies that preceded the Dodd-Frank Act, the Commission sees no reason

why Congress would have placed additional constraints, nor any reason

it would have placed them with respect to physical commodities but not

excluded commodities or others. This comment also does not address the

thrust of the Commission's interpretation, which is that finding a

mandate is the only way to read the entirety of the statute

harmoniously, including the timing requirements of CEA section

4a(a)(2)(B) and the reporting requirements of Section 719 of the Dodd-

Frank Act, account for the historical context, and, at the same time,

avoid reading CEA section 4a(a)(2)(A) as the functional equivalent of

CEA section 4a(a)(1).\134\ CME also cited CEA section 4a(a)(5), which

requires position limits for economically equivalent swaps, to make the

same point that there are still meaningful provisions in CEA section

4a(a), even with a necessity finding. But CEA section 4a(a)(1) already

authorizes the Commission to establish limits on swaps as necessary,

and so the authority, which would be discretionary under CME's reading,

to impose limits on economically equivalent swaps would add nothing to

the statute and the amendment would be wholly superfluous.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\134\ In this vein, then-Commissioner Mark Wetjen, who was an

aide to Senate Majority Leader Harry Reid during the Dodd-Frank

legislative process, stated at the Commission's public meeting to

adopt the December 2013 proposal that to read Section 4a(a)(2)(A) to

require the same antecedent necessity finding as Section 4a(a)(1)

``does not comport with my understanding of the statute's intent as

informed by my experience working as a Senate aide during

consideration of these provisions.'' Statement of Commissioner Mark

Wetjen, Public Meeting of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission

(Nov. 5, 2013), http://www.cftc.gov/PressRoom/SpeechesTestimony/wetjenstatement110513.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

6. Conclusion

Having carefully considered the text, purpose and legislative

history of CEA section 4a(a) as a whole, along with its own experience

and expertise and the comments on its proposed interpretation, the

Commission preliminarily believes for the reasons above that Congress--

while not expressing itself with ideal clarity--decided that position

limits were necessary for a subset of commodities, physical

commodities, mandated the Commission to impose them on those

commodities in accordance with certain criteria, and required that the

Commission do so expeditiously, without first making antecedent

findings that they are necessary to prevent excessive speculation.

Consistent with this interpretation, Congress also directed the agency

to report back to Congress on their effectiveness within one year. In

the Commission's preliminary view, this interpretation, even if not the

only possible interpretation, best gives effect to the text and purpose

of the Dodd-Frank Act amendments in the context of the pre-existing

position limits provision, while ensuring that neither the amendments

nor the pre-existing language is rendered superfluous.

C. Necessity Finding

1. Necessity

The Commission reiterates its preliminary alternative necessity

finding as articulated in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal:

\135\ Out of an abundance of caution in light of the district court

decision in ISDA v. CFTC,\136\ and without prejudice to any argument

the Commission may advance in any forum, the Commission reproposes, as

a separate and independent basis for the Rule, a preliminary finding

herein that the speculative position limits in this reproposed Rule are

necessary to achieve their statutory purposes.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\135\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75685.

\136\ International Swaps and Derivatives Association v. United

States Commodity Futures Trading Commission, 887 F. Supp. 2d 259

(D.D.C. 2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As described in the Proposal, the policy basis and reasoning for

the Commission's necessity finding is illustrated by two major

incidents in which market participants amassed massive futures

positions in silver and natural gas, respectively, which enabled them

to cause sudden and unreasonable fluctuations and unwarranted changes

in the prices of those commodities. CEA section 4a(a)(1) calls for

position limits for the purpose of diminishing, eliminating, or

preventing the burden of excessive speculation.\137\ Although both

episodes involved manipulative intent, the Commission believes that

such intent is not necessary for an excessively large position to give

rise to sudden and unreasonable fluctuations or unwarranted changes in

the price of an underlying commodity. This is illustrated, for example,

by the fact that when the perpetrators of the silver manipulation lost

the ability to control their scheme, i.e., to manipulate the market at

will, they were forced to liquidate quickly, which, given the amount of

contracts sold in a very short time, caused silver prices to plummet.

Any trader who was forced by conditions in the market or their own

financial condition to liquidate a very large position could

predictably have similar effects on prices, regardless of their

motivation for amassing the position in the first place. Moreover,

although these two episodes unfolded in contract markets for silver and

natural gas, and unfolded at two different times in the past, there is

nothing unique about either market at either relevant time that causes

the Commission to restrict its preliminary finding of necessity to

those markets or to reach a different conclusion based on market

conditions today. Put another way, any contract market has a limited

ability, closely linked to the market's size, to absorb the

establishment and liquidation of large speculative positions in an

orderly manner.\138\ The silver and natural gas examples illustrate

these issues, but the reasoning applies beyond their specific facts.

Accordingly, the Commission preliminarily finds it necessary to

implement position limits as a prophylactic measure for the 25 core

referenced futures contracts.\139\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\137\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(1).

\138\ Establishment of Speculative Position Limits, 46 FR 50938,

50940 (Oct. 16, 1981).

\139\ The Commission's necessity finding is also supported by

the consideration of costs and benefits below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96717]]

The Commission received many comments on its preliminary

alternative necessity finding; the Commission summarizes and responds

to significant comments below.

a. Studies' Lack of Consensus.\140\ The Commission stated in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal that the lack of consensus in

the studies reviewed at that time warrants acting on the side of

caution and implementing position limits as a prophylactic measure,

``to protect against undue price fluctuations and other burdens on

commerce that in some cases have been at least in part attributable to

excessive speculation.'' \141\ Some commenters suggested that a lack of

consensus means instead that the Commission should not implement

position limits,\142\ that the issue merits further study,\143\ that it

would be arbitrary and capricious to implement position limits,\144\

and that the desire to err on the side of caution should be irrelevant

to an assessment of whether position limits are necessary.\145\ In

short, these comments contend that the lack of consensus means position

limits cannot be necessary.\146\ The Commission disagrees. The lack of

consensus does not provide ``objective evidence that position limits

are not necessary;'' \147\ rather, it suggests that they remain

controversial.\148\ In response to these comments, the Commission

believes that Congress could not have intended by using the word

``necessary'' to restrict the Commission from determining to implement

position limits unless experts unanimously agree or form a consensus

they would be beneficial. Otherwise a necessity finding would be

virtually impossible and, in fact, the Commission could plausibly be

stymied by interested persons publishing self-interested studies. The

Commission's view in this respect is supported by the text of CEA

section 4a(a)(1), which states that there shall be such limits as ``the

Commission finds'' are necessary.\149\ Thus, while the Commission finds

the studies useful, it does not cede the necessity finding to the

authors.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\140\ The Commission observed in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal that the studies discussed therein ``overall show a

lack of consensus regarding the impact of speculation on commodity

markets and the effectiveness of position limits.'' 78 FR at 75695.

\141\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75695.

\142\ E.g., CL-CCMR-59623 at 4-5; CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 3; CL-

FIA-59595 at 7; and CL-IECAssn-59679 at 3.

\143\ E.g., CL-BG Group-59656 at 3; CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 3; and

CL-WGC-59558 at 2.

\144\ CL-Chamber-59684 at 4.

\145\ CL-CCMR-59623 at 4-5.

\146\ Contra CL-AFR-59711 at 1; CL-AFR-59685 at 1; CL-Public

Citizen-59648 at 3; CL-WEED-59628.

\147\ CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 3.

\148\ A discussion of the cumulative studies reviewed by the

Commission follows below. See below, Section I.C.2. (discussing

studies and reports received or reviwed in connection with the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal), and accompanying text.

\149\ This assumes that, contrary to the Commission's

interpretation of the statute, Congress did not make that

determination itself as to physical commodity markets.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Reliance on Silver and Natural Gas Studies.\150\ The Commission

stated in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal that it ``found

two studies of actual market events to be helpful and persuasive in

making its preliminary alternative necessity finding,'' \151\ namely,

the Interagency Silver Study \152\ and the PSI Report on Excessive

Speculation in the Natural Gas Market.\153\ Some commenters criticized

the Commission's reliance on these two studies.\154\ These commenters

dismissed the two studies, variously, as limited, outdated,\155\

dubious,\156\ unpersuasive, anecdotal, and irrelevant.\157\ Other

commenters characterized the episodes as extreme or unique.\158\ Some

commenters observed that neither study recommended position

limits.\159\ One noted that, ``Each study focuses on activities in a

single market during a limited timeframe that occurred years ago.''

\160\ Others noted that the Commission has undertaken no independent

analysis of each market, commodity, or contract affected by this

rulemaking.\161\ They then claim that because particular markets or

commodities have unique characteristics, one cannot extrapolate from

these two specific episodes to other commodities or other markets.\162\

Several commenters describe the Hunt brothers silver crisis and the

collapse of the natural gas speculator Amaranth as instances of market

manipulation rather than excessive speculation.\163\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\150\ The Commission stated in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal that it found two studies of actual market events to be

helpful and persuasive in making its preliminary alternative

necessity finding, namely, the interagency report on the silver

crisis, U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Commission, ``Part Two, A

Study of the Silver Market, May 29, 1981, Report to The Congress in

Response to Section 21 of the Commodity Exchange Act, and the PSI

Report on, U.S. Senate, ``Excessive Speculation in the Natural Gas

Market,'' June 25, 2007.

\151\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75695.

\152\ Commodity Futures Trading Commission, Report to The

Congress in Response to Section 21 of the Commodity Exchange Act,

May 29, 1981, Part Two, A Study of the Silver Market.

\153\ Excessive Speculation in the Natural Gas Market, Staff

Report with Additional Minority Staff Views, Permanent Subcommittee

on Investigations, United States Senate, Released in Conjunction

with the Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations June 25 & July 9,

2007 Hearings.

\154\ One commenter called the Commission's choice `cherry-

picking.' CL-Citadel-59717 at 4.

\155\ The Commission disagrees; that an exemplary event occurred

in the past does not make it irrelevant.

\156\ Contra CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 6 (pointing to ``concrete

examples'').

\157\ E.g., CL-Chamber-59684 at 3; CL-CME-59718 at 3, 18; CL-

IECAssn-59679 at 2; CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 12; and CL-USCF-59644 at

3.

\158\ E.g., CL-IECAssn-59679 at 2; and CL-BG Group-59656 at 3.

Certainly the Commission seeks to prevent extreme events such as

Amaranth and the Hunt brothers, however infrequently they may occur.

\159\ E.g., CL-CME-59718 at 18; and CL-CCMR-59623 at 3.

\160\ CL-CME-59718 at 18.

\161\ E.g., CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 2; CL-WGC-59558 at 2.

\162\ E.g., CL-Citadel-59717 at 4; CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 12-14;

CL-MFA-59606 at 10; and CL-WGC-59558 at 2.

\163\ E.g., CL-Better Markets-59716 at 12; CL-BG Group-59656 at

3; CL-COPE-59622 at 4-5; CL-CCMR-59623 at 4; CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at

13; and CL-AMG-59709 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As discussed above, the presence of manipulative intent or activity

does not preclude the existence of excessive speculation, and traders

do not need manipulative intent for the accumulation of very large

positions to cause the negative consequences observed in the Hunt and

Amaranth incidents. These are some reasons position limits are valuable

as a prophylactic measure for, in the language of CEA section 4a(a)(1),

``preventing'' burdens on interstate commerce. The Hunt brothers, who

distorted the price of silver, and Amaranth, who distorted the price of

natural gas, are examples that illustrate the burdens on interstate

commerce of excessive speculation that occurred in the absence of

position limits, and position limits would have restricted those

traders' ability to cause unwarranted price movement and market

volatility, and this would be so even had their motivations been

innocent. Both episodes involved extraordinarily large speculative

positions, which the Commission has historically associated with

excessive speculation.\164\ We are also given no persuasive reason to

change our conclusion that extraordinarily large speculative positions

could result in sudden or unreasonable fluctuations or unwarranted

price changes in other physical commodity markets, just as they did in

silver and natural case in the Hunt Brothers and Amaranth episodes.

Although commenters describe changes in these markets over time, the

characteristics that we find salient have

[[Page 96718]]

not changed materially.\165\ Thus, these two examples remain relevant

and compelling.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\164\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75685, n.

60.

\165\ See infra Section I.C.1.f., and accompanying text.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

CME makes a textual argument in support of the position that CEA

section 4a(a)(2) requires a commodity-by-commodity determination that

position limits are necessary. It cites several places in CEA section

4a(a)(1) that refer to limits as necessary to eliminate ``such burden''

on ``such commodity'' or ``any commodity.'' \166\ However, the

prophylactic measures described herein address vulnerabilities

characteristic of each market.\167\ Accordingly, the Commission

believes the statute's use of the singular is immaterial.\168\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\166\ CL-CME-59718 at 13-14.

\167\ See, e.g., Establishment of Speculative Position Limits,

46 FR at 50940 (Oct. 16, 1981) (``[I]t appears that the capacity of

any contract market to absorb the establishment and liquidation of

large speculative positions in an orderly manner is related to the

relative size of such positions, i.e., the capacity of the market is

not unlimited.'').

\168\ See also 1 U.S.C. 1 (``In determining the meaning of any

Act of Congress, unless the context indicates otherwise--words

importing the singular include and apply to several persons,

parties, or things[.]'')

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission's analysis applies to all physical commodities, and

it would account for differences among markets by setting the limits at

levels based on updated data regarding estimated deliverable supply in

each of the given underlying commodities in the case of spot-month

limits or based on exchange recommendation, if an exchange recommended

a spot-month limit level of less than 25 percent of estimated

deliverable supply, and open interest in the case of single-month and

all-months-combined limits, for each separate commodity. The

Commission's Reproposal regarding whether to adopt conditional spot-

month limits is also based on updated data.\169\ The Commission also

does not find it relevant that the Interagency Silver Study and the PSI

Report, each of which was published before the Dodd-Frank Act became

law, do not recommend the imposition of position limits. Based on the

facts described in those reports, along with the Commission's

understanding of the policies underlying CEA section 4a(a)(1) in light

of the Commission's own experience with legacy limits, the Commission

preliminarily finds that position limits are necessary within the

meaning of that section.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\169\ See the Commission's discussion of its verification of

estimates of deliverable supply and work with open interest data,

below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

c. Commission research. One commenter asserted that the Commission

failed ``to conduct proper economic analysis to determine, if in fact,

the position limits as proposed were likely to have any positive impact

in promoting fair and orderly commodity markets.'' \170\ While

acknowledging the Commission's resource constraints, this commenter

remarked on ``the paucity of the published record by the CFTC's s own

staff'' \171\ and suggests that outside authors be given ``controlled

access to all of the CFTC's data regarding investor and hedger trading

records.'' \172\ This commenter then proceeds to accuse the Commission

of failing to ``conduct such research because they felt the data would

not in fact support the proposed position limit regulations.'' \173\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\170\ CL-USCF-59644 at 2.

\171\ CL-USCF-59644 at 2. This commenter exaggerates. The last

arguably relevant report of Commission staff is ``Commodity Swap

Dealers & Index Traders with Commission Recommendations'' (Sept.

2008), available at http://www.cftc.gov/idc/groups/public/@newsroom/documents/file/cftcstaffreportonswapdealers09.pdf. However, several

authors or co-authors of academic papers reviewed by the Commission

are or have been affiliated with the Commission in various

capacities and have added to the current literature relating to

position limits. Each of Harris, see note240, Kirilenko, see note

2400, and Overdahl, see notes 240 and 241, are former Chief

Economists of the Commission. Other authors, e.g., Aulerich, Boyd,

Brunetti, B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Einloth, Haigh, Hranaiova,

Kyle, Robe, and Rothenberg, are now or have been staff and/or

consultants to the Commission, have spent sabbaticals at the

Commission, or have been detailed to the Commission from other

federal agencies. Graduate students studying with some study

authors, including some working on dissertations, have also cycled

through the Commission as interns. Cf. note 180 (disclaimer on paper

by Harris and B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin).

\172\ CL-USCF-59644 at 3. Data regarding investor and hedger

trading records may be protected by section 8 of the CEA, 7 U.S.C.

12. In general, ``the Commission may not publish data and

information that would separately disclose the business transactions

or market positions of any person and trade secrets or names of

customers . . . .'' 7 U.S.C. 12(a)(1). The Commission must therefore

be very careful about granting outside economists access to such

data. Commission registrants have in the past ``questioned why the

CFTC was permitting outside economists to access CFTC data, why the

CFTC was permitting the publication of academic articles using that

data, and . . . the administrative process by which the CFTC was

employing these outside economists.'' Review of the Commodity

Futures Trading Commission's Response to Allegations Pertaining to

the Office of the Chief Economist, Prepared by the Office of the

Inspector General, Commodity Futures Trading Commission, Feb. 21.

2014, at ii, available at http://www.cftc.gov/idc/groups/public/@freedomofinformationact/documents/file/oigreportredacted.pdf. The

Commission is sensitive to these concerns, and strives to ensure

that reports and publications that rely on Commission data do not

reveal sensitive information. To do so requires an expenditure of

effort by Commission staff.

\173\ CL-USCF-59644 at 3. The Commission rejects the commenter's

aspersion. The Commission's Office of the Inspector General

addressed the perception of institutional censorship in its ``Follow

Up Report: Review of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission's

Response to Allegations Pertaining to the Office of the Chief

Economist, Jan. 13, 2016 (``Follow Up Report''), available at http://www.cftc.gov/idc/groups/public/@aboutcftc/documents/file/oig_oce011316.pdf. The Follow Up Report emphasizes ``that there has

been no allegation that the Chairman or Commissioners have attempted

to prevent certain topics from being researched or to alter

conclusions,'' Follow Up Report at 11, but nevertheless recommended

``that OCE not prohibit research topics relevant to the CFTC

mission.'' Follow Up Report at 10. The Follow Up Report observed

that recently ``OCE has focused almost exclusively on short-term

research and economic analysis in support of other Divisions and the

Commission.'' Follow Up Report at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission disagrees that it has failed to conduct proper

economic analysis to determine the likely benefits of position limits.

CEA section 15(a) requires that before promulgating a regulation under

the Act, the Commission consider the costs and benefits of the action

according to five statutory factors. The Commission does so below in

robust fashion with respect to the Reproposal in its entirety,

including the alternative necessity finding. Neither section 15(a) of

the CEA nor the Administrative Procedure Act requires the Commission to

conduct a study in any particular form so long as it considers the

costs and benefits and the entire administrative record. Section 719(a)

of the Dodd-Frank Act, on the other hand, provides that the Commission

``shall conduct a study of the effects (if any) of the position limits

imposed pursuant to the . . . [CEA] on excessive speculation'' and

report to Congress on such matters after the imposition of position

limits.\174\ The Commission will do so as required by Section 719(a),

thereby fully discharging its duty. At all stages, the Commission has

relied on and will continue to rely on the input of staff economists in

the Division of Market Oversight (``DMO'') and the Office of the Chief

Economist (``OCE'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\174\ 15 U.S.C. 8307(a). See December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, 78 FR at 75684 (discussing section 719(a) of the Dodd-

Frank Act in the context of the Commission's construal of CEA

section 4a(a) to mandate that the Commission impose position

limits).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

d. Excessive Speculation

One commenter opined that, ``in discussing only the Hunt Brothers

and Amaranth case studies the Commission has not given adequate weight

to the benefits that speculators provide to the market.'' \175\ To the

contrary, the Commission recognizes that speculation is part of a well-

functioning market, particularly insofar as speculators contribute

valuable liquidity. The focus of this reproposed rulemaking is not

speculation per se; Congress identified excessive speculation as an

undue

[[Page 96719]]

burden on interstate commerce in CEA section 4a(a)(1).\176\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\175\ CL-MFA-59606 at 11-12.

\176\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(1). One commenter suggests that the

Commission base speculative position limits on ``a determination of

an acceptable total level of speculation that approximates the

historic ratio of hedging to investor/speculative trading.'' CL-A4A-

59714 at 4. The Commission declines at this time to adopt such a

ratio as basis for speculative position limits. Among other things,

the Commission does not now collect reliable data distinguishing

hedgers from speculators. Also, there may be levels above a historic

hedging ratio that still provide liquidity rather than denoting

excessive speculation. While the Commission has authority under

section 4a(a)(1) of the Act to impose position limits on a group or

class of traders, the only way that the Commission knows how to

implement limit levels based on such a historic ratio would be to

impose rationing, which the Commission declines to do at this time.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter asserted that the Commission must provide a

definition of excessive speculation before making any necessity

finding.\177\ The Commission disagrees that the rule must include such

a definition. The statute contains no such requirement, and did not

contain such a requirement prior to the Dodd-Frank Act. The Commission

has never based necessity findings on a rigid definition. The

Commission's position on this issue has been clear over time: ``The CEA

does not define excessive speculation. But the Commission historically

has associated it with extraordinarily large speculative positions . .

. .'' \178\ CEA section 4a(a)(1) states that position limits should

diminish, eliminate, or prevent burdens on interstate commerce

associated with sudden or unreasonable fluctuations or unwarranted

changes in the price of commodities.\179\ It stands to reason that

excessive speculation involves positions large enough to risk such

unreasonable fluctuations or unwarranted changes. This commenter also

urges the Commission to ``demonstrate and determine that . . . harmful

excessive speculation exists or is reasonably likely to occur with

respect to particular commodities'' \180\ before implementing any

position limits.\181\ As stated in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, the Commission referenced its prior determination in 1981

``that, with respect to any particular market, the `existence of

historical trading data' showing excessive speculation or other burdens

on that market is not `an essential prerequisite to the establishment

of a speculative limit.' '' \182\ The Commission reiterates this

statement and underscores that these risks are characteristic of

contract markets generally. Differences among markets can be addressed,

as the Commission reproposes to do here, by setting the limit levels to

account for individual market characteristics. Attempting to

demonstrate and determine that excessive speculation is reasonably

likely to occur with respect to particular commodities before

implementing position limits is impractical because historical trading

data in a particular commodity is not necessarily indicative of future

events in that commodity. Further, it would require the Commission to

determine what may happen in a forecasted future state of the market in

a particular commodity. As the Commission has often repeated, position

limits are a prophylactic measure. Inherently, then, position limits

are designed to address the burdens of excessive speculation well

before they occur, not when the Commission somehow determines that such

speculation is imminent, which the Commission (or any market actor for

that matter) cannot reliably do.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\177\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 3, 14-15; see also CL-FIA-59595 at

6-7.

\178\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75685, n.

60 (citation omitted).

\179\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(1).

\180\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 3; see also CL-CCMR-59623 at 4; CL-

Chamber-59684 at 4. Contra CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 6 (stating

``[c]ontrary to the complaints of some critics, it would be a waste

of time and resources for the Commission to expand the proposed

rules beyond the existing justification to repeat the same analysis,

reach the same conclusions, and issue the same findings for each of

the 28 commodities.'').

\181\ See also CL-CCMR-59623 at 4-5. Another commenter

``contends that the best available evidence discounts the theory

that there is excessive speculation distorting the prices in the

commodity markets.'' CL-MFA-59606 at 13 (citing Pirrong). Such a

contention is inconsistent with ``Congress' determination, codified

in CEA section 4a(a)(1), that position limits are an effective tool

to address excessive speculation as a cause of sudden or

unreasonable fluctuations or unwarranted changes in the price of . .

. [agricultural and exempt] commodities. December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75695 (footnote omitted). Another

commenter mischaracterizes the finding of the Congressional Budget

Report, ``Evaluating Limits on Participation and Transactions in

Markets for Emissions Allowances'' (2010), available at http://www.cbo.gov/publication/21967 (``CBO Report''); the CBO Report does

not conclude ``that position limits are harmful to markets.'' CL-

IECAssn-59679 at 3. Rather, in the context of creating markets for

emissions allowance trading, the CBO Report discusses both the uses

and benefits and the challenges and drawbacks of not only position

limits but also circuit breakers, in addition to banning certain

types of traders and banning allowance derivatives. Among other

things, the CBO Report states, ``Position Limits would probably

lessen the possibility of systemic risk and manipulation in

allowance markets . . . .'' CBO Report at viii. Another commenter

states that a ``CFTC study'' found that the 2008 crude oil crisis

was primarily due to fundamental factors in the supply and demand of

oil. CL-CCMR-59623 at 4. The referenced study is Harris and

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, The Role of Speculators in the Crude

Oil Futures Market (working paper 2009). See generally note 240

(listing studies that employ the Granger method of statistical

analysis). While Harris is a former Chief Economist, and

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin is a former staff economist in OCE, as

noted above, the cover page of the referenced paper contains the

standard disclaimer, ``This paper reflects the opinions of its

authors only, and not those of the U.S. Commodity Futures Trading

Commission, the Commissioners, or other staff of the Commission.''

That is, it is not a ``CFTC study.'' In addition, other studies of

that market at that time reached different conclusions. Cf. note 252

(citing study that concludes price changes precede the position

change). The Commission reviewed several studies of the crude oil

market around 2008 and discusses them herein. See discussion of

persuasive academic studies, below. The Commission cautions that,

given the continuing controversy surrounding position limits, it is

unlikely that one study will ever be completely dispositive of these

complicated and difficult issues.

\182\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75683.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

e. Volatility

Commenters assert, variously, that ``the volatility of commodity

markets has decreased steadily over the past decade,'' \183\ that

``research found that there was a negative correlation between

speculative positions and market volatility,'' \184\ research shows

that factors other than excessive speculation were primarily

responsible for specific instances of price volatility,\185\ that

futures markets are associated with lower price volatility,\186\ that

particular types of speculators provide liquidity rather than causing

price volatility,\187\ that position limits will increase

volatility,\188\ etc. It would follow, then, according to these

commenters, that because they believe there is little or no volatility

(no sudden or unreasonable fluctuations or unwarranted price changes),

or no volatility caused by excessive speculation, position limits

cannot be necessary.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\183\ CL-CCMR-59623 at 4 (claim supported only by a reference to

a comment letter that pre-dates the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal).

\184\ CL-MFA-59606 at 12 (citing one academic paper, Irwin and

Sanders, The Impact of Index and Swap Funds on Commodity Futures

Markets: Preliminary Results (working paper 2010)). See generally

note 240 (studies that employ the Granger method of statistical

analysis).

\185\ E.g., CL-MFA-59606 at 11-12, n. 26. Contra CL-AFR-59685 at

1 (stating ``We understand that other factors contribute to highly

volatile commodity prices, but excessive speculation plays a

significant part, according to studies by Princeton, MIT, the

Petersen Institute, the University of London, and the U.S. Senate,

among other highly credible sources.'').

\186\ CL-MFA-59606 at 13, n. 30.

\187\ E.g., CL-MFA-59606 at 12-13 (hedge funds). Cf. CL-SIFMA

AMG-59709 at 15 (asserting ``neither Amaranth nor the Hunt brothers

were in any way involved in commodity index swaps''), 16 (registered

investment companies and ERISA accounts).

\188\ CL-MFA- 59606 at 13. Contra CL-CMOC-59702 at 2

(maintaining that witness testimony before policymakers ``confirmed

that the erosion of the position limits regime was a leading cause

in market instability and wild price swings seen in recent years and

that it had led to diminished confidence in the commodity derivative

markets as a hedging and price discovery tool'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As stated above, the Commission recognizes that speculation is part

of a

[[Page 96720]]

well-functioning market particularly, as noted in comments, as a source

of liquidity. Position limits address excessive speculation, not

speculation per se. Position limits neither exclude particular types of

speculators nor prohibit speculative transactions; they constrain only

speculators with excessively large positions in order to diminish,

eliminate, or prevent an undue and unnecessary burden on interstate

commerce in a commodity.\189\ The Commission agrees that futures

markets are associated with, and may indeed contribute to, lower

volatility in underlying commodity prices. However, as Congress

observed, in CEA section 4a(a)(1), excessive speculation in a commodity

contract that causes sudden or unreasonable fluctuations or unwarranted

changes in the price of such commodity, is an undue and unnecessary

burden on interstate commerce in such commodity.\190\ In promulgating

CEA section 4a(a)(1), Congress adopted position limits as a useful tool

to diminish, eliminate, or prevent those problems. The Commission

believes that position limits are a necessary prophylactic measure to

guard against disruptions arising from excessive speculation, and the

Commission has endeavored to repropose limit levels that are not so low

as to hamper healthy speculation as a source of liquidity.\191\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\189\ That a particular type of speculator trades a different

type of instrument, employs a different trading strategy, or is

unlevered, diversified, subject to other regulatory regimes, etc.,

so as to distinguish it in some way from Amaranth or the Hunt

brothers does not overcome the size of the position held by the

speculator, and the risks inherent in amassing extraordinarily large

speculative positions.

\190\ CEA section 4a(a)(1); 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(1).

\191\ See the discussion of the impact analysis, below under

Sec. 150.2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

f. Basis for Determination

One commenter states, ``The necessity finding . . . proffered by

the Commission--which consists of a discussion of two historical events

and a cursory review of existing studies and reports on position limits

related issues--falls short of a comprehensive analysis and

justification for the proposed position limits.\192\ We disagree with

the commenter's opinion that the Commission's analysis is not

comprehensive or falls short of justifying the reproposed rule.\193\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\192\ CL-Citadel-59717 at 3-4 (footnote omitted). Contra CL-Sen.

Levin-59637 at 6 (declaring that ``[t]he Commission's analysis and

findings, paired with concrete examples, provide a comprehensive

explanation of the principles and reasoning behind establishing

position limits.'').

\193\ Although the events described in the proposal are

sufficient to support the necessity finding for the reasons given,

the Commission also notes reports that more recent market events

have been perceived as involving excessively large positions that

have caused or threatened to cause market disruptions. See, e.g., Ed

Ballard, Speculators sit on Sugar Pile, Raising Fears of Selloff,

The Wall Street Journal (Nov. 21, 2016) (``Speculative investors

have built a record position in sugar this year, sparking fears of a

swift pullback in its price.''); Of mice and markets, A surge in

speculation is making commodity markets more volatile, The Economist

(Sept. 10, 2016) (discussing ``scramble by funds to unwind their

short positions in'' West Texas Intermediate that appears to have

``fanned a rally in spot oil prices''). As discussed elsewhere,

willingness to participate in the futures and swaps markets may be

reduced by perceptions that a participant with an unusually large

speculative position could exert unreasonable market power.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter states that the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal ``does not provide any quantitative analysis of how the

outcome of these [two historical] events might have differed if the

proposed position limits had been in place.'' \194\ The Commission

disagrees. The Commission stated in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal that, ``The Commission believes that if Federal speculative

position limits had been in effect that correspond to the . . . .

[proposed] limits . . . , across markets now subject to Commission

jurisdiction, such limits would have prevented the Hunt brothers and

their cohorts from accumulating such large futures positions.'' \195\

This statement was based on calculations using a methodology similar to

\196\ that proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

applied to quantitative data included and as described therein.\197\

The Commission's stated belief is unchanged at the higher single-month

and all-months-combined limit levels of 7,600 contracts that the

Commission adopts today for silver.\198\ Nevertheless, historical data

regarding absolute position size from the period of the late-1970's to

1980 may not be readily comparable to the numerical limits adopted in

the current market environment. Accordingly, the Commission is

reproposing establishing levels using the methodology based on the size

of the current market as described elsewhere in this release.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\194\ CL-WGC-59558 at 2; see also CL-BG Group-59656 at 3.

\195\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75690.

\196\ The Commission's methodology is a fair approximation of

how the limits would have been applied during the time of the silver

crisis. See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75690.

\197\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75690-1.

\198\ For example, using historical month-end open interest

data, the Commission calculated a single- and all-months-combined

limit level of 6,700 contracts, which would have been exceeded by a

total Hunt position of over 12,000 contracts for March delivery.

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75690. Baldly, a

position of 12,000 contracts would still exceed a 7,600 contract

limit.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With respect to Amaranth, the Commission stated, ``Based on certain

assumptions . . . , the Commission believes that if Federal speculative

position limits had been in effect that correspond to the limits that

the Commission . . . [proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal], across markets now subject to Commission jurisdiction, such

limits would have prevented Amaranth from accumulating such large

futures positions and thereby restrict its ability to cause unwarranted

price effects.'' \199\ This statement of belief about Amaranth was also

based on calculations using the methodology applied to quantitative

data as described and included in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal preamble.\200\ The historical size of Amaranth positions would

no longer breach the higher single-month and all-months-combined limit

levels of 200,900 contracts that the Commission adopts today for

natural gas.\201\ However, the Commission is reproposing setting a

level using a methodology that adapts to changes in the market for

natural gas, i.e., the fact that it has grown larger and more liquid

since the collapse of Amaranth. Thus, it stands to reason that a

speculator might now have to accumulate a larger position than

Amaranth's historical position to present a similar risk of disruption

to the natural gas market. In fact, the Commission has long recognized

``that the capacity of any contract market to absorb the establishment

and liquidation of large speculative positions in an orderly manner is

related to the relative size of such positions, i.e., the capacity of

the market is not unlimited.'' \202\ A larger market should have larger

capacity, other things being equal; \203\ hence, the Commission is

adopting higher levels of limits. Moreover, costly disruptions like

those associated with Amaranth remain entirely possible. Because the

costs of these disruptions can be great, and borne by members of the

public

[[Page 96721]]

unconnected with trading markets, the Commission preliminarily finds it

necessary to impose speculative position limits as a preventative

measure. As markets differ in size, the limit levels differ

accordingly, each designed to prevent the accumulation of positions

that are extraordinary in size in the context of each market.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\199\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75692.

\200\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75692-3.

\201\ See level of initial limits under App. D to part 150.

\202\ Establishment of Speculative Position Limits, 46 FR 50938,

50940.

\203\ A gross comparison such as this may not meaningful. For

example, the Commission could have increased the size of Amaranth's

historical position proportionately to the increased size of the

market and compared it to the limit level for natural gas that the

Commission adopts today. But such an approach would be less rigorous

than the analysis on which the Commission bases its determination

today.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters opined that the Commission, in reaching its

preliminary alternative necessity finding, ignores current market

developments and does not employ the ``new tools'' other than position

limits available to it to prevent excessive speculation or manipulative

or potentially manipulative behavior.\204\ Specifically, some

commenters suggested that position limits are not necessary because

position accountability rules and exchange-set limits are

adequate.\205\ The Commission agrees that the Dodd-Frank Act gave the

Commission new tools with which to protect and oversee the commodity

markets, and agrees that these along with older tools may be useful in

addressing market volatility. However, the Commission disagrees that

the availability of other tools means that position limits are not

necessary.\206\ Rather the statute, at a minimum, reflects Congress'

judgment that position limits may be found by the Commission to be

necessary. The Commission notes that although CEA section 4a(a)

position limits provisions have existed for many years, the Dodd-Frank

Act not only retained CEA section 4a(a), but added, rather than

deleted, several sections. This leads to the conclusion that Congress

appears to share the Commission's view that the other tools provided by

Congress were not sufficient.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\204\ E.g., CL-CCMR-59623 at 3 (supporting additional

transparency and reporting); CL-Citadel-59717 at 4 (pointing to

available tools, including ``enhanced market surveillance, broadened

reporting requirements, broadened special call authorities, and

exchange limits''); CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 13 (noting that tools

that the Commission has incorporated include ``enhanced market

surveillance, broadened reporting requirements, broadened special

call authorities, and exchange limits''); CL-MFA-59606 at 10; and

CL-SIFMA AMG-59709 at 5-6 (providing examples of new tools).

\205\ E.g., CL-CME-59718 at 18; CL-ICE-59645 at 2-4; CL-FIA-

59595 at 6, n. 13, 12-13; and CL-AMG-59709 at 8.

\206\ The Commission observes that logically there is no reason

why the availability of some regulatory tools under the CEA should

preclude the use of another tool explicitly authorized by Congress.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Position accountability, for example, is an older tool, from the

era of the CFMA. As the Commission explained in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal, the CFMA ``provided a statutory basis for

exchanges to use pre-existing position accountability levels as an

alternative means to limit the burdens of excessive speculative

positions. Nevertheless, the CFMA did not weaken the Commission's

authority in CEA section 4a to establish position limits as an

alternative means to prevent such undue burdens on interstate commerce.

More recently, in the CFTC Reauthorization Act of 2008, Congress gave

the Commission expanded authority to set position limits for

significant price discovery contracts on exempt commercial markets,''

\207\ and it expanded the Commission's authority again in the Dodd-

Frank Act.\208\ While position accountability is useful in providing

exchanges with information about specific trading activity so that

exchanges can act if prudent to require a trader to reduce a position

after the position has already been amassed, position limits operate

prophylactically without requiring case-by-case, ex post determinations

about large positions. As to exchange-set accountability levels or

position limits set at levels below those of federal position limits,

those remain useful as well and should be used, at the exchanges'

discretion, in conjunction with federal position limits. They may be

most useful, for example, with respect to contracts that are not core-

referenced futures contracts or if an exchange determines that federal

limits are too high to address adequately the conditions in the markets

it administers. In the regulations that the Commission reproposes

today, the Commission would update (rather than eliminate) the

acceptable practices for exchange-set speculative position limits and

position accountability rules to conform to the Dodd-Frank Act changes

[as described in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal].\209\

Generally, for contracts subject to speculative limits, exchanges may

set limits no higher than the federal limits,\210\ and may impose

``restrictions . . . to reduce the threat of market manipulation or

congestion, to maintain orderly execution of transactions, or for such

other purposes consistent with its responsibilities.'' \211\ And Sec.

150.5(b)(3) sets forth the requirements for position accountability in

lieu of exchange-set limits in the case of contracts not subject to

federal limits. The exchanges are also still authorized to react to

instances of greater price volatility by exercising emergency authority

as they did during the silver crisis.\212\ In addition, the Commission

has striven to take current market developments into account by

considering the market data to which the Commission has access as

described herein and by considering the description of current market

developments to the extent included in the comments the Commission has

received in connection with the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal.

Some commenters suggest that the Commission, in reaching its

preliminary alternative necessity finding, has not undertaken any

empirical analysis of available data.\213\ As discussed above, the

Commission carefully reviewed the Interagency Silver Study and the PSI

Report on Excessive Speculation in the Natural Gas Market.\214\ The

Commission also carefully considered the studies submitted during the

various comment periods regarding the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal and the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal. Other

commenters suggest that the Commission relies on incomplete,

unreliable, or out of date data, and that the Commission should collect

more and/or better data before determining that position limits are

necessary or implementing position limits.\215\ The Commission

disagrees. The Commission has considered the recent data presented by

the exchanges in support of their estimates of deliverable supply. The

Commission is expending significant, agency-wide efforts to improve

data collection and to analyze the data it receives. The quality of the

data on which the Commission relies has improved since the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal. The Commission is satisfied with the

quality of the data on which it bases its Reproposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\207\ 78 FR at 75681 (footnotes omitted).

\208\ See generally December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78

FR at 75681.

\209\ See generally December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78

FR at 75747-8.

\210\ See discussion of requirements for exchange-set position

limits under Sec. 150.5, below, and exchange core principles

regarding position limits, below.

\211\ See reproposed Sec. 150.5(a)(6)(iii).

\212\ See generally 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(6) (DCM Core Principles:

Emergency Authority); 7 U.S.C. 7b-3(f)(8) (Core Principles for Swap

Execution Facilities--Emergency Authority); 17 CFR 37.800 (Swap

Execution Facility Core Principle 8--Emergency authority), 17 CFR

38.350 (Designated Contract Markets -Emergency Authority--Core

Principle 6).

\213\ E.g., CL-FIA-59595 at 3; CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 2, 8-9.

\214\ See supra Section I.C.2 (discussing the Interagency Silver

Study and the PSI Report on Excessive Speculation in the Natural Gas

Market).

\215\ E.g., CL-Citadel-59717 at 4-5; CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 8-9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter opines that, ``The Proposal's `necessary' finding

offers no reasoned basis for adopting its framework and the shift in

regulatory policy it embodies.'' \216\ To the contrary,

[[Page 96722]]

the necessity finding, including the Commission's responses to

comments, is the Commission's explanation of why position limits are

necessary.\217\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\216\ CL-CME-59718 at 3.

\217\ See CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 6 (stating that the

Commission's necessity finding ``appropriately reflects

Congressional action in enacting the Dodd-Frank Act which requires

the Commission to impose appropriate position limits on speculators

trading physical commodities.'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

g. Non-Spot-Month Limits

Some commenters opine that ``the Commission's proposed non-spot-

month position limits do not increase the likelihood of preventing the

excessive speculation or manipulative trading exemplified by Amaranth

or the Hunt brothers relative to the status quo.'' \218\ The Commission

disagrees; as repeated above, ``the capacity of the market is not

unlimited.'' \219\ This includes markets in non-spot month contracts.

Thus, as with spot-month contracts, extraordinarily large positions in

non-spot month contracts may still be capable of distorting

prices.\220\ If prices are distorted, the utility of hedging may

decline.\221\ One commenter argues for non-spot month position

accountability rules; \222\ the Commission discusses position

accountability above.\223\ Another argues that Amaranth was really just

``another case of spot-month misconduct.'' \224\ The Commission

disagrees that this limits the relevance of Amaranth; a speculator like

Amaranth may attempt to distort the perception of supply and demand in

order to benefit, for instance, calendar spread positions by, for

instance, creating the perception of a nearby shortage of the commodity

which a speculator could do by accumulating extraordinarily large long

positions in the nearby month.\225\ One commenter states that

``improperly calibrated non-spot month limits would also deter

speculative activity that triggers no risk of manipulation or `causing

sudden or unreasonable fluctuations or unwarranted changes in the price

of such commodity,' the hallmarks of `excessive speculation.' '' \226\

The Commission sees little merit in this objection because the

Reproposal would calibrate the levels of the non-spot month limits to

accommodate speculative activity that provides liquidity for hedgers.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\218\ CL-AMG-59709 at 9. See the Commission's response to the

comment regarding the purported lack of ``quantitative analysis of

how the outcome of these [two historical] events might of differed

if the proposed position limits had been in place'' at the text

accompanying notes 192-200 above. See also CL-CME-59718 at 41-3; CL-

ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 28.

\219\ See note 202 supra and accompanying text.

\220\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75691

(citing the PSI Report, ``Amaranth accumulated such large positions

and traded such large volumes of natural gas futures that it

distorted market prices, widened price spread, and increased price

volatility.'').

\221\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75692

(citing the PSI Report, ``Commercial participants in the 2006

natural gas markets were reluctant or unable to hedge.'').

\222\ CL-CME-59718 at 41-42.

\223\ See notes 207-212 supra and accompanying text.

\224\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 28.

\225\ The Commission discussed the trading activity of Amaranth

at length in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75691-3; in particular, Amaranth's calendar spread trading is

discussed at 78 FR 75692. The Commission repeats that the findings

of the Permanent Subcommittee in the PSI Report support the

imposition of speculative position limits outside the spot month. A

trader, who does not liquidate an extraordinarily large long futures

position in the nearby physical-delivery futures contract, contrary

to typical declining open interest patterns in a physical-delivery

contract approaching expiration, may cause the nearby futures price

to increase as short position holders, who do not wish to make

physical delivery, bid up the futures price in an attempt to offset

their short positions. Potential liquidity providers who do not

currently hold a deliverable commodity may be hesitant to establish

short positions as a physical-delivery futures contract approaches

expiration, because exchange rules and contract terms require such

short position holder to prepare to make delivery by obtaining the

cash commodity.

\226\ CL-CME-59718 at 43; cf. CL-APGA-59722 at 3 (asserting that

``the non-spot month limits being proposed by the Commission are too

high to be effective'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

h. Meaning of Necessity

One commenter suggests that position limits could only be necessary

if they were the only means of preventing the Hunt brothers and

Amaranth crises.\227\ First, while the Commission relies on these

incidents to explain its reasoning, the risks they illustrate apply to

all markets in physical commodities, and so the efficacy of the limits

the Commission adopts today, and the extent to which other tools are

sufficient, cannot be judged solely by whether they might have

prevented those specific incidents. Second, in any event, the

Commission rejects such an overly restrictive reading, which lacks a

basis in both common usage and statutory construction. The Commission

preliminarily finds that limits are necessary as a prophylactic tool to

strengthen the regulatory framework to prevent excessive speculation ex

ante to diminish the risk of the economic harm it may cause further

than it would reliably be from the other tools alone. Other commenters

question why the Commission proposed limits at levels they contend are

too high to be effective, undercutting the Commission's alternative

necessity finding.\228\ One commenter points out that the limit levels

as proposed would not have prevented the misconduct alleged by the

Commission in a particular enforcement action filed in 2011.\229\ As

repeated elsewhere in this Notice \230\ and in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal,\231\ in establishing limits, the Commission

must, ``to the maximum extent practicable, in its discretion . . .

ensure sufficient market liquidity for bona fide hedgers.\232\ The

Commission realizes that the reproposed initial limit levels may

prevent or deter some, but fail to eliminate all, excessive speculation

in the markets for the 25 commodities covered by this first phase of

implementation. But the Commission is concerned that initial limit

levels set lower than those reproposed today, and in particular low

enough to prevent market manipulation or excessive speculation in

specific, less egregious cases than the Hunt brothers or Amaranth,

could impair liquidity for hedges.\233\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\227\ CL-CCMR-59623 at 4.

\228\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 28; CL-Better Markets-59716 at 24;

CL-APGA-59722 at 6-7.

\229\ CL-Better Markets-59716 at 22, n. 38 (Parnon Energy).

\230\ See the discussion in levels of limits, under Sec. 150.2,

below.

\231\ E.g., December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75681.

\232\ CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B)(iii), 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(3)(B)(iii).

Some commenters expressed concern that position limits could

disproportionately affect commercial entities. E.g., CL-CME-59718 at

43; CL-APGA-59722 at 3. Some commenters expressed concern about the

application of position limits to trade options. E.g., CL-APGA-59722

at 3; CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 3. The Commission reminds commenters that

speculative position limits do not apply to bona fide hedging

transactions or positions. CEA section 4a(c), 7 U.S.C. 6a(c).

\233\ The Commission will revisit the specific limitations set

forth in CEA section 4a(a)(3) when, under reproposed Sec. 150.2(e),

it considers resetting limit levels.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission requests comment on all aspects of this section.

2. Studies and Reports

The Commission has reviewed and evaluated studies and reports

received as comments on the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, in

addition to the studies and reports reviewed in connection with the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal \234\ (such

[[Page 96723]]

studies and reports, collectively, ``studies''). Appendix A to this

preamble is a summary of the various studies reviewed and evaluated by

the Commission.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\234\ A list of studies and reports that the Commission reviewed

in connection with the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal was

included in its Appendix A to the preamble. December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75784-7. One commenter observed that the

studies reviewed in connection with the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal are not all ``necessarily germane to specific

position limits proposed.'' CL-Citadel-59717 at 4. See also CL-CCMR-

59623 at 5 (stating that it had reviewed the studies, and found that

``only 27 address position limits''). The Commission acknowledges

that some studies are more relevant than others. The Commission in

the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal was disclosing the

studies that it had reviewed and evaluated. The Commission requested

comment on its discussion of the studies, and invited commenters to

advise the Commission of other studies to consider, in the hope that

commenters would indicate which studies they believe are more

germane or persuasive and suggest other studies for Commission

review.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission observed in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, ``There is a demonstrable lack of consensus in the studies.''

\235\ Neither the passage of time nor the additional studies have

changed the Commission's view: As a group, these studies do not show a

consensus in favor of or against position limits.\236\ In addition to

arriving at disparate conclusions, the quality of the studies varies.

Nevertheless, the Commission believes that some well-executed studies

suggest that excessive speculation cannot be excluded as a possible

cause of undue price fluctuations and other burdens on commerce in

certain circumstances. All of these factors persuade the Commission to

act on the side of caution in preliminarily finding limits necessary,

consistent with their prophylactic purpose. For these reasons,

explained in more detail below, the Commission preliminarily concludes

that the studies, individually or taken as a whole, do not persuade the

Commission to reverse course \237\ or to change its necessity

finding.\238\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\235\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75694.

\236\ See 162 Cong. Rec. E1005-03, E1006 (June 28, 2016)

(Statement of Rep. Conaway, Chairman of the House Committee on

Agriculture) (``Comment letters on either side declaring that the

matter is settled in their favor among respectable economists are

simply incorrect.''). Contra CL-CCMR-59623 at 5, which says, ``The

Committee staff also reviewed these studies and found that of them,

only 27 address position limits, with the majority opposing such

limits.'' The commenter describes how it arrives at this conclusion

as follows: ``The Committee staff reviewed the abstract and body of

each study to determine if the author assessed: (1) Whether position

limits are effective at reducing speculation; or (2) whether

excessive speculation is distorting prices in commodities markets.

If the author presented a critical analysis of the issue, rather

than just mentioning position limits or excessive speculation in

passing, then the Committee staff included the study in its tally.''

Such a method is relatively unsophisticated, and the Commission

cannot evaluate it without knowing to which studies the commenter

refers. The commenter continues, ``Of the total, 105 studies address

whether excessive speculation is distorting prices in today's

commodity markets, with 66 of these studies finding that excessive

speculation is not a problem.'' This statement did not identify the

66 studies or 105 studies on which it based its belief. Accordingly,

the Commission is unable to evaluate the basis of its belief.

\237\ See discussion of mandate, above. We emphasize that this

discussion relates only to the Commission's alternative necessity

finding. To the extent there is a Congressional mandate that the

Commission establish position limits, these studies could be no

basis to disregard it. As noted in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, ``Studies that militate against imposing any speculative

position limits appear to conflict with the Congressional mandate .

. . that the Commission impose limits on futures contracts, options,

and certain swaps for agricultural and exempt commodities.'' 78 FR

at 75695 (footnote omitted). Separately, ``such studies also appear

to conflict with Congress' determination, codified in CEA section

4a(a)(1), that position limits are an effective tool to address

excessive speculation as a cause of sudden or unreasonable

fluctuations or unwarranted changes in the price of such

commodities,'' irrespective of whether they are mandated. Id. The

Commission acknowledges that some of the studies, when considered as

comments on the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, can be

understood to suggest that, contrary to the Congressional

determination, there is no empirical evidence that excessive

speculation exists, that excessive speculation causes sudden or

unreasonable fluctuations or unwarranted changes in the price of a

commodity, or is an undue and unnecessary burden on interstate

commerce in a commodity.

\238\ See discussion of necessity finding, above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission's deliberations are informed by its consideration of

the studies. The Commission recognizes that speculation and volatility

are not per se unusual or exceptional occurrences in commodity markets.

Some economic studies attempt to distinguish normal, helpful

speculative activity in commodity markets from excessive speculation,

and normal volatility from unreasonable price fluctuations. It has

proven difficult in some studies to discriminate between the proper

workings of a well-functioning market and unwanted phenomena. That some

studies have as yet failed to do so with precision or certainty does

not, in light of the full record, persuade the Commission to reverse

course or to change its necessity finding.

In general, many studies focused on subsidiary questions and did

not directly address the desirability or utility of position limits.

Their proffered interpretations may not be the only plausible

explanation for statistical results. There is no broad academic

consensus on the formal, testable economic definition of ``excessive

speculation'' in commodity futures markets or other relevant terms such

as ``price bubble.'' There is also no broad academic consensus on the

best statistical model to test for the existence of excessive

speculation. There are not many papers that quantify the impact and

effectiveness of position limits in commodity futures markets. The

Commission has identified some reasons why there are not many

compelling, peer-reviewed economic studies engaging in quantitative,

empirical analysis of the impact of position limits on prices or price

volatility: Limitations on publicly available data, including detailed

information on specific trades and traders; pre-existing position

limits in some commodity markets, making it difficult to determine how

those markets would operate in the absence of position limits; and the

difficulties inherent in modelling complex economic phenomena.

The studies that the Commission considered can be grouped into

seven categories.\239\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\239\ These categories are not exclusive; some studies employ or

examine more than one type of methodology. That researchers in the

different categories employed different methodologies complicates

the task of comparing the studies across the seven categories. In

addition, some studies were not susceptible to meaningful economic

analysis for various reasons, such as being written in a foreign

language, being founded on suspect methodologies, being press

releases, etc. These studies include: Basak and Pavlova, A Model

Financialization of Commodities (working paper 2013); Bass,

Finanazm[auml]rkte als Hungerverursacher? (working paper 2011);

Bass, Finanzspekulation und Nahrungsmittelpreise. Anmerkungenzum

Stand der Forschung (working paper 2013); Bukold,

[Ouml]lpreisspekulation und Benzinpreise in Deutschland, (2011);

Chevalier, (Minist[egrave]re de l'Economie, de l'Industrie e t de

l'emploi): Rappor t du groupe de travai l sur la volatilit[egrave]

des prix du p[egrave]trole, (2010); Dicker, Oil's Endless Bid,

(2011); Ederington and Lee, Who Trades Futures and How: Evidence

from the Heating Oil Market?, Journal of Business 2002; Evans, The

Official Demise of the Oil Bubble, Wall Street Journal 2008; Gheit

and Katzenberg, Surviving Lower Oil Prices, Oppenheimer & Co.

(2008); Ghosh, Commodity Speculation and the Food Crisis, (working

paper 2010); Halova, The Intraday Volatility-Volume Relationship in

Oil and Gas Futures, (working paper 2012); Jouyet, Rappor t d'

[eacute]tape-Pr[eacute]venir e t g[eacute]rer l'instabilit[eacute]

des march[eacute]s agricoles, (2010); Korzenik, Fundamental

Misconceptions in the Speculation Debate, (2009); Lake Hill Capital

Management, Investable Indices are Distorting Commodity Markets?,

(2013); Lee, Cheng, and Koh, Would Position Limits Have Made any

Difference to the `Flash Crash' on May 6, 2010?, Review of Futures

Markets (2010); Markham, Manipulation of Commodity Futures Prices:

The Unprosecutable Crime, Yale Journal of Regulation (1991); Mayer,

The Growing Financializsation of Commodity Markets: Divergences

between Index Investors and Money Managers, Journal of Development

Studies (2012); Morse, Oil dotcom, Research Notes, (2008); Naylor,

Food Security in an Era of Economic Volatility (working paper 2010);

Newell, Commodity Speculation's ``Smoking Gun'' (2008); Peri,

Vandone, and Baldi, Internet, Noise Trading and Commodity Prices

(working paper 2012); Soros, Interview with Stern Stern Magazine

(2008); Tanaka, IEA Says Speculation Amplifying Oil Price Moves,

(2006); Von Braun and Tadesse, Global Food Price Volatility and

Spikes: An Overview of Costs, Cause and Solutions (2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Granger Causality Analyses \240\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\240\ Studies that employ the Granger method of statistical

analysis include: Algieri, Price Volatility, Speculation and

Excessive Speculation in Commodity Markets: Sheep or Shepherd

Behaviour? (working paper 2012); Antoshin, Canetti, and Miyajima,

IMF Global Financial Stability Report: Financial Stress and

Deleveraging: Macrofinancial Implications and Policy, Annex 1.2,

Financial Investment in Commodities Markets (October 2008);

Aulerich, Irwin, and Garcia, Bubbles, Food Prices, and Speculation:

Evidence from the CFTC's Daily Large Trader Data Files (NBER

Conference 2012); Borin and Di Nino, The Role of Financial

Investments in Agricultural Commodity Derivatives Markets (working

paper 2012); Brunetti and B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Is

Speculation Destabilizing? (working paper 2009); Cooke and Robles,

Recent Food Prices Movements: A Time Series Analysis (working paper

2009); Frenk, Review of Irwin and Sanders 2010 OECD Report (Better

Markets June 10, 2010); Gilbert, Commodity Speculation and Commodity

Investment (2010); Gilbert, How to Understand High Food Prices,

Journal of Agricultural Economics (2008); Gilbert, Speculative

Influences on Commodity Futures Prices, 2006-2008, UN Conference on

Trade and Development (2010); Goyal and Tripathi, Regulation and

Price Discovery: Oil Spot and Futures Markets (working paper 2012);

Grosche, Limitations of Granger Causality Analysis to Assess the

Price Effects From the Financialization of Agricultural Commodity

Markets Under Bounded Rationality, Agricultural and Resource

Economics (2012); Harris and B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, The Role

of Speculators in the Crude Oil Futures Market (working paper 2009);

Irwin and Sanders, Energy Futures Prices and Commodity Index

Investment: New Evidence from Firm-Level Position Data (working

paper 2014); Irwin and Sanders, The Impact of Index and Swap Funds

on Commodity Futures Markets: A Systems Approach, Journal of

Alternative Investments (working paper 2010); Irwin and Sanders, The

Impact of Index and Swap Funds on Commodity Futures Markets:

Preliminary Results (working paper 2010); Irwin and Sanders, The

``Necessity'' of New Position Limits in Agricultural Futures

Markets: The Verdict from Daily Firm-Level Position Data (working

paper 2014); Irwin and Sanders, The Performance of CBOT Corn,

Soybean, and Wheat Futures Contracts after Recent Changes in

Speculative Limits (working paper 2007); Irwin, Sanders, and Merrin,

Devil or Angel: The Role of Speculation in the Recent Commodity

Price Boom, Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics (2009);

Kaufman, The role of market fundamentals and speculation in recent

price changes for crude oil, Energy Policy, Vol. 39, Issue 1

(January 2011); Kaufmann and Ullman, Oil Prices, Speculation, and

Fundamentals: Interpreting Causal Relations Among Spot and Futures

Prices, Energy Economics, Vol. 31, Issue 4 (July 2009); Mayer, The

Growing Interdependence Between Financial and Commodity Markets, UN

Conference on Trade and Development (discussion paper 2009); Mobert,

Do Speculators Drive Crude Oil Prices? (2009 working paper); Robles,

Torero, and von Braun, When Speculation Matters (working paper

2009); Sanders, Boris, and Manfredo, Hedgers, Funds, and Small

Speculators in the Energy Futures Markets: An Analysis of the CFTC's

Commitment of Traders Reports, Energy Economics (2004); Sanders,

Irwin, and Merrin, The Adequacy of Speculation in Agricultural

Futures Markets: Too Much of a Good Thing?, Applied Economic

Perspectives and Policy (2010); Sanders, Irwin, and Merrin, Smart

Money? The Forecasting Ability of CFTC Large Traders, Journal of

Agricultural and Resource Economics (2009); Sanders, Irwin, and

Merrin, A Speculative Bubble in Commodity Futures? Cross-Sectional

Evidence, Agricultural Economics (2010); Singleton, The 2008 Boom/

Bust in Oil Prices (working paper 2010); Singleton, Investor Flows

and the 2008 Boom/Bust in Oil Prices (working paper 2011); Stoll and

Whaley, Commodity Index Investing and Commodity Futures Prices

(working paper 2010); Timmer, Did Speculation Affect World Rice

Prices?, UN Food and Agricultural Organization (working paper 2009);

Tse and Williams, Does Index Speculation Impact Commodity Prices?,

Financial Review, Vol. 48, Issue 3 (2013); Tse, The Relationship

Among Agricultural Futures, ETFs, and the US Stock Market, Review of

Futures Markets (2012); Varadi, An Evidence of Speculation in Indian

Commodity Markets (working paper 2012); Williams, Dodging Dodd-

Frank: Excessive Speculation, Commodities Markets, and the Burden of

Proof, Law & Policy Journal of the University of Denver (2015).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96724]]

Some economic studies considered by the Commission employ the

Granger method of statistical analysis. The Granger method seeks to

assess whether there is a strong linear correlation between two sets of

data that are arranged chronologically forming a ``time series.'' While

the Granger test is referred to as the ``Granger causality test,'' it

is important to understand that, notwithstanding this shorthand,

``Granger causality'' does not necessarily establish an actual cause

and effect relationship. The result of the Granger method is evidence,

or the lack of evidence, of the existence of a linear correlation

between the two time series. The absence of Granger causality does not

necessarily imply the absence of actual causation.

Comovement or Cointegration Analyses \241\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\241\ Studies that employ the comovement or cointegration

methods include: Ad[auml]mmer, Bohl and Stephan, Speculative Bubbles

in Agricultural Prices (working paper 2011); Algieri, A Roller

Coaster Ride: an Empirical Investigation of the Main Drivers of

Wheat Price (working paper 2013); Babula and Rothenberg, A Dynamic

Monthly Model of U.S. Pork Product Markets: Testing for and

Discerning the Role of Hedging on Pork-Related Food Costs, Journal

of Int'l Agricultural Trade and Development (2013); Baffes and

Haniotos, Placing the 2006/08 Commodity Boom into Perspective, World

Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5371 (2010); Basu and Miffre,

Capturing the Risk Premium of Commodity Futures: The Role of Hedging

Pressure, Journal of Banking and Risk (2013); Belke, Bordon, and

Volz, Effects of Global Liquidity on Commodity and Food Prices,

German Institute for Economic Research (2013); Bicchetti and

Maystre, The Synchronized and Long-lasting Structural Change on

Commodity Markets: Evidence from High Frequency Data (working paper

2012); Boyd, B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, and Haigh, The Prevalence,

Sources, and Effects of Herding (working paper 2013); Bunn,

Chevalier, and Le Pen, Fundamental and Financial Influences on the

Co-movement of Oil and Gas Prices (working paper 2012);

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Harris, and Haigh, Fundamentals, Trader

Activity, and Derivatives Pricing (working paper 2008);

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe, Does it Matter Who Trades

Energy Derivatives?, Review of Env't, Energy, and Economics (2013);

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe, Does ``Paper Oil'' Matter?

(working paper 2011); B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe,

Speculators, Commodities, and Cross-Market Linkages (working paper

2012); Cheng, Kirilenko, and Xiong, Convective Risk Flows in

Commodity Futures Markets (working paper 2012); Coleman and Dark,

Economic Significance of Non-Hedger Investment in Commodity Markets

(working paper 2012); Creti, Joets, and Mignon, On the Links Between

Stock and Commodity Markets' Volatility, Energy Economics (2010);

Dorfman and Karali, Have Commodity Index Funds Increased Price

Linkages between Commodities? (working paper 2012); Filimonov,

Bicchetti, Maystre, and Sornette, Quantification of the High Level

of Endogeneity and of Structural Regime Shifts in Commodity Markets,

(working paper 2013); Haigh, Harris, and Overdahl, Market Growth,

Trader Participation and Pricing in Energy Futures Markets (working

paper 2007); Hoff, Herding Behavior in Asset Markets, Journal of

Financial Stability (2009); Kawamoto, Kimura, et al., What Has

Caused the Surge in Global Commodity Prices and Strengthened Cross-

market Linkage?, Bank of Japan Working Papers Series No.11-E-3 (May

2011); Korniotis, Does Speculation Affect Spot Price Levels? The

Case of Metals With and Without Futures Markets (working paper, FRB

Finance and Economic Discussion Series 2009); Le Pen and

S[eacute]vi, Futures Trading and the Excess Comovement of Commodity

Prices (working paper 2012); Pollin and Heintz, How Wall Street

Speculation is Driving Up Gasoline Prices Today (AFR working paper

2011); Tang and Xiong, Index Investment and Financialization of

Commodities, Financial Analysts Journal (2012); and Windawi,

Speculation, Embedding, and Food Prices: A Cointegration Analysis

(working paper 2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The comovement method looks for whether there is correlation that

is contemporaneous and not lagged. A subset of these comovement studies

use a technique called cointegration for testing correlation between

two sets of data.

Models of Fundamental Supply and Demand \242\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\242\ Studies that employ models of fundamental supply and

demand include: Acharya, Ramadorai, and Lochstoer, Limits to

Arbitrage and Hedging: Evidence from Commodity Markets, Journal of

Financial Economics (2013); Allen, Litov, and Mei, Large Investors,

Price Manipulation, and Limits to Arbitrage: An Anatomy of Market

Corners, Review of Finance (2006); Bos and van der Molen, A Bitter

Brew? How Index Fund Speculation Can Drive Up Commodity Prices,

Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics (2010);

Breitenfellner, Crespo, and Keppel, Determinants of Crude Oil

Prices: Supply, Demand, Cartel, or Speculation?, Monetary Policy and

the Economy (2009); Brennan and Schwartz, Arbitrage in Stock Index

Futures, Journal of Business (1990); Byun and Sungje, Speculation in

Commodity Futures Market, Inventories and the Price of Crude Oil

(working paper 2013); Chan, Trade Size, Order Imbalance, and

Volatility-Volume Relation, Journal of Financial Economics (2000);

Chordia, Subrahmanyam and Roll, Order imbalance, Liquidity, and

Market Returns, Journal of Financial Economics (2002); Cifarelli and

Paladino, Oil Price Dynamics and Speculation: a Multivariate

Financial Approach, Energy Economics (2010); Doroudian and

Vercammen, First and Second Order Impacts of Speculation and

Commodity Price Volatility (working paper 2012); Ederington,

Dewally, and Fernando, Determinants of Trader Profits in Futures

Markets (working paper 2013); Einloth, Speculation and Recent

Volatility in the Price of Oil (working paper 2009); Frankel and

Rose, Determinants of Agricultural and Mineral Commodity Prices

(working paper 2010); Girardi, Do Financial Investors Affect

Commodity Prices? (working paper 2011); Gorton, Hayashi,

Rouwenhorst, The Fundamentals of Commodity Futures Returns, Review

of Finance (2013); Guilleminot and Ohana, The Interaction of Hedge

Funds and Index Investors in Agricultural Derivatives Markets

(working paper 2013); Gupta and Kamzemi, Factor Exposures and Hedge

Fund Operational Risk: The Case of Amaranth (working paper 2009);

Haigh, Hranaiova, and Overdahl, Hedge Funds, Volatility, and

Liquidity Provisions in the Energy Futures Markets, Journal of

Alternative Investments (2007); Haigh, Hranaiova, and Overdahl,

Price Dynamics, Price Discovery, and Large Futures Trader

Interactions in the Energy Complex, (working paper 2005); Hamilton,

Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of 2007-2008, Brookings

Paper on Economic Activity (2009); Hamilton and Wu, Effects of

Index-Fund Investing on Commodity Futures Prices, International

Economic Review, Vol. 56, No. 1 (2015); Hamilton and Wu, Risk Premia

in Crude Oil Futures Prices, Journal of International Money and

Finance (2013); Harrison and Kreps, Speculative Investor Behavior in

a Stock Market with Heterogeneous Expectations, Quarterly Journal of

Economics (1978); Henderson, Pearson and Wang, New Evidence on the

Financialization of Commodity Markets (working paper 2012);

Hirshleifer, Residual Risk, Trading Costs, and Commodity Futures

Risk Premia, Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 1, No. 2, Oxford

University Press (1988); Hong and Yogo, Digging into Commodities

(working paper 2009); Interagency Task Force on Commodity Markets,

Interim Report on Crude Oil, multiple federal agencies including the

CFTC (2008); Juvenal and Petrella, Speculation in the Oil Market

(working paper 2012); Juvenal and Petrella, Speculation in

Commodities, and Cross-Market Linkages (working paper 2011); Kilian,

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: Disentangling Demand and Supply

Shocks in the Crude Oil Market, American Economic Review (2007);

Kilian and Lee, Quantifying the Speculative Component in the Real

Price of Oil: The Role of Global Oil Inventories (working paper

2013); Kilian and Murphy, The Role of Inventories and Speculative

Trading in the Global Market for Crude Oil, Journal of Applied

Econometrics (2010); Knittel and Pindyck, The Simple Economics of

Commodity Price Speculation, (working paper 2013); Kyle and Wang,

Speculation Duopoly with Agreement to Disagree: Can Overconfidence

Survive the Market Test?, Journal of Finance (1997); Manera,

Nicolini and Vignati, Futures Price Volatility in Commodities

Markets: The Role of Short-Term vs Long-Term Speculation (working

paper 2013); Mei, Acheinkman, and Xiong, Speculative Trading and

Stock Prices: An Analysis of Chinese A-B Share Premia, Annals of

Economics and Finance (2009); Morana, Oil Price Dynamics, Macro-

finance Interactions and the Role of Financial Speculation, Journal

of Banking & Finance, Vol. 37, Issue 1 (Jan. 2012); Mou, Limits to

Arbitrage and Commodity Index Investment: Front-Running the Goldman

roll (working paper 2011); Plato and Hoffman, Measuring the

Influence of Commodity Fund Trading on Soybean Price Discovery

(working paper 2007); Sornette, Woodard and Zhou, The 2006-2008 Oil

Bubble and Beyond: Evidence of Speculation, and Prediction, Physica

A. (2009); Stevans and Sessions, Speculation, Futures Prices, and

the U.S. Real Price of Crude Oil, American Journal of Social and

Management Science (2010); Trostle, Global Agricultural Supply and

Demand: Factors Contributing to the Recent Increase in Food

Commodity Prices, USDA Economic Research Service (2008);Van der

Molen, Speculators Invading the Commodity Markets (working paper

2009); Weiner, Do Birds of A Feather Flock Together? Speculation in

the Oil Markets, (Working Paper 2006); Weiner, Speculation in

International Crises: Report from the Gulf, Journal of Int'l

Business Studies (2005); Westcott and Hoffman, Price Determination

for Corn and Wheat: The Role of Market Factors and Government

Programs (working paper 1999); Wright, International Grain Reserves

and Other Instruments to Address Volatility in Grain Markets, World

Bank Research Observer (2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96725]]

Some economists have developed economic models for the supply and

demand of a commodity. These models often include theories of how

storage capacity and use affect supply and demand, which may influence

the price of a physical commodity over time. An economist looks at

where the model is in equilibrium with respect to quantities of a

commodity supplied and demanded to arrive at a ``fundamental'' price or

price return. The economist then looks for deviations between the

fundamental price (based on the model) and the actual price of a

commodity. When there is a statistically significant deviation between

the fundamental price and the actual price, the economist generally

infers that the price is not driven by market fundamentals of supply

and demand.

Switching Regressions or Similar Analyses \243\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\243\ Studies that include switching regressions or similar

analyses include: Brooks, Prokopczuk, and Wu, Boom and Bust in

Commodity Markets: Bubbles or Fundamentals? (working paper 2014);

Baldi and Peri, Price Discovery in Agricultural Commodities: the

Shifting Relationship Between Spot and Futures Prices (working paper

2011); Chevallier, Price Relationships in Crude oil Futures: New

Evidence from CFTC Disaggregated Data, Environmental Economics and

Policy Studies (2012); Cifarelli and Paladino, Commodity Futures

Returns: A non-linear Markov Regime Switching Model of Hedging and

Speculative Pressures (working paper 2010); Fan and Xu, What Has

Driven Oil Prices Since 2000? A Structural Change Perspective,

Energy Economics (2011); Hache and Lantz, Speculative Trading & Oil

Price Dynamic: A Study of the WTI Market, Energy Economics, Vol. 36,

p.340 (March 2013); Lammerding, Stephan, Trede, and Wifling,

Speculative Bubbles in Recent Oil Price Dynamics: Evidence from a

Bayesian Markov Switching State-Space Approach, Energy Economics

Vol. 36 (2013); Sigl-Gr[uuml]b and Schiereck, Speculation and

Nonlinear Price Dynamics in Commodity Futures Markets, Investment

Management and Financial Innovations, Vol. 77 (2010); Silvernnoinen

and Thorp, Financialization, Crisis and Commodity Correlation

Dynamics, Journal of Int'l Financial Markets, Institutions, and

Money (2013).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the context of studies relating to position limits, economists

employing switching regression analysis generally posit a model with

two states: A normal state, where prices reflect market fundamentals,

and a second state, often interpreted as a ``bubble.'' \244\ Using

price data, authors of these studies calculate the probability of a

transition between the two states. The point of transition is called a

structural ``breakpoint.'' Examination of these breakpoints permits the

researcher to identify the duration of a particular ``bubble.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\244\ While there is no broad academic consensus on the formal,

testable economic definition of the term ``price bubble,'' price

bubbles are colloquially thought to be unsustainable surges in asset

prices fueled by speculation and followed by ``crashes'' or

precipitous price drops.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Eigenvalue Stability Analysis \245\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\245\ Studies that employ eigenvalue stability analysis include:

Czudaj and Beckman, Spot and Futures Commodity Markets and the

Unbiasedness Hypothesis--Evidence from a Novel Panel Unit Root Test,

Economic Bulletin (2013); Du, Yu, and Hayes, Speculation and

Volatility Spillover in the Crude Oil and Agricultural Commodity

Markets: A Bayesian Analysis, (working paper 2012); Gilbert,

Speculative Influences on Commodity Futures Prices, 2006-2008, UN

Conference on Trade and Development (working paper 2010); Gutierrez,

Speculative Bubbles in Agricultural Commodity Markets, European

Review of Agricultural Economics (2012); Phillips and Yu, Dating the

Timeline of Financial Bubbles During the Subprime Crisis,

Quantitative Economics (2011).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some economists have run regression analyses \246\ on price and

time-lagged values of price. They estimate an equation that relates

current to past time values over short time intervals and solve for the

roots of that equation, called the eigenvalues (latent values), in

order to detect unusual price changes. If they find an eigenvalue \247\

with an absolute value of greater than one, they infer that the price

of the commodity is in a ``bubble.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\246\ In statistical modeling, regression analysis is a process

for estimating the relationships among certain types of variables

(values that change over time or in different circumstances).

\247\ In this context, an eigenvalue is a mathematical

calculation that summarizes the dynamic properties of the data

generated by the model. Generally, an eigenvalue is a concept from

linear algebra.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Theoretical Models \248\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\248\ Studies that present theoretical models include: Avriel

and Reisman, Optimal Option Portfolios in Markets with Position

Limits and Margin Requirements, Journal of Risk (2000); Dai, Jin and

Liu, Illiquidity, Position Limits, and Optimal Investment (working

paper 2009); Dicembrino and Scandizzo, The Fundamental and

Speculative Components of the Oil Spot Price: A Real Options Value

Approach (working paper 2012); Dutt and Harris, Position Limits for

Cash-Settled Derivative Contracts, Journal of Futures Markets

(2005); Ebrahim and ap Gwilym, Can Position Limits Restrain Rogue

Traders?, at p.832 Journal of Banking & Finance (2013); Edirsinghe,

Naik, and Uppal, Optimal Replication of Options with Transaction

Costs and Trading Restrictions, Journal of Financial and

Quantitative Analysis (1993); Froot, Scharfstein, and Stein, Herd on

the Street: Informational Inefficiencies in a Market with Short Term

Speculation, (Working Paper 1990); Kumar and Seppi, Futures

Manipulation with ``Cash Settlement'', Journal of Finance (1992);

Kyle and Viswanathan, How to Define Illegal Price Manipulation,

American Economic Review (2008); Kyle and Wang, Speculation Duopoly

with Agreement to Disagree: Can Overconfidence Survive the Market

Test?, Journal of Finance (1997); Lee, Cheng and Koh, An Analysis of

Extreme Price Shocks and Illiquidity Among Systematic Trend

Followers (working paper 2010); Leitner, Inducing Agents to Report

Hidden Trades: A Theory of an Intermediary, Review of Finance

(2012); Liu, Financial-Demand Based Commodity Pricing: A Theoretical

Model for Financialization of Commodities (working paper 2011);

Lombardi and van Robays, Do Financial Investors Destabilize the Oil

Price? (working paper, European Central Bank, 2011); Morris,

Speculative Investor Behavior and Learning, Quarterly Journal of

Economics (1996); Parsons, Black Gold & Fool's Gold: Speculation in

the Oil Futures Market, Economia (2009); Pierru and Babusiaux,

Speculation without Oil Stockpiling as a Signature: A Dynamic

Perspective (working paper 2010); Pirrong, Manipulation of the

Commodity Futures Market Delivery Process, Journal of Business

(1993); Pirrong, The Self-Regulation of Commodity Exchanges: The

Case of Market Manipulation, Journal of Law and Economics (1995);

Pliska and Shalen, The Effects of Regulation on Trading Activity and

Return Volatility in Futures Markets, Journal of Futures Markets

(2006); Routledge, Seppi, and Spatt, Equilibrium Forward Curves for

Commodities, Journal of Finance (2000); Schulmeister, Technical

Trading and Commodity Price Fluctuations (working paper 2012);

Schulmeister, Torero, and von Braun, Trading Practices and Price

Dynamics in Commodity Markets (working paper 2009); Shleifer and

Vishney, The Limits of Arbitrage, Journal of Finance (1997); Sockin

and Xiong, Feedback Effects of Commodity Futures Prices (working

paper 2012); Vansteenkiste, What is Driving Oil Price Futures?

Fundamentals Versus Speculation (working paper, European Central

Bank, 2011); Westerhoff, Speculative Markets and the Effectiveness

of Price Limits, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control (2003).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96726]]

Some studies perform little or no empirical analysis and instead

present a general theoretical model that may bear, directly or

indirectly, on the effect of excessive speculation in the commodities

markets. Because these papers do not include empirical analysis, they

contain many untested assumptions and conclusory statements, limiting

their usefulness to the Commission.

Surveys of Economic Literature and Opinion Pieces \249\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\249\ Studies that are survey or opinion pieces include:

Anderson, Outlaw, and Bryant, The Effects of Ethanol on Texas Food

and Feed, Agricultural and Food Policy Center Research Report

(2008); Baffes, The Long-term Implications of the 2007-2008

Commodity-Price Boom, Development in Practice (2011); Basu and

Gavin, What Explains the Growth in Commodity Derivatives? (working

paper 2011); Berg, The Rise of Commodity Speculation: from

Villainous to Venerable, (2011); Bessenbinder, Lilan, and Mahadeva,

The Role of Speculation in Oil Markets: What Have We Learned So Far?

(working paper 2012); Cagan, Financial Futures Markets: Is More

Regulation Needed?, Journal of Futures Markets (1981); Chincarini,

The Amaranth Debacle: Failure of Risk Measures or Failure of Risk

Management (working paper 2007); Chincarini, Natural Gas Futures and

Spread Position Risk: Lessons from the Collapse of Amaranth Advisors

L.L.C., Journal of Applied Finance (2008); CME Group, Inc.,

Excessive Speculation and Position Limits in Energy Derivatives

Markets (working paper); Cooper, Excessive Speculation and Oil Price

Shock Recessions: A Case of Wall Street ``D[eacute]j[agrave] vu All

Over Again,'' Consumer Federation of America (2011); Dahl, Future

Markets: The Interaction of Economic Analyses and Regulation:

Discussion, American Journal of Agricultural Economics (1980); De

Schutter, Food Commodities Speculation and Food Price Crises, United

Nations Special Report on the Right to Food (2010); Easterbrook,

Monopoly, Manipulation, and the Regulation of Futures Markets,

Journal of Business (1986); Eckaus, The Oil Price Really is a

Speculative Bubble (working paper 2008); Ellis, Michaely, and

O'Hara, The Making of a Dealer Market: From Entry to Equilibrium in

the Trading of Nasdaq Stocks, Journal of Finance (2002); European

Commission, Review of the Markets in Financial Instruments Directive

(working paper 2010); European Commission, Tackling the Challenges

in Commodity Markets, Communication from the European Commission to

the European Parliament (2011); Frenk and Turbeville, Commodity

Index Traders and the Boom/Bust Cycle in Commodities Prices, Better

Markets Copyright (2011); Goldman Sachs, Global Energy Weekly March

2011 (2011); Government Accountability Office, Issues Involving the

Use of the Futures Markets to Invest in Commodity Indexes, (Report

2009); Greenberger, The Relationship of Unregulated Excessive

Speculation to Oil Market Price Volatility (working paper 2010);

Harris, Circuit Breaker and Program Trading Limits: What Have We

Learned, Brooking Institutions Press (1997); Henn, CL-WEED-59628;

Her Majesty's Treasury, Global Commodities: A Long Term Vision for

Stable, Secure, and Sustainable Global Markets, (2008); House of

Commons Select Committee on Science & Technology of the United

Kingdom, Strategically Important Metals, (2011); Hunt, Thought for

the Day: Unreported Copper Stocks, Simon Hunt Strategic Services

(2011); Inamura Kimata, and Takeshi, Recent Surge in Global

commodity Prices--Impact of Financialization of Commodities and

Globally Accommodative Monetary Conditions, Bank of Japan Review

March 2011; International Monetary Fund, Is Inflation Back?

Commodity Prices and Inflation, Chapter 3 of IMF's World Economic

Outlook ``Financial Stress, Downturns, and Recoveries'' (2008);

Irwin and Sanders, Index Funds, Financialization, and Commodity

Futures Markets, Applied Economic Perspective and Policy (2010);

Jack, Populists vs Theorists: Futures Markets and the Volatility of

Prices, Exploration in Economic History (2006); Jickling and Austin,

Hedge Fund Speculation and Oil Prices (working paper 2011); Kemp,

Crisis Remarks the Commodity Business, Reuters Columnist (2008);

Khan, The 2008 Oil Price ``Bubble (working paper 2009); Koski and

Pontiff, How Are Derivatives Used? Evidence from the Mutual Fund

Industry, Journal of Finance (1996); Lagi, Bar-Yam, and Bertrand,

The Food Crisis: A Quantitative Model Of Food Prices Including

Speculators and Ethanol Conversion (working paper 2012); Lagi, Bar-

Yam, and Bertrand, The Food Crisis: A Quantitative Model Of Food

Prices Including Speculators and Ethanol Conversion (working paper

2011); Lines, Speculation in Food Commodity Markets, World

Development Movement (2010); Luciani, From Price Taker to Price

Maker? Saudi Arabia and the World Oil Market (working paper 2009);

Masters and White, The Accidental Hunt Brother: How Institutional

Investors are Driving UP Food and Energy Prices (working paper

2008); Medlock and Myers, Who is in the Oil Futures Market and How

Has It Changed?, (working paper 2009); Newman, Financialiation and

Changes in the Social Relations along commodity Chains: The Case of

Coffee, Review of Radical Political Economics (2009); Nissanke,

Commodity Markets and Excess Volatility: An Evolution of Price

Dynamics Under Financialization (working paper 2011); Nissanke,

Commodity Market Linkage in the Global Financial Crisis: Excess

Volatility and Development Impact, Journal of Development Studies

(2012); Parsons, Black Gold & Fool's Gold: Speculation in the Oil

Futures Market, (Economia 2009); Jones, Price Limits: A Return to

Patience and Rationality in U.S. Markets, Speech to the CME Global

Financial Leadership (2010); Petzel, Testimony before the CFTC,

(July 28, 2009); Pfuderer and Gilbert, Index Funds Do Impact

Agricultural Prices? (working paper 2012); Pirrong, Squeezes,

Corners, and the Anti-Manipulation Provisions of the Commodity

Exchange Act, Regulation (1994); Pirrong, Annex B to CL-ISDA/SIFMA-

59611; Plante and Yucel, Did Speculation Drive Oil Prices? Market

Fundamentals Suggest Otherwise, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

(2011); Plante and Yucel, Did Speculation Drive Oil Prices? Futures

Market Points to Fundamentals, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

(2011); Ray and Schaffer, Index Funds and the 2006-2008 Run-up in

Agricultural Commodity Prices (working paper 2010); Rossi, Analysis

of CFTC Proposed Position Limits on Commodity Index Fund Trading

(working paper 2011); Smith, World Oil: Market or Mayhem?, Journal

of Economic Perspectives (2009); Technical Committee of the

International Organization of Securities Commissions, Task Force on

Commodity Futures Market Final Report, (2009); Tokic, Rational

Destabilizing Speculation, Positive Feedback Trading, and the Oil

Bubble of 2008, Energy Economics (2011); U.S. Commodity Futures

Trading Commission, Part Two, A Study of the Silver Market, May 29,

1981, Report to the Congress in Response to Section 21 Of The

Commodity Exchange Act., (1981); U.S. Commodity Futures Trading

Commission, Staff Report on Commodity Swap Dealers and Index Traders

with Commission Recommendations, (2008); U.S. Senate Permanent

Subcommittee, Excessive Speculation in the Natural Gas Market,

(2007); U.S. Senate Permanent Subcommittee, Excessive Speculation in

the Wheat Market, (2009); U.S. Senate Permanent Subcommittee, The

Role of Market Speculation in Rising Oil and Gas Prices: A Need to

Put the cop Back on the Beat, (2006); United Nations Commission of

Experts on Reforms of the International and Monetary System, Report

of the Commission of Experts, (2009); United Nations Conference on

Trade and Development, The Global Economic Crisis: Systemic Failures

and Multilateral Remedies, (2009); United Nations Conference on

Trade and Development, The Financialization of Commodity Markets,

(2009); United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Trade

and Development Report: Price Formation in Financialized Commodity

Markets: The Role of Information, (2011); United Nations Food and

Agricultural Organization, Final Report of the Committee on

Commodity Problems: Extraordinary Joint Intersessional Meeting of

the Intergovernmental Group (IGG), (2010); United Nations Food and

Agricultural Organization, Price Volatility in Agricultural Markets,

Economic and Social Perspectives Policy Brief (2010); United Nations

Food and Agricultural Organization, Price Volatility in Food and

Agricultural Markets: Policy Response, (2011); Urbanchuk,

Speculation and the Commodity Markets (2011); Verleger, Annex A to

CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611; Woolley, Why are Financial Markets so

Inefficient and Exploitative--and a Suggested Remedy, (2010); Wray,

The Commodities Market Bubble: Money Manager Capitalism and the

Financialization of Commodities (working paper 2008).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission considered more than seventy studies that are survey

or opinion pieces. Some of these studies provide useful background

material but, on the whole, they offer mere opinion unsupported by

rigorous empirical analysis. While they may be useful for developing

hypotheses or informing policymakers, these secondary sources often

exhibit policy bias and are not neutral, reliable bases for scientific

inquiry the way that primary economic studies are.\250\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\250\ For example, these surveys may posit ``facts'' that are

unsupported by testing, may not test their hypotheses, or may claim

results that are subject to multiple interpretations.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

More Persuasive Academic Studies

While the economic literature is inconclusive, the Commission can

[[Page 96727]]

identify a few of the well-executed studies that do not militate

against and, to some degree, support the Commission's reproposal to

follow, out of due caution, a prophylactic approach.\251\ Hamilton and

Wu, in Risk Premia in Crude Oil Futures Prices, Journal of

International Money and Finance (2013), using models of fundamental

supply and demand, find evidence that changes in non-commercial

positions can affect the risk premium in crude oil futures prices; that

is, Hamilton and Wu found that, for a limited period around the time of

the 2008 financial crisis that gave rise to the Dodd-Frank Act,

increases in speculative positions reduced the risk premiums \252\ in

crude oil futures prices.\253\ This is important because, all else

being equal, one would expect the risk premium to be the component of

price that would be affected by traders accumulating large

positions.\254\ Hamilton, in Causes of the Oil Shock of 2007-2008,

Brookings Paper on Economic Activity (2009), also concludes that the

oil price run-up was caused by strong demand confronting stagnating

world production, but that something other than fundamental factors of

supply and demand (as modeled) may have aggravated the speed and

magnitude of the ensuing oil price collapse. Singleton, in Investor

Flows and the 2008 Boom/Bust in Oil Prices (working paper 2011),

employs a technique that is similar to Granger causality and finds a

negative correlation between speculative positions and risk

premiums.\255\ Chevallier, in Price Relationships in Crude Oil Futures:

New Evidence from CFTC Disaggregated Data, Environmental Economics and

Policy Studies (2012), applies switching regression analysis to

position data and concludes that one cannot eliminate the possibility

of speculation as one of the main factors contributing to oil price

volatility in 2008. This study also suggests that when supply and

demand are highly inelastic, i.e., relatively unresponsive to price

changes, financial investors may have contributed to oil price

volatility by taking large positions in energy sector commodity index

funds.\256\ As one may infer from this small sample, some of the more

compelling studies that support the proposition that large positions

may move prices involve empirical studies of the oil market. The

Commission acknowledges that not all commodity markets exhibit the same

price behavior at the same times. Even so, that the findings of a

particular study of the market experience of a particular commodity

over a particular time period may not be extensible to other commodity

markets or over other time periods does not mean that the Commission

should disregard that study. This is because, as explained elsewhere,

these markets are over time all susceptible to similar risks from

excessive speculation. Again, this supports a prophylactic approach to

limits and a determination that limits are necessary to effectuate

their statutory purposes.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\251\ Generally, studies that the Commission considers to be

well-executed, for example, employ well-accepted, defensible,

scientific methodology, document and present facts and results that

can be replicated, are on point regarding issues relevant to

position limits, and may eventually appear in respected, peer-

reviewed academic journals.

\252\ A risk premium is the amount of return on a particular

asset or investment that is in excess of the expected rate of return

on a theoretically risk free asset or investment, i.e., one with a

virtually certain or guaranteed return.

\253\ The economic rationale behind this is that speculative

traders would be taking long positions to earn the risk premium,

among other things. If more speculative traders are going long,

i.e., bidding to earn the risk premium, the risk premium would be

reduced. In this way, speculators make it cheaper for short hedgers

to lock in their price risk. Contra Harris and

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, The Role of Speculators in the Crude

Oil Futures Market (working paper 2009) (concluding that price

changes precede the position change). In this way, speculators make

it cheaper for short hedgers to lock in their price risk.

\254\ Long speculators would tend to be compensated for assuming

the price risk that is inherent with going long in the crude oil

futures contract. If more speculators are bidding to earn the risk

premium by taking long position in crude oil futures contracts, it

should lower the risk premium, all else being equal.

\255\ That is, when long speculative positions are larger, the

risk premiums are smaller.

\256\ See also Hamilton and Wu, Risk Premia in Crude Oil Futures

Prices, Journal of International Money and Finance (2013); Hamilton,

Causes of the Oil Shock of 2007-2008, Brookings Paper on Economic

Activity (2009).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

identified two studies of actual market events to be helpful and

persuasive in making its alternative necessity finding: \257\ The

inter-agency report on the silver crisis \258\ and the PSI Report on

Excessive Speculation in the Natural Gas Market.\259\ These two studies

and some of the other reports included in the survey category \260\ do

not use statistical or theoretical models to reach economically

rigorous conclusions. Some of the evidence cited in these studies is

anecdotal. Still, these two studies are in-depth examinations of actual

market events and the Commission continues to find them to be helpful

and persuasive in making its preliminary alternative necessity finding.

The Commission reiterates that the PSI Report (because it closely

preceded Congress' amendments to CEA section 4a(a) in the Dodd-Frank

Act) indicates how Congress views limits as necessary as a prophylactic

measure to prevent the adverse effects of excessively large speculative

positions. The studies, individually or taken as a whole, do not

dissuade the Commission from its consistent view that large speculative

positions and outsized market power pose risks to well-functioning

commodities markets, nor from its preliminary finding that speculative

position limits are necessary to achieve their statutory purposes.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\257\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75695-6.

\258\ U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Commission, ``Part Two, A

Study of the Silver Market,'' May 29, 1981, Report to Congress in

Response to Section 21 of The Commodity Exchange Act.

\259\ U.S. Senate Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations,

``Excessive Speculation in the Natural Gas Market,'' June 25, 2007.

\260\ E.g., U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Commission, Staff

Report on Commodity Swap Dealers and Index Traders with Commission

Recommendations (2008); U.S. Senate Permanent Subcommittee,

Excessive Speculation in the Wheat Market (2009); U.S. Senate

Permanent Subcommittee, The Role of Market Speculation in Rising Oil

and Gas Prices: A Need to Put the Cop Back on the Beat (2006).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission requests comment on its discussion of studies and

reports. It also invites commenters to advise the Commission of any

additional studies that the Commission should consider, and why.

II. Compliance Date for the Reproposed Rules

Commenters requested that the Commission delay the compliance date,

generally for at least nine months, to provide adequate time for market

participants to come into compliance with a final rule.\261\ In

addition, a commenter requested the Commission delay the compliance

date until no earlier than January 3, 2018, to coordinate with the

expected implementation date for position limits in Europe.\262\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\261\ See, e.g., CL-FIA-60937 at 5.

\262\ CL-FIA-61036 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to commenters, in this reproposal, the Commission

proposes to delay the compliance date of any final rule until, at

earliest, January 3, 2018, as provided under reproposed Sec. 150.2(e).

The Commission is of the opinion that a delay would provide market

participants with sufficient time to come into compliance with a final

rule, particularly in light of grandfathering provisions, discussed

below.

The Commission believes that a delay until January 3, 2018, would

provide time for market participants to gain

[[Page 96728]]

access to adequate systems to compute futures-equivalent positions. The

Commission bases this opinion on its experience, including with swap

dealers and clearing members of derivative clearing organizations, who,

as reporting entities under part 20 (swaps large trader reporting),

have been required to prepare reports of swaps on a futures-equivalent

basis for years. As discussed above, futures-equivalent reporting of

swaps under part 20 generally has improved. This means many reporting

entities already have implemented acceptable systems to compute

futures-equivalent positions. The systems developed for that purpose

also should be acceptable for monitoring compliance with position

limits. The Commission believes it is reasonable to expect some

reporting entities to offer futures-equivalent computation services to

market participants. In this regard, such reporting entities already

compute and report, under part 20, futures-equivalent positions for

swap counterparties with reportable positions, including spot-month

positions and non-spot-month positions.

The Commission notes that market participants who expect to be over

the limits would need to assess whether exemptions are available

(including requesting non-enumerated bona fide hedging positon

exemptions or spread exemptions from exchanges, as discussed below

under reproposed Sec. Sec. 150.9 and 150.10). In the absence of

exemptions, such market participants would need to develop plans for

coming into compliance.

The Commission notes the request for a further delay in a

compliance date may be mitigated by the grandfathering provisions in

the Reproposal. First, the reproposed rules would exclude from position

limits ``pre-enactment swaps'' and ``transition period swaps,'' as

discussed below. Second, the rules would exempt certain pre-existing

positions from position limits under reproposed Sec. 150.2(f).

Essentially, this means only futures contracts initially would be

subject to non-spot-month position limits, as well as swaps entered

after the compliance date. The Commission notes that a pre-existing

position in a futures contract also would not be a violation of a non-

spot-month limit, but, rather, would be grandfathered, as discussed

under reproposed Sec. 150.2(f)(2), below. Nevertheless, the Commission

intends to provide a substantial implementation period to ease the

compliance burden.

The Commission requests comment on its discussion of the proposed

compliance date.

III. Reproposed Rules

The Commission is not addressing comments that are beyond the scope

of this reproposed rulemaking.

A. Sec. 150.1--Definitions

1. Various Definitions Found in Sec. 150.1

Among other elements, the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

included amendments to the definitions of ``futures-equivalent,''

``long position,'' ``short position,'' and ``spot-month'' found in

Sec. 150.1 of the Commission's regulations, to conform them to the

concepts and terminology of the CEA, as amended by the Dodd-Frank Act.

The Commission also proposed to add to Sec. 150.1, definitions for

``basis contract,'' ``calendar spread contract,'' ``commodity

derivative contract,'' ``commodity index contract,'' ``core referenced

futures contract,'' ``eligible affiliate,'' ``entity,'' ``excluded

commodity,'' ``intercommodity spread contract,'' ``intermarket spread

positions,'' ``intramarket spread positions,'' ``physical commodity,''

``pre-enactment swap,'' ``pre-existing position,'' ``referenced

contract,'' ``spread contract,'' ``speculative position limit,''

``swap,'' ``swap dealer'' and ``transition period swap.'' In addition,

the Commission proposed to move the definition of bona fide hedging

from Sec. 1.3(z) into part 150, and to amend and update it. Moreover,

the Commission proposed to delete the definition for ``the first

delivery month of the `crop year.' '' \263\ Separately, the Commission

proposed making a non-substantive change to list the definitions in

alphabetical order rather than by use of assigned letters.\264\

According to the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, this last

change would be helpful when looking for a particular definition, both

in the near future, in light of the additional definitions proposed to

be adopted, and in the expectation that future rulemakings may adopt

additional definitions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\263\ At that time, the Commission noted that several terms that

are not currently in part 150 were not included in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal even though definitions for those terms

were adopted in vacated part 151. The Commission stated its view

that the definition of those terms was not necessary for clarity in

light of other revisions proposed in that rulemaking. The terms not

proposed at that time include ``swaption'' and ``trader.''

\264\ The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal also made

several non-substantive edits to the definitions to make them easier

to read.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Finally, in connection with the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, which provided new alternative processes for DCMs and SEFs to

recognize certain positions in commodity derivative contracts as non-

enumerated bona fide hedges or enumerated anticipatory bona fide

hedges, and to exempt from federal position limits certain spread

positions, the Commission proposed to further amend certain relevant

definitions, including changes to the definitions of ``futures-

equivalent,'' ``intermarket spread position,'' and ``intramarket spread

position.''

Separately, as noted in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

amendments to two definitions were proposed in the November 2013

Aggregation Proposal,\265\ which was approved by the Commission on the

same date as the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal. The November

2013 Aggregation Proposal, a companion to the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, included amendments to the definitions of ``eligible

entity'' and ``independent account controller.'' \266\ The Commission

notes that since the amendments were part of the separate Aggregation

proposal, the proposed amendments to those definitions, and comments

thereon, are addressed in the final Aggregation rulemaking (the ``2016

Final Aggregation Rule''); \267\ therefore, the Commission is not

addressing the definitions of ``eligible entity'' and ``independent

account controller'' herein.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\265\ See Aggregation of Positions, 78 FR 68946 (Nov. 15, 2013)

at 68965, 68974 (proposing changes to the definitions of ``eligible

entity'' and ``independent account controller'') (``November 2013

Aggregation Proposal''). The Commission issued a supplement to this

proposal in September 2015, but the supplement did not propose any

changes to the definitions. See 80 FR 58365 (Sept. 29, 2015).

\266\ The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal mirrored the

amendments to the definitions of ``eligible entity'' and

``independent account controller,'' proposed in the November 2013

Aggregation Proposal, and also included some non-substantive change

to the definition of ``independent account controller.''

\267\ See 2016 Final Aggregation Rule, adopted by the Commission

separately from this Reproposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is reproposing the amendments to the definitions in

Sec. 150.1, as set forth in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

and as amended in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, with

modifications made in response to public comments. The Reproposal also

includes non-substantive changes to certain definitions to enhance

readability and clarity for market participants and the public,

including the extraction of definitions that were contained in the

definition of ``referenced contract'' to stand on their own. The

amendments and the public

[[Page 96729]]

comments relevant to each amendment are discussed below.

a. Basis Contract

Proposed Rule: In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission proposed to exclude ``basis contracts'' from the definition

of ``referenced contracts.'' \268\ While the term ``basis contract'' is

not defined in current Sec. 150.1, the Commission proposed a

definition for basis contract in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal. Proposed Sec. 150.1 defined basis contract to mean ``a

commodity derivative contract that is cash-settled based on the

difference in: (1) The price, directly or indirectly, of: (a) A

particular core referenced futures contract; or (b) a commodity

deliverable on a particular core referenced futures contract, whether

at par, a fixed discount to par, or a premium to par; and (2) the

price, at a different delivery location or pricing point than that of

the same particular core referenced futures contract, directly or

indirectly, of: (a) A commodity deliverable on the same particular core

referenced futures contract, whether at par, a fixed discount to par,

or a premium to par; or (b) a commodity that is listed in appendix B to

this part as substantially the same as a commodity underlying the same

core referenced futures contract.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\268\ The Commission also notes that the proposed definition of

``commodity index contract'' excluded intercommodity spread

contracts, calendar spread contracts, and basis contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also proposed Appendix B to part 150, Commodities

Listed as Substantially the Same for Purposes of the Definition of

Basis Contract. As proposed, the definition of basis contract would

include contracts cash-settled on the difference in prices of two

different, but economically closely related commodities, for example,

certain quality differentials (e.g., RBOB gasoline vs. 87

unleaded).\269\ As explained when it was proposed, the intent of the

proposed definition was to reduce the potential for excessive

speculation in referenced contracts where, for example, a speculator

establishes a large outright directional position in referenced

contracts and nets down that directional position with a contract based

on the difference in price of the commodity underlying the referenced

contracts and a close economic substitute that was not deliverable on

the core referenced futures contract.\270\ In the absence of this

provision, the speculator could then increase further the large

position in the referenced contracts. By way of comparison, the

Commission noted in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal that

there is greater concern (i) that someone may manipulate the markets by

disguise of a directional exposure through netting down the directional

exposure using one of the legs of a quality differential (if that

quality differential contract were not exempted), than (ii) that

someone may use certain quality differential contracts that were

exempted from position limits to manipulate the outright price of a

referenced contract.\271\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\269\ The proposed basis contract definition was not intended to

include significant time differentials in prices of the two

commodities (e.g., the proposed basis contract definition did not

include calendar spreads for nearby vs. deferred contracts).

\270\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal at 75696.

\271\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received a number of comment

letters regarding the proposed definition of basis contract. One

commenter supported the proposed definition of basis contract and

stated that it appreciates the Commission's inclusion of Appendix B

listing the commodities it believes are substantially the same as a

core referenced futures contract for purposes of identifying contracts

that meet the basis contract definition.\272\ Other comment letters

requested that the Commission broaden the definition to include

contracts that settle to other types of differentials, such as

processing differentials (e.g., crack or crush spreads) or quality

differentials (e.g., sweet vs. sour crude oil). One commenter

recommended a definition of basis contract that includes crack spreads,

by-products priced at a differential to other by-products (e.g., jet

fuel vs. heating oil, both of which are crude oil by-products), and a

commodity that includes similar commodities such as a contract based on

the difference in prices between light sweet crude and a sour crude

that is not deliverable against the NYMEX Light Sweet Crude Oil core

referenced futures contract. This commenter suggested that if these

types of contracts are included as basis contracts, market participants

should be able to net certain contracts where a commodity is priced at

a differential to a product or by-product, subject to prior approval

according to a process created by the Commission.\273\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\272\ CL-Working Group-59693 at 68.

\273\ CLWorking Group-59959 at 16.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Two commenters specifically requested that the list in Appendix B

include Jet fuel (54 grade) as substantially the same as heating oil

(67 grade). They also requested that WTI Midland (Argus) vs. WTI

Financial Futures should be listed as basis contracts for Light

Louisiana Sweet (LLS) Crude Oil.\274\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\274\ CL-FIA-59595 at 19; CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 35.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Noting that basis contracts are excluded from the definition of

referenced contract and thus not subject to speculative position

limits, two commenters requested CFTC expand the list in Appendix B to

part 150 of commodities considered substantially the same as a core

referenced futures contract, and the corresponding list of basis

contracts, to reflect the commercial practices of market

participants.\275\ One of these commenters recommended that the

Commission adopt a flexible process for identifying any additional

commodities that are substantially the same as a commodity underlying a

core referenced futures contract for inclusion in Appendix B, and allow

market participants to request a timely interpretation regarding

whether a particular commodity is substantially the same as a core

referenced futures contract or that a particular contract qualifies as

a basis contract.\276\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\275\ CL-FIA-59595 at 4 and 18-19; CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 34-35.

\276\ CL-FIA-59595 at 19.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

the definition of basis contract as originally proposed, but to change

the defined term from ``basis contract'' to ``location basis

contract.'' The Commission intended the ``basis contract'' definition

to encompass contracts that settle to the difference between prices in

separate delivery locations of the same (or substantially the same)

commodity, while the industry seems to use the term ``basis'' more

broadly to include other price differentials, including, among other

things, processing differentials and quality differentials. Thus, under

the Reproposal, the term is changing from ``basis contract'' to

``location basis contract'' in order to reduce any confusion stemming

from the more encompassing use of the word ``basis'' in industry

parlance.\277\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\277\ Consequently, the Commission realizes that its

determination to retain its traditional definition while clarifying

its meaning by adopting the amended term of ``locational basis

contract'' does not provide for the expanded definition of basis

contract requested by some of the commenters. A broader definition

of basis contract would result in the exclusion of more derivative

contracts from the definition of referenced contract than previously

proposed. A contract excluded from the definition of referenced

contract is not subject to position limit under this Reproposal. The

Commission declines to exclude more than the locational basis

contracts that it previously proposed from the definition of

referenced contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96730]]

The Commission is reproposing Appendix B as originally proposed.

The Commission is not persuaded by commenters' suggestions for

expanding the current list of commodities considered ``substantially

the same'' in Appendix B. While a commenter requested the Commission

expand the list to address all ``commercial practices'' used by market

participants, the Commission believes this request is too vague and too

broad to be workable. In addition, although a commenter recommended

that the Commission adopt a flexible process for identifying any

additional commodities that are substantially the same as a commodity

underlying a core referenced futures contract for inclusion in Appendix

B,\278\ the Commission observes that market participants are already

provided the flexibility of two processes: (i) To request an exemptive,

no-action or interpretative letter under Sec. 140.99; and/or (ii) to

petition for changes to Appendix B under Sec. 13.2. Under either

process, the Commission would need to carefully consider whether it

would be beneficial and consistent with the policies underlying CEA

section 4a to list additional commodities as substantially the same as

a commodity underlying a core referenced futures contract, especially

since various market participants might have conflicting views on such

a determination in certain cases.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\278\ As noted above, according to the commenter, a flexible

process would allow market participants to request a timely

interpretation regarding whether a particular commodity is

substantially the same as a core referenced futures contract or that

a particular contract qualifies as a ``basis contract. See CL-FIA-

59595 at 19

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Finally, the Commission notes that comments regarding other types

of differentials were addressed in the Commission's 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal, which would allow exchanges to grant spread

exemptions, including calendar spreads, quality differential spreads,

processing spreads, and product or by-product differential

spreads.\279\ Comments responding to that 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal and the Commission's Reproposal are discussed below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\279\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38476-80.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Commodity Derivative Contract

Proposed Rule: The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal would

define in Sec. 150.1 the term ``commodity derivative contract'' for

position limits purposes as shorthand for any futures, option, or swap

contract in a commodity (other than a security futures product as

defined in CEA section 1a(45)). The proposed use of such a generic term

would be a convenient way to streamline and simplify references in part

150 to the various kinds of contracts to which the position limits

regime applies. As such, this new definition can be found frequently

throughout the Commission's proposed amendments to part 150.\280\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\280\ See, e.g., amendments to Sec. 150.1 (the definitions of:

``location basis contract,'' the definition of ``bona fide hedging

position,'' ``inter-market spread position,'' ``intra-market spread

position,'' ``pre-existing position,'' ``speculative position

limits,'' and ``spot month''), Sec. Sec. 150.2(f)(2), 150.3(d),

150.3(h), 150.5(a), 150.5(b), 150.5(e), 150.7(d), 150.7(f), Appendix

A to part 150, and Appendix C to part 150.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on the

proposed definition.

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

the definition as proposed for the reasons given above.

c. Commodity Index Contract, Spread Contract, Calendar Spread Contract,

and Intercommodity Spread Contract

Proposed Rule: The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal excluded

commodity index contracts from the definition of referenced contracts;

thus, commodity index contracts would not be subject to position

limits. The Commission also proposed to define the term commodity index

contract, which is not in current Sec. 150.1, to mean ``an agreement,

contract, or transaction that is not a basis contract or any type of

spread contract, based on an index comprised of prices of commodities

that are not the same or substantially the same.''

Further, the Commission proposed to add a definition of basis

contract, as discussed above, and spread contract to clarify which

types of contracts would not be considered a commodity index contract

and thus would be subject to position limits. Under the proposal, a

spread contract was defined as ``a calendar spread contract or an

intercommodity spread contract.'' \281\ Finally, the Commission

proposed the addition of definitions for a calendar spread contract,

and an intercommodity spread contract to clarify the meanings of those

terms. In particular, under the proposal, a calendar spread contract

would mean ``a cash-settled agreement, contract, or transaction that

represents the difference between the settlement price in one or a

series of contract months of an agreement, contract or transaction and

the settlement price of another contract month or another series of

contract months' settlement prices for the same agreement, contract or

transaction.'' An intercommodity spread contract would mean ``a cash-

settled agreement, contract or transaction that represents the

difference between the settlement price of a referenced contract and

the settlement price of another contract, agreement, or transaction

that is based on a different commodity.'' \282\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\281\ In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission noted that while the proposed definition of ``referenced

contract'' specifically excluded guarantees of a swap, basis

contracts and commodity index contracts, spread contracts were not

excluded from the proposed definition of ``referenced contract.''

The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal at 75702.

\282\ In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission also clarified that if a swap was based on the difference

between two prices of two different commodities, with one linked to

a core referenced futures contract price (and the other either not

linked to the price of a core referenced futures contract or linked

to the price of a different core referenced futures contract), then

the swap was an ``intercommodity spread contract,'' was not a

commodity index contract, and was a referenced contract subject to

the position limits specified in Sec. 150.2. The Commission further

clarified that a contract based on the prices of a referenced

contract and the same or substantially the same commodity (and not

based on the difference between such prices) was not a commodity

index contract and was a referenced contract subject to position

limits specified in Sec. 150.2. See December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, 78 FR at 75697, n. 163.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal further noted that part

20 of the Commission's regulations requires reporting entities to

report commodity reference price data sufficient to distinguish between

commodity index contract and non-commodity index contract positions in

covered contracts.\283\ Therefore, for commodity index contracts, the

Commission stated its intention to rely on the data elements in Sec.

20.4(b) to distinguish data records subject to Sec. 150.2 position

limits from those contracts that are excluded from Sec. 150.2. The

Commission explained that this would enable the Commission to set

position limits using the narrower data set (i.e., referenced contracts

subject to Sec. 150.2 position limits) as well as conduct surveillance

using the broader data set.\284\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\283\ Id. at 75697, n. 163.

\284\ Id. at 75697.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on the

proposed definitions for commodity index contract, spread contract,

calendar spread contract, and intercommodity spread contract.\285\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\285\ The Commission notes that although it did not receive

comments on the proposed definitions for commodity index contract,

spread contract, calendar spread contract, and intercommodity spread

contract, it did receive a number of comments regarding the

interplay of those defined terms and the definition of ``referenced

contract.'' Discussion of those comments are included in the

discussion of the proposed definition of ``referenced contract''

below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96731]]

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

the definitions as originally proposed for the reasons provided above,

with the exception that, under the Reproposal, the term ``basis

contract'' will be replaced with the term ``location basis contract,''

in the reproposed definition of commodity index contract, to conform to

the name change discussed above. In addition, the Commission notes that

while it had proposed to subsume the definitions of commodity index

contract, spread contract, calendar spread contract, and intercommodity

spread contract under the definition of referenced contract, in the

Reproposal it is enumerating each as a separate definition for ease of

reference.

d. Core referenced Futures Contract

Proposed Rule: The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal provided

a list of futures contracts in Sec. 150.2(d) to which proposed

position limit rules would apply. The Commission proposed the term

``core referenced futures contract'' as a short-hand phrase to denote

such contracts.\286\ Accordingly, the Commission proposed to include in

Sec. 150.1 a definition of core referenced futures contract to mean

``a futures contract that is listed in Sec. 150.2(d).'' In its

proposal, the Commission also clarified that core referenced futures

contracts include options that expire into outright positions in such

contracts.\287\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\286\ The selection of the core referenced futures contracts is

explained in the discussion of Sec. 150.2. See discussion below.

\287\ See 78 FR at 75697 n. 166.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on the

proposed definition.

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

the definition as originally proposed.

e. Eligible Affiliate

Proposed Rule: The term ``eligible affiliate,'' used in proposed

Sec. 150.2(c)(2), is not defined in current Sec. 150.1. The

Commission proposed to amend Sec. 150.1 to define an ``eligible

affiliate'' as an entity with respect to which another person: (1)

Directly or indirectly holds either: (i) A majority of the equity

securities of such entity, or (ii) the right to receive upon

dissolution of, or the contribution of, a majority of the capital of

such entity; (2) reports its financial statements on a consolidated

basis under Generally Accepted Accounting Principles or International

Financial Reporting Standards, and such consolidated financial

statements include the financial results of such entity; and (3) is

required to aggregate the positions of such entity under Sec. 150.4

and does not claim an exemption from aggregation for such entity.\288\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\288\ See proposed Sec. 150.1.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The definition of ``eligible affiliate'' proposed in the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal qualified persons as eligible affiliates

based on requirements similar to those adopted by the Commission in a

separate rulemaking.\289\ On April 1, 2013, the Commission provided

relief from the mandatory clearing requirement of CEA section

2(h)(1)(A) of the Act for certain affiliated persons if the affiliated

persons (``eligible affiliate counterparties'') meet requirements

contained in Sec. 50.52.\290\ Under both Sec. 50.52 and the

definition proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, a

person is an eligible affiliate if another person (e.g. a parent

company), directly or indirectly, holds a majority ownership interest

in such affiliates, reports its financial statements on a consolidated

basis under Generally Accepted Accounting Principles or International

Financial Reporting Standards, and such consolidated financial

statements include the financial results of such affiliates. In

addition, for purposes of the position limits regime, that other person

(e.g., a parent company) must be required to aggregate the positions of

such affiliates under Sec. 150.4 and not claim an exemption from

aggregation for such affiliates.\291\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\289\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75698.

\290\ See Clearing Exemption for Swaps Between Certain

Affiliated Entities, 78 FR 21749, 21783, Apr. 11, 2013. Section

50.52(a) addresses eligible affiliate counterparty status, allowing

a person not to clear a swap subject to the clearing requirement of

section 2(h)(1)(A) of the Act and part 50 if the person meets the

requirements of the conditions contained in paragraphs (a) and (b)

of Sec. 50.52. The conditions in paragraph (a) of Sec. 50.52

specify either one counterparty holds a majority ownership interest

in, and reports its financial statements on a consolidated basis

with, the other counterparty, or both counterparties are majority

owned by a third party who reports its financial statements on a

consolidated basis with the counterparties.

The conditions in paragraph (b) of Sec. 50.52 address factors

such as the decision of the parties not to clear, the associated

documentation, audit, and recordkeeping requirements, the policies

and procedures that must be established, maintained, and followed by

a dealer and major swap participant, and the requirement to have an

appropriate centralized risk management program, rather than the

nature of the affiliation. As such, those conditions are less

pertinent to the definition of eligible affiliate.

\291\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75698; see also definition of ``eligible affiliate'' in Sec. 150.1,

as proposed therein.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received few comments on the

proposed definition of ``eligible affiliate.'' Commenters requested

that the Commission harmonize the definition of ``eligible affiliate''

with the definition of ``eligible affiliate counterparty'' under Sec.

50.52 in order to include ``sister affiliates'' within the

definition.\292\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\292\ See, e.g., CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 3 and 33, CL-Working

Group-59693 at 66-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission notes that under Sec. 150.4,

aggregation is required by a person that holds an ownership or equity

interest of 10 percent or greater in another person, unless an

exemption applies. Under reproposed Sec. 150.2(c)(2), sister

affiliates would not be required to comply separately with position

limits, provided such entities are eligible affiliates.\293\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\293\ Of course, sister affiliates would be required to

aggregate, as would any other market participants, if they were

trading together pursuant to an express or implied agreement.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As such, the Commission does not believe a there is a need to

conform the ``eligible affiliate'' definition in reproposed Sec. 150.1

to the definition of ``eligible affiliate counterparty'' in Sec. 50.52

in order to accommodate sister affiliates. The Commission notes that a

third person that holds an ownership or equity interest in each of the

sister affiliates--e.g., the parent company--would be required to

aggregate positions of such eligible affiliates. Thus, the Commission

is reproposing the definition without changes.

f. Entity

Proposed Rule: The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal defined

``entity'' to mean ``a `person' as defined in section 1a of the Act.''

\294\ The term, not defined in current Sec. 150.1, is used in a number

of contexts, and in various definitions in the proposed amendments to

part 150. Thus, the definition originally proposed would provide a

clear and unambiguous meaning for the term, and prevent confusion.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\294\ CEA section 1a(38); 7 U.S.C. 1a(38). See also December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75698.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on the

proposed definition.

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

the definition as originally proposed, for the reasons provided above.

g. Excluded Commodity

Proposed Rule: The phrase ``excluded commodity'' was added into the

CEA in the CFMA, and is defined in CEA

[[Page 96732]]

section 1a(19), but is not defined or used in current part 150.\295\

CEA section 4a(a)(2)(A), as amended by the Dodd-Frank Act, utilizes the

phrase ``excluded commodity'' when it provides a timeline under which

the Commission is charged with setting limits for futures and option

contracts other than on excluded commodities.\296\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\295\ CEA section 1a(19); 7 U.S.C. 1a(19).

\296\ CEA section 4a(2)(A); 7 U.S.C. 6a(2)(A).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal included in Sec. 150.1,

a definition of excluded commodity that simply incorporates the

statutory meaning, as a useful term for purposes of a number of the

proposed changes to part 150. For example, the phrase was used in the

proposed amendments to Sec. 150.5, in its provision of requirements

and acceptable practices for DCMs and SEFs in their adoption of rules

and procedures for monitoring and enforcing position limits and

accountability provisions; the phrase was also used in the definition

of bona fide hedging position.

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on the

proposed definition.

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

the definition as previously proposed, for the reasons provided above.

h. First Delivery Month of the Crop Year

Proposed Rule: The term ``first delivery month of the crop year''

is currently defined in Sec. 150.1(c), with a table of the first

delivery month of the crop year for the commodities for which position

limits are currently provided in Sec. 150.2. The crop year definition

had been pertinent for purposes of the spread exemption to the

individual month limit in current Sec. 150.3(a)(3), which limits

spreads to those between individual months in the same crop year and to

a level no more than that of the all-months limit.\297\ Under the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the definition of ``crop year''

would be deleted from Sec. 150.1. The proposed elimination of the

definition conformed with level of individual month limits set at the

level of the all-months limits, thus negating the purpose of the

existing spread exemption in current Sec. 150.3(a)(3), which the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal also eliminated.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\297\ Prior to the adoption of Part 151, a single-month limit

was set at a level that was lower than the all-months-combined

limit. Operating in conjunction with the lower single-month limit

level, as noted below, Sec. 150.3(a)(3) provides a limited

exemption for calendar spread positions to exceed that single-month

limit, as long as the single month position (including calendar

spread positions) is no greater than the level of the all-months-

combined limit. In part 151, the Commission determined to set the

single-month position limit levels in Sec. 150.2 at the same level

as the all-months-combined limits; in vacating part 151, the court

retained the amendments to Sec. 150.2, leaving the single-month

limit at the same level as those of the all-months-combined limit

levels. The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal retained parity

of the single-month limit and all-months-combined limits levels.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that in its 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, the Commission proposed to retain a spread exemption in Sec.

150.3 and not, as proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, to eliminate it altogether.\298\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\298\ Moreover, the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal

did not limit the exemption to spread positions held between

individual months of a futures contract in the same crop year, nor

limit the size of an individual month position to the all-months

limit.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on the

proposed deletion of the crop year definition.

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

the deletion of the definition of the term ``first delivery month of

the crop year'' as originally proposed. The Commission notes that,

although in its 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission proposed to retain a spread exemption in Sec. 150.3 and, in

fact, provides for the approval by exchanges of exemptions to spread

positions beyond the limited exemption for spread positions in current

Sec. 150.3(a)(3), the crop year definition remains unnecessary since

the level of individual month limits has been set at the level of the

all-months limits.

i. Futures Equivalent

Proposed Rule: In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission proposed to broaden the definition of the term ``futures-

equivalent'' found in current Sec. 150.1(f) of the Commission's

regulations,\299\ and to expand upon clarifications included in the

current definition relating to adjustments and computation times.\300\

The Dodd-Frank Act amendments to CEA section 4a,\301\ in part, direct

the Commission to apply aggregate federal position limits to physical

commodity futures contracts and to swaps contracts that are

economically equivalent to such physical commodity futures contracts on

which the Commission has established limits. In order to aggregate

positions in futures, options and swaps contracts, it is necessary to

adjust the position sizes, since such contracts may have varying units

of trading (e.g., the amount of a commodity underlying a particular

swap contract could be larger than the amount of a commodity underlying

a core referenced futures contract). The Commission proposed to adjust

position sizes to an equivalent position based on the size of the unit

of trading of the core referenced futures contract. Under the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, the definition of ``futures equivalent''

in current Sec. 150.1(f), which is applicable only to an option

contract, would be extended to both options and swaps.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\299\ 17 CFR 150.1(f) currently defines ``futures-equivalent''

only for an option contract, adjusting the open position in options

by the previous day's risk factor, as calculated at the close of

trading by the exchange.

\300\ The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal defined

``futures-equivalent'' for: (1) An option contact, adjusting the

position size by an economically reasonable and analytically

supported risk factor, computed as of the previous day's close or

the current day's close or contemporaneously during the trading day;

and (2) a swap, converting the position size to an economically

equivalent amount of an open position in a core referenced futures

contract. See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75698-9.

\301\ Amendments to CEA section 4a(1) authorize the Commission

to extend position limits beyond futures and option contracts to

swaps traded on an exchange and swaps not traded on an exchange that

perform or affect a significant price discovery function with

respect to regulated entities. 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(1). In addition, under

new CEA sections 4a(a)(2) and 4a(a)(5), speculative position limits

apply to agricultural and exempt commodity swaps that are

``economically equivalent'' to DCM futures and option contracts. 7

U.S.C. 6a(a)(2) and (5).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed two further clarifications to the definition of the term

``futures-equivalent.'' First, the Commission proposed to address

circumstances in which a referenced contract for which futures

equivalents must be calculated is itself a futures contract. The

Commission noted that this may occur, for example, when the referenced

contract is a futures contract that is a mini-sized version of the core

referenced futures contract (e.g., the mini-corn and the corn futures

contracts).\302\ The Commission proposed to clarify in proposed Sec.

150.1 that the term ``futures-equivalent'' includes a futures contract

which has been converted to an economically equivalent amount of an

open position in a core

[[Page 96733]]

referenced futures contract. This clarification would mirror the

expanded definition of ``futures-equivalent'' in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal, as it would pertain to swaps.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\302\ Under current Sec. 150.2, for purposes of compliance with

federal position limits, positions in regular sized and mini-sized

contracts are aggregated. The Commission's practice of aggregating

futures contracts when a DCM lists for trading two or more futures

contracts with substantially identical terms, is to scale down a

position in the mini-sized contract, by multiplying the position in

the mini-sized contract by the ratio of the unit of trading in the

mini-sized contract to that of the regular sized contract. See

paragraph (b)(2)(D) of app. C to part 38 of the Commission's

regulations for guidance regarding the contract size or trading unit

for a futures or futures option contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Second, the Commission proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal to clarify the definition of the term ``futures-

equivalent'' to provide that, for purposes of calculating futures

equivalents, an option contract must also be converted to an

economically equivalent amount of an open position in a core referenced

futures contract. This clarification would address situations, for

example, where the unit of trading underlying an option contract (that

is, the notional quantity underlying an option contract) may differ

from the unit of trading underlying a core referenced futures

contract.\303\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\303\ For an example of a futures-equivalent conversion of a

swaption, see example 6, WTI swaptions, Appendix A to part 20 of the

Commission's regulations.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission expressed the view in the 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal that these clarifications would be consistent with the

methodology the Commission used to provide its analysis of unique

persons over percentages of the proposed position limit levels in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal.\304\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\304\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38483. See also Table 11 in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, 78 FR at 75731-3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received two comments on the

proposed definition of ``futures-equivalent'' in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal.\305\ Each comment was generally supportive of

the proposed definition. Although one commenter commended the

flexibility granted to market participants to use different option

valuation models, it recommended that the Commission provide guidance

on when it would consider an option valuation model unsatisfactory and

what the factors the Commission would consider in arriving at such an

opinion.\306\ According to the commenter, the Commission should utilize

a ``reasonableness approach'' by explicitly providing a ``safe harbor''

for models that produce results within 10 percent of an exchange or

Commission model, and should permit market participants to demonstrate

the reasonableness under prevailing market conditions of any model that

falls outside this safe harbor.\307\ It was also recommended that the

Commission consider the exchanges' approach to option valuation where

appropriate because these approaches are already in use and familiar to

market participants.\308\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\305\ CL-MFA-59606; CL-FIA-59595 at 15.

\306\ CL-MFA-59606 at 16-17.

\307\ MFA also stated that the Commission should not second

guess the results of reasonable models and impose findings of

violations after-the-fact as that would introduce tremendous

uncertainty into compliance with the position limits regime. Id at

17.

\308\ Id at 17.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Both MFA and FIA supported the optional use of the prior day's

delta to calculate a futures-equivalent position for purposes of

speculative position limit compliance.\309\ In addition, each requested

that the Commission confirm or adopt a provision similar to CME Rule

562. That exchange rule provides, among other things, that if a

participant's position exceeds position limits as a result of an option

assignment, that participant is allowed one business day to liquidate

the excess position without being considered in violation of the

limits. FIA urged the Commission to provide market participants with a

reasonable period of time to reduce its position below the speculative

position limit.\310\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\309\ CL-MFA-59606 at 17; CL-FIA-59595 at 15.

\310\ CL-FIA-59595 at 15.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

the definition of ``futures-equivalent'' as proposed in the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits proposal, with the exception that it now

proposes adopting the current exchange practice with regard to option

assignments, as discussed below.

Regarding risk (delta) models, the Reproposal does not provide a

``safe harbor'' as requested since risk models, generally, should

produce similar results. The Commission believes a difference of 10

percent above or below the delta resulting from an exchange's model

generally would be too great to be economically reasonable. However,

the Commission notes that, under the Reproposal, should a market

participant believe its model produces an economically reasonable and

analytically supported risk factor for a particular trading session

that differs significantly from a result published by an exchange for

that same time,\311\ it may describe the circumstances that result in a

significant difference and request that staff review that model for

reasonableness.\312\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\311\ Under Sec. 16.01(a)(2), a reporting market is required to

record for each trading session the option delta, when a delta

system is used, while Sec. 16.01(e) requires a reporting market to

make that option delta readily available to the public. A reporting

market for this purpose is defined in Sec. 15.00(q) as a DCM or a

registered entity under CEA section 1a(40) (under CEA section

1a(40), registered entities include, among others, DCMs, DCOs, SEFs,

SDRs).

\312\ Deltas are computed using an option pricing model.

Different option pricing models incorporate different assumptions.

For a discussion of circumstances where assumptions in an option

pricing model may not hold, see, for example, Paul Wilmott,

Derivatives: The Theory and Practice of Financial Engineering

chapter 29 (1998) (describing circumstances where delta hedging an

option position (i.e., replication trading) can move the price of

the underlying asset, violating an assumption of certain option

pricing models that replication trading has no influence on the

price of the underlying asset).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Regarding the time period for a participant to come into compliance

because of option assignment, the Commission agrees that a participant

in compliance only because of a previous day's delta, and no longer,

after option assignment, in compliance on a subsequent day, should have

one business day to liquidate the excess position resulting from option

assignment without being considered in violation of the limits.\313\

Exchanges currently provide the same amount of time to come into

compliance.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\313\ The Commission believes that, in the circumstance of

option assignment, one business day is a reasonable amount of time

to come into compliance because the markets for commodities subject

to federal limits under Sec. 150.2 are generally liquid.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

j. Intermarket Spread Position and Intramarket Spread Position

Proposed Rule: In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission proposed to add to current Sec. 150.1 new definitions of

the terms ``intermarket spread position'' and ``intramarket spread

position.'' \314\ These terms were defined in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal within the definition of ``referenced

contract.'' In connection with its 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal to permit exchanges to process applications for exemptions

from federal position limits for certain spread positions, the

Commission proposed to expand the definitions of these terms as

proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\314\ In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission proposed to define an ``intermarket spread position'' as

``a long position in a commodity derivative contract in a particular

commodity at a particular designated contract market or swap

execution facility and a short position in another commodity

derivative contract in that same commodity away from that particular

designated contract market or swap execution facility.'' The

Commission also proposed to define an ``intramarket spread

position'' as ``a long position in a commodity derivative contract

in a particular commodity and a short position in another commodity

contract in the same commodity on the same designated contract

market or swap execution facility.'' See December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75699-700.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In particular, in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal,

[[Page 96734]]

the Commission proposed to define an ``intermarket spread position'' to

mean ``a long (short) position in one or more commodity derivative

contracts in a particular commodity, or its products or its by-

products, at a particular designated contract market, and a short

(long) position in one or more commodity derivative contracts in that

same, or similar, commodity, or its products or its by-products, away

from that particular designated contract market.'' Similarly, the

Commission proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal

to define an ``intramarket spread position'' to mean ``a long position

in one or more commodity derivative contracts in a particular

commodity, or its products or its by-products, and a short position in

one or more commodity derivative contracts in the same, or similar,

commodity, or its products or its by-products, on the same designated

contract market.''

The Commission expressed the view that the expanded definitions

proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal would take

into account that a market participant may take positions in multiple

commodity derivative contracts to establish an intermarket spread

position or an intramarket spread position. The expanded definitions

would also take into account that such spread positions may be

established by taking positions in derivative contracts in the same

commodity, in similar commodities, or in the products or by-products of

the same or similar commodities. By way of example, the Commission

noted that the expanded definitions would include a short position in a

crude oil derivative contract and long positions in a gasoline

derivative contract and a diesel fuel derivative contract

(collectively, a reverse crack spread).

Comments Received: The Commission did not receive any comments in

response to the definitions of ``intermarket spread position'' and

``intramarket spread position'' proposed in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal \315\ or in response to the 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\315\ As noted above, the definitions of ``intermarket spread

position'' and ``intramarket spread position'' were included.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

the definitions of the terms ``intermarket spread position'' and

``intramarket spread position'' as proposed in the 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal.

k. Long Position

Proposed Rule: The term ``long position'' is currently defined in

Sec. 150.1(g) to mean ``a long call option, a short put option or a

long underlying futures contract.'' The Commission proposed to update

the definition to make it also applicable to swaps such that a long

position would include a long futures-equivalent swap.

Commission Reproposal: Though no commenters suggested changes to

the definition of ``long position,'' the Commission is concerned that

the proposed definition does not clearly articulate that futures and

options contracts are subject to position limits on a futures-

equivalent basis in terms of the core referenced futures contract.

Longstanding market practice has applied position limits on futures and

options on a futures-equivalent basis, and the Commission believes that

practice ought to be made explicit in the definition in order to

prevent confusion. Thus, the Commission is reproposing an amended

definition to clarify that a long position is ``on a futures-equivalent

basis, a long call option, a short put option, a long underlying

futures contract, or a swap position that is equivalent to a long

futures contract.'' This clarification is consistent with the

clarification to the definition of futures-equivalent basis proposed in

the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal. Though the substance of

the definition is fundamentally unchanged, the revised language should

prevent unnecessary confusion over the application of futures-

equivalency to different kinds of commodity derivative contracts.

l. Physical Commodity

Proposed Rule: The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal would

amend Sec. 150.1 by adding in a definition of the term ``physical

commodity'' for position limit purposes. Congress used the term

``physical commodity'' in CEA sections 4a(a)(2)(A) and 4a(a)(2)(B) to

mean commodities ``other than excluded commodities as defined by the

Commission.'' Therefore, the Commission interprets ``physical

commodities'' to include both exempt and agricultural commodities, but

not excluded commodities, and proposes to define the term as such.\316\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\316\ For position limits purposes, proposed Sec. 150.1 would

define ``physical commodity'' to mean any agricultural commodity as

that term is defined in Sec. 1.3 of this chapter or any exempt

commodity as that term is defined in section 1a(20) of the Act.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on the

proposed definition.

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

the definition as originally proposed.

m. Pre-enactment Swap and Pre-Existing Position

Proposed Rule: The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal would

amend Sec. 150.1 by adding in new definitions of the terms ``pre-

enactment swap'' and ``pre-existing position'' for position limit

purposes. Under the definitions proposed in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, ``pre-enactment swap'' means any swap entered into

prior to enactment of the Dodd-Frank Act of 2010 (July 21, 2010), the

terms of which have not expired as of the date of enactment of that

Act, while ``pre-existing position'' means any position in a commodity

derivative contract acquired in good faith prior to the effective date

of any bylaw, rule, regulation or resolution that specifies an initial

speculative position limit level or a subsequent change to that level.

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on the

proposed definitions either of the terms ``pre-enactment swap'' or

``pre-existing position.''

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

both definitions as previously proposed.

n. Referenced Contract

Proposed Rule: Part 150 currently does not include a definition of

the phrase ``referenced contract,'' which was introduced and adopted in

vacated part 151.\317\ As was noted when part 151 was adopted, the

Commission identified 28 core referenced futures contracts and proposed

to apply aggregate limits on a futures equivalent basis across all

derivatives that met the definition of referenced contracts.\318\ The

definition of referenced contract proposed in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal was similar to that of vacated part 151,

[[Page 96735]]

but there were certain differences, including an exclusion of

guarantees of swaps and the incorporation of other terms into the

definition of referenced contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\317\ Vacated Sec. 151.1 defined ``Referenced Contract'' to

mean ``on a futures-equivalent basis with respect to a particular

Core Referenced Futures Contract, a Core Referenced Futures Contract

listed in Sec. 151.2, or a futures contract, options contract, swap

or swaption, other than a basis contract or contract on a commodity

index that is: (1) Directly or indirectly linked, including being

partially or fully settled on, or priced at a fixed differential to,

the price of that particular Core Referenced Futures Contract; or

(2) directly or indirectly linked, including being partially or

fully settled on, or priced at a fixed differential to, the price of

the same commodity underlying that particular Core Referenced

Futures Contract for delivery at the same location or locations as

specified in that particular Core Referenced Futures Contract.''

\318\ Position Limits for Futures and Swaps, 76 FR at 71629.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the term

``referenced contract'' was proposed to be defined in Sec. 150.1 to

mean, on a futures-equivalent basis with respect to a particular core

referenced futures contract, a core referenced futures contract listed

in Sec. 150.2(d) of this part, or a futures contract, options

contract, or swap, other than a guarantee of a swap, a basis contract,

or a commodity index contract: (1) That is: (a) Directly or indirectly

linked, including being partially or fully settled on, or priced at a

fixed differential to, the price of that particular core referenced

futures contract; or (b) directly or indirectly linked, including being

partially or fully settled on, or priced at a fixed differential to,

the price of the same commodity underlying that particular core

referenced futures contract for delivery at the same location or

locations as specified in that particular core referenced futures

contract; and (2) where: (a) Calendar spread contract means a cash-

settled agreement, contract, or transaction that represents the

difference between the settlement price in one or a series of contract

months of an agreement, contract or transaction and the settlement

price of another contract month or another series of contract months'

settlement prices for the same agreement, contract or transaction; (b)

commodity index contract means an agreement, contract, or transaction

that is not a basis or any type of spread contract, based on an index

comprised of prices of commodities that are not the same or

substantially the same; (c) spread contract means either a calendar

spread contract or an intercommodity spread contract; and (d)

intercommodity spread contract means a cash-settled agreement, contract

or transaction that represents the difference between the settlement

price of a referenced contract and the settlement price of another

contract, agreement, or transaction that is based on a different

commodity.

Comments Received: The Commission received numerous comments \319\

regarding various aspects of the definition of ``referenced contract.''

Some were generally supportive of the proposed definition while others

suggested changes. One commenter expressly stated its support for

speculative limits on futures, options, and swaps because each

financial instrument ``can be used to develop market power and increase

volatility.'' \320\ Another commenter expressed its support for the

exclusion of guarantees of swaps from the definition of referenced

contract.\321\ These comments and the Commission's response are

detailed below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\319\ The commenters included AGA, APGA, Atmos, API, Better

Markets, BG Group, Calpine, Citadel, CME, CMOC, COPE, DEU, EEI,

EPSA, FIA, ICE, IECA, ISDA/SIFMA, GFMA, IATP, MFA, NEM, NFP, NGSA,

OLAM, PAAP, SCS, and Vectra.

\320\ CL-IECA-59713 at 4.

\321\ CL-IECAssn-59679 at 31.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission is reproposing the definition

of referenced contract with two substantive modifications from the

original proposal, both of which are discussed further below. First,

the Commission is now proposing to amend the definition of ``referenced

contract'' to expressly exclude trade options. Second, the Reproposal

would clarify the meaning of ``indirectly linked.'' The Reproposal also

moves four definitions that were embedded in the proposed definition of

referenced contract, specifically ``calendar spread contract,''

``commodity index contract,'' ``spread contract,'' and ``intercommodity

spread contract,'' to their own definitions in Sec. 150.1, while

otherwise retaining those definitions as proposed. In addition, the

Reproposal makes non-substantive modifications to the definition of

referenced contract to make it easier to read.

Comments Received: In response to a specific request for comment in

the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, many commenters recommended

excluding trade options from the definition of referenced

contract.\322\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\322\ See, e.g., CL-FIA-59595 at 4 and 19, CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at

3, CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 3 and 34, CL-NEM-59620 at 2, CL-DEU-59627

at 7, CL-AGA-59632 at 4-5, CL-AGA-60382 at 10, CL-Olam-59658 at 3,

CL-BG Group-59656 at 4, CL-BG Group-60383 at 4, CL-COPE-59662 at 5

and 8, CL-Calpine-59663 at 5, CL-PAAP-59664 at 4, CL-NGSA-59673 at

27-33, CL-ICE-59669 at 13, CL-EPSA-60381 at 4-5, CL-A4A-59714 at 5,

CL-NFP-59690 at 7-8, CL-Working Group-59693 at 55-58, CL-API-59694

at 7, CL-IECAssn-59679 at 22, CL-IECAssn-59957 at 6-9, CL-Atmos-

59705 at 4, CL-APGA-59722 at 9, CL-EEI-59945 at 5-6, CL-EPSA-55953

at 6-7, and CL-SCS-60399 at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: In response to numerous comments, the

reproposed definition of ``referenced contract'' expressly excludes

trade options that meet the requirements of Sec. 32.3. The Commission

notes that in its trade options final rule,\323\ the cross-reference to

vacated part 151 position limits was deleted from Sec. 32.3(c). At

that time, the Commission stated its belief that federal speculative

position limits should not apply to trade options, as well as its

intention to address trade options in the context of the any final

rulemaking on position limits.\324\ Therefore, the Commission is

reproposing the definition of ``referenced contract'' to expressly

exclude trade options that meet the requirements of Sec. 32.3 of this

chapter.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\323\ Trade Options, 81 FR 14966 (Mar. 21, 2016).

\324\ Id. at 14971.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: Commenters asserted that certain aspects of the

definition of referenced contract are unclear and/or unworkable. For

example, commenters suggested that the concept of ``indirectly linked''

is unclear and so market participants may not know whether a particular

contract is subject to limits.\325\ Some commenters believe that the

definition is overbroad and captures products that they state do not

affect price discovery or impair hedging and are not truly

economically-equivalent.\326\ Commenters request that the Commission

support its determination regarding which contracts are economically

equivalent by providing a description of the methodology used to

determine the contracts considered to be economically-equivalent,

including examples of over-the-counter (``OTC'') and FBOT

contracts.\327\ One commenter stated that support is necessary because

``mechanically assign[ing]'' the label of economically-equivalent to

any contract that references a core referenced futures contract does

not make it equivalent.\328\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\325\ See, e.g., CL-CMC-59634 at 14, and CL-COPE-59662 at 7, n.

20 (stating ``[i]t is one thing if the Commission means a reference

to a contract that itself directly references a core referenced

futures contract. It is more troubling and likely unworkable if the

Commission means a more subjective economic link to a delivery

location that is used in a core referenced futures contract. At a

minimum, the Commission should provide examples of indirect linkage

that triggers referenced contract status'').

\326\ See, e.g., CL-COPE-59662 at 7, and CL-BG Group-59656 at 4.

\327\ See, e.g., CL-MFA-59606 at 4 and 15-16.

\328\ CL-COPE-59950 at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission agrees with commenters that

there is a need to clarify the meaning of ``indirectly linked.'' The

Commission notes that including contracts that are ``indirectly

linked'' to the core referenced futures contract under the definition

of referenced contract is intended to prevent the evasion of position

limits through the creation of an economically equivalent contract that

does not directly reference the core referenced futures contract price.

Under the reproposed definition, ``indirectly linked'' means a contract

that settles to a price based on another derivative contract that,

either directly or through linkage to another derivative contract, has

a settlement price based on

[[Page 96736]]

the price of a core referenced futures contract or based on the price

of the same commodity underlying that particular core referenced

futures contract for delivery at the same location specified in that

particular core referenced futures contract. Therefore, contracts that

settle to the price of a referenced contract, for example, would be

indirectly linked to the core referenced futures contract (e.g., a swap

that prices to the ICE Futures US Henry LD1 Fixed Price Futures (H)

contract, which is a referenced contract that settles directly to the

price of the NYMEX Henry Hub Natural Gas (NG) core referenced futures

contract).

On the other hand, an outright derivative contract whose settlement

price is based on an index published by a price reporting agency

(``PRA'') that surveys cash market transaction prices (even if the cash

market practice is to price at a differential to a futures contract)

would not be directly or indirectly linked to the core referenced

futures contract.\329\ Similarly, a derivative contract whose

settlement price was based on the same underlying commodity at a

different delivery location (e.g., ultra-low sulfur diesel delivered at

L.A. Harbor) would not be linked, directly or indirectly, to the core

referenced futures contract. The Commission is publishing an updated

CFTC Staff Workbook of Commodity Derivative Contracts Under the

Regulations Regarding Position Limits for Derivatives along with this

release, which provides a non-exhaustive list of referenced contracts

and may be helpful to market participants in determining categories of

contracts that fit within the definition. Under the Reproposal, as

always, market participants may request clarification from the

Commission when necessary.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\329\ The Commission notes that while the outright derivative

contract would not be indirectly linked to the core referenced

contract, a derivative contract that settles to the difference

between the core referenced futures contract and the PRA index would

be directly linked because it settles in part to the core referenced

futures contract price.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Regarding comments that the definition is overbroad and captures

products that commenters state do not affect price discovery or are not

truly economically-equivalent, the Commission notes that commenters

seem to be confusing the statutory definitions of ``significant price

discovery function'' (in CEA section 4a(a)(4)) and ``economically

equivalent'' (in CEA section 4a(a)(5)). As a matter of course,

contracts can be economically equivalent without serving a significant

price discovery function. The Commission notes that there is no

unpublished methodology used to determine which contracts are

referenced contracts. Instead, the Commission proposed, and, following

notice and comment, is now reproposing a definition for referenced

contracts, and contracts that fit under that definition will be subject

to federal speculative position limits.

Comments Received: Several commenters suggested that cash-settled

contracts should not be subject to position limits.\330\ One commenter

asserted that non-deliverable cash-settled contracts are

``fundamentally different'' from deliverable commodity contracts and

should not be subject to position limits.\331\ The commenter also

asserted that subjecting penultimate-day contracts such as options to a

limit structure would make managing an option portfolio ``virtually

impossible'' and would result in confusion and uncertainty.\332\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\330\ See, e.g., CL-Vectra-60369 at 3, and CL-Citadel-59717 at

9.

\331\ CL-Vectra-60369 at 3.

\332\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined not to make

any changes in the Reproposal that would broadly exempt cash-settled

contracts from position limits. Cash-settled contracts are economically

equivalent to deliverable contracts, and Congress has required that the

Commission impose limits on economically equivalent swaps. The

Commission notes that Congress took action twice to address this issue.

In CEA section 4a(a)(5)(A), Congress required the Commission to adopt

position limits for swaps that are economically equivalent to futures

or options on futures or commodities traded on a futures exchange, for

which the Commission has adopted position limits. Previously, in the

CFTC Reauthorization Act of 2008,\333\ Congress imposed a core

principle for position limitations on swaps that are significant price

discovery contracts.\334\ In addition, because cash-settled referenced

contracts are economically equivalent to the physical delivery contract

in the same commodity, a trader has an incentive to manipulate one

contract in order to benefit the other.\335\ The Commission notes that

a trader with positions in both the physically delivered and cash-

settled referenced contracts would have, in the absence of position

limits, increased ability to manipulate one contract to benefit

positions in the other.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\333\ Incorporated as Title XIII of the Food, Conservation and

Energy Act of 2008, Pub. L. 110-246, 122 Stat. 1624 (June 18, 2008),

\334\ CEA section 2(h)(7) (2009).

\335\ Under the reproposed definition, a cash-settled contract

must be linked, directly or indirectly, to the core referenced

futures contract or the same underlying commodity in the same

delivery location in order to be considered a ``referenced

contract.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Moreover, if speculators were incentivized to abandon physical

delivery contracts for cash-settled contracts so as to avoid position

limits, it could result in degradation of the physical delivery

contract markets that position limits are intended and designed to

protect.

Comments Received: One commenter asked the Commission to confirm

that a non-transferable repurchase right granted in connection with a

hedged commodity transaction does not count towards position limits,

citing CME Group and ICE Futures rules to that effect. The commenter is

concerned that such a transaction could be deemed a commodity option

and therefore legally a swap, but that it believed the transaction

satisfies the criteria for exemption from definition as a swap.\336\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\336\ CL-Olam-59658 at 8-9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: As the commenter notes, whether the contract

is subject to position limits depends on whether it is a swap. The

Commission points out that the release adopting the definition of swap

noted the Commission's belief that its forward contract interpretation

``provides sufficient clarity with respect to the forward contract

exclusion from the swap and future delivery definitions.'' \337\ Also

in that release, the Commission noted that commodity options are

swaps.\338\ Separately, the Commission adopted Commission Sec. 32.3,

providing an exemption from the commodity option definition for trade

options; the exemption was recently further amended.\339\ The commenter

should apply these rules to determine whether a given contract is a

swap. In addition, the Commission notes that under Commission Sec.

140.99, the commenter may request clarification or exemptive relief

regarding whether a non-transferable repurchase right falls under the

definition of a ``swap.'' To the extent the commenter seeks a

clarification or change to the definition of a swap, the current

rulemaking has not been expanded to revisit that definition.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\337\ See, Further Definition of ``Swap,'' ``Security-Based

Swap,'' and ``Security-Based Swap Agreement''; Mixed Swaps;

Security-Based Swap Agreement Recordkeeping; Final Rule (``Swap

Definition Rulemaking''), 77 FR 48208, 48231 (Aug. 13, 2012).

\338\ Id. at 48237.

\339\ See Commodity Options, 77 FR 25320, 75326 (Apr. 27, 2012);

see also Trade Options, 81 FR 14966 (Mar. 21, 2016).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96737]]

Comments Received: One commenter \340\ requested clarification that

a bid, offer, or indication of interest for an OTC swap that does not

constitute a binding transaction will not count towards position

limits, noting that current CME Rule 562 provides that such bids or

offers would be in violation of the limit.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\340\ See, e.g., CL-MFA-59606 at 5 and 23.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Reproposal does not change the

definition originally proposed in response to the comment requesting

clarification that a bid, offer, or indication of interest for an OTC

swap that does not constitute a binding transaction will not count

towards position limits. Nevertheless, the Commission clarifies that

under the Reproposal, such bids, offers, or indications of interest do

not count toward position limits.\341\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\341\ The Commission notes that it is discussing bids, offers,

and indications of interest in the context of whether these would

violate position limits, and is not addressing other issues such as

whether or not their use may indicate spoofing in violation of CEA

section 4(c)(a)(5).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: One commenter requested that the Commission

exclude from the definition of referenced contract any agreement,

contract, and transaction exempted from swap regulations by virtue of

an exemption order, interpretation, no-action letter, or other

guidance; the commenter stated that it believes the Commission can use

its surveillance capacity and anti-manipulation authority, along with

its MOU with FERC, to monitor these nonfinancial commodity transactions

as well as the market participants relying on the exemptive

relief.\342\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\342\ CL-NFP-59690 at 14-15.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Reproposal does not change the proposed

definition in response to the comment requesting that the Commission

exclude from the definition of referenced contract any agreement,

contract, and transaction exempted from swap regulations by virtue of

an exemption order, interpretation, no-action letter, or other

guidance. The Commission notes that any contract that is not a

commodity derivative contract, including one that has been excluded

from the definition of swap, is not subject to position limits. The

commenter is requesting a broad exclusion from the definition of

referenced contract, based on other regulatory relief which may have

been adopted for a variety of policy reasons unrelated to position

limits. Consequently, in light of the many and varied policy reasons

for issuing an exemption order, interpretation, no-action letter or

other guidance from swap regulation, each such action would need to be

considered in the context of the goals of the Commission's position

limits regime. Rather than issuing a blanket exemption from the

definition of referenced contract for any agreement, contract, and

transaction exempted from swap regulations, therefore, the Commission

believes it would be better to consider each such action on its own

merits prior to issuing an exemption from position limits. Under the

Reproposal, if a market participant desires to extend a previously

taken exemptive action by exempting certain agreements, contracts, and

transactions from the definition of referenced contract, the market

participant can request that the particular exemption order,

interpretation, no-action letter, or other guidance be so extended.

This would allow the Commission to consider the particular action taken

and the merits of that particular exemption in the context of the

position limits regime.

The Commission notes that in the particular exemptive order cited

by the commenter,\343\ certain delineated non-financial energy

transactions between certain specifically defined entities were

exempted, pursuant to CEA sections 4(c)(1) and 4(c)(6), from all

requirements of the CEA and Commission regulations issued thereunder,

subject to certain anti-fraud, anti-manipulation, and record inspection

conditions. All entities that meet the requirements for the exemption

provided by the Federal Power Act 201(f) Order are, therefore, already

exempt from position limits compliance for all transactions that meet

the Order's conditions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\343\ See the Between NFP Electrics Exemptive Order (Order

Exempting, Pursuant to Authority of the Commodity Exchange Act,

Certain Transactions Between Entities Described in the Federal Power

Act, and Other Electric Cooperatives, 78 FR 19670 (Apr. 2, 2013)

(``Federal Power Act 201(f) Order''). See also CL-NFP-59690 at 14-

15. The Federal Power Act 201(f) Order exempted all ``Exempt Non-

Financial Energy Transactions'' (as defined in the Federal Power Act

201(f) Order) that are entered into solely between ``Exempt

Entities'' (also as defined in the Federal Power Act 201(f) Order,

namely any electric facility or utility that is wholly owned by a

government entity as described in the Federal Power Act (`FPA')

section 201(f); (ii) any electric facility or utility that is wholly

owned by an Indian tribe recognized by the U.S. government pursuant

to section 104 of the Act of November 2, 1994; (iii) any electric

facility or utility that is wholly owned by a cooperative,

regardless of such cooperative's status pursuant to FPA section

201(f), so long as the cooperative is treated as such under Internal

Revenue Code section 501(c)(12) or 1381(a)(2)(C), and exists for the

primary purpose of providing electric energy service to its member/

owner customers at cost; or (iv) any other entity that is wholly

owned, directly or indirectly, by any one or more of the

foregoing.). See Federal Power Act 201(f) Order at 19688.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: Commenters were divided with respect to the

exclusion of ``commodity index contracts'' from the definition of

referenced contract. As a result of the exclusion, the position of a

market participant who enters into a commodity index contract with a

dealer will not be subject to position limits. One commenter supported

the exclusion of commodity index contracts from the definition of

referenced contracts.\344\ The commenter was concerned, however, that a

dealer who offsets his or her exposure in such contracts by purchasing

futures contracts on the constituent components of the commodity index

will be subject to position limits in the referenced contracts. The

commenter urged the Commission to recognize as a bona fide hedge ``the

offsetting nature of the dealer's position by exempting the futures

contracts that a dealer acquires to hedge its commitments under

commodity index contracts.'' \345\ Alternatively, the Commission should

``modify the definition of `referenced contract' and the definition of

`commodity derivative contract' by excluding core referenced futures

contracts and related futures contracts, options contracts or swaps

that are offset on an economically equivalent basis by the constituent

portions of commodity index contracts.'' \346\ Another commenter

supported the Commission's proposal to exclude swaps that reference

indices such as the Goldman Sachs Commodity Index (GSCI) from the

definition of a referenced contract.\347\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\344\ CL-GFMA-60314 at 4.

\345\ Id.

\346\ Id.

\347\ CL-CMOC-59720 at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter asked that the Commission reconsider excluding

commodity index contracts from the definition of referenced

contract.\348\ Another commenter urged that commodity index contracts

should be included in the definition of referenced contract in

conjunction with (1) a class limit (as was proposed for vacated part

151, but not included in final part 151); and (2) a lower position

limit set at a level ``aimed to maintain no more than'' 30 percent

speculation in each commodity (based on COT report classifications)

that is reset every 6 months.\349\ The same commenter noted that

trading by passive, long only

[[Page 96738]]

commodity index fund speculators does not provide liquidity, but rather

takes net liquidity, dilutes the pool of market information to be less

reflective of fundamental forces, causes volatility, and causes an

increased frequency of contango attributed to frequent rolls from

selling a nearby contract and buying a deferred (second month)

contract. The commenter noted that, broadly, speculators in commodity

futures historically constituted between 15 and 30 percent of open

interest without meaningfully disrupting the market and providing

beneficial intermediation between hedging producers and hedging

consumers.\350\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\348\ CL-IATP-59701 at 2.

\349\ CL-Better Markets-59716 at 1-35, and particularly at 32.

\350\ CL-Better Markets-59716 at 5, and CL-Better Markets-60401

at 4, 16-17.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission is reproposing the provision

excluding commodity index contracts from the definition of referenced

contract as previously proposed.

Regarding commenters who requested that the Commission alter the

proposed definition to include commodity index derivative contracts,

the Commission notes that if it were to include such contracts, the

Commission's rules would allow netting of such positions in commodity

index contracts with other offsetting referenced contracts. The ability

to net such commodity index derivative contracts positions with other

offsetting referenced contracts would eliminate the need for a bona

fide hedging exemption for such contracts. Thus, the Commission

believes such netting would contravene Congressional intent, as

expressed in CEA section 4a(c)(B)(i) in its requirement to permit a

pass-thru swap offset only if the counterparty's position would qualify

as a bona fide hedge.

Another commenter suggested including commodity index contracts

under the definition of referenced contract in conjunction with a class

limit (e.g., a separate limit for commodity index contracts compared to

all other categories of derivative contracts). The commenter suggested

that the limit be set at a level aimed at maintaining a particular

ratio of speculative trading in the market. In response to this

commenter, the Commission declines in this Reproposal to propose class

limits because it believes any adoption of a class limit would require

a rationing scheme wherein unrelated legal entities would be limited by

the positions of other unrelated legal entities. Further, the

Commission is concerned that class limits (including the one proposed

by the commenter) could impair liquidity in the relevant markets.\351\

The Commission also notes that it currently does not collect

information to effectively enforce any ratio of speculative trading,

and has not done so since the Commission eliminated Series '03

reporting in 1981.\352\ The Reproposal does not make any changes to the

definition of referenced contract pursuant to this comment.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\351\ See also, December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75741.

\352\ The Commission's Series '03 reports required large traders

to classify how much of their position was speculative and how much

was hedging and formed the basis of the earliest versions of the

CFTC Commitments of Traders Reports. See ``Reporting Requirements

for Contract Markets, Futures Commission Merchants, Members of

Exchanges and Large Traders,'' 46 FR 59960 (Dec. 8, 1981)

(eliminating the routine of Series '03 reports by large traders).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Finally, in response to the commenter who suggested that, in

addition to excluding commodity index contracts as proposed, the

Commission should recognize as bona fide hedge positions those

positions that offset a position in a commodity index derivative

contract by using the component futures contracts, the Commission

observes that it still believes, as discussed in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal, that financial products do not meet the

temporary substitute test. As such, the offset of financial risks

arising from financial products is inconsistent with the statutory

definition of a bona fide hedging position. The Commission also

declines in this Reproposal to accept the commenter's request to exempt

these offsetting positions using its authority under CEA section

4a(a)(7) because it does not believe that permitting the offset of

financial risks furthers the purposes of the Commission's position

limits regime as described in CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B). Finally, the

commenter suggested as an alternative that the Commission modify the

definition of referenced contract to broadly exclude any derivative

contracts that are used to offset commodity index exposure. However,

the Commission believes such a broad exclusion would, at best, be too

difficult to administer and, at worst, provide an easy vehicle for

entities to evade position limits regulations.

Comments Received: One commenter suggested that the Commission

unnecessarily limited the scope of permissible netting by not

recognizing cross-commodity netting, recommending either a threshold

correlation factor of 60 percent or an approach that would permit pro

rata netting to the extent of demonstrated correlation.\353\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\353\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 3 and 32-33.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission believes that recognizing

cross-commodity netting as requested by the commenter would

substantially expand the definition of referenced contract and, thus,

may weaken: (1) The protection of the price discovery function in the

core referenced futures contract; (2) the prevention of excessive

speculation; and (3) the prevention of market manipulation. Therefore,

this Reproposal does not change the definition of referenced contract

to accommodate cross-commodity netting.

Comments Received: One commenter requested that all ``nonfinancial

commodity derivatives'' used by commercial end-users for hedging

purposes be expressly excluded from the definition of referenced

contract (and so excluded from position limits). The commenter also

suggested that the Commission allow an end-user to identify a swap as

being used to ``hedge or mitigate commercial risks'' at the time the

swap is executed and noted that such trades are highly-customized

bilateral agreements that are difficult to convert into futures

equivalents.\354\ The commenter also requested that ``customary

commercial agreements'' be excluded from referenced contract

definition. The commenter stated that these contracts may reference a

core referenced futures contract or may be misinterpreted as directly

or indirectly linking to a core referenced futures contract, but that

the Commission has already determined that Congress did not intend to

regulate such agreements as swaps.\355\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\354\ CL-NFP-59690 at 9-12.

\355\ CL-NFP-59690 at 13 (citing to Further Definition of

``Swap,'' ``Security-Based Swap,'' and ``Security-Based Swap

Agreement''; Mixed Swaps; Security-Based Swap Agreement

Recordkeeping, 77 FR 48208 (Aug. 13, 2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: This Reproposal does not amend the

definition of referenced contract in response to the request that

``nonfinancial commodity derivatives'' used by commercial end-users for

hedging purposes be expressly excluded from the definition of

referenced contract. The Commission understands the comment to mean

that when a particular transaction qualifies for the end-user

exemption, it should also be exempt from position limits by excluding

such transactions from the definition of ``referenced contract.'' The

commenter quotes language from the end-user exemption definition, which

was issued to provide relief from the clearing and trade execution

mandates. The Commission notes that under the CEA's statutory language,

the commercial end user exemption

[[Page 96739]]

definition is broader than the bona fide hedging definition. Under the

canons of statutory construction, when Congress writes one section

differently than another, the differences should be assumed to have

different meaning. Thus, the Commission believes that the more

restrictive language in the bona fide hedging definition should be

applied here. The definition of bona fide hedging position, as proposed

in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, as amended by the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, and as reproposed here, would be

consistent with the differences in the two definitions, as adopted by

Congress. The Commission notes that under this Reproposal, commercial

end-users may rely on any applicable bona fide hedge exemption.

In response to the commenter's concern regarding ``customary

commercial agreements,'' the Commission reiterates its belief that

contracts that are exempted or excluded from the definition of ``swap''

are not considered referenced contracts and so are not subject to

position limits.

o. Short Position

Proposed Rule: The term ``short position'' is currently defined in

Sec. 150.1(c) to mean a short call option, a long put option, or a

short underlying futures contract. In the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, the Commission proposed to amend the definition to state that

a short position means a short call option, a long put option or a

short underlying futures contract, or a short futures-equivalent swap.

This proposed revision reflects the fact that under the Dodd-Frank Act,

the Commission is charged with applying the position limits regime to

swaps.

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments regarding

the proposed amendment to the definition of ``short position.''

Commission Reproposal: Though no commenters suggested changes to

the definition of ``short position,'' the Commission is concerned that

the proposed definition, like the proposed definition of ``long

position'' described supra, does not clearly articulate that futures

and options contracts are subject to position limits on a futures-

equivalent basis in terms of the core referenced futures contract.

Longstanding market practice has applied position limits to futures and

options on a futures-equivalent basis, and the Commission believes that

practice ought to be made explicit in the definition in order to

prevent confusion. Thus, in this Reproposal, the Commission is

proposing to amend the definition to clarify that a short position is

on a futures-equivalent basis, a short call option, a long put option,

a short underlying futures contract, or a swap position that is

equivalent to a short futures contract. Though the substance of the

definition is fundamentally unchanged, the revised language should

prevent unnecessary confusion over the application of futures-

equivalency to different kinds of commodity derivative contracts.

p. Speculative Position Limit

The term ``speculative position limit'' is currently not defined in

Sec. 150.1. In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission proposed to define the term ``speculative position limit''

to mean ``the maximum position, either net long or net short, in a

commodity derivatives contract that may be held or controlled by one

person, absent an exemption, such as an exemption for a bona fide

hedging position. This limit may apply to a person's combined position

in all commodity derivative contracts in a particular commodity (all-

months-combined), a person's position in a single month of commodity

derivative contracts in a particular commodity, or a person's position

in the spot-month of commodity derivative contacts in a particular

commodity. Such a limit may be established under federal regulations or

rules of a designated contract market or swap execution facility. An

exchange may also apply other limits, such as a limit on gross long or

gross short positions, or a limit on holding or controlling delivery

instruments.'' \356\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\356\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75825.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As explained in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

proposed definition is similar to definitions for position limits used

by the Commission for many years,\357\ as well as glossaries published

by the Commission for many years.\358\ For example, the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal noted that the version of the staff glossary

currently posted on the CFTC Web site defines speculative position

limit as ``[t]he maximum position, either net long or net short, in one

commodity future (or option) or in all futures (or options) of one

commodity combined that may be held or controlled by one person (other

than a person eligible for a hedge exemption) as prescribed by an

exchange and/or by the CFTC.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\357\ Id. at 75701. As noted in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, ``the various regulations and defined terms

included use of maximum amounts `net long or net short,' which

limited what any one person could `hold or control,' `one grain on

any one contract market' (or in `in one commodity' or `a particular

commodity'), and `in any one future or in all futures combined.' For

example, in 1936, Congress enacted the CEA, which authorized the

CFTC's predecessor, the CEC, to establish limits on speculative

trading. Congress empowered the CEC to `fix such limits on the

amount of trading . . . as the [CEC] finds is necessary to diminish,

eliminate, or prevent such burden.' [CEA section 6a(1) (Supp. II

1936)] It also noted that the first speculative position limits were

issued by the CEC in December 1938, 3 FR 3145, Dec. 24, 1938, and

that those first speculative position limits rules provided, also in

Sec. 150.1, for limits on position and daily trading in grain for

future delivery, and adopted a maximum amount ``net long or net

short position which any one person may hold or control in any one

grain on any one contract market'' as 2,000,000 bushels ``in any one

future or in all futures combined.'' Id.

\358\ For example, the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

noted that the Commission's annual report for 1983 includes in its

glossary ``Position Limit: the maximum position, either net long or

net short, in one commodity future combined which may be held or

controlled by one person as prescribed by any exchange or by the

CFTC.'' Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission received no comments on the proposed definition, and

is reproposing the definition without amendment.

q. Spot-Month

Proposed Rule: In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission proposed to adopt a definition of ``spot-month'' that

expands upon the current Sec. 150.1 definition.\359\ The definition,

as proposed, specifically addressed both physical-delivery contracts

and cash-settled contracts, and clarified the duration of ``spot-

month.'' Under the proposed definition, the ``spot-month'' for

physical-delivery commodity derivatives contracts would be the period

of time beginning at of the close of trading on the trading day

preceding the first day on which delivery notices could be issued or

the close of trading on the trading day preceding the third-to-last

trading day, until the contract was no longer listed for trading (or

available for transfer, such as through exchange for physical

transactions). The proposed definition included similar, but slightly

different language for cash-settled contracts, providing that the spot

month would begin at the earlier of the start of the period in which

the underlying cash-settlement price was calculated or the close of

trading on the trading day preceding the third-to-last trading day and

would continue until the contract

[[Page 96740]]

cash-settlement price was determined. In addition, the proposed

definition included a proviso that, if the cash-settlement price was

determined based on prices of a core referenced futures contract during

the spot month period for that core referenced futures contract, then

the spot month for that cash-settled contract would be the same as the

spot month for that core referenced futures contract.\360\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\359\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75701-02;

As noted in in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

definition proposed would be an expansion upon the definition

currently found in Sec. 150.1, but greatly simplified from the

definition adopted in vacated Sec. 151.3 (in the Part 151

regulations, the ``spot month'' definition in Sec. 151.1 simply

cited to the ``spot month'' definition provided in Sec. 151.3).

\360\ See id. at 75825-6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received several comments

regarding the definition of spot month.\361\ One commenter noted that

the definition of the spot month for federal limits does not always

coincide with the definition of spot month for purposes of any exchange

limits and assumes that the Commission did not intend for this to

happen. For example, the commenter noted the proposed definition of

spot month would commence at the close of trading on the trading day

preceding the first notice day, while the ICE Futures US definition

commences as of the opening of trading on the second business day

following the expiration of regular option trading on the expiring

futures contract. Regarding the COMEX contracts, the commenter stated

that the exchange spot month commences at the close of business, rather

than at the close of trading, which would allow market participants to

incorporate exchange of futures for related position transactions

(EFRPs) that occur after the close of trading, but before the close of

business.\362\ Finally, the commenter requested the Commission ensure

the definition of spot month for federal limits is the same as the

definition of spot month for exchange limits for all referenced

contracts.\363\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\361\ See, e.g., CL-FIA-59595 at 10, CL-NFP-59690 at 19, CL-

NGSA-59673 at 44, and CL-ICE-59669 at 5-6.

\362\ CL-FIA-59595 at 10.

\363\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Two commenters urged the Commission to reconsider its proposed

definition of spot month for cash-settled contracts that encompasses

the entire period for calculation of the settlement price, preferring

the current exchange practice which is to apply the spot month limit

during the last three days before final settlement.\364\ One commenter

noted its concern that the proposed definition would discourage use of

calendar month average price contracts.\365\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\364\ See, e.g., CL-NGSA-59673 at 44, CL-ICE-59669 at 5-6.

\365\ See, CL-ICE-59669 at 5-6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter recommended that the Commission define ``spot

month'' in relation to each core referenced futures contract and all

related physically-settled and cash-settled referenced contracts, to

assure that the definition works appropriately in terms of how each

underlying nonfinancial commodity market operates, and to ensure that

commercial end-users of such nonfinancial commodities can effectively

use such referenced contracts to hedge or mitigate commercial

risks.\366\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\366\ CL-NFP-59690 at 19.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also received the recommendation from one commenter

that the Commission should publish a calendar listing the spot month

for each Core Referenced Futures Contract to provide clarity to market

participants and reduce the cost of identifying and tracking the spot

month.\367\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\367\ CL-FIA-59595 at 10-11.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: For core referenced futures contracts, the

Commission agrees with the commenter that the definition of spot month

for federal limits should be the same as the definition of spot month

for exchange limits. The Commission is therefore the definition of spot

month in this Reproposal generally follows exchange practices. In the

reproposed version, spot month means the period of time beginning at

the earlier of the close of business on the trading day preceding the

first day on which delivery notices can be issued by the clearing

organization of a contract market, or the close of business on the

trading day preceding the third-to-last trading day, until the contract

expires for physical delivery core referenced futures contracts,\368\

except for the following: (a) ICE Futures U.S. Sugar No. 11 (SB)

referenced contract for which the spot month means the period of time

beginning at the opening of trading on the second business day

following the expiration of the regular option contract traded on the

expiring futures contract; (b) ICE Futures U.S. Sugar No. 16 (SF)

referenced contract,\369\ for which the spot month means the period of

time beginning on the third-to-last trading day of the contract month

until the contract expires \370\ and (c) Chicago Mercantile Exchange

Live Cattle (LC) referenced contract, for which the spot month means

the period of time beginning at the close trading on the fifth business

day of the contract month.\371\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\368\ As noted above, this Reproposal does not address the three

cash-settled contracts (Class III Milk, Feeder Cattle, and Lean

Hogs) which, under the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, were

included in the list of core referenced futures contracts.

Therefore, the reproposed spot month definition does not address

those three contracts.

\369\ While the Commission realized that Sugar 16 does not

currently have a spot month, its delivery period takes place after

the last trading day (similar to crude oil). Therefore, the

Reproposal amends the spot month definition for Sugar No. 16 to

mirror the three day period for other contracts that deliver after

the end of trading.

\370\ In regard to the modifier ``until the contract expires,''

the Commission views ``expires'' as meaning the end of delivery

period or until cash-settled.

\371\ In response to FIA's comment, CL-FIA-59595 at 10, the

Commission notes that the spot periods for exchange-set limits on

COMEX products begin at the close of trading and not the close of

business. See http://www.cmegroup.com/market-regulation/position-limits.html. However, the Commission understands that CME Group

staff determines compliance with spot month limits in conjunction

with the receipt of futures large trader reports. In consideration

of the practicality of this approach, and in light of the definition

of reportable position, the Commission believes that it would be

more practical, clear, and consistent with existing exchange

practices, for the spot month to begin ``at the close of the

market.'' See CFTC Regulation 15.00(p).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As noted above, in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, spot

month was proposed to be defined to begin at the earlier of: (1) ``the

close of trading on the trading day preceding the first day on which

delivery notices can be issued to the clearing organization''; or (2)

``the close of trading on the trading day preceding the third-to-last

trading day''--based on the comment letters received, the proposed

definition resulted in some confusion.\372\ The Commission observes

that the current definition also seems to be a source of some confusion

when it defines ``spot month,'' in current CFTC Regulation 150.1(a), to

begin ``at the close of trading on the trading day preceding the first

day on which delivery notices can be issued to the clearing

organization.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\372\ As a note of clarification, in light of the confusion of

some commenters, position limits apply to open positions; once the

position isn't open the limits don't apply.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission understands current DCM practice for physical-

delivery contracts permitting delivery before the close of trading

generally is that the spot month begins at the start of the first

business day on which the clearing house can issue ``stop'' notices to

a clearing member carrying a long position, or, at the close of

business on the day preceding the first business day on which the

clearing house can issue ``stop'' notices to a clearing member carrying

a long position, but current DCM rules vary somewhat. For some ICE

contracts,\373\ the spot month includes ``any month for which delivery

notices have been or may be issued,'' \374\ and begins at the open of

trading; \375\ the

[[Page 96741]]

CME spot month, as noted above, begins at the close of trading.

However, the Commission understands that the amended ``spot month''

definition, as reproposed herein, would be consistent with the existing

spot month practices of exchanges when enforcing the start of the spot

month limits in any of the 25 core referenced futures contracts, based

on the timing of futures large trader reports, discussed below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\373\ See, e.g., Cotton No. 2.

\374\ See ICE Rule 6.19.

\375\ See, e.g., Cotton No. 2 Position Limits and Position

Accountability information: ``ICE (1) Delivery Month: Cocoa, Coffee

``C'', Cotton, World Cotton, FCOJ, Precious Metals--on and after

First Notice Day Sugar#11 on and after the Second Business Day

following the expiration of the regular option contract traded on

the expiring futures contract.'' https://www.theice.com/products/254/Cotton-No-2-Futures.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Furthermore, based on Commission staff discussions with staff from

several DCMs regarding exchange current practices, the Commission

believes that the spot month should begin at the same time as futures

large trader reports are submitted--that is, under the definition of

reportable position, the spot month should begin ``at the close of the

market.'' \376\ The Commission views the ``close of the market'' as

consistent with ``the close of business.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\376\ See current Sec. 15.00(p).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In consideration of the practicality of this approach, and in light

of the definition of ``reportable position,'' the Commission believes

that it would be more practical, clear, and consistent with existing

exchange practices, for the spot month to begin ``at the close of

business.'' In addition, as noted by one commenter,\377\ when the

exchange spot month commences at the close of business, rather than at

the close of trading, it would allow market participants to incorporate

exchange of futures for related position transactions (``EFRPs'') \378\

that occur after the close of trading, but before the close of

business.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\377\ CL-FIA-59595 at 10.

\378\ The Commission notes that DCM determinations of allowable

blocks, EFRPs, and transfer trades, in regards to position limits,

must also consider compliance with DCM Core Principle 9; discussion

of the interplay is beyond the scope of this Reproposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission points out an additional correction made to the

reproposed definition, changing it from ``preceding the first day on

which delivery notices can be issued to the clearing organization of a

contract market'' to ``preceding the first day on which delivery

notices can be issued by the clearing organization of a contract

market'' [emphasis added]. The Commission understands that the spot

periods on the exchanges commence the day preceding the first day on

which delivery notices can be issued by the clearing organization of a

contract market, not the first day on which notices can be issued to

the clearing organization. The ``spot month'' definition in this

Reproposal, therefore, has been changed to correct this error.

The revisions included in the reproposed definition addresses the

concerns of the commenter who suggested the Commission define the spot

month according to each core referenced futures contract and for cash-

settled and physical delivery referenced contracts that are not core

referenced futures contracts, although for clarity and brevity the

Commission has chosen to highlight contracts that are the exception to

the general definition rather than list each of the 25 core referenced

futures contracts and multitude of referenced contracts separately.

In response to the commenters' concern regarding cash-settled

referenced contracts, the Reproposal changes the definition of spot

month to agree with the limits proposed in Sec. 150.2. In the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission defined the spot month

for certain cash-settled referenced contracts, including calendar month

averaging contracts, to be a longer period than the spot month period

for the related core referenced futures contract. However, the

Commission did not propose a limit for such contracts in proposed Sec.

150.2, rendering superfluous that aspect of the proposed definition of

spot month, at this time. The Commission is reproposing the definition

of spot month without this provision, thereby addressing the concerns

of the commenters regarding the impact of the definition on calendar

month averaging contracts outside of the spot month for the relevant

core referenced futures contract. In order to make clearer the relevant

spot month periods for referenced contracts other than core referenced

futures contracts, the Commission has included subsection (3) of the

definition that states that the spot month for such referenced

contracts is the same period as that of the relevant core referenced

futures contract.

The Commission believes that the revised definition reproposed here

sufficiently clarifies the applicable spot month periods, which can

also be determined via exchange rulebooks and defined contract

specifications, such that a defined calendar of spot months is not

necessary. Further, a published calendar would need to be revised every

year to update spot month periods for each contract and each

expiration. The Commission believes this constant revision may lead to

more confusion than it is meant to correct.

r. Spot-Month, Single-Month, and All-Months-Combined Position Limits

Proposed Rule: In addition to a definition for ``spot month,''

current part 150 includes definitions for ``single month,'' and for

``all-months'' where ``single month'' is defined as ``each separate

futures trading month, other than the spot month future,'' and ``all-

months'' is defined as ``the sum of all futures trading months

including the spot month future.''

As noted in the December 2013 Position Limits proposal, vacated

part 151 retained only the definition for spot month, and, instead,

adopted a definition for ``spot-month, single-month, and all-months-

combined position limits.'' The definition specified that, for

Referenced Contracts based on a commodity identified in Sec. 151.2,

the maximum number of contracts a trader could hold was as provided in

Sec. 151.4.

In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, as noted above, the

Commission proposed to amend Sec. 150.1 by deleting the definitions

for ``single month,'' and for ``all-months,'' but, unlike the vacated

part 151, the proposal did not include a definition for ``spot-month,

single-month, and all-months-combined position limits.'' Instead, it

proposed to adopt a definition for ``speculative position limits'' that

should obviate the need for these definitions.\379\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\379\ See Section III.A.1.r (Spot-month, single-month, and all-

months-combined position limits) above for a discussion of the

proposed definition of ``speculative position limit.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments regarding

the deletion of these definitions.

Commission Reproposal: This Reproposal, consistent with the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, eliminates the definitions for

``single month,'' and for ``all-months,'' for the reasons provided

above.

s. Swap and Swap Dealer

Proposed Rule: While the terms ``swap'' and ``swap dealer'' are not

currently defined in Sec. 150.1, the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal amended Sec. 150.1 to define these terms as they are defined

in section 1a of the Act and as further defined in section 1.3 of this

chapter.'' \380\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\380\ 7 U.S.C. 1a(47) and 1a(49); Sec. 1.3(xxx) (``swap'') and

Sec. 1.3(ggg) (``swap dealer''). See Further Definition of ``Swap

Dealer,'' ``Security-Based Swap Dealer,'' ``Major Swap

Participant,'' ``Major Security-Based Swap Participant'' and

``Eligible Contract Participant,'' 77 FR 30596 (May 23, 2012); see

also, Swap Definition Rulemaking.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on these

definitions.

[[Page 96742]]

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

these definitions as originally proposed, for the reasons provided

above.

2. Bona Fide Hedging Definition

a. Bona Fide Hedging Position (BFH) Definition--Background

Prior to the 1974 amendments to the CEA, the definition of a bona

fide hedging position was found in the statute. The 1974 amendments

authorized the newly formed Commission to define a bona fide hedging

position.\381\ The Commission published a final rule in 1977, providing

a general definition of a bona fide hedging position in Sec.

1.3(z)(1).\382\ The Commission listed certain positions, meeting the

requirements of the general definition of a bona fide hedging position,

in Sec. 1.3(z)(2) (i.e., enumerated bona fide hedging positions). The

Commission provided an application process for market participants to

seek recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions in

Sec. Sec. 1.3(z)(3) and 1.48.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\381\ Those amendments to CEA section 4a(3), subsequently re-

designated Sec. 4a(c)(1), 7 U.S.C. 6a(c)(1), provide that no rule

of the Commission shall apply to positions which are shown to be

bona fide hedging positions, as such term is defined by the

Commission. See, sec. 404 of the Commodity Futures Trading

Commission Act of 1974, Pub. L. 93-463, 88 Stat. 1389 (Oct. 23,

1974). See 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75703 for

additional discussion of the history of the definition of a bona

fide hedging position.

\382\ 42 FR 42748 (Aug. 24, 1977). Previously, the Secretary of

Agriculture, pursuant to section 404 of the Commodity Futures

Trading Commission Act of 1974 (Pub. L. 93-463), promulgated a

definition of bona fide hedging transactions and positions. 40 FR

111560 (March 12, 1975). That definition, largely reflecting the

statutory definition previously in effect, remained in effect until

the newly-established Commission defined that term. Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

During the 1980's, exchanges were required to incorporate the

Commission's general definition of bona fide hedging position into

their exchange-set position limit regulations.\383\ While the

Commission had established position limits on only a few commodity

futures contracts in Sec. 150.2, Commission rule Sec. 1.61

(subsequently incorporated into Sec. 150.5) required DCMs to establish

limits on commodities futures not subject to federal limits. The

Commission directed in Sec. 1.61(a)(3) (subsequently incorporated into

Sec. 150.5(d)(1)) that no DCM regulation regarding position limits

would apply to bona fide hedging positions as defined by a DCM in

accordance with Sec. 1.3(z)(1).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\383\ 46 FR 50938 at 50945 (Oct. 16, 1981).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In 1987, the Commission provided interpretive guidance regarding

the bona fide hedging definition and risk management exemptions for

futures in financial instruments (now termed excluded

commodities).\384\ This guidance permitted exchanges, for purposes of

exchange-set limits on excluded commodities, to recognize risk

management exemptions.\385\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\384\ 52 FR 34633 (Sept. 14, 1987) and 52 FR 27195 (July 20,

1987).

\385\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75704.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the 1990's, the Commission allowed exchanges to experiment with

substituting position accountability levels for position limits.\386\

The CFMA, in 2000, codified, in DCM Core Principle 5, position

accountability as an acceptable practice.\387\ The CFMA, however, did

not address the definition of a bona fide hedging position.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\386\ Exchange rules for position accountability levels require

a market participant whose position exceeds an accountability level

to consent automatically to requests of the exchange: (1) To provide

information about a position; and (2) to not increase or to reduce a

position, if so ordered by the exchange. In contrast, a speculative

position limit rule does not authorize an exchange to order a market

participant to reduce a position. Rather, a position limit sets a

maximum permissible size for a speculative position. The Commission

notes that it may require a market participant to provide

information about a position, for example, by issuing a special call

under Sec. 18.05 to a trader with a reportable position in futures

contracts.

\387\ DCM Core Principle 5 is codified in CEA section 5(d)(5), 7

U.S.C. 7(d)(5). See Section 111 of the Commodity Futures

Modernization Act of 2000, Pub. L. No. 106-554, 114 Stat. 2763 (Dec.

21, 2000) (CFMA).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With the passing of the CFMA in 2000, the Commission's requirements

for exchanges to adopt position limits and associated bona fide hedging

exemptions, in Sec. 150.5, were rendered mere guidance. That is,

exchanges were no longer required to establish limits and no longer

required to use the Commission's general definition of a bona fide

hedging position. Nonetheless, the Commission continued to guide

exchanges to adopt position limits, particularly for the spot month in

physical-delivery physical commodity derivatives, and to provide for

exemptions.

The Farm Bill of 2008 authorized the Commission to regulate swaps

traded on exempt commercial markets (ECM) that the Commission

determined to be a significant price discovery contract (SPDC).\388\

The Commission implemented these provisions in part 36 of its

rules.\389\ The Commission provided guidance to ECMs in complying with

Core Principle IV regarding position limitations or

accountability.\390\ That guidance provided, as an acceptable practice

for cleared trades, that the ECM's position limit rules may exempt bona

fide hedging positions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\388\ See Sec. 13201 of the Food, Conservation and Energy Act

of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-246, 122 Stat. 1624 (June 18, 2008) (Farm

Bill of 2008). These provisions were subsequently superseded by the

Dodd-Frank Act.

\389\ 66 FR 42270 (Aug. 10, 2001). Part 36 was removed and

reserved to conform to the amendments to the CEA by the Dodd-Frank

Act.

\390\ 17 CFR part 36, App. B (2010).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In 2010, the Dodd-Frank Act added a directive, for purposes of

implementation of CEA section 4a(a)(2), for the Commission to define a

bona fide hedging position for physical commodity derivatives

consistent with, in the Commission's opinion, the reasonably certain

statutory standards in CEA section 4a(c)(2). Those statutory standards

build on, but differ slightly from, the Commission's general definition

in rule 1.3(z)(1).\391\ The Commission interprets those statutory

standards as directing the Commission to narrow the bona fide hedging

position definition for physical commodities.\392\ The Commission

discusses those differences, below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\391\ It should be noted that a 2011 final rule of the

Commission would have amended the definition of a bona fide hedging

position in Sec. 1.3(z), to be applicable only to excluded

commodities, and would have added a new definition of a bona fide

hedging position to Part 151, to be applicable to physical

commodities. Position Limits for Futures and Swaps, 76 FR 71626

(Nov.18, 2011). However, prior to the compliance date for that 2011

rulemaking, a federal court vacated most provisions of that

rulemaking, including the amendments to the definition of a bona

fide hedging position. International Swaps and Derivatives Ass'n v.

United State Commodity Futures Trading Comm'n, 887 F. Supp. 2d 259

(D.D.C. 2012). Because the Commission has not instructed Federal

Register to roll back the 2011 changes to the CFR, the current

definition of a bona fide hedging position is found in the 2010

version of the Code of Federal Regulations. 17 CFR 1.3(z) (2010).

\392\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75705.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. BFH Definition Summary

Under the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed a new definition of bona fide hedging position, to replace the

current definition in Sec. 1.3(z), that would be applicable to

positions in excluded commodities and in physical commodities.\393\ The

proposed definition was organized into an opening paragraph and five

numbered paragraphs. In the opening paragraph, for positions in either

excluded commodities or physical commodities, the proposed definition

would have applied two general requirements: The incidental test; and

the orderly trading requirement. For excluded commodities, the

Commission proposed in paragraph (1) a definition that conformed to the

Commission's 1987

[[Page 96743]]

interpretations permitting risk management exemptions in excluded

commodity contracts. For physical commodities, the Commission proposed

in paragraph (2) to amend the current general definition to conform to

CEA section 4a(c) and to remove the application process in Sec. Sec.

1.3(z)(3) and 1.48, that permits market participants to seek

recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions. Rather, the

Commission proposed that a market participant may request either a

staff interpretative letter under Sec. 140.99 \394\ or seek CEA

section 4a(a)(7) exemptive relief.\395\ Paragraphs (3) and (4) listed

enumerated exemptions. Paragraph (5) listed the requirements for cross-

commodity hedges of enumerated exemptions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\393\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75702-23. In doing so, the Commission proposed to remove and reserve

Sec. 1.3(z).

\394\ Section 140.99 sets out general procedures and

requirements for requests to Commission staff for exemptive, no-

action and interpretative letters.

\395\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR 75719.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to comments on the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, in the 2016 Supplemental Proposal, the Commission amended the

proposed definition of bona fide hedging position.\396\ The amended

definition proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Proposal would no longer

apply the two general requirements (the incidental test and the orderly

trading requirement). For excluded commodities, the Commission again

proposed paragraph (1) of the definition, substantially as in 2013. For

physical commodities, the Commission again proposed to conform

paragraph (2) more closely to CEA section 4a(c), but also proposed an

application process for market participants to seek recognition of non-

enumerated bona fide hedging positions, without the need to petition

the Commission. The Commission again proposed paragraphs (3) through

(5).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\396\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38462-64.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to comments on both the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal and the 2016 Supplemental Proposal, the Commission is now

reproposing the definition of bona fide hedging position, generally as

proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Proposal, but with a few further

amendments. First, for excluded commodities, the Commission clarifies

further the discretion of exchanges in recognizing risk management

exemptions. Second, for physical commodities, the Commission: (a)

Clarifies the scope of the general definition of a bona fide hedging

position; (b) conforms that general definition more closely to CEA

section 4a(c) by including recognition of positions that reduce risks

attendant to a swap that was used as a hedge; and, (c) re-organizes

additional requirements for enumerated hedges and requirements for

other recognition as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, apart

from the general definition.

c. BFH Definition Discussion--Remove Incidental Test and Orderly

Trading Requirement

Proposed Rule: As noted above, the Commission proposed to retain,

in its December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,\397\ then proposed to

remove, in its 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal,\398\ two

general requirements contained in the Sec. 1.3(z)(1) definition of

bona fide hedging position: the incidental test; and the orderly

trading requirement. The incidental test requires, for a position to be

recognized as a bona fide hedging position, that the ``purpose is to

offset price risks incidental to commercial cash, spot, or forward

operations.'' The orderly trading requirement mandates that ``such

position is established and liquidated in an orderly manner in

accordance with sound commercial practices.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\397\ 78 FR at 75706.

\398\ 81 FR at 38462.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: Commenters generally objected to retaining the

incidental test and the orderly trading requirement in the definition

of bona fide hedging position, as proposed in 2013.\399\ A number of

commenters supported the Commission's 2016 Supplemental Proposal to

remove the incidental test and the orderly trading requirement.\400\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\399\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38462.

\400\ See, e.g., CL-NCFC-60930 at 2, CL-FIA-60937 at 5 and 23,

and CL-IECAssn-60949 at 5-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Incidental Test: Commenters objected to the incidental test,

because that test is not included in the standards in CEA section 4a(c)

for the Commission to define a bona fide hedging position for physical

commodities.\401\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\401\ See, e.g., CL-CME-58718 at 47, and CL-NGFA-60941 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

However, other commenters noted their belief that eliminating the

incidental test would permit swap dealers or purely financial entities

to avail themselves of bona fide hedging exemptions, to the detriment

of commercial hedgers.\402\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\402\ See, e.g., CL-IATP-60951 at 4, CL-AFR-60953 at 2, CL-

Better Markets-60928 at 5, and CL-Rutkowski-60962 at 1.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Orderly trading requirement: One commenter urged the Commission to

eliminate the orderly trading requirement, because this requirement

does not apply to over-the-counter markets, the Commission does not

define orderly trading in a bi-lateral market, and this requirement

imposes a duty on end users to monitor market activities to ensure they

do not cause a significant market impact; additionally, the commenter

noted the anti-disruptive trading prohibitions and polices apply

regardless of whether the orderly trading requirement is imposed.\403\

Similarly, another commenter urged the Commission to exempt commercial

end-users from the orderly trading requirement, arguing that an orderly

trading requirement unreasonably requires commercial end-users to

monitor markets to measure the impact of their activities without clear

guidance from the Commission on what would constitute significant

market impact.\404\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\403\ See CL-COPE-59662 at 13.

\404\ See CL-DEU-59627 at 5-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Other commenters to the 2013 Proposal requested the Commission

interpret the orderly trading requirement consistently with the

Commission's disruptive trading practices interpretation (i.e., a

standard of intentional or reckless conduct) and not to apply a

negligence standard.\405\ Yet another commenter requested clarification

on the process the Commission would use to determine whether a position

has been established and liquidated in an orderly manner, whether any

defenses may be available, and what would be the consequences of

failing the requirement.\406\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\405\ See, e.g., CL-FIA-59595 at 5, 33-34, CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at

14-15, CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 4, 39, CL-CME-59718 at 67, and CL-ICE-

59669 at 11.

\406\ See CL-Working Group-59693 at 14.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

However, one commenter is concerned that eliminating the orderly

trading requirement for bona fide hedging for swaps positions would

discriminate against market participants in the futures and options

markets. The commenter noted that, if the Commission eliminates this

requirement, the Commission could not use its authority effectively to

review exchange-granted exemptions for swaps from position limits to

prevent or diminish excessive speculation.\407\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\407\ See CL-IATP-60951 at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: In the reproposed definition of bona fide

hedging position, the Commission is eliminating the incidental test and

the orderly trading requirement.

Incidental Test: Under the Reproposal, the incidental test has been

eliminated, because the Commission views the economically appropriate

test (discussed below) as including the concept of the offset of price

risks

[[Page 96744]]

incidental to commercial cash, spot, or forward operations. It was

noted in the 2013 Position Limits Proposal that, ``The Commission

believes the concept of commercial cash market activities is also

embodied in the economically appropriate test for physical commodities

in [CEA section 4a(c)(2)].'' \408\ It should be noted the incidental

test has been part of the regulatory definition of bona fide hedging

since 1975,\409\ but that the requirement was not explained in the 1974

proposing notice (``proposed definition otherwise deviates in only

minor ways from the hedging definition presently contained in [CEA

section 4a(3)]'').\410\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\408\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75707.

\409\ 40 FR 11560 (March 12, 1975).

\410\ 39 FR 39731 (Nov. 11, 1974).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is not persuaded by the commenters who believe

eliminating the incidental test would permit financial entities to

avail themselves of a bona fide hedging exemption, because the

incidental test is essentially embedded in the economically appropriate

test. In addition, for a physical-commodity derivative, the reproposed

definition, in mirroring the statutory standards of CEA section 4a(c),

requires a bona fide hedging position to be a substitute for a

transaction taken or to be taken in the cash market (either for the

market participant itself or for the market participant's pass-through

swap counterparty), which generally would preclude financial entities

from availing themselves of a bona fide hedging exemption (in the

absence of qualifying for a pass-through swap offset exemption,

discussed below).

Orderly Trading Requirement: The Reproposal also eliminates the

orderly trading requirement. That provision has been a part of the

regulatory definition of bona fide hedging since March 12, 1975 \411\

and previously was found in the statutory definition of bona fide

hedging position prior to the 1974 amendment removing the statutory

definition from CEA section 4a(3). However, the Commission is not aware

of a denial of recognition of a position as a bona fide hedging

position, as a result of a lack of orderly trading. Further, the

Commission notes that the meaning of the orderly trading requirement is

unclear in the context of the over-the-counter (OTC) swap market or in

the context of permitted off-exchange transactions (e.g., exchange of

futures for physicals).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\411\ 40 FR 11560 (Mar. 12, 1975).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In regard to the anti-disruptive trading prohibitions of CEA

section 4c(a)(5), those prohibitions apply to trading on registered

entities, but not to OTC transactions. It should be noted that the

anti-disruptive trading prohibitions in CEA section 4c(a)(5) make it

unlawful to engage in trading on a registered entity that

``demonstrates intentional or reckless disregard for orderly execution

of trading during the closing period'' (emphasis added); however, the

Commission has not, under the authority of CEA section 4c(a)(6),

prohibited the intentional or reckless disregard for the orderly

execution of transactions on a registered entity outside of the closing

period.

The Commission notes that an exchange may impose a general orderly

trading on all market participants. Market participants may request

clarification from exchanges on their trading rules. The Commission

does not believe that the absence of an orderly trading requirement in

the definition of bona fide hedging position would discriminate against

any particular trading venue for commodity derivative contracts.

d. BFH Definition Discussion-- Excluded Commodities

Proposed Rule: In both the 2013 Position Limits Proposal and the

2016 Supplement Proposal, the proposed definition of bona fide hedging

position for contracts in an excluded commodity included a standard

that the position is economically appropriate to the reduction of risks

in the conduct and management of a commercial enterprise (the

economically appropriate test) and also specified that such position

should be either (i) specifically enumerated in paragraphs (3) through

(5) of the definition of bona fide hedging position; or (ii) recognized

as a bona fide hedging position by a DCM or SEF consistent with the

guidance on risk management exemptions in proposed Appendix A to part

150.\412\ As noted above, the 2016 Supplemental Proposal would

eliminate the two additional general requirements (the incidental test

and the orderly trading requirement).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\412\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75707;

2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38505.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: One commenter believed that, to avoid an overly

restrictive definition due to the limited set of examples provided by

the Commission, only the general definition of a bona fide hedging

position should be applicable to hedges of an excluded commodity.\413\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\413\ CL-BG Group-59656 at 9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: After consideration of comments and review

of the record, the Commission has determined in the Reproposal to apply

the economically appropriate test to enumerated exemptions, as

proposed.\414\ However, the Reproposal amends the proposed definition

of a bona fide hedging position for an excluded commodity, to clarify

that an exchange may otherwise recognize risk management exemptions in

an excluded commodity, without regard to the economically appropriate

test. Regarding risk management exemptions, the Commission notes that

Appendix A (which codifies the Commission's two 1987 interpretations of

the bona fide hedging definition in the context of excluded

commodities) includes examples of risk altering transactions, such as a

temporary increase in equity exposure relative to cash bond holdings.

Such risk altering transactions appear inconsistent with the

Commission's interpretation of the economically appropriate test.

Accordingly, the Reproposal removes the economically appropriate test

from the guidance for exchange-recognized risk management exemptions in

excluded commodities.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\414\ The Commission did not propose to apply to excluded

commodities any of the additional standards in the general

definition applicable to hedges of a physical commodity.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Regarding an exchange's obligation to comply with core principles

pertaining to position limits on excluded commodities, as discussed

further in Sec. 150.5, the Commission clarifies that under the

Reproposal, exchanges have reasonable discretion as to whether to adopt

the Commission's definition of a bona fide hedging position, including

whether to grant risk management exemptions, such as those that would

be consistent with, but not limited to, the examples in Appendix A to

part 150. That is, the set of examples in Appendix A to part 150 is

non-restrictive, as it is guidance. The Reproposal also makes minor

wording changes in Appendix A to part 150, including to clarify an

exchange's reasonable discretion in granting risk management exemptions

and to eliminate a reference to the orderly trading requirement which

has been deleted, as discussed above, but otherwise is adopting

Appendix A as proposed.

e. BFH Definition Discussion--Physical Commodities General Definition

As noted in its proposal, the core of the Commission's approach to

defining bona fide hedging over the years has focused on transactions

that offset a

[[Page 96745]]

recognized price risk.\415\ Once a bona fide hedge is implemented, the

hedged entity should be price insensitive because any change in the

value of the underlying physical commodity is offset by the change in

value of the entity's physical commodity derivative position.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\415\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75702-3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Because a firm that has hedged its price exposure is price neutral

in its overall physical commodity position, the hedged entity should

have little incentive to manipulate or engage in other abusive market

practices to affect prices. By contrast, a party that maintains a

derivative position that leaves it with exposure to price changes is

not neutral as to price and, therefore, may have an incentive to affect

prices. Further, the intention of a hedge exemption is to enable a

commercial entity to offset its price risk; it was never intended to

facilitate taking on additional price risk.

The Commission recognizes there are complexities to analyzing the

various commercial price risks applicable to particular commercial

circumstances in order to determine whether a hedge exemption is

warranted. These complexities have led the Commission, from time to

time, to issue rule changes, interpretations, and exemptions. Congress,

too, has periodically revised the Federal statutes applicable to bona

fide hedging, most recently in the Dodd-Frank Act.

CEA section 4a(c)(1),\416\ as re-designated by the Dodd-Frank Act,

authorizes the Commission to define bona fide hedging positions

``consistent with the purposes of this Act.'' CEA section 4a(c)(2), as

added by the Dodd-Frank Act, provides new requirements for the

Commission to define bona fide hedging positions in physical commodity

derivatives ``[f]or the purposes of implementation of [CEA section

4a(a)(2)] for contracts of sale for future delivery or options on the

contracts of commodities [traded on DCMs].'' \417\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\416\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(c)(1).

\417\ The Reproposal provides for a phased approach to

implementation of CEA section 4a(a)(2), to reduce the potential

administrative burden on exchanges and market participants, and to

facilitate adoption of monitoring policies, procedures and systems.

See, e.g., December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75725.

The first phase of implementation of CEA section 4a(a)(2), in this

Reproposal, initially sets federal limits on 25 core referenced

futures contracts and their associated referenced contracts. The

Commission is establishing a definition of bona fide hedging

position for physical commodities in connection with its

implementation of CEA section 4a(a)(2), applicable to federal

limits. However, the Reproposal does not mandate adoption of that

definition of a bona fide hedging position for purposes of exchange-

set limits in contracts that are not yet subject to a federal limit.

See below regarding guidance and requirements under reproposed Sec.

150.5 for exchange-set limits in physical commodities.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

General Definition: The Commission's proposed general definition

for physical commodity derivative contracts, mirroring CEA section

4a(c)(2)(a), specifies a bona fide hedging position is one that:

(a) Temporary substitute test: represents a substitute for

transactions made or to be made or positions taken or to be taken at a

later time in the physical marketing channel;

(b) Economically appropriate test: is economically appropriate to

the reduction of risks in the conduct and management of a commercial

enterprise; and

(c) Change in value requirement: arises from the potential change

in the value of assets, liabilities, or services, whether current or

anticipated.

In addition to the above, the Commission's proposed general

definition, mirroring CEA section 4a(c)(2)(B)(i), also recognizes a

bona fide hedging position that:

(d) Pass-through swap offset: reduces risks attendant to a position

resulting from a swap that was executed opposite a counterparty for

which the transaction would qualify as a bona fide hedging transaction

under the general definition above.

The Commission proposed another provision, based on the statutory

standards, to recognize as a bona fide a position that:

(e) Pass-through swap: is itself the swap executed opposite a pass-

through swap counterparty, provided that the risk of that swap has been

offset.

The Commission received a number of comments on the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal and the 2016 Supplemental Proposal. Those

concerning the incidental test and the orderly trading requirement are

discussed above. Others are discussed below.

i. Temporary Substitute Test and Risk Management Exemptions

Proposed Rule: The temporary substitute test is discussed in the

2013 Position Limits Proposal at 75708-9. As the Commission noted in

the proposal, it believes that the temporary substitute test is a

necessary condition for classification of positions in physical

commodities as bona fide hedging positions. The proposed test mirrors

the statutory test in CEA section 4a(c)(2)(a)(i). The statutory test

does not include the adverb ``normally'' to modify the verb

``represents'' in the phrase ``represents a substitute for transactions

taken or to be taken at a later time in a physical marketing channel.''

Because the definition in Sec. 1.3(z)(1) includes the adverb

``normally,'' the Commission interpreted that provision to be merely a

temporary substitute criterion, rather than a test. Accordingly, the

Commission previously granted risk management exemptions for persons to

offset the risk of swaps and other financial instruments that did not

represent substitutes for transactions or positions to be taken in a

physical marketing channel. However, given the statutory change in

direction, positions that reduce the risk of such speculative swaps and

financial instruments would no longer meet the requirements for a bona

fide hedging position under the proposed definition in Sec. 150.1.

Comments Received: A number of commenters urged the Commission not

to deny risk-management exemptions for financial intermediaries who

utilize referenced contracts to offset the risks arising from the

provision of diversified, commodity-based returns to the

intermediaries' clients.\418\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\418\ See, e.g., CL-FIA-59595 at 5, 34-35; CL-AMG-59709 at 2,

12-15; and CL-CME-59718 at 67-69.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

However, other commenters noted the ``proposed rules properly

refrain from providing a general exemption to financial firms seeking

to hedge their financial risks from the sale of commodity-related

instruments such as index swaps, Exchange Traded Funds (ETFs), and

Exchange Traded Notes (ETNs),'' because such instruments are inherently

speculative and may overwhelm the price discovery function of the

derivative market.\419\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\419\ See, e.g., CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 8, and CL-Better

Markets-60325 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Reproposal would retain the temporary

substitute test, as proposed. The Commission interprets the statutory

temporary substitute test as more stringent than the temporary

substitute criterion in Sec. 1.3(z)(1); \420\ that is, the Commission

views the statutory test as narrowing the standards for a bona fide

hedging position. Further, the Commission believes that retaining a

risk management exemption for swap intermediaries, without regard to

the purpose of the counterparty's swap, would fly in the face of the

statutory restrictions on pass-through swap offsets (requiring the

position of the pass-through swap counterparty to

[[Page 96746]]

qualify as a bona fide hedging transaction).\421\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\420\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75709.

\421\ See CEA section 4a(c)(2)(B)(i).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Proposed Rule on risk management exemption grandfather provisions:

The Commission proposed in Sec. 150.2(f) and Sec. 150.3(f) to

grandfather previously granted risk-management exemptions, as applied

to pre-existing positions.\422\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\422\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75734-5 and 75739-41.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: Commenters requested that the Commission extend

the grandfather relief to permit pre-existing risk management positions

to be increased after the effective date of a limit.\423\ Commenters

also requested that the Commission permit the risk associated with a

pre-existing position to be offset by a futures position in a deferred

contract month, after the liquidation of an offsetting position in a

nearby futures contract month.\424\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\423\ See, e.g., CL-AMG-59709 at 2, 18.

\424\ See, e.g., id. at 18-19.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some commenters urged the Commission not to deny risk-management

exemptions for financial intermediaries who utilize referenced

contracts to offset the risks arising from the provision of diversified

commodity-based returns to the intermediaries' clients.\425\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\425\ CL-FIA-59595 at 5,34-35; CL-AMG-59709 at 2, 12-15; and CL-

CME-59718 at 67-69.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In contrast, other commenters noted that the proposed rules

``properly refrain'' from providing a general exemption to financial

firms seeking to hedge their financial risks from the sale of

commodity-related instruments such as index swaps, ETFs, and ETNs

because such instruments are ``inherently speculative'' and may

overwhelm the price discovery function of the derivative market.\426\

Another commenter noted, because commodity index contracts are

speculative, the Commission should not provide a regulatory exemption

for such contracts.\427\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\426\ CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 8; and CL-Better Markets-60325 at

2.

\427\ CL-CMOC-59720 at 4-5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Reproposal clarifies and expands the

relief in Sec. 150.3(f) (previously granted exemptions) by: (1)

Clarifying that such previously granted exemptions may apply to pre-

existing financial instruments that are within the scope of existing

Sec. 1.47 exemptions, rather than only to pre-existing swaps; and (2)

recognizing exchange-granted non-enumerated exemptions in non-legacy

commodity derivatives outside of the spot month (consistent with the

Commission's recognition of risk management exemptions outside of the

spot month), and provided such exemptions are granted prior to the

compliance date of the final rule, once adopted, and apply only to pre-

existing financial instruments as of the effective date of that final

rule. These two changes are intended to reduce the potential for market

disruption by forced liquidations, since a market intermediary would

continue to be able to offset risks of pre-effective-date financial

instruments, pursuant to previously-granted federal or exchange risk

management exemptions.

The Reproposal clarifies that the Commission will continue to

recognize the offset of the risk of a pre-existing financial instrument

as bona fide using a derivative position, including a deferred

derivative contract month entered after the effective date of a final

rule, provided a nearby derivative contract month is liquidated.

However, under the Reproposal, such relief will not be extended to an

increase in positions after the effective date of a limit, because that

appears contrary to Congressional intent to narrow the definition of a

bona fide hedging position, as discussed above.

ii. Economically Appropriate Test

Commission proposal: The economically appropriate test is discussed

in the 2013 Position Limits Proposal at 75709-10. The proposed

economically appropriate test mirrors the statutory test, which, in

turn, mirrors the test in current Sec. 1.3(z)(1).

Comments received: Several commenters requested that the Commission

broadly interpret the phrase ``economically appropriate'' to include

more than just price risk, stating that there are other types of risk

that are economically appropriate to address in the management of a

commercial enterprise including operational risk, liquidity risk,

credit risk, locational risk, and seasonal risk.\428\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\428\ See, e.g., CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 4, CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at

14, CL-API-60939 at 2, CL-CMC-60950 at 4-5, CL-NCFC-60930 at 2, CL-

ADM-60934 at 2-6, CL-FIA-60937 at 5 and 20, CL-NGFA-60941 at 4, and

CL-Associations-60972 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commenters suggested that if the Commission objected to expanding

its interpretation of ``economically appropriate'' risks, then the

Commission should allow the exchanges to utilize discretion in their

interpretations of the economically appropriate test.\429\ Another

commenter believed that the Commission should provide ``greater

flexibility'' in the various bona fide hedging tests, because hedging

that reduces all the various types of risk should be deemed

``economically appropriate.'' \430\ Commenters suggested that a broader

view of the types of risks considered to be ``economically

appropriate'' should not be perceived as being at odds with the

Commission's view of ``price risk'' because all of these risks can

inform and determine price, noting that firms evaluate different risks

and determine a price impact based on a combination of their likelihood

of occurrence and the price impact in the event of occurrence.\431\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\429\ See, e.g., CL-CMC-60950 at 4-5, and CL-Olam-59946 at 2-4.

\430\ CL-ICE-60929 at 10.

\431\ See, e.g., CL-ADM-60934 at 2-6, and CL-API-60939 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Reproposal does not broaden the

interpretation of the phrase ``economically appropriate.'' The

Commission notes that it has provided interpretations and guidance over

the years as to the meaning of ``economically appropriate.'' \432\ The

Commission reiterates its view that, to satisfy the economically

appropriate test and the change in value requirement of CEA section

4a(c)(2)(A)(iii), the purpose of a bona fide hedging position must be

to offset price risks incidental to a commercial enterprise's cash

operations.\433\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\432\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75709-10.

\433\ Id. at 75710.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that an exchange is permitted to recognize

non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions under the process of Sec.

150.9, discussed below, subject to assessment of the particular facts

and circumstances, where price risk arises from other types of risk.

The Reproposal does not, however, allow the exchanges to utilize

unbounded discretion in interpreting ``economically appropriate'' in

such recognitions. The Commission believes that such a broad delegation

is not authorized by the CEA and, in the Commission's view, would be

contrary to the reasonably certain statutory standard of the

economically appropriate test. Further, as explained in the discussion

of Sec. 150.9, exchange determinations will be subject to the

Commission's de novo review.

Comments on gross vs. net hedging: A number of commenters requested

that the Commission recognize as bona fide both ``gross hedging'' and

``net hedging,'' without regard to overall risk.\434\ Commenters

generally requested, as ``gross hedging,'' that an enterprise should be

permitted the flexibility to use either a long or short derivative to

offset the risk of any cash position, identified at the discretion of

[[Page 96747]]

the commercial enterprise, irrespective of the commercial enterprise's

net cash market position.\435\ For example, a commenter contended that

a commercial enterprise should be able to hedge fixed-price purchase

contracts (e.g., with a short futures position), without regard to the

enterprise's fixed-price sales contracts, even if such a short

derivative position may increase the enterprise's risk.\436\ One

commenter stated that the ``new proposed interpretation'' of the

``economically appropriate'' test requires a commercial enterprise to

include, and consider for purposes of bona fide hedging, portions of

its portfolio it would not otherwise consider in managing risk.\437\

Another commenter did not agree that market participants should be

required to calculate risk on a consolidated basis, because this

approach would require commercial entities to build out new systems. As

an alternative, that commenter requests the Commission recognize

current risk management tools.\438\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\434\ See, e.g., CL-MGEX-60936 at 11, CL-CMC-60950 at 6, CL-

Associations-60972 at 2.

\435\ See, e.g., CL-Olam-59658 at 4-6.

\436\ CL-FIA-59595 at 20-21.

\437\ CL-Working Group-60947 at 15.

\438\ CL-CMC-60950 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Reproposal retains the Commission's

interpretation, as proposed, of economically appropriate gross hedging:

that in circumstances where net hedging does not measure all risk

exposures, an enterprise may appropriately enter into, for example, a

calendar month spread position as a gross hedge. A number of comments

misconstrued the Commission's historical interpretation of gross and

net hedging. The Commission has not recognized selective identification

of cash positions to justify a position as bona fide; rather, the

Commission has permitted a regular practice of excluding certain

commodities, products, or by-products, in determining an enterprise's

risk position.\439\ As proposed, the Reproposal requires such excluded

commodities to be de minimis or difficult to measure, because a market

participant should not be permitted to ignore material cash market

positions and enter into derivative positions that increase risk while

avoiding a position limit restriction; rather, such a market

participant's speculative activity must remain below the level of the

speculative position limit.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\439\ See, e.g., instructions to Form 204.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Note, however, under a partial reading of a preamble to a 1977

proposal, the Commission has appeared to recognize gross hedging,

without regard to net risk, as bona fide; the Commission noted in 1977

that: ``The previous statutory definition of bona fide hedging

transactions or positions contained in section 4a of the Act before

amendment by the CFTC Act and the present definition permit persons to

classify as hedging any purchase or sale for future delivery which is

offset by their gross cash position irrespective of their net cash

position.'' \440\ However, under a full reading of that 1977 proposal,

the Commission made clear that gross hedging was appropriate in

circumstances where ``net cash positions do not necessarily measure

total risk exposure due to differences in the timing of cash

commitments, the location of stocks, and differences in grades or types

of the cash commodity.'' \441\ Thus, the 1977 proposal noted the

Commission ``does not intend at this time to alter the provisions of

the present definition with respect to the hedging of gross cash

position.'' \442\ At the time of the 1977 proposal, the ``present

definition'' had been promulgated in 1975 by the Administrator of the

Commodity Exchange Authority based on the statutory definition; and the

Administrator had interpreted the statutory definition to recognize

gross hedging as bona fide in the context of a merchant who ``may hedge

his fixed-price purchase commitments by selling futures and at the same

time hedge his fixed-price sale commitments by buying futures,'' rather

than hedging only his net position.\443\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\440\ 42FR 14832 at 14834 (Mar. 16, 1977).

\441\ Id.

\442\ Id.

\443\ See, Letter from Roger R. Kauffman, Adm'r, Commodity

Exchange Authority, to Reid Bondurant, Cotton Exchange (Feb. 13,

1959) (emphasis added), cited in CL-Olam-59658 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments on specific, identifiable risk: Commenters requested the

Commission consider as economically appropriate any derivative position

that a business can reasonably demonstrate reduces or mitigates one or

more specific, identifiable risks related to individual or aggregated

positions or transactions, based on its own business judgment and risk

management policies, whether risk is managed enterprise-wide or by

legal entity, line of business, or profit center.\444\ One commenter

disagreed with what it called a ``one-size-fits-all'' risk management

paradigm that requires market participants to calculate risk on a

consolidated basis because this approach would require commercial

entities to build out new systems in order to manage risk this way. The

commenter requests that the Commission instead recognize that current

risk management tools are used effectively for positions that are below

current limits and those tools remain effective above position limit

levels as well.\445\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\444\ See, e.g., CL-API-59694 at 4, CL-IECAssn-59679 at 10-11,

CL-APGA-59722 at 9-10, CL-NCFC-59942 at 5, CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 15,

and CL-EEI-Sup-60386 at 7.

\445\ CL-CMC-60950 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Reproposal declines to assess the bona

fides of a position based solely on whether a commercial enterprise can

identify any particular cash position within an aggregated person, the

risks of which such derivative position offsets. The Commission

believes that such an approach would run counter to the aggregation

rules in Sec. 150.4 and would permit an enterprise to cherry pick cash

market exposures to justify exceeding position limits, with either a

long or short derivative position, even though such derivative position

increases the enterprise's risk.

The Commission views a derivative position that increases an

enterprise's risk as contrary to the plain language of CEA section

4a(c) and the Commission's bona fide hedging definition, which requires

that a bona fide hedging position ``is economically appropriate to the

reduction of risks in the conduct and management of a commercial

enterprise.'' \446\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\446\ CEA section 4a(c)(2)(A)(ii).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

If a transaction that increases a commercial enterprise's overall

risk should be considered a bona fide hedging position, this would

result in position limits not applying to certain positions that should

be considered speculative. For example, assume an enterprise has

entered into only two cash forward transactions and has no inventory.

The first cash forward transaction is a purchase contract (for a

particular commodity for delivery at a particular later date). The

second cash forward transaction is a sales contract (for the same

commodity for delivery on the same date as the purchase contract).

Under the terms of the cash forward contracts, the enterprise may take

delivery on the purchase contract and re-deliver the commodity on the

sales contract. Such an enterprise does not have a net cash market

position that exposes it to price risk, because it has both purchased

and sold the same commodity for delivery on the same date (such as cash

forward contracts for the same cargo of Brent crude oil). The

enterprise could establish a short derivative position that would

offset the risk of the purchase contract; however, that would increase

the enterprise's price risk. Alternatively, the enterprise

[[Page 96748]]

could establish a long derivative position that would offset the risk

of the sales contract; however, that would increase the enterprise's

price risk. If price risk reduction at the level of the aggregate

person is not a requirement of a bona fide hedging position, such an

enterprise could establish either a long or short derivative position,

at its election, and claim an exemption from position limits for either

derivative position, ostensibly as a bona fide hedging position. If

either such position could be recognized as bona fide, position limits

would simply not apply to such an enterprise's derivative position,

even though the enterprise had no price risk exposure to the commodity

prior to establishing such derivative position and created price risk

exposure to the commodity by establishing the derivative position.

Based on the Commission's experience and expertise, it believes that

such a result (entering either a long or short derivative position,

whichever the market participant elects) simply cannot be recognized as

a legitimate risk reduction that should be exempt from position limits;

rather, such a position should be considered speculative for purposes

of position limits.

The Commission notes that a commercial enterprise that wishes to

separately manage its operations, in separate legal entities, may,

under the aggregation requirements of Sec. 150.4, establish

appropriate firewalls and file a notice for an aggregation exemption,

because separate legal entities with appropriate firewalls are treated

as separate persons for purposes of position limits. The Commission

explained that an aggregation exemption was appropriate in

circumstances where the risk of coordinated activity is mitigated by

firewalls.\447\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\447\ See discussion under section II.B.3 (Criteria for

Aggregation Relief in Rule 150.4(b)(2)(i)) of the 2016 Final

Aggregation Rule.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments on processing hedge: A commenter requested the Commission

recognize, as bona fide, a long or short derivative position that

offsets either inputs or outputs in a processing operation, based on

the business judgment of the commercial enterprise that it might not be

an appropriate time to hedge both inputs and outputs, and requested the

Commission withdraw the processing hedge example on pages 75836-7 of

the 2013 Position Limits Proposal (proposed example 5 in Appendix C to

part 150).\448\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\448\ CL-Cargill-59638 at 2-4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: For the reasons discussed above regarding

gross hedging and specific, identifiable risks, the Reproposal does not

recognize as a bona fide hedging position a derivative position that

offsets either inputs or outputs in a processing operation, absent

additional facts and circumstances. The Commission reiterates its view

that, as explained in the Commission's 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

by way of example, processing by a soybean crush operation or a fuel

blending operation may add relatively little value to the price of the

input commodity. In such circumstances, it would be economically

appropriate for the processor or blender to offset the price risks of

both the unfilled anticipated requirement for the input commodity and

the unsold anticipated production; such a hedge would, for example,

fully lock in the value of soybean crush processing.\449\ However,

under such circumstances, merely entering an outright derivative

position (i.e., either a long position or a short position, at the

processor's election) appears to be risk increasing, since the price

risk of such outright position appears greater than, and not offsetting

of, the price risk of anticipated processing and, thus, such outright

position would not be economically appropriate to the reduction of

risks.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\449\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75709.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments on economically appropriate anticipatory hedges:

Commenters requested the Commission recognize derivative positions as

economically appropriate to the reduction of certain anticipatory

risks, such as irrevocable bids or offers.\450\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\450\ See, e.g., CL-Cargill-59638 at 2-4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has a long history of

providing for the recognition, in Sec. 1.3(z)(2), as enumerated bona

fide hedging positions, of anticipatory hedges for unfilled anticipated

requirements and unsold anticipated production, under the process of

Sec. 1.48.\451\ The Reproposal continues to enumerate those two

anticipatory hedges, along with two new anticipatory hedges for

anticipated royalties and contracts for services, as discussed below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\451\ 17 CFR 1.3(z)(2) and 1.48 (2010).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission did not propose an enumerated exemption for binding,

irrevocable bids or offers as the Commission believes that an analysis

of the facts and circumstances would be necessary prior to recognizing

such an exemption. Consequently, the Reproposal does not provide for

such an enumerated exemption. However, the Commission withdraws the

view that a binding, irrevocable bid or offer fails to meet the

economically appropriate test.\452\ Rather, the Commission will permit

exchanges, under Sec. 150.9, to make a facts-and-circumstances

determination as to whether to recognize such and other anticipatory

hedges as non-enumerated bona fide hedges, consistent with the

Commission's recognition ``that there can be a gradation of

probabilities that an anticipated transaction will occur.'' \453\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\452\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75720.

\453\ Id. at 75719.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iii. Change in Value Requirement

Commission proposal: To satisfy the change in value requirement,

the hedging position must arise from the potential change in the value

of: (I) Assets that a person owns, produces, manufactures, processes,

or merchandises or anticipates owning, producing, manufacturing,

processing, or merchandising; (II) liabilities that a person owes or

anticipates incurring; or (III) services that a person provides,

purchases, or anticipates providing or purchasing.\454\ The proposed

definition incorporated the potential change in value requirement in

current Sec. 1.3(z)(1).\455\ This provision largely mirrors the

provision of CEA section 4a(c)(2)(A)(iii).\456\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\454\ Id. at 75710.

\455\ 17 CFR 1.3(z) (2010).

\456\ As noted in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78

FR at 75710, CEA section 4a(c)(2)(A)(iii)(II) uses the phrase

``liabilities that a person owns or anticipates incurring.'' The

Commission interprets the word ``owns'' to be a typographical error,

and interprets the word ``owns'' to be ``owes.'' A person may owe on

a liability, and may anticipate incurring a liability. If a person

``owns'' a liability, such as a debt instrument issued by another,

then such person owns an asset. Because assets are included in CEA

section 4a(c)(2)(A)(iii)(I), the Commission interprets ``owns'' to

be ``owes.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments on change in value: One commenter urged a more narrow

definition of bona fide hedging that restricts exemptions to

``commercial entities that deal exclusively in the production,

processing, refining, storage, transportation, wholesale or retail

distribution, or consumption of physical commodities.'' \457\ However,

numerous commenters urged the Commission to enumerate new exemptions

consistent with the change in value requirement, such as for

merchandising, as discussed below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\457\ CL-PMAA-NEFI-60952 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Reproposal retains the change in value

requirement as proposed, which mirrors CEA section 4a(c)(2)(A)(iii).

Rather than further restrict the types of commercial entities who may

avail themselves of a

[[Page 96749]]

bona fide hedging exemption under the change in value requirement, the

Commission notes that the reproposed definition also reflects the

statutory requirement under the temporary substitute test, that the

hedging position be a substitute for a position taken or to be taken in

a physical marketing channel, either by the market participant or the

market participant's pass-through swap counterparty.

Comments on anticipatory merchandising or storage: Numerous

commenters asserted the Commission should recognize anticipatory

merchandising as a bona fide hedge, as included in CEA section

4a(c)(A)(iii), such as (1) a merchant desiring to lock in the price

differential between an unfixed price forward commitment and an

anticipated offsetting unfixed price forward commitment, where there is

a reasonable basis to infer that an offsetting transaction was likely

to occur (such as in anticipation of shipping), (2) a bid or offer,

where there is a reasonably anticipated risk that such bid or offer

will be accepted, or (3) an anticipated purchase and/or anticipated

storage of a commodity, prior to anticipated merchandising (or

usage).\458\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\458\ See, e.g., CL-FIA-59595 at 30-31, CL-FIA-60303 at 6, CL-

EEI-EPSA-59602 at 17-18, CL-EEI-59945 at 6, CL-CMC-60950 at 6, CL-

CMC-60391 at 4-5, CL-CMC-60318 at 5, CL-CMC-59634 at 3, 20-22, CL-

Cargill-59638 at 2-4, CL-ADM-59640 at 2-3, CL-Olam-59946 at 4, CL-BG

Group-59656 at 10-11, CL-ASCA-59667 at 2, CL-NGSA-60379 at 5, CL-

NGSA-59674 at 2, 18-24, CL-Working Group-60383 at 15, CL-Working

Group-59937 at 5-6, 10-12, CL-Working Group-59656 at 16-18, 21-23,

26, CL-API-59694 at 5-6, CL-MSCGI-59708 at 2-3, 18-20, CL-CME-59718

at 56-57, 59, CL-Armajaro-59729 at 1, CL-AFBF-59730 at 2, CL-NCFC-

59942 at 2-4, CL-ICE-60310 at 4, CL-ICE-60387 at 9, CL-ISDA/SIFMA-

59611 at 37-38, CL-COPE-59662 at 15-16, and CL-GSC-59703 at 3-4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commenters recommended the Commission recognize unfilled storage

capacity as the basis of a bona fide hedge of, either (1) anticipated

rents (e.g., a type of anticipated asset or liability), (2) anticipated

merchandising, or (3) anticipated purchase and storage prior to

usage.\459\ By way of example, one commenter contended anticipated rent

on a storage asset is like an option and the appropriate hedge position

should be dynamically adjusted.\460\ Also by way of example, another

commenter suggested enumerated hedges should include (1) offsetting

long and short positions in commodity derivative contracts as hedges of

storage or transportation of the commodity underlying such contracts;

and (2) positions that hedge the value of assets owned, or anticipated

to be owned, used to produce, process, store or transport the commodity

underlying the derivative.\461\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\459\ See, e.g., CL-Cargill-59638 at 2-4, CL-CME-59718 at 57-58,

CL-NEM-59586 at 4, CL-FIA-59595 32-33, CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 4, CL-

CMC-59634 at 5, CL-LDC-59643 at 2, CL-BG Group-59656 at 10, CL-COPE-

59950 at 5, CL-COPE-59662 at 14-15, CL--Working Group-59693 at 23-

26, CL-GSC-59703 at 2-3, CL-AFBF-59730 at 2, CL-SEMP-59926 at 6-7,

CL-EDF-60398 at 8-9, CL-EDF-59961 at 2-3, CL-Andersons-60256 at 1-3,

and CL-SEMP-60384 at 4-5.

\460\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611, Annex B at 7.

\461\ CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 13.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission notes that an exchange, under

reproposed Sec. 150.9, as discussed below, is permitted to recognize

anticipated merchandising or anticipated purchase and storage, as

potential non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions, subject to

assessment of the particular facts and circumstances, including such

information as the market participant's activities (taken or to be

taken) in the physical marketing channel and arrangements for storage

facilities. While the Commission previously discussed its doubt that

storage hedges generally will meet the economically appropriate test,

because the value fluctuations in a calendar month spread in a

commodity derivative contract will likely have at best a low

correlation with value fluctuations in expected returns (e.g., rents)

on unfilled storage capacity,\462\ the Commission now withdraws that

discussion of doubt and, as reproposed, would review exchange-granted

non-enumerated bona fide hedging exemptions for storage with an open

mind.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\462\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75718.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission does not express a view as this time on one

commenter's assertion that the anticipated rent on a storage asset is

like an option; the commenter did not provide data regarding the

relationship between calendar spreads and the ``profitability of

filling storage.'' The Commission notes that, under the Reproposal, an

exchange could evaluate the particulars of such a situation in an

application for a non-enumerated hedging position.

Similarly, as reproposed, an exchange could evaluate the

particulars of other situations, such as a commenter's example of

storage or transportation hedges. The Commission notes that it is not

clear from the comments how the value fluctuations of calendar month or

location differentials are related to the fluctuations in value of

storage or transportation. Regarding a commenter's examples of assets

owned or anticipated to be owned, it is not clear how the value

fluctuations of whatever would be the relevant hedging position (e.g.,

long, short, or calendar month spread) are related to the fluctuations

in value of whatever would be the particular assets (e.g., tractors,

combines, silos, semi-trucks, rail cars, pipelines) to be used to

produce, process, store or transport the commodity underlying the

derivative.

Comments on unfixed price commitments: Commenters recommended the

Commission recognize, as a bona fide hedge, the fixing of the price of

an unfixed price commitment, for example, to reduce the merchant's

operational risk and potentially to acquire a commodity through the

delivery process on a physical-delivery futures contract.\463\ Another

commenter provided an example of a preference to shift unfixed-price

exposure on cash commitments from daily index prices to the first-of-

month price under the NYMEX Henry Hub Natural Gas core referenced

futures contract.\464\ A commenter suggested that the interpretation of

a fixed price contract should include ``basis priced contracts which

are purchases or sales with the basis value fixed between the buyer and

the seller against a prevailing futures'' contract; the commenter noted

such basis risk could be hedged with a calendar month spread to lock in

their purchase and sale margins.\465\ Another commenter requested the

Commission explicitly recognize index price transactions as appropriate

for a bona fide hedging exemption, citing concerns that the price of an

unfixed price forward sales contract may fall below the cost of

production.\466\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\463\ See, e.g., CL-Olam-59946 at 4, and CL-NCFC -59942 at 2-4.

\464\ CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 4-5.

\465\ CL-NGFA-60941 at 4.

\466\ CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission affirms its belief that a

reduction in a price risk is required under the economically

appropriate test of CEA section 4a(c)(2)(A)(ii); consistent with the

economically appropriate test, a potential change in value (i.e., a

price risk) is required under CEA section 4a(c)(2)(A)(iii). In both the

reproposed and proposed definitions of bona fide hedging position, the

incidental test would require a reduction in price risk. Although the

Reproposal deletes the incidental test from the first paragraph of the

bona fide hedging position definition (as discussed above), the

Commission notes that it interprets risk in the economically

appropriate test as price risk, and does not interpret risk to include

operational risk. Interpreting risk to include operational risk would

broaden the scope of a bona fide hedging position beyond the

Commission's historical interpretation

[[Page 96750]]

and may have adverse impacts that are inconsistent with the policy

objectives of limits in CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B).

The Commission has consistently required a bona fide hedging

position to be a position that is shown to reduce price risk in the

conduct and management of a commercial enterprise.\467\ By way of

background, the Commission notes, in promulgating the definition of

bona fide hedging position in Sec. 1.3(z), it explained that a bona

fide hedging position ``must be economically appropriate to risk

reduction, such risks must arise from operation of a commercial

enterprise, and the price fluctuations of the futures contracts used in

the transaction must be substantially related to fluctuations of the

cash market value of the assets, liabilities or services being

hedged.'' \468\ As noted above, the Dodd-Frank Act added CEA section

4a(c)(2), which copied the economically appropriate test from the

Commission's definition in Sec. 1.3(z)(1). Thus, the Commission

believes it is reasonable to interpret that statutory standard in the

context of the Commission's historical interpretation of Sec. 1.3(z).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\467\ The Commission distinguishes operational risk, which may

arise from a potential failure of a counterparty to a cash market

forward transaction, from price risks in the conduct and management

of a commercial enterprise.

\468\ 42 FR 14832 at 14833 (March 16, 1977) (proposed

definition). The Commission also adopted the incidental test

(requiring that the ``purpose is to offset price risks incidental to

commercial cash or spot operations''). 42 FR 42748 at 42751 (Aug.

24, 1977) (final definition). Previously, the Secretary of

Agriculture promulgated a definition of bona fide hedging position

that required a purpose ``to offset price risks incidental to

commercial cash or spot operations.'' 40 FR 11560 at 11561 (Mar. 12,

1975).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

While the Commission has enumerated a calendar month spread as a

bona fide hedge of offsetting unfixed-price cash commodity sales and

purchases, the Reproposal will permit an exchange, under reproposed

Sec. 150.9, to conduct a facts-and-circumstances, case-by-case review

to determine whether a calendar month spread is appropriately

recognized as a bona fide hedging position for only a cash commodity

purchase or sales contract. For example, assume a merchant enters into

an unfixed-price sales contract (e.g., priced at a fixed differential

to a deferred month futures contract), and immediately enters into a

calendar month spread to reduce the risk of the fixed basis moving

adversely. It may not be economically appropriate to recognize as bona

fide a long futures position in the spot (or nearby) month and a short

futures position in a deferred calendar month matching the merchant's

cash delivery obligation, in the event the spot (or nearby) month price

is higher than the deferred contract month price (referred to as

backwardation, and characteristic of a spot cash market with supply

shortages), because such a calendar month futures spread would lock in

a loss and may be indicative of an attempt to manipulate the spot (or

nearby) futures price.

Regarding the risk of an unfixed price forward sales contract

falling below the cost of production, the Reproposal enumerates a bona

fide hedging exemption for unsold anticipated production; the

Commission clarifies, as discussed below, that such an enumerated hedge

is available regardless of whether production has been sold forward at

an unfixed (that is, index) price.

Comments on cash and carry: Commenters requested the Commission

enumerate, as a bona fide hedging position, a ``cash and carry'' trade,

where a market participant enters a nearby long futures position and a

deferred short futures position, with the intention to take delivery

and carry the commodity for re-delivery.\469\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\469\ See, e.g., CL-Armajaro-59729 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Reproposal does not propose to enumerate

a cash and carry trade as a bona fide hedging position. A cash and

carry trade appears to fail the temporary substitute test, since such

market participant is not using the derivative contract as a substitute

for a position taken or to be taken in the physical marketing channel.

The long futures position in the cash and carry trade is in lieu of a

purchase in the cash market. In the 2016 Supplemental Proposal, the

Commission asked whether, and subject to what conditions (e.g.,

potential facilitation of liquidity for a bona fide hedger of

inventory), a cash and carry position might be recognized by an

exchange as a spread exemption under Sec. 150.10, subject to the

Commission's de novo review.\470\ This issue is discussed under Sec.

150.10, regarding exchange recognition of spread exemptions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\470\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38479.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iv. Pass-Through Swap Offsets and Offsets of Hedging Swaps

Commission proposal: The Commission proposed to recognize as bona

fide a commodity derivative contract that reduces the risk of a

position resulting from a swap executed opposite a counterparty for

which the position at the time of the transaction would qualify as a

bona fide hedging position.\471\ This proposal mirrors the requirements

in CEA section 4a(c)(B)(i). The proposal also clarified that the swap

itself is a bona fide hedging position to the extent it is offset.

However, the Commission proposed that it would not recognize as bona

fide hedges an offset in physical-delivery contracts during the shorter

of the last five days of trading or the time period for the spot month

in such physical-delivery commodity derivative contract (the ``five-

day'' rule, discussed further below).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\471\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75710.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments received: As noted above, commenters recommended that the

Commission's bona fide hedging definition should reflect the standards

in CEA section 4a(c). One commenter suggested that the Commission

broaden the pass-through swap offset provisions to accommodate

secondary pass-through transactions among affiliates within a corporate

organization to make ``the most efficient and effective use of their

existing corporate structures.'' \472\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\472\ CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 8-9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission agrees that the bona fide

hedging definition, in general, and the pass-through swap provision, in

particular, should more closely reflect the statutory standards in CEA

section 4a(c). Under the proposed definition, a market participant who

reduced the risk of a swap, where such swap was a bona fide hedging

position for that market participant, would not have received

recognition for the swap offset as a bona fide hedging position, as

this provision in CEA section 4a(c)(2)(B)(ii) was not mirrored in the

proposed definition.\473\ To adhere more closely to the statutory

standards, the Reproposal recognizes such offset as a bona fide hedging

position. Consistent with the proposal for offset of a pass-through

swap, the Reproposal imposes a five-day rule restriction on the offset

in a physical-delivery contract of a swap used as a bona fide hedge;

however, as reproposed, an exchange listing a physical-delivery

contract may recognize, on a case-by-case basis, such offset as a non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position pursuant to the process in

reproposed Sec. 150.9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\473\ For example, assume a market participant entered a swap as

a bona fide hedging position and, subsequently, offset (that is,

lifted) that hedge using a futures contract. The Commission's

original proposal would not have recognized the lifting of the hedge

as a bona fide hedging transaction, although the statute does.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Reproposal retains and clarifies in subparagraph (ii)(A) that

the bona fides of a pass-through swap may be

[[Page 96751]]

determined at the time of the transaction by the intermediary. The

clarification is intended to reduce the burden on such intermediary of

otherwise needing to confirm the continued bona fides of its

counterparty over the life of the pass-through swap.

In addition, the Reproposal retains, as proposed, application of

the five-day rule to pass-through swap offsets in a physical-delivery

contract. However, the Commission notes that under the Reproposal, an

exchange listing a physical-delivery contract may recognize, on a case-

by-case basis, a pass-through swap offset (in addition to the offset of

a swap used as a bona fide hedge), during the last five days of trading

in a spot month, as a non-enumerated bona fide hedge pursuant to the

process in reproposed Sec. 150.9.

Further, the Reproposal retains the recognition of a pass-through

swap itself that is offset, not just the offsetting position (and,

thus, permitting the intermediary to exclude such pass-through swap

from position limits, in addition to excluding the offsetting

position).

Regarding the request to broaden the pass-through swap offset

provisions to accommodate secondary pass-through transactions among

affiliates, the Commission declines in this Reproposal to broaden the

pass-through swap offset exemption beyond the provisions in CEA section

4a(c)(2)(B)(i). However, the Commission notes that a group of

affiliates under common ownership is required to aggregate positions

under the Commission's requirements in Sec. 150.4, absent an

applicable aggregation exemption. In the circumstance of aggregation of

positions, recognition of a secondary pass-through swap transaction

would not be necessary among such an aggregated group, because the

group is treated as one person for purposes of position limits.

v. Additional Requirements for Enumeration or Other Recognition

Commission proposal: In 2013, the Commission proposed in

subparagraph (2)(i)(D) of the definition of a bona fide hedging

position, that, in addition to satisfying the general definition of a

bona fide hedging position, a position would not be recognized as bona

fide unless it was enumerated in paragraph (3), (4), or (5)(discussed

below), or recognized as a pass-through swap offset or pass-through

swap.\474\ In 2016, in response to comments on the 2013 proposed

definition, the Commission proposed, in subparagraph (2)(i)(D)(2) of

the definition, to also recognize as bona fide any position that has

been otherwise recognized as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position by either a designated contract market or a swap execution

facility, each in accordance with Sec. 150.9(a), or by the

Commission.\475\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\474\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75711.

\475\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38505.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments received: Commenters objected to the requirement for a

position to be specifically enumerated in order to be recognized as

bona fide, noting that the enumerated requirement is not supported by

the legislative history of the Dodd-Frank Act, conflicts with

longstanding Commission practice and precedent, and may be overly

restrictive due to the limited set of specific enumerated hedges.\476\

Other commenters recommended that the Commission expand the list of

enumerated bona fide hedge positions, to encompass all transactions

that reduce risks in the conduct and management of a commercial

enterprise, such as anticipatory merchandising hedges and other general

examples.\477\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\476\ See, e.g., CL-CME-59718 at 47-53, and CL-BG Group-59656 at

9.

\477\ See, e.g., CL-FIA-59595 at 32, CL-FIA-60303 at 6, CL-API-

60939 at 3, CL-AGA-60943 at 4, CL-CMC-60950 at 6-9, CL-EEI-EPSA-

60925 at 13, and CL-FIA-60937 at 5 and 21.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: In response to comments, the Reproposal

retains, as proposed in 2016, a proposed definition that recognizes as

bona fide, in addition to enumerated positions, any position that has

been otherwise recognized as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position by either a designated contract market or a swap execution

facility, each in accordance with reproposed Sec. 150.9(a), or by the

Commission. These provisions for recognition of non-enumerated

positions are included in re-designated subparagraph (2)(iii)(C) of the

reproposed definition of a bona fide hedging position.

The Commission notes that it is not possible to list all positions

that would meet the general definition of a bona fide hedging position.

However, the Commission observes that the commenters' many general

examples, which they recommended be included in the list of enumerated

bona fide hedging positions, generally did not provide sufficient

context or facts and circumstances to permit the Commission to evaluate

whether recognition as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

would be warranted. Context would be supplied, for instance, by the

provision of the particular market participant's historical activities

in the physical marketing channel and such participant's estimate, in

good faith, of its reasonably expected activities to be taken in the

physical marketing channel.

In a clarifying change, the Commission notes that the Reproposal

has re-designated the provisions proposed in subparagraph (2)(i)(D), in

new subparagraph 2(iii), regarding the additional requirements for

recognition of a position in a physical commodity contract as a bona

fide hedging position. Concurrent with this re-designation, the

Commission notes the Reproposal re-organizes, also for clarity, the

application of the five-day rule to pass-through swaps and hedging

swaps in subparagraph (2)(iii)(B), as discussed above.\478\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\478\ However, as noted above, as reproposed, an exchange

listing a physical-delivery contract may recognize, on a case-by-

case basis, a pass-through swap offset, or the offset of a swap used

as a bona fide hedge, during the last five days of trading in a spot

month, as a non-enumerated bona fide hedge pursuant to the process

in reproposed Sec. 150.9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. Enumerated Hedging Positions

a. Proposed Enumerated Hedges

In paragraph (3) of the proposed definition of a bona fide hedging

position, the Commission proposed four enumerated hedging positions:

(i) Hedges of inventory and cash commodity purchase contracts; (ii)

hedges of cash commodity sales contracts; (iii) hedges of unfilled

anticipated requirements; and (iv) hedges by agents.\479\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\479\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75713.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments received: Numerous commenters objected to the provision in

proposed subparagraph (3)(iii)(A) that would have limited recognition

of a hedge for unfilled anticipated requirements to one year for

agricultural commodities. For example, commenters noted a need to hedge

unfilled anticipated requirements for sugar for a time period longer

than twelve months.\480\ Similarly, other commenters noted there may be

a need to offset risks arising from investments in processing capacity

in agricultural commodities for a period in excess of twelve

months.\481\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\480\ See, e.g., Ex Parte No-869, notes of Feb. 25, 2015 ex

parte meeting with The Hershey Company, The J.M. Smucker Co., Louis

Dreyfus Commodities, Noble Americans Corp., et al.

\481\ See, e.g., CL-NGFA-60941 at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Other commenters recommended the Commission (1) remove the

restriction that unfilled anticipated requirement hedges by a utility

be ``required or encouraged to hedge by its public utility commission''

because most public utility commissions do not require or encourage

such hedging, (2) expand the reach beyond utilities, by including

[[Page 96752]]

entities designated as providers of last resort who serve the same role

as utilities, and (3) clarify the meaning of unfilled anticipated

requirements, consistent with CFTC Staff Letter No. 12-07.\482\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\482\ See, e.g., CL-Working Group-59693 at 27-28, CL-EEI-EPSA-

55953 at 19. CFTC Staff Letter No. 12-07 notes that unfilled

anticipated requirements may be recognized as the basis of a bona

fide hedging position or transaction under Commission Regulation

151.5(a)(2)(ii)(C) when a commercial enterprise has entered into

long-term, unfixed-price supply or requirements contracts as the

price risk of such ``unfilled'' anticipated requirements is not

offset by an unfixed price forward contract as the price risk

remains with the commercial, even though the commercial enterprise

has contractually assured a supply of the commodity. Instead, the

price risk continues until the forward contract's price is fixed;

once the price is fixed on the supply contract, the commercial

enterprise no longer has price risk and the derivative position, to

the extent the position is above an applicable speculative position

limit, must be liquidated in an orderly manner in accordance with

sound commercial practices.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Reproposal retains the enumerated

exemptions as proposed, with two amendments. First, the Commission

agrees with the commenters' request to remove the twelve month

constraint on hedging unfilled anticipated requirements for

agricultural commodities, as that provision appears no longer to be a

necessary prudential constraint. Second, the Commission agrees with the

commenters' request to remove the condition that a utility be

``required or encouraged to hedge by its public utility commission.''

Accordingly, the condition that a utility be ``required or encouraged

to hedge by its public utility commission'' is omitted from the

reproposed definition. The Commission notes that under the Reproposal,

a market participant, who is not a utility, may request that an

exchange consider recognizing a non-enumerated exemption, as it is not

clear who would be appropriately identified as a ``provider of last

resort'' and under what circumstance such person would reasonably

estimate its unfilled requirements.

Consistent with CFTC Staff Letter No. 12-07, the Commission affirms

its belief that unfilled anticipated requirements are those anticipated

inputs that are estimated in good faith and that have not been filled.

Under the Reproposal, an anticipated requirement may be filled, for

example, by fixed-price purchase commitments, holdings of commodity

inventory by the market participant, or unsold anticipated production

of the market participant. However, an unfixed-price purchase

commitment does not fill an anticipated requirement, in that the market

participant's price risk to the input has not been fixed.

b. Proposed Other Enumerated Hedges Subject to the Five-Day Rule

In paragraph (4) of the proposed definition of a bona fide hedging

position, the Commission proposed four other enumerated hedging

positions: (i) Hedges of unsold anticipated production; (ii) hedges of

offsetting unfixed-price cash commodity sales and purchases; (iii)

hedges of anticipated royalties; and (iv) hedges of services.\483\ The

Commission proposed to apply the five-day rule to all such positions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\483\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75714.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments received on the five-day rule: Numerous commenters

requested that the five-day rule be removed from the Commission's other

enumerated bona fide hedging positions, as that condition is not

included in CEA section 4a(c).

Commission Reproposal on the five-day rule: The Commission is

retaining the prudential condition of the five-day rule in the other

enumerated hedging positions. The Commission has a long history of

applying the five-day rule, in its legacy agricultural federal position

limits, to hedges of unsold anticipated production and hedges of

offsetting unfixed-price cash commodity sales and purchases. However,

as discussed in relation to reproposed Sec. 150.9, the Commission will

permit an exchange, in effect, to remove the five-day rule on a case-

by-case basis in physical-delivery contracts, as a non-enumerated bona

fide hedging position, by applying the exchange's experience and

expertise in protecting its own physical-delivery market.

Comments on other enumerated exemptions: As noted above, commenters

recommended removing the twelve-month limitation on agricultural

production, as unnecessarily short in comparison to the expected life

of investment in production facilities.\484\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\484\ See, e.g., CL-NGFA-60941 at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal on other enumerated exemptions: The

Reproposal removes the twelve-month limitations on unsold anticipated

agricultural production and hedges of services for agricultural

commodities. As noted above, that provision appears no longer to be a

necessary prudential constraint. Otherwise, the Reproposal retains the

other enumerated exemptions, as proposed.

c. Proposed Cross-Commodity Hedges

In paragraph (5) of the proposed definition of a bona fide hedging

position, the Commission proposed to recognize as bona fide cross-

commodity hedges.\485\ Cross-commodity hedging would be conditioned on:

(i) The fluctuations in value of the position in the commodity derivate

contract (or the commodity underlying the commodity derivative

contract) being substantially related to the fluctuations in value of

the actual or anticipated cash position or pass-through swap (the

substantially related test); and (ii) the five-day rule being applied

to positions in any physical-delivery commodity derivative contract.

The Commission proposed a non-exclusive safe harbor for cross-commodity

hedges that would have two factors: A qualitative factor; and a

quantitative factor.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\485\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75716.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments on cross-commodity hedges: Numerous commenters requested

the Commission withdraw the safe harbor quantitative ``test,'' and

noted such test is impracticable where there is no relevant cash market

price series for the commodity being hedged.\486\ Some commenters

requested the Commission retain a qualitative approach to assessing

whether the fluctuations in value of the position in the commodity

derivate contract are substantially related to the fluctuations in

value of the actual or anticipated cash position.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\486\ See, e.g., CL-ICE-60929 at 16, CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 6-7,

CL-NCFC-60930 at 2-3, CL-API-60939 at 2, CL-NGFA-60941 at 8, CL-EEI-

EPSA-60925 at 10, and CL-IECAssn-60949 at 5-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter urged the Commission to clarify that market

participants need not treat as enumerated cross-commodity hedges

strategies where the cash position being hedged is the same cash

commodity as the commodity underlying the futures contract even if the

cash commodity is not deliverable against the contract. The commenter

believes that this clarification would verify that non-deliverable

grades of certain commodities could be deemed as the same cash

commodity and thus not be deemed a cross-commodity hedge subject to the

five-day rule.\487\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\487\ CL-CME-60926 at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commenters requested the Commission not apply a five-day rule to

cross-commodity hedges or, alternatively, permit exchanges to determine

the appropriate facts and circumstances where a market participant may

be permitted to hold such positions into the spot month,

[[Page 96753]]

noting that a cross-commodity hedge in a physical-delivery contract may

be the best hedge of its commercial exposure.\488\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\488\ See, e.g., CL-FIA-60937 at 22, CL-CCI-60935 at 8-9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Reproposal retains the cross-commodity

hedge provision in paragraph (5) of the definition of a bona fide

hedging position as proposed. However, for the reasons requested by

commenters and because of confusion regarding application of a safe

harbor, the Reproposal does not include the safe harbor quantitative

test. If questions arise regarding the bona fides of a particular

cross-commodity hedge, it would, as reproposed, be reviewed based on

facts and circumstances, including a market participant's qualitative

review of a particular cross-commodity hedge.

The Reproposal retains the five-day rule, because a market

participant who is hedging the price risk of a non-deliverable cash

commodity has no need to make or take delivery on a physical-delivery

contract. However, the Commission notes that an exchange may consider,

on a case-by-case basis in physical-delivery contracts, whether to

recognize such cross-commodity positions as non-enumerated bona fide

hedges during the shorter of the last five days of trading or the time

period for the spot month, by applying the exchange's experience and

expertise in protecting its own physical-delivery market, under the

process of Sec. 150.9.

4. Commodity Trade Options Deemed Cash Equivalents

Commission proposal: The Commission requested comment as to whether

the Commission should use its exemptive authority under CEA section

4a(a)(7) to provide that the offeree of a commodity option would be

presumed to be a pass-through swap counterparty for purposes of the

offeror of the trade option qualifying for the pass-through swap offset

exemption.\489\ Alternatively, the Commission, noting that forward

contracts may serve as the basis of a bona fide hedging position

exemption, proposed that it may similarly include trade options as one

of the enumerated bona fide hedging exemptions. The Commission noted,

for example, such an exemption could be similar to the enumerated

exemption for the offset of the risk of a fixed-price forward contract

with a short futures position.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\489\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75711.

The Commission also requested comment on whether it would be

appropriate to exclude commodity trade options from the definition

of referenced contract. As discussed above, the Commission has

determined to exclude trade options from the definition of

referenced contract. Previous to this reproposed rule, the

Commission observed that federal position limits should not apply to

trade options. 81 FR 14966 at 14971 (Mar. 21, 2016).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments on trade option exemptions: Commenters requested that the

Commission clarify that hedges of commodity trade options be recognized

as bona fide hedges, as would be available for other cash

positions.\490\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\490\ See, e.g., CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 15.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission agrees with the commenters

and has determined to address the request that commodity trade options

should be recognized as the basis for a bona fide hedging position, as

would be available for other cash positions. The reproposed definition

of a bona fide hedging position adds new paragraph (6), specifying that

a commodity trade option meeting the requirements of Sec. 32.3 may be

deemed a cash commodity purchase or sales contract, as the case may be,

provided that such option is adjusted on a futures-equivalent basis.

The reproposed definition also provides non-exclusive guidance on

making futures-equivalent adjustments to a commodity trade option. For

example, the guidance provides that the holder of a trade option, who

has the right, but not the obligation, to call the commodity at a fixed

price, may deem that trade option, converted on a futures-equivalent

basis, to be a position in a cash commodity purchase contract, for

purposes of showing that the offset of such cash commodity purchase

contract is a bona fide hedging position.

Because the price risk of an option, including a trade option with

a fixed strike price, should be measured on a futures-equivalent

basis,\491\ the Commission has determined that under the reproposed

definition, a trade option should be deemed equivalent to a cash

commodity purchase or sales contract only if adjusted on a futures-

equivalent basis. The Commission notes that it may not be possible to

compute a futures-equivalent basis for a trade option that does not

have a fixed strike price. Thus, under the reproposed definition, a

market participant may not use a trade option as a basis for a bona

fide hedging position until a fixed strike price reasonably may be

determined.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\491\ See the discussion of the definition of futures-equivalent

in reproposed Sec. 150.1, above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

5. App. C to Part 150--Examples of Bona Fide Hedging Positions for

Physical Commodities

Commission proposal: The Commission proposed a non-exhaustive list

of examples meeting the requirements of the proposed definition of a

bona fide hedging position, noting that market participants could see

whether their practices fall within the list.\492\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\492\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75739,

75828.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments on examples: Comments regarding the processing hedge

example number 5 of proposed Appendix C to part 150 are discussed

above. Another commenter requested the Commission affirm that

aggregation is required pursuant to an express or implied agreement

when that agreement is to trade referenced contracts, and that

aggregation is not triggered by the condition in example number 7 of

proposed Appendix C to part 150, where a Sovereign grants an option to

a farmer at no cost, conditioned on the farmer entering into a fixed-

price forward sale.\493\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\493\ CL-FIA-59595 at 35, CL-FIA-59566 at 3-7, citing December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75837.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission agrees with the commenter

that aggregation is required pursuant to an express or implied

agreement when that agreement is to trade referenced contracts.

Proposed example number 7 was focused on recognizing the legitimate

public policy objectives of a sovereign furthering the development of a

cash spot and forward market in agricultural commodities. To avoid

confusion regarding the aggregation policy under rule 150.4, in the

Reproposal, the Commission has revised example number 7, and has

provided an interpretation that a farmer's synthetic position of a long

put option may be deemed a pass-through swap, for purposes of a

sovereign who has granted a cash-settled call option at no cost to such

farmer in furtherance of a public policy objective to induce such

farmer to sell production in the cash market. The Commission notes the

combination of a farmer's forward sale agreement and a granted call

option is approximately equivalent to a purchased put option. A farmer

anticipating production or holding inventory may use such a long

position in a put option as a bona fide hedging position.

The Reproposal also includes a number of conforming amendments and

corrections of typographical errors. Specifically, it conforms example

number 4 regarding a utility to the

[[Page 96754]]

changes to paragraph (3)(iii)(B) of the bona fide hedging position

definition, as discussed above. The references in the examples to a 12-

month restriction on hedges of agricultural commodities have also been

removed because the Reproposal eliminates those proposed restrictions

from the reproposed enumerated bona fide hedging positions, as

discussed above. In addition, based on discussions with cotton

merchants, example number 6, regarding agent hedging, has been amended

from a generic example to a specific illustration of the hedge of

cotton equities purchased by a cotton merchant from a producer, under

the USDA loan program. Finally, the Reproposal corrects typographical

errors in example number 12, regarding the hedge of copper inventory

and the cross-hedge of copper wire inventory, to correctly reflect the

25,000 pound unit of trading in the Copper core referenced futures

contract, and deletes the unnecessary reference to the price

relationship between the nearby and deferred Copper futures contracts.

B. Sec. 150.2--Position Limits

1. Setting Levels of Spot Month Limits

In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed to establish speculative position limits on 28 core referenced

futures contracts in physical commodities.\494\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\494\ See generally December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78

FR at 75725. The 28 core referenced futures contracts for which

initial limit levels were proposed are: Chicago Board of Trade

(``CBOT'') Corn, Oats, Rough Rice, Soybeans, Soybean Meal, Soybean

Oil and Wheat; Chicago Mercantile Exchange Feeder Cattle, Lean Hog,

Live Cattle and Class III Milk; Commodity Exchange, Inc., Gold,

Silver and Copper; ICE Futures U.S. Cocoa, Coffee C, FCOJ-A, Cotton

No. 2, Sugar No. 11 and Sugar No. 16; Kansas City Board of Trade

Hard Winter Wheat (on September 6, 2013, CBOT and the Kansas City

Board of Trade (``KCBT'') requested that the Commission permit the

transfer to CBOT, effective December 9, of all contracts listed on

the KCBT, and all associated open interest); Minneapolis Grain

Exchange Hard Red Spring Wheat; and New York Mercantile Exchange

(``NYMEX'') Palladium, Platinum, Light Sweet Crude Oil, NY Harbor

ULSD, RBOB Gasoline and Henry Hub Natural Gas.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As stated in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission proposed to set the initial spot month position limit levels

for referenced contracts at the existing DCM-set levels for the core

referenced futures contracts because the Commission believed this

approach to be consistent with the regulatory objectives of the Dodd-

Frank Act amendments to the CEA and many market participants are

already used to those levels.\495\ The Commission also stated that it

was considering setting initial spot month limits based on estimated

deliverable supplies submitted by CME Group Inc. (``CME'') in

2013.\496\ The Commission suggested that it might use the exchange's

estimated deliverable supplies if it could verify that they are

reasonable.\497\ The Commission further stated that it was considering

another alternative of using, in the Commission's discretion, the

recommended level, if any, of the spot month limit as submitted by each

DCM listing a core referenced futures contract (if lower than 25

percent of estimated deliverable supply).\498\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\495\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75727.

Several commenters supported establishing the initial levels of spot

month speculative position limit levels at the levels then

established by DCMs and listed in Appendix D to part 150, December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75739-40 (generally stating

that the then current levels are high enough and raising them could

cause problems with contract performance. E.g., CL-WGC-59558 at 1-2;

CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 7; CL-AFBF-59730 at 3; CL-NGFA-59956 at 2;

CL-NGFA-60312 at 3; CL-NCBA-59624 at 3; CL-Bakers-59691 at 1.

Several commenters expressed the view that DCMs are best able to

determine appropriate spot month limits and the Commission should

defer to their expertise. E.g., CL-NCBA-59624 at 3; CL-Cactus-59660

at 3; CL-TCFA-59680 at 3; CL-NGFA-59610 at 2; CL-MGEX-59635 at 2;

CL-MGEX-59932 at 2; CL-MGEX-60380 at 1; CL-ICE-60311 at 1; CL-

Thornton-59729 at 1.

\496\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75727.

The CME July 1, 2013 deliverable supply estimates are available on

the Commission's Web site at http://www.cftc.gov/idc/groups/public/@swaps/documents/file/cmegroupdeliverable070113.pdf; see also

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75727, n. 406.

Several commenters supported using the alternative level of spot-

month position limits based on CME's deliverable supply estimates as

listed in Table 9 of the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

generally stating that the alternative estimates are more up to date

than the deliverable supply estimates underlying the spot month

speculative position limits currently established by the DCMs, and

therefore more appropriate for use in setting federal limits. E.g.,

CL-FIA-59595 at 3, 8; CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 9; CL-CMC-59634 at 14;

CL-Olam-59658 at 1, 3; CL-BG Group-59656 at 6; CL-COPE-59662 at 21;

CL-Calpine-59663 at 3; CL-NGSA-59673 at 37; CL-NGSA-59900 at 11; CL-

Working Group-59693 at 58-59; CL-CME-60406 at 2-3 and App. A; CL-

CME-60307 at 4; CL-CME-59718 at 3, 20-23; CL-Sempra-59926 at 3-4;

CL-BG Group-59937 at 2-3; CL-EPSA-59953 at 2-3; CL-ICE-59966 at 5-6;

CL-ICE-59962 at 5; CL-US Dairy-59597 at 4; CL-Rice Dairy-59601 at 1;

CL-NMPF-59652 at 4; CL-FCS-59675 at 5.

\497\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75727.

The U.S. Chamber of Commerce's Center for Capital Markets

Competitiveness commented that the CFTC must update estimates of

deliverable supply, rather than relying on existing exchange-set

spot month limit levels. CL-Chamber-59684 at 6-7.

\498\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75728.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. Verification of Estimated Deliverable Supply

The Commission received comment letters from CME, Intercontinental

Exchange (``ICE'') and Minneapolis Grain Exchange, Inc. (``MGEX'')

containing estimates of deliverable supply. CME submitted updated

estimates of deliverable supply for CBOT Corn (C), Oats (O), Rough Rice

(RR), Soybeans (S), Soybean Meal (SM), Soybean Oil (SO), Wheat (W), and

KC HRW Wheat (KW); COMEX Gold (GC), Silver (SI), Platinum (PL),

Palladium (PA), and Copper (HG); NYMEX Natural Gas (NG), Light Sweet

Crude Oil (CL), NY Harbor ULSD (HO), and RBOB Gasoline (RB).\499\ ICE

submitted estimates of deliverable supply for Cocoa (CC), Coffee C

(KC), Cotton No. 2 (CT), FCOJ-A (OJ), Sugar No. 11 (SB), and Sugar No.

16 (SF).\500\ MGEX submitted an estimate of deliverable supply for Hard

Red Spring Wheat (MWE).\501\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\499\ CL-CME-61007 at 5. See also CL-CME-61011; CL-CME-61012;

CL-CME-60785 (earlier submission of deliverable supply estimates);

CL-CME-60435 (earlier submission of deliverable supply estimates);

CL-CME-60406 (earlier submission of deliverable supply estimates).

The Commission did not receive an estimate for Live Cattle (LC).

\500\ CL-ICE-60786. ICE also submitted an estimate for Henry Hub

natural gas. CL-ICE-60684.

\501\ CL-MGEX-61038 at Exhibit A; see also CL-MGEX-60938 at 2

(earlier submission of deliverable supply estimate).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is verifying that the estimates for C, O, RR, S, SM,

SO, W, and KW submitted by CME are reasonable. The Commission is

verifying that the estimate for MWE submitted by MGEX is reasonable.

The Commission is verifying that the estimates for CC, KC, CT, OJ, SB,

and SF submitted by ICE are reasonable. The Commission is verifying

that the estimates for GC, SI, PL, PA, and HG submitted by CME are

reasonable. Finally, the Commission is verifying that the estimates for

NG, CL, HO, and RB submitted by CME are reasonable. In verifying that

all of these estimates of deliverable supply are reasonable, Commission

staff reviewed the exchange submissions and conducted its own research.

Commission staff reviewed the data submitted, confirmed that the data

submitted accurately reflected the source data, and considered whether

the data sources were authoritative. Commission staff considered

whether the assumptions made by the exchanges in the submissions were

acceptable, or whether alternative assumptions would lead to similar

results. In response to Commission staff questions about the exchange

submissions, the Commission received revised estimates from exchanges.

In some cases, Commission staff conducted trade source interviews.

Commission staff replicated the calculations included in the

submissions.

[[Page 96755]]

In verifying the exchange estimates of deliverable supply, the

Commission is not endorsing any particular methodology for estimating

deliverable supply beyond what is already set forth in Appendix C to

part 38 of the Commission's regulations.\502\ As circumstances change

over time, exchanges may need to adjust the methodology, assumptions

and allowances that they use to estimate deliverable supply to reflect

then current market conditions and other relevant factors. The

Commission anticipates that it will base initial spot-month position

limits on the current verified exchange estimates as and to the extent

described below, unless an exchange provides additional updates during

the Reproposal comment period that the Commission can verify as

reasonable.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\502\ 17 CFR part 38, Appendix C.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. Single-Month and All-Months-Combined Limits

Commission Proposal: In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

the Commission proposed to set the level of single-month and all-

months-combined limits (collectively, non-spot month limits) based on

total open interest for all referenced contracts in a commodity.\503\

The Commission also proposed to estimate average open interest based on

the largest annual average open interest computed for each of the past

two calendar years, using either month-end open contracts or open

contracts for each business day in the time period, as the Commission

finds in its discretion to be reliable.\504\ For setting the levels of

initial non-spot month limits, the Commission proposed to use open

interest for calendar years 2011 and 2012 in futures contracts, options

thereon, and in swaps that are significant price discovery contracts

that are traded on exempt commercial markets.\505\ The Commission

explained that it had reviewed preliminary data submitted to it under

part 20, but preliminarily decided not to use it for purposes of

setting the initial levels of single-month and all-months-combined

position limits because the data prior to January 2013 was less

reliable than data submitted later.\506\ The Commission noted that it

was considering using part 20 data, should it determine such data to be

reliable, in order to establish higher initial levels in a final

rule.\507\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\503\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

The Commission currently sets the single-month and all-months-

combined limits based on total open interest for a particular

commodity futures contract and options on that futures contract, on

a futures-equivalent basis.

\504\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75730.

\505\ Id.

\506\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75733.

Thus, the initial levels as proposed in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal represented the lower bounds for the initial levels

that the Commission would establish in final rules.

\507\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75734.

The Commission also stated that it was considering using data from

swap data repositories, as practicable. Id. The Commission has

determined that it is not yet practicable to use data from swap data

repositories.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the June 2016 Supplemental Proposal, the Commission noted that,

since the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission worked

with industry to improve the quality of swap position data reported to

the Commission under part 20.\508\ The Commission also noted that, in

light of the improved quality of such swap position data reporting, the

Commission intended to rely on part 20 swap position data, given

adjustments for obvious errors (e.g., data reported based on a unit of

measure, such as an ounce, rather than a futures-equivalent number of

contracts), to establish initial levels of federal non-spot month

limits on futures and swaps in a final rule.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\508\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38459.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: Commenters requested that the Commission delay

the imposition of hard non-spot month limits until it has collected and

evaluated complete open interest data.\509\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\509\ E.g., CL-FIA-59595 at 3, 14; CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 10-11;

CL-MFA-60385 at 4-7; CL-MFA-59606 at 22-23; CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at

28-29; CL-CMC-59634 at 13; CL-Olam-59658 at 3; CL-COPE-59662 at 22;

CL-Calpine-59663 at 4; CL-CCMC-59684 at 4-5; CL-NFP-59690 at 20; CL-

Just Energy-59692 at 4; CL-Working Group-59693 at 62.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined that certain

part 20 large trader position data, after processing and editing by

Commission staff as described below,\510\ is reliable. The Commission

has determined to repropose the initial non-spot month position limit

levels based on the combination of such adjusted part 20 swaps data and

data on open interest in physical commodity futures and options from

the relevant exchanges, as described below. The Commission is using two

12-month periods of data, covering a total of 24 months, rather than

two calendar years of data, as is practicable, in reproposing the

initial non-spot month position limit levels.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\510\ Where relevant and practicable, Commission staff consulted

and followed the Office of Management and Budget Standards and

Guidelines for Statistical Surveys, September 2006, available at

https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/omb/inforeg/statpolicy/standards_stat_surveys.pdf.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Data Editing

Commission staff analyzed and evaluated the quality of part 20 data

for the period from July 1, 2014 through June 30, 2015 (``Year 1''),

and the period from July 1, 2015 through June 30, 2016 (``Year

2'').\511\ The Commission used open contracts as reported for each

business day in the time periods, rather than month-end open contracts,

primarily because it lessens the impact of missing data. Averaging

generally also smooths over errors in reporting when there is both

under- and over-reporting, both of which the Commission observed in the

part 20 data. By calculating a daily average for each month for each

reporting entity,\512\ one calculates a reporting entity's open

contracts on a ``representative day'' for each month. The Commission

then summed the open contracts for each reporting entity on this

representative day, to determine the average open interest for a

particular month.\513\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\511\ There is no part 20 swaps data for Sugar No. 16 (SF).

\512\ A reporting entity is a clearing member or a swap dealer

required to report large trader position data for physical commodity

swaps, as defined in 17 CFR 20.1.

\513\ Because there may be missing data, using open contracts

for each business day in the time period that a reporting entity

submits a report may overestimate open interest, compared to taking

a straight average of the open contracts over all business days in

the time period. However, the Commission believes it is reasonable

to assume that the open position in swaps for a reporting entity

failing to report for a particular business day is more accurately

reflected by that reporting entity's average reported open swaps for

the month, rather than zero. Hence, in choosing this approach, the

Commission chooses to repropose higher non-spot month limit levels.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

First, for each of Year 1 and Year 2, Commission staff identified

all reported positions in swaps that do not satisfy the definition of

referenced contract as proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal \514\ and removed those positions from the data set. For

example, swaps settled using the price of the LME Gold PM Fix contract

do not meet the definition of referenced contract for the gold core

referenced futures contract (GC) but positions reported based on these

types of swaps represented 14% of records submitted

[[Page 96756]]

under part 20 by reporting entities for gold swaps. The percentage of

average daily open interest excluded from the adjusted part 20 swaps

data resulting from this deletion are set forth in Table 1 below. Other

adjustments to the data are described below. Because not all

commodities required exclusion of non-referenced contracts, the

Commission reports only the 11 commodities that required this type of

exclusion.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\514\ This adjustment may have removed fewer than all of the

reported positions in swaps that do not satisfy the definition of

referenced contract as adopted, and therefore may have resulted in a

higher level of open interest (which would result in a higher limit

level). For instance, swaps reported under part 20 include trade

options, and the Commission is reproposing an amended definition of

``referenced contract'' to expressly exclude trade options. See the

discussion of the defined term ``referenced contract'' under Sec.

150.1, above. Because part 20 does not require trade options to be

identified, the Commission could not exclude records of trade

options from open interest or position size.

Table III-B-1--Percent of Adjusted Average Daily Open Interest Excluded

as Not Meeting the Definition of Referenced Contract

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Year 1 percent Year 2 percent

of excluded of excluded

Core referenced futures contract adjusted open adjusted open

interest (%) interest (%)

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Cotton No. 2 (CT)....................... 0.22 0.00

Sugar No. 11 (SB)....................... 0.05 0.00

Gold (GC)............................... 42.59 0.00

Silver (SI)............................. 48.10 0.00

Platinum (PL)........................... 9.12 5.36

Palladium (PA).......................... 56.87 6.87

Copper (HG)............................. 37.58 0.25

Natural Gas (NG)........................ 12.49 12.52

Light Sweet Crude (CL).................. 3.60 0.83

New York Harbor ULSD (HO)............... 0.96 1.74

RBOB Gasoline (RB)...................... 1.34 1.30

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Second, Commission staff checked and edited the remaining data to

mitigate certain types of errors. Commission staff identified three

general types of reporting errors and made edits to adjust the data

for:

(i) Positions that were clearly reported in units of a commodity

when they should have been reported in the number of gross futures-

equivalent contracts. For example, a position in gold (GC) with a

futures contract unit of trading of 100 ounces might be reported as

480,000 contracts, when other available information, reasonable

assumptions, consultation with reporting entities and/or Commission

expertise indicate that the position should have been reported as 4,800

contracts (that is, 480,000 ounces divided by 100 ounces per contract).

Commission staff corrected such reported swaps position data and

included the corrected data in the data set.

(ii) Positions that are not obviously reported in units of a

commodity but appear to be off by one or more decimal places (e.g., a

position is overstated, but not by a multiple of the contract's unit of

trading). For example, a position in COMEX gold is reported as 100,000

and the notional value might be reported as $13,000,000, when the price

of gold is $1300 and the COMEX gold contract is for 100 ounces,

indicating that the position should have been reported as 100 futures-

equivalent contracts. Staff corrected such reported swaps position data

and included the corrected data in the data set.

(iii) Positions reported multiple times per day or otherwise

extremely different from surrounding days' reported open interest. In

some cases, reporting entities submitted the same report using

different reporting identifiers, for the same day. In other cases, a

position would inexplicably spike for one day, to a multiple of other

days' reported open interest. When Commission staff checked with the

reporting entity, the reporting entity confirmed that the reports were,

indeed, erroneous. Commission staff did not include such incorrectly

reported duplicative swaps position data in its analysis. In other

cases, positions that were clearly reported incorrectly, but for which

Commission staff could discern neither a reason nor a reasonable

adjustment, were not included. For example, Commission staff deleted

all swap position data reports submitted by one swap dealer from its

analysis because the reports were inexplicably anomalous in light of

other available information, reasonable assumptions and Commission

expertise. As another example, one reporting entity reported extremely

large values for only certain types of positions. After speaking with

the reporting entity, Commission staff determined that there was no

systematic adjustment to be made, but that the actual positions were,

in fact, small. Hence, Commission staff did not include such reported

swaps position data in its analysis.

The number of principal records edited, resulting from the edits

relating to the three types of edits to erroneous position reports

noted above, is set forth in Table 2 below. A principal record is a

report of a swaps open position where the reporting entity is a

principal to the swap, as opposed to a counterparty record.

Table III-B-2--Percentage of Principal Records Adjusted by Edit Type and Underlying Commodity, Referenced

Contracts Only

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Number of Number of

records records

Edit type adjusted year adjusted year

1 (%) 2 (%)

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Corn (C).................................... (i)............................... 0.00 0.0001

(iii)............................. 0.00 0.66

Oats (O).................................... (iii)............................. 0.00 0.20

Rough Rice (RR)............................. (iii)............................. 0.38 0.00

[[Page 96757]]

Soybeans (S)................................ (i)............................... 0.00 0.03

(iii)............................. 2.38 1.46

Soybean Meal (SM)........................... (iii)............................. 0.00 0.41

Soybean Oil (SO)............................ (iii)............................. 9.15 4.93

Wheat (W)................................... (i)............................... 0.00 0.01

(iii)............................. 1.77 0.71

Wheat (MWE)................................. (iii)............................. 0.043 0.002

Wheat (KW).................................. (iii)............................. 1.34 0.68

Cocoa (CC).................................. (i)............................... 0.001 0.0005

(iii)............................. 1.79 0.25

Coffee C (KC)............................... (i)............................... 0.00 0.01

(iii)............................. 5.33 0.60

Cotton No. 2 (CT)........................... (iii)............................. 16.76 5.59

FCOJ-A (OJ)................................. (iii)............................. 13.30 17.43

Sugar No. 11 (SB)........................... (i)............................... 0.00 0.0009

(iii)............................. 1.21 0.54

Live Cattle (LC)............................ (i)............................... 0.002 0.00

(iii)............................. 45.65 15.50

Gold (GC)................................... (i)............................... 1.99 0.02

(ii).............................. 0.32 0.00

(iii)............................. 91.45 89.04

Silver (SI)................................. (i)............................... 3.01 0.19

(iii)............................. 93.08 89.52

Platinum (PL)............................... (i)............................... 2.75 0.01

(ii).............................. 0.33 0.01

(iii)............................. 23.51 21.11

Palladium (PA).............................. (i)............................... 0.62 0.00

(ii).............................. 0.30 0.00

(iii)............................. 32.97 22.29

Copper (HG)................................. (i)............................... 4.94 0.48

(iii)............................. 20.80 16.82

Natural Gas (NG)............................ (i)............................... 0.01 1.03

(iii)............................. 7.68 3.80

Light Sweet Crude (CL)...................... (i)............................... 0.001 0.003

(iii)............................. 9.53 8.43

New York Harbor ULSD (HO)................... (i)............................... 0.01 0.0006

(iii)............................. 29.58 4.33

RBOB Gasoline (RB).......................... (i)............................... 0.22 0.60

(iii)............................. 30.46 24.62

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some records also appeared to contain errors attributable to other

factors that Commission staff could detect and for which Commission

staff can correct. For example, there were instances where the

reporting entity misreported the ownership of the position, i.e.,

principal vs. counterparty. Commission staff corrected the misreported

ownership data and included the corrected data in the data set. Such

corrections are important to ensure that data is not double counted. In

Year 1, eight reporting entities required an adjustment to the reported

position ownership information. In Year 2, five reporting entities

required an adjustment to the reported position ownership information.

Third, in the part 20 large trader swap data, staff checked and

adjusted the average daily open interest for positions resulting from

inter-affiliate transactions and duplicative reporting of positions due

to transactions between reporting entities. For an example of

duplicative reporting by reporting entities (which is reporting in

terms of futures-equivalent contracts), assume Swap Dealer A and Swap

Dealer B have an open swap equivalent to 50 futures contracts, Swap

Dealer A also has a swap equivalent to 25 futures contracts with End

User X, and Swap Dealer B has a swap equivalent to 200 futures

contracts with End User Y. The total open swaps in this scenario is

equivalent to 275 futures contracts. However, Swap Dealer A will report

a gross position of 75 contracts and Swap Dealer B will report a gross

position of 250 contracts. Simply summing these two gross positions

would overestimate the open swaps as 325 contracts--50 contracts more

than there actually should be. For this reason, Commission staff used

the counterparty accounts of each reporting entity to flag counterparty

accounts of other reporting entities. Commission staff then used the

daily average of the gross positions for these accounts to reduce the

amount of average daily open swaps. Similarly, Commission staff flagged

the counterparty accounts for entities that are affiliates of each

reporting entity in order to adjust the amount of average daily open

swaps. These adjustments to the Year 1 data are reflected in Table 3

below, and the corresponding adjustments to the Year 2 data are

reflected in Table 4 below.

[[Page 96758]]

Table III-B-3--Average Daily Open Interest in Year 1 Adjusted for Duplicate and Affiliate Reporting by

Underlying Commodity

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Average adjusted

Average adjusted daily open

Average adjusted daily open interest reporting

Paired swaps for daily open interest reporting entity

interest entity duplication &

duplication affiliates

removed removed

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Corn (C)............................................ 655,492 522,566 359,715

Oats (O)............................................ 684 667 646

Rough Rice (RR)..................................... 916 640 362

Soybeans (S)........................................ 157,017 139,608 109,858

Soybean Meal (SM)................................... 125,444 99,795 71,887

Soybean Oil (SO).................................... 74,831 64,854 55,265

Wheat (W)........................................... 272,839 229,453 162,999

Wheat (MGE)......................................... 3,430 3,021 1,944

Wheat (KW).......................................... 14,918 14,213 9,436

Cocoa (CC).......................................... 15,207 13,792 11,257

Coffee C (KC)....................................... 31,540 28,539 24,164

Cotton No. 2 (CT)................................... 51,442 42,806 35,102

FCOG-A (OJ)......................................... 160 142 121

Sugar No. 11 (SB)................................... 279,355 256,887 211,994

Live Cattle (LC).................................... 46,361 36,999 23,626

Gold (GC)........................................... 79,778 64,363 47,727

Silver (SI)......................................... 19,373 14,678 9,867

Platinum (PL)....................................... 25,145 24,530 21,566

Palladium (PA)...................................... 2,044 1,939 1,929

Copper (HG)......................................... 31,143 28,718 22,859

Natural Gas (NG).................................... 4,100,419 3,603,368 2,866,128

Light Sweet Crude (CL).............................. 2,039,963 1,875,660 1,587,450

NY Harbor ULSD (HO)................................. 178,978 161,617 138,360

RBOB Gasoline (RB).................................. 103,586 100,021 81,822

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table III-B-4--Average Daily Open Interest in Year 2 Adjusted for Duplicate and Affiliate Reporting by

Underlying Commodity

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Average adjusted

Average adjusted daily open

Average adjusted daily open interest reporting

Paired swaps for daily open interest reporting entity

interest entity duplication &

duplication affiliates

removed removed

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Corn (C)............................................ 1,265,639 960,088 641,014

Oats (O)............................................ 1,029 858 480

Rough Rice (RR)..................................... 396 250 4

Soybeans (S)........................................ 453,419 351,279 235,679

Soybean Meal (SM)................................... 282,123 209,023 134,399

Soybean Oil (SO).................................... 282,207 198,744 125,106

Wheat (W)........................................... 437,711 334,136 222,420

Wheat (MWE)......................................... 15,167 9,511 3,079

Wheat (KW).......................................... 65,533 47,722 29,563

Cocoa (CC).......................................... 141,526 100,564 56,853

Coffee C (KC)....................................... 97,128 74,739 51,846

Cotton No. 2 (CT)................................... 137,295 99,496 60,477

FCOJ-A (OJ)......................................... 1,137 640 5

Sugar No. 11 (SB)................................... 717,967 558,423 382,816

Live Cattle (LC).................................... 102,131 77,783 52,330

Gold (GC)........................................... 62,804 50,054 36,029

Silver (SI)......................................... 9,306 6,207 3,510

Platinum (PL)....................................... 2,575 2,507 2,285

Palladium (PA)...................................... 889 857 823

Copper (HG)......................................... 82,479 65,187 47,365

Natural Gas (NG).................................... 4,239,581 3,828,739 3,331,141

Light Sweet Crude (CL).............................. 2,318,074 2,050,270 1,744,137

NY Harbor ULSD (HO)................................. 170,316 117,004 65,721

RBOB Gasoline (RB).................................. 102,094 66,560 30,477

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Staff made numerous significant adjustments to the part 20 data for

natural gas, due to numerous reports in units rather than the number of

gross futures-equivalent contracts and the large number of reports of

swaps that did not meet the definition of referenced contract.

[[Page 96759]]

The Commission continues to be concerned about the quality of data

submitted in large trader reports pursuant to part 20 of the

Commission's regulations. Commissioners and staff have expressed

concerns about data reporting publicly on a variety of occasions.\515\

Nevertheless, the Commission anticipates that over time part 20

submissions will become more reliable and intensive efforts by

Commission staff to process and edit raw data will become less

necessary. As stated in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, for

setting subsequent levels of non-spot month limits, the Commission

proposes to estimate average open interest in referenced contracts

using data reported pursuant to parts 16, 20, and/or 45.\516\ It is

crucial, therefore, that market participants make sure they submit

accurate data to the Commission, and resubmit data discovered to be

erroneous, because subsequent limit levels will be based on that data.

Reporting is at the heart of the Commission's market and financial

surveillance programs, which are critical to the Commission's mission

to protect market participants and promote market integrity. Failure to

meet reporting obligations to the Commission by submitting reports and

data that contain errors and omissions in violation of the part 20

regulations may subject reporting entities to enforcement actions and

remedial sanctions.\517\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\515\ See, e.g., CFTC Staff Advisory No. 15-66, available at

http://www.cftc.gov/idc/groups/public/@lrlettergeneral/documents/letter/15-66.pdf (reminding swap dealers and major swap participants

of their swap data reporting obligations); Remarks of Chairman

Timothy Massad before the ABA Derivatives and Futures Law Committee,

2016 Winter Meeting, Jan. 22, 2016, available at http://www.cftc.gov/PressRoom/SpeechesTestimony/opamassad-37 (improving

data reporting).

\516\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75734.

\517\ The CFTC announced its first case enforcing the Reporting

Rules in September 2015. See Order: Australia and New Zealand

Banking Group Ltd. (``ANZ''), available at http://www.cftc.gov/idc/groups/public/@lrenforcementactions/documents/legalpleading/enfaustraliaorder091715.pdf (the Order finds that during the period

from at least March 1, 2013 through November 30, 2014, ANZ filed

large trader reports that routinely contained errors).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

4. Setting Levels of Spot-Month Limits

In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed to set the initial spot month speculative position limit

levels for referenced contracts at the existing DCM-set levels for the

core referenced futures contracts.\518\ As an alternative, the

Commission stated that it was considering using 25 percent of an

exchange's estimate of deliverable supply if the Commission verified

the estimate as reasonable.\519\ As a further alternative, the

Commission stated that it was considering setting initial spot month

position limit levels at a recommended level, if any, submitted by a

DCM (if lower than 25 percent of estimated deliverable supply).\520\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\518\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75727.

One commenter urged the Commission to retain the legacy speculative

limits for enumerated agricultural products. The ``enumerated''

agricultural products refer to the list of commodities contained in

the definition of ``commodity'' in CEA section 1a; 7 U.S.C. 1a. This

list of agricultural contracts includes nine currently traded

contracts: Corn (and Mini-Corn), Oats, Soybeans (and Mini-Soybeans),

Wheat (and Mini-wheat), Soybean Oil, Soybean Meal, Hard Red Spring

Wheat, Hard Winter Wheat, and Cotton No. 2. See 17 CFR 150.2. The

position limits on these agricultural contracts are referred to as

``legacy'' limits because these contracts on agricultural

commodities have been subject to federal positions limits for

decades. This commenter stated, ``There is no appreciable support

within our industry or, as far as we know, from the relevant

exchanges to move beyond current levels . . . . Changing current

limits, as proposed in the rule, will have a negative impact on

futures-cash market convergence and will compromise contract

performance.'' CL-AFBF-59730 at 3. Contra CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 32

(setting initial spot-month limits at the existing exchange-set

levels would be arbitrary because the exchange-set levels have not

been calibrated to apply as ``a ceiling on the spot-month positions

that a trader can hold across all exchanges for futures, options and

swaps''); CL-ICE-59966 at 6 (``the Proposed Rule . . . effectively

halves the present position limit in the spot month by aggregating

across trading venues and uncleared OTC swaps''). See also CL-ISDA/

SIFMA-59611 at 3 (the spot month limit methodology is ``both

arbitrary and unjustified'').

\519\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75727.

The Commission also stated that if the Commission could not verify

an exchange's estimate of deliverable supply for any commodity as

reasonable, the Commission might adopt the existing DCM-set level or

a higher level based on the Commission's own estimate, but not

greater than would result from the exchange's estimated deliverable

supply for a commodity.

One commenter was unconvinced that estimated deliverable supply

is ``the appropriate metric for determining spot month position

limits'' and opined that the ``real test'' should be whether limits

``allow convergence of cash and futures so that futures markets can

still perform their price discovery and risk management functions.''

CL-NGFA-60941 at 2. Another commenter stated, ``While 25% may be a

reasonable threshold, it is based on historical practice rather than

contemporary analysis, and it should only be used as a guideline,

rather than formally adopted as a hard rule. Deliverable supply is

subject to numerous environmental and economic factors, and is

inherently not susceptible to formulaic calculation on a yearly

basis.'' CL-MGEX-60301 at 1. Another commenter expressed the view

that the 25 percent formula is not ``appropriately calibrated to

achieve the statutory objective'' set forth in section

4a(a)(3)(B)(i) of the CEA, 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(3)(B)(i). CL-CME-60926 at

3. Another commenter opined that because the Commission ``has not

established a relationship between `estimated deliverable supply'

and spot-month potential for manipulation or excessive

speculation,'' the 25 percent formula is arbitrary. CL-ISDA/SIFMA-

59611 at 31.

Several commenters opined that 25 percent of deliverable supply

is too high. E.g., CL-AFR-59685 at 2; CL-Tri-State Coalition for

Responsible Investment-59682 at 1; CL-CMOC-59720 at 3; CL-WEED-59628

(``Only a lower limit would ensure market stability and prevent

market manipulation.''); CL-Public Citizen-60313 at 1 (``There is no

good reason for a single firm to take 25% of a market.''); CL-IECA-

59964 at 3 (25 percent of deliverable supply ``is a lot of market

power in the hands of speculators''). One commenter stated that

``position limits should be set low enough to restore a commercial

hedger majority in open interest in each core referenced contract,''

CL-IATP-60323 at 5 (suggesting in a later submission that position

limits at 5-10 percent of estimated deliverable supply in each

covered contract applied on an aggregated basis might ``enable

commercial hedgers to regain for all covered contracts their pre-

2000 average share of 70 percent of agricultural contracts''). CL-

IATP-60394 at 2. One commenter supported expanding position limits

``to ensure rough or approximate convergence of futures and

underlying cash at expiration.'' CL-Thornton-59702 at 1.

Several commenters supported setting limits based on updated

estimates of deliverable supply which reflect current market

conditions. E.g., CL-ICE-59966 at 5; CL-FIA-59595 at 8; CL-EEI-EPSA-

59602 at 9; CL-MFA-59606 at 5; CL-CMC-59634 at 14; CL-Olam-59658 at

3; CL-CCMC-59684 at 6-7.

\520\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75728.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In determining the levels at which to repropose the initial

speculative position limits, the Commission considered, without

limitation, the recommendations of the exchanges as well as data to

which the exchanges do not have access. In considering these and other

factors, the Commission became very concerned about the effect of

alternative limit levels on traders in the cash-settled referenced

contracts. A DCM has reasonable discretion in establishing the manner

in which it complies with core principle 5 regarding position

limits.\521\ As the Commission observed in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, ``there may be a range of spot month limits, including

limits set below 25 percent of deliverable supply, which may serve as

practicable to maximize . . . [the] policy objectives [set forth in

section 4a(a)(3)(B) of the CEA].'' \522\ The Commission must also

consider the competitiveness of futures markets.\523\ Thus, the

Commission accepts the recommendations of the exchanges and has

determined to repropose federal limits below 25 percent of deliverable

supply, where setting a limit level at less than 25 percent of

deliverable supply does not appear to restrict unduly positions in the

cash-settled referenced contracts. The exchanges retain the ability to

adopt lower exchange-set limit levels than the initial

[[Page 96760]]

speculative position limit levels that the Commission reproposes today.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\521\ CEA section 5(d)(1)(B), 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(1)(B).

\522\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

\523\ CEA section 15(a)(2)(B), 7 U.S.C. 19(a)(2)(B).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. CME and MGEX Agricultural Contracts

As explained above, the Commission has verified that the estimates

of deliverable supply for each of the CBOT Corn (C), Oats (O), Rough

Rice (RR), Soybeans (S), Soybean Meal (SM), Soybean Oil (SO), Wheat (W)

core referenced futures contract, the Hard Red Winter Wheat (KW) core

referenced futures contract submitted by CME, and the Hard Red Spring

Wheat (MWE) core referenced futures contract submitted by MGEX are

reasonable.

Nevertheless, the Commission has determined to repropose the

initial speculative spot month position limit levels for C, O, RR, S,

SM, SO, W and KW at the recommended levels submitted by CME,\524\ all

of which are lower than 25 percent of estimated deliverable

supply.\525\ As is evident from the table set forth below, this also

means that the Commission is reproposing the initial speculative

position limit levels for these eight contracts as proposed in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal. These initial levels track the

existing DCM-set levels for the core referenced futures contracts;

\526\ therefore, as noted in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, many market participants are already used to these

levels.\527\ The Commission continues to believe this approach is

consistent with the regulatory objectives of the Dodd-Frank Act

amendments to the CEA.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\524\ CL-CME-61007 at 5.

\525\ The Commission noted in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal ``that DCMs historically have set or maintained exchange

spot month limits at levels below 25 percent of deliverable

supply.'' December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

\526\ See CL-CME-61007 (specifying lower exchange-set limit

levels for W and RR in certain circumstances).

\527\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75727.

Table III-B-5--CME Agricultural Contracts--Spot Month Limit Levels

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Previously 25% of estimated Reproposed

Contract proposed limit deliverable speculative limit

level \528\ supply \529\ level

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

C................................................... 600 900 600

O................................................... 600 900 600

RR.................................................. 600 2,300 600

S................................................... 600 1,200 600

SM.................................................. 720 2,000 720

SO.................................................. 540 3,400 540

W \530\............................................. 600 1,000 600

KW.................................................. 600 3,000 600

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission has also determined to repropose the initial

speculative spot month position limit level for MWE at 1,000 contracts,

which is the level requested by MGEX \531\ and just slightly lower than

25 percent of estimated deliverable supply.\532\ This is an increase

from the previously proposed level of 600 contracts and is greater than

the reproposed speculative spot month position limit levels for W and

KW.\533\ Upon deliberation, the Commission accepts the recommendation

of MGEX.\534\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\528\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75839

(Appendix D to Part 150--Initial Position Limit Levels).

\529\ Rounded up to the next 100 contracts.

\530\ The W core referenced futures contract refers to soft red

winter wheat, the KW core reference futures contract refers to hard

red winter wheat, and the MWE core reference futures contract refers

to hard red spring wheat; i.e., the contracts are for different

products.

\531\ CL-MGEX-61038 at 2; see also CL-MGEX-60938 at 2 (earlier

submission of deliverable supply estimate).

\532\ The difference is due to rounding. The MGEX estimate of

4,005 contract equivalents for MWE deliverable would have supported

a spot-month limit level of 1,100 contracts (rounded up to the next

100 contracts). The Commission noted in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal ``that DCMs historically have set or maintained

exchange spot month limits at levels below 25 percent of deliverable

supply.'' December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

\533\ Most commenters who supported establishing the same level

of speculative limits for each of the three wheat core referenced

futures contracts focused on parity in the non-spot months. However,

some commenters did support wheat party in the spot month. See,

e.g., CL-CMC-59634 at 15; CL-NCFC-59942 at 6.

\534\ The difference between an estimate of 4,000 contracts,

which would result in a limit level of 1,000, and 4,005 contracts,

which results in a limit level of 1,100 contracts, is small enough

that the Commission's prior statements regarding the 25% formula are

instructive. As stated in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, the 25 percent formula ``is consistent with the

longstanding acceptable practices for DCM core principle 5 which

provides that, for physical-delivery contracts, the spot-month limit

should not exceed 25 percent of the estimated deliverable supply.''

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729. The

Commission continues to believe, based on its experience and

expertise, that the 25 percent formula is an ``effective

prophylactic tool to reduce the threat of corners and squeezes, and

promote convergence without compromising market liquidity.''

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

Table III-B-6--CME and MGEX Agricultural Contracts--Spot Month

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Unique persons over spot month

limit

Core referenced futures Basis of spot- -------------------------------- Reportable

contract month level Limit level Physical persons spot

Cash settled delivery month only

contracts contracts

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Corn (C)...................... CME [dagger] 600 0 36 1,050

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 900 0 20

Oats (O)...................... CME [dagger] 600 0 0 33

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 900 0 0

Soybeans (S).................. CME [dagger] 600 0 22 929

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 1,200 0 14

Soybean Meal (SM)............. CME [dagger] 720 0 14 381

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 2,000 0 *

[[Page 96761]]

Soybean Oil (SO).............. CME [dagger] 540 0 21 397

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 3,400 0 0

Wheat (W)..................... CME [dagger] 600 0 11 444

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 1,000 0 6

Wheat (MWE)................... Parity w/CME [dagger] 600 0 * 102

recommendation.

25% DS.......... [dagger][dagge 0 *

r] 1,000

Wheat (KW).................... CME [dagger] 600 0 4 250

recommendation.

25% DS (MW)..... 1,000 0 *

25% DS (KW)..... 3,000 0 *

Rough Rice (RR)............... CME [dagger] 600 0 0 91

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 2,300 0 0

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Reproposed speculative position limit levels are shown in bold.

``25% DS'' means 25 percent of the deliverable supply as estimated by the exchange listing the core referenced

futures contract.

[dagger] Denotes existing limit level.

[dagger][dagger] Limit level requested by MGEX.

* Denotes fewer than 4 persons.

The Commission's impact analysis reveals no traders in cash settled

contracts in any of C, O, S, SM, SO, W, MWE, KW, or RR, and no traders

in physical delivery contracts for O and RR, above the initial

speculative limit levels for those contracts. The Commission found

varying numbers of traders in the C, S, SM, SO, W, MWE, KW physical

delivery contracts over the initial levels, but the numbers were very

small for MWE and KW.\535\ Because the levels that the Commission

reproposes today for C, O, S, SM, SO, W, KW, and RR maintain the status

quo for those contracts, the Commission assumes that some or possibly

all of such traders over the initial levels are hedgers. Hedgers may

have to file for an applicable exemption, but hedgers with bona fide

hedging positions should not have to reduce their positions as a result

of speculative position limits per se. Thus, the number of traders in

the C, S, SM, SO, W and KW physical delivery contracts who would need

to reduce speculative positions below the initial limit levels should

be lower than the numbers indicated by the impact analysis. The

Commission believes that setting initial speculative levels at 25

percent of deliverable supply would, based upon logic and the

Commission's impact analysis, affect fewer traders in the C, S, SM, SO,

W and KW physical delivery contracts. Consistent with its statement in

the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission believes

that accepting the recommendation of the DCM to set these lower levels

of initial spot month limits will serve the objectives of preventing

excessive speculation, manipulation, squeezes and corners,\536\ while

ensuring sufficient market liquidity for bona fide hedgers in the view

of the listing DCM and ensuring that the price discovery function of

the market is not disrupted.\537\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\535\ Four or fewer traders.

\536\ Contra CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 55 (proposed spot month

limits ``are almost certainly far smaller than necessary to prevent

corners or squeezes'').

\537\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Softs

As explained above, the Commission has verified that the estimates

of deliverable supply for each of the IFUS Cocoa (CC), Coffee ``C''

(KC), Cotton No. 2 (CT), FCOJ-A (OJ), Sugar No. 11 (SB), and Sugar No.

16 (SF) core referenced futures contracts submitted by ICE are

reasonable.

The Commission has determined to repropose the initial speculative

spot month position limit levels for the CC, KC, CT, OJ, SB, and SF

\538\ core referenced futures contracts at 25 percent of estimated

deliverable supply, based on the estimates of deliverable supply

submitted by ICE.\539\ As is evident from the table set forth below,

this also means that the Commission is reproposing initial speculative

position limit levels that are significantly higher than the levels for

these six contracts as previously proposed. As stated in the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, the 25 percent formula ``is consistent

with the longstanding acceptable practices for DCM core principle 5

which provides that, for physical-delivery contracts, the spot-month

limit should not exceed 25 percent of the estimated deliverable

supply.'' \540\ The Commission continues to believe, based on its

experience and expertise, that the 25 percent formula is an ``effective

prophylactic tool to reduce the threat of corners and squeezes, and

promote convergence without compromising market liquidity.'' \541\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\538\ One commenter supported considering ``tropicals (sugar/

coffee/cocoa) . . . separately from those agricultural crops

produced in the US domestic market.'' CL-Thornton-59702 at 1; see

also CL-Armajaro-59729 at 1.

\539\ CL-IFUS-60807.

\540\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

The Commission also noted ``that DCMs historically have set or

maintained exchange spot month limits at levels below 25 percent of

deliverable supply.'' December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR

at 75729.

\541\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

Table III-B-7--IFUS Soft Agricultural Contracts--Spot Month Limit Levels

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Previously 25% of estimated Reproposed

Contract proposed limit deliverable speculative limit

level \542\ supply \543\ level

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

CC.................................................. 1,000 5,500 5,500

[[Page 96762]]

KC.................................................. 500 2,400 2,400

CT.................................................. 300 1,600 1,600

OJ.................................................. 300 2,800 2,800

SB.................................................. 5,000 23,300 23,300

SF.................................................. 1,000 7,000 7,000

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\542\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75839-40

(Appendix D to Part 150--Initial Position Limit Levels).

\543\ Rounded up to the next 100 contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission did not receive any estimate of deliverable supply

for the CME Live Cattle (LC) core referenced futures contract from CME,

nor did CME recommend any change in the limit level for LC. In the

absence of any such update, the Commission is reproposing the initial

speculative position limit level of 450 contracts. Of 616 reportable

persons, the Commission's impact analysis did not reveal any unique

person trading cash settled or physical delivery spot month contracts

who would have held positions above this level for LC.

With respect to the IFUS CC, KC, CT, OJ, SB, and SF core referenced

futures contracts, the Commission's impact analysis did not reveal any

unique person trading cash settled spot month contracts who would have

held positions above the initial levels that the Commission adopts

today; as illustrated below, lower levels would mostly have affected

small numbers of traders in physical delivery contracts.

Table III-B-8--IFUS Soft Agricultural Contracts--Spot Month

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Unique persons over spot month

limit

Core referenced futures Basis of spot- -------------------------------- Reportable

contract month level Limit level Physical persons spot

Cash settled delivery month only

contracts contracts

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Cocoa (CC).................... 15% DS.......... 3,300 0 0 164

25% DS.......... [dagger][dagge 0 0

r] 5,500

Coffee ``C'' (KC)............. 15% DS.......... 1,440 0 * 336

25% DS.......... [dagger][dagge 0 *

r] 2,400

Cotton No. 2 (CT)............. 15% DS.......... 960 0 * 122

25% DS.......... [dagger][dagge 0 0

r] 1,600

FCOJ-A (OJ)................... 15% DS.......... 1,680 0 0 38

25% DS.......... [dagger][dagge 0 0

r] 2,800

Sugar No. 11 (SB)............. 15% DS.......... 13,980 * 10 443

25% DS.......... [dagger][dagge 0 *

r] 23,300

Sugar No. 16 (SF)............. 15% DS.......... 4,200 0 0 12

[dagger][dagger] [dagger][dagge 0 0

25% DS. r] 7,000

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Reproposed speculative position limit levels are shown in bold.

``15% DS'' means 15 percent of the deliverable supply as estimated by the exchange listing the core referenced

futures contract and is included to provide information regarding the distribution of reportable traders.

``25% DS'' means 25 percent of the deliverable supply as estimated by the exchange listing the core referenced

futures contract.

[dagger][dagger] Limit level requested by ICE.

* Denotes fewer than 4 persons.

c. Metals

As explained above, the Commission has verified that the estimates

of deliverable supply for each of the COMEX Gold (GC), COMEX Silver

(SI), NYMEX Platinum (PL), NYMEX Palladium (PA), and COMEX Copper (HG)

core referenced futures contracts submitted by CME are reasonable.

Nevertheless, the Commission has determined to repropose the

initial speculative spot month position limit levels for GC, SI, and HG

at the recommended levels submitted by CME,\544\ all of which are lower

than 25 percent of estimated deliverable supply.\545\ In the case of GC

and SI, this is a doubling of the current exchange-set limit

levels.\546\ In the case of HG, the initial level is the same as the

existing DCM-set level for the core referenced futures contract and

lower than the level previously proposed.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\544\ CL-CME-61007 at 5.

\545\ The Commission noted in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal ``that DCMs historically have set or maintained exchange

spot month limits at levels below 25 percent of deliverable

supply.'' December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

\546\ One commenter cautioned against raising limit levels for

GC to 25 percent of deliverable supply, and expressed concern that

higher federal limits would incentivize exchanges to raise their own

limits. CL-WGC-59558 at 2-4.

Table III-B-9--CME Metals Contracts--Spot Month Limit Levels

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Previously 25% of estimated Reproposed

Contract proposed limit deliverable speculative limit

level \547\ supply \548\ level

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

GC.................................................. 3,000 11,200 6,000

[[Page 96763]]

SI.................................................. 1,500 5,600 3,000

PL.................................................. 500 900 100

PA.................................................. 650 900 -500

HG.................................................. 1,200 1,100 1,000

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission has also determined to repropose the initial

speculative spot month position limit level for PL at 100 contracts and

PA at 500 contracts, which are the levels recommended by CME. In the

case of PL and PA, the reproposed level is the same as the existing

DCM-set level for the core referenced futures contract, and a decrease

from the previously proposed levels of 500 and 650 contracts,

respectively.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\547\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75840

(Appendix D to Part 150--Initial Position Limit Levels).

\548\ Rounded up to the next 100 contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission found varying numbers of traders in the GC, SI, PL,

PA, and HG physical delivery contracts over the initial levels, but the

numbers were very small except for PA.\549\ Because the levels that the

Commission reproposes today for PL, PA, and HG maintain the status quo

for those contracts, the Commission assumes that some or possibly all

of such traders over the reproposed levels are hedgers. The Commission

reiterates the discussion above regarding agricultural contracts:

hedgers may have to file for an applicable exemption, but hedgers with

bona fide hedging positions should not have to reduce their positions

as a result of speculative position limits per se. Thus, the number of

traders in the metals physical delivery contracts who would need to

reduce speculative positions below the reproposed limit levels should

be lower than the numbers indicated by the impact analysis. And, while

setting initial speculative levels at 25 percent of deliverable supply

would, based upon logic and the Commission's impact analysis, affect

fewer traders in the metals physical delivery contracts, consistent

with its statement in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission believes that setting these lower levels of initial spot

month limits will serve the objectives of preventing excessive

speculation, manipulation, squeezes and corners,\550\ while ensuring

sufficient market liquidity for bona fide hedgers in the view of the

listing DCM and ensuring that the price discovery function of the

market is not disrupted.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\549\ Fewer than four unique persons.

\550\ Contra CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 55 (proposed spot month

limits ``are almost certainly far smaller than necessary to prevent

corners or squeezes'').

Table III-B-10--CME Metal Contracts--Spot Month

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Unique persons over spot month

limit

Core referenced futures Basis of spot- -------------------------------- Reportable

contract month level Limit level Physical persons spot

Cash settled delivery month only

contracts contracts

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Gold (GC)..................... CME 6,000 * * 518

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 11,200 0 0

Silver (SI)................... CME 3,000 0 0 311

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 5,600 0 0

Platinum (PL)................. CME [dagger] 500 13 * 235

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 900 10 *

50% DS.......... 1,800 * 0

Palladium (PA)................ CME [dagger] 100 6 14 164

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 900 0 0

Copper (HG)................... CME [dagger] 1,000 0 * 493

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 1,100 0 *

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Reproposed speculative position limit levels are shown in bold.

``25% DS'' means 25 percent of the deliverable supply as estimated by the exchange listing the core referenced

futures contract.

``50% DS'' means 50 percent of the deliverable supply as estimated by the exchange listing the core referenced

futures contract and is included to provide information regarding the distribution of reportable traders.

[dagger] Denotes existing exchange-set limit level.

* Denotes fewer than 4 persons.

The Commission's impact analysis reveals no unique persons in the

SI and HG cash settled referenced contracts, and very few unique

persons in the cash settled GC referenced contract, whose positions

would have exceeded the initial limit levels for those contracts. Based

on the Commission's impact analysis, setting the initial federal spot

month limit levels for PL and PA at the lower levels recommended by CME

would impact a few traders in PL and PA cash settled contracts.

The Commission has carefully considered the numbers of unique

persons that would be impacted by each of the cash-settled and

physical-delivery spot month limits in the PL and PA referenced

contracts. The Commission notes those limits would appear to impact

more traders in the physical-delivery PA contract than in the cash-

settled PA contract, while fewer traders would be impacted in the

physical-delivery PL contract than in the cash-settled PL contract (in

any event, few traders would appear to be affected).\551\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\551\ In this regard, the Commission notes that CME did not have

access to the Commission's impact analysis when CME recommended

levels for its physical-delivery core referenced futures contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96764]]

The Commission also observed the distribution of those cash-settled

traders over time; as reflected in the open interest table discussed

below regarding setting non-spot month limits, it can be readily

observed that open interest in each of the cash-settled PL and PA

referenced contracts was markedly lower in the second 12-month period

(year 2) than in the prior 12-month period (year 1). Accordingly, the

Commission accepts the CME recommended levels in PL and PA referenced

contracts.

d. Energy

As explained above, the Commission has verified that the estimates

of deliverable supply for each of the NYMEX Natural Gas (NG), Light

Sweet Crude (CL), NY Harbor ULSD (HO), and RBOB Gasoline (RB) core

referenced futures contracts submitted by CME are reasonable.

The Commission has determined to repropose the initial speculative

spot month position limit levels for the NG, CL, HO, and RB core

referenced futures contracts at 25 percent of estimated deliverable

supply which, in the case of CL, HO, and RB is higher than the levels

recommended by CME.\552\ As is evident from the table set forth below,

this also means that the Commission is reproposing speculative position

limit levels that are significantly higher than the levels for these

four contracts as previously proposed. As stated in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal, the 25 percent formula ``is consistent with

the longstanding acceptable practices for DCM core principle 5 which

provides that, for physical-delivery contracts, the spot-month limit

should not exceed 25 percent of the estimated deliverable supply.''

\553\ The Commission continues to believe, based on its experience and

expertise, that the 25 percent formula is an ``effective prophylactic

tool to reduce the threat of corners and squeezes, and promote

convergence without compromising market liquidity.'' \554\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\552\ CL-CME-61007 at 5. One commenter opined that 25 percent of

deliverable supply would result in a limit level that is too high

for natural gas, and suggest 5 percent as an alternative that

``would provide ample liquidity and significantly reduce the

potential for excessive speculation.'' CL-Industrial Energy

Consumers of America-59964 at 3. Another commenter supported

increasing ``the spot-month position limit levels for Henry Hub

Natural Gas referenced contracts to be consistent with CME Group's

or ICE's estimates of deliverable supply and more generally the

significant new sources of natural gas.'' CL-NGSA-59674 at 3.

\553\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

\554\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

\555\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75840

(App. D to part 150--Initial Position Limit Levels).

\556\ Rounded up to the next 100 contracts.

Table III-B-11--CME Energy Contracts--Spot Month Limit Levels

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Previously 25% of estimated Reproposed

Contract proposed limit deliverable speculative limit

level \555\ supply \556\ level

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

NG.................................................. 1,000 2,000 2,000

CL.................................................. 3,000 10,400 10,400

HO.................................................. 1,000 2,900 2,900

RB.................................................. 1,000 6,800 6,800

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

The levels that CME recommended for NG, CL, HO, and RB are twice

the existing exchange-set spot month limit levels. Nevertheless, the

Commission is reproposing speculative spot month limit levels at 25

percent of deliverable supply for CL, HO, and RB because the Commission

believes that higher levels will lessen the impact on a number of

traders in both cash settled and physical delivery contracts. For NG,

the Commission is reproposing the physical delivery limit at 25% of

deliverable supply, as recommended by CME; \557\ the Commission is also

reproposing a conditional spot month limit exemption of 10,000 for

cash-settled contracts in natural gas only.\558\ This exemption would

to some degree maintain the status quo in natural gas because each of

the NYMEX and ICE cash-settled natural gas contracts, which settle to

the final settlement price of the physical delivery contract, include a

conditional spot month limit exemption of 5,000 contracts (for a total

of 10,000 contracts).\559\ However, neither the

[[Page 96765]]

NYMEX and ICE penultimate contracts, which settle to the daily

settlement price on the next to last trading day of the physical

delivery contract, nor OTC swaps, are currently subject to any spot

month position limit. In addition, the Commission's impact analysis

suggests that a conditional spot month limit exemption greater than 25%

of deliverable supply for cash settled contracts in natural gas would

potentially benefit many traders.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\557\ One commenter expressed concern about setting the spot

month limit for natural gas swaps at the same level as for the

physically settled futures contract, because some referenced

contracts cease to be economically equivalent ``during the limited

window at expiry.'' CL-BG Group-59937 at 3.

\558\ This exemption for up to 10,000 contracts would be five

times the spot month limit of 2,000 contracts, consistent with the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal. See December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75736-8. Under vacated Sec. 151.4, the

Commission would have applied a spot-month position limit for cash-

settled contracts in natural gas at a level of five times the level

of the limit for the physical delivery core referenced futures

contract. See Position Limits for Futures and Swaps, 76 FR 71626,

71687 (Nov. 18, 2011).

\559\ Some commenters supported retaining a conditional spot

month limit in natural gas. E.g., CL-ICE-60929 at 12 (``Any changes

to the current terms of the Conditional Limit would disrupt present

market practice for no apparent reason. Furthermore, changing the

limits for cash-settled contracts would be a significant departure

from current rules, which have wide support from the broader market

as evidenced by multiple public comments supporting no or higher

cash-settled limits.''). Contra CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 7 (``The

proposed higher limit for cash settled contracts is ill-advised. It

would not only raise the affected position limits to levels where

they would be effectively meaningless, it would also introduce

market distortions favoring certain contracts and certain exchanges

over others, and potentially disrupt important markets, including

the U.S. natural gas market that is key to U.S. manufacturing.'');

CL-Public Citizen-59648 at 5 (``Congress, in allowing an exemption

for bona fide hedgers but not pure speculators, could not possibly

have intended for the Commission to implement position limits that

allow market speculators to hold 125 percent of the estimated

deliverable supply. Once again, while this exception for cash-

settled contracts would avoid market manipulations such as corners

and squeezes (since cash-settled contracts give no direct control

over a commodity), it does not address the problem of undue

speculative influence on futures prices.''); CL-Better Markets-60401

at 17 (``There is no justification for treating cash and physically-

settled contracts differently in any month, and settlement

characteristics should not be a determinant of the ability to exceed

the limits in any month.''). One commenter urged the Commission ``to

eliminate the requirement that traders hold no physical-delivery

position in order to qualify for the conditional spot-month limit

exemption'' in order to maintain liquidity in the NYMEX natural gas

futures contract. CL-BG Group-59656 at 6-7. See also CL-NGSA-59674

at 38-39 (supporting the higher conditional spot month limit in

natural gas without restricting positions in the underlying physical

delivery contract); CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 10 (the Commission should

permit ``market participants to rely on higher speculative limits

for cash-settled contracts while still holding a position in the

physical-delivery contract''); CL-APGA-59722 at 8 (the Commission

should condition the spot month limit exemption for cash settled

natural gas contracts by precluding a trader from holding more than

one quarter of the deliverable supply in physical inventory). Cf.

CL-CME-59971 at 3 (eliminate the five times natural gas limit

because it ``encourages participants to depart from, or refrain from

establishing positions in, the primary physical delivery contract

market and instead opt for the cash-settled derivative contract

market, especially during the last three trading days when the five

times limit applies. By encouraging departure from the primary

contract market, the five times limit encourages a process of de-

liquefying the benchmark physically delivered futures market and

directly affects the determination of the final settlement price for

the NYMEX NG contract- the very same price that a position

representing five times the physical limit will settle against.'').

Table III-B-12--Energy Contracts--Spot Month

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Unique persons over spot month

limit

Core referenced futures Basis of spot- -------------------------------- Reportable

contract month level Limit level Physical persons spot

Cash settled delivery month only

contracts contracts

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Natural Gas (NG).............. CME 2,000 131 16 1,400

recommendation.

50% DS.......... 4,000 77 *

Conditional 10,000 20 0

Exemption.

Light Sweet Crude (CL)........ CME [dagger][dagge 19 8 1,733

recommendation. r] 6,000

25% DS.......... 10,400 16 *

50% DS.......... 20,800 * 0

NY Harbor ULSD (HO)........... CME 2,000 24 11 470

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 2,900 15 5

50% DS.......... 5,800 5 0

RBOB Gasoline (RB)............ CME 2,000 23 14 463

recommendation.

25% DS.......... 6,800 * 0

50% DS.......... 13,600 0 0

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Reproposed speculative position limit levels are shown in bold.

``25% DS'' means 25 percent of the deliverable supply as estimated by the exchange listing the core referenced

futures contract.

``50% DS'' means 50 percent of the deliverable supply as estimated by the exchange listing the core referenced

futures contract and is included to provide information regarding the distribution of reportable traders.

[dagger][dagger] CME recommended a step-down spot month limit of 6,000/5,000/4,000 contracts in the last three

days of trading.

* Denotes fewer than 4 persons.

5. Setting Levels of Single-Month and All-Months-Combined Limits

The Commission has determined to use the futures position limits

formula, 10 percent of the open interest for the first 25,000 contracts

and 2.5 percent of the open interest thereafter, to repropose the non-

spot month speculative position limits for referenced contracts,

subject to the details and qualifications set forth in this

Notice.\560\ The Commission continues to believe that ``the non-spot

month position limits would restrict the market power of a speculator

that could otherwise be used to cause unwarranted price movements.''

\561\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\560\ As noted in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

the Commission has used the 10, 2.5 percent formula in administering

the level of the legacy all-months position limits since 1999.

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729-30.

Several commenters did not support establishing non-spot month

limits. See, e.g., CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 27 (``There is no

justification whatsoever for non-spot-month limits.''); CL-EEI-EPSA-

59602 at 10 (``limits outside the spot month are not necessary'');

CL-AMG-59709 at 10 (the Commission should ``decline to adopt non-

spot-month position limits''); CL-CME-59718 at 39 (the Proposal's

non-spot-month position limit formula should be withdrawn''); CL-

CAM-60097 at 2 (``Non-spot month limits are neither necessary nor

appropriate.''); CL-BG Group-60383 at 2 (``Any final rule should be

limited to a federally mandated spot-month limit (not any/all month

limits).''). Some of these same commenters supported position

accountability in the non-spot months rather than limits. See, e.g.,

CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 10, CL-FIA-59595 at 3, CL-MFA-60385 at 5, CL-

ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 29, CL-Calpine-59663 at 3-4, CL-Working Group-

60396 at 10, CL-EDF-60398 at 4, CL-ICE-59966 at 8, CL-BG Group-60383

at 2, CL-CMC-59634 at 11. Some commenters also urged the Commission

to wait until it has reliable data before establishing non-spot

month limits. See, e.g., CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 11; CL-FIA-59595 at 3,

14; CL-MFA-60385 at 5; CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 29; CL-Olam-59658 at

1, 3. See also discussion of part 20 data adjustments under Sec.

150.2, below. Contra CL-O SEC-59972 (``corners and other supply

fluctuations can occur during non-spot months'').

A commenter who did not support adopting non-spot month limits

suggested a fall-back position of adopting ``any months limits'' but

not ``all months limits,'' and suggested an alternative 10, 5

percent formula in specified circumstances. CL-Working Group-59693

at 62. See also CL-CME-59718 at 44 (supporting a 10, 5 percent

formula). One commenter supported abolishing single month limits

``in favor of an ``all months'' or gross position that would

effectively allow the player to adapt their position to the

realities of an agricultural crop that doesn't flow in equal monthly

chunks.'' CL-Thornton-59702 at 1. Another commenter stated that

``[p]osition limits should be a function of the liquidity of the

market,'' CL-MFA-59606 at 21, and asserted that applying the 10, 2.5

percent formula will result in ``a self-reinforcing cycle of lower

open interest and lower position limits in successive years.'' CL-

MFA-59696 at 22. Another commenter supported ``tying the overall

non-spot month position limits to an acceptable aggregate (market-

wide) level of speculation, and tying individual trader limits to

that aggregate level.'' CL-Public Citizen-59648 at 4. Another

commenter expressed the belief that the 10, 2.5 percent formula

would result in non-spot month limits that ``are much too high to

adequately regulate excessive speculation that might lead to price

fluctuations.'' CL-Tri-State-59682 at 1. To ``address the

cumulative, disruptive effect of traders who hold large, but not

dominant positions,'' one commenter suggested basing non-spot month

position limits on ``an acceptable total level of speculation that

approximates the historic ratio of hedging to investor/speculative

trading.'' CL-A4A-59714 at 4. See CL-Better Markets-60401 at 4

(``Historically, speculators in commodity futures have constituted

between 15%-30% of market activity, and within this range

speculators productively facilitated effective hedging without

meaningfully disrupting or independently shaping the market's

behavior.'').

\561\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75730.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. CME and MGEX Agricultural Contracts

The Commission is reproposing the non-spot month speculative

position limit levels for the Corn (C), Oats (O), Rough Rice (RR),

Soybeans (S), Soybean Meal (SM), Soybean Oil (SO), and Wheat (W) core

referenced futures contracts based on the 10, 2.5 percent open interest

formula.\562\ Based on the Commission's experience since 2011 with non-

spot month speculative position limit levels for the Hard Red Winter

Wheat (KW) and Hard Red Spring Wheat (MWE) core referenced futures

contracts, the Commission is reproposing the limit levels for those two

commodities at the current level of 12,000 contracts rather than

reducing them to the lower levels that would result from applying the

10, 2.5 percent formula.\563\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\562\ One commenter expressed concern ``that proposed all-

months-combined speculative position limits based on open interest

levels is not necessarily the appropriate methodology and could lead

to contract performance problems.'' This commenter urged ``that all-

months-combined limits be structured to `telescope' smoothly down to

legacy spot-month limits in order to ensure continued convergence.''

CL-NGFA-60312 at 4.

\563\ One commenter supported a higher limit for KW than

proposed to promote growth and to enable liquidity for Kansas City

hedgers who often use the Chicago market. CL-Citadel-59717 at 8.

Another commenter supported setting ``a non-spot month and combined

position limit of no less than 12,000 for all three wheat

contracts.'' CL-MGEX-60301 at 1. Contra CL-O SEC-59972 at 7-8

(commending ``the somewhat more restrictive limitations . . . on

wheat trading'').

\564\ The W core referenced futures contract refers to soft red

winter wheat, the KW core reference futures contract refers to hard

red winter wheat, and the MWE core reference futures contract refers

to hard red spring wheat; i.e., the contracts are for different

products.

[[Page 96766]]

Table III-B-13--CME and MGEX Agricultural Contracts--Non-Spot Month Limit Levels

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Previously Reproposed

Contract Current limit proposed speculative

level limit level limit level

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

C............................................................... 33,000 53,500 62,400

O............................................................... 2,000 1,600 5,000

RR.............................................................. 1,800 2,200 5,000

S............................................................... 15,000 26,900 31,900

SM.............................................................. 6,500 9,000 16,900

SO.............................................................. 8,000 11,900 16,700

W \564\......................................................... 12,000 16,200 32,800

KW.............................................................. 12,000 6,500 12,000

MWE............................................................. 12,000 3,300 12,000

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Maintaining the status quo for the non-spot month limit levels for

the KW and MWE core referenced futures contracts means there will be

partial wheat parity.\565\ The Commission has determined not to raise

the reproposed limit levels for KW and MWE to the limit level for W, as

32,800 contracts appears to be extraordinarily large in comparison to

open interest in the KW and MWE markets, and the limit levels for KW

and MWE are already larger than a limit level based on the 10, 2.5

percent formula. Even when relying on a single criterion, such as

percentage of open interest, the Commission has historically recognized

that there can ``result . . . a range of acceptable position limit

levels.'' \566\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\565\ Several commenters supported adopting equivalent non-spot

month position limits for the three existing wheat referenced

contracts traders. See, e.g., CL-FIA-59595 at 4, 15; CL-CMC-60391 at

8; CL-CMC-60950 at 11; CL-CME-59718 at 44; CL-AFBF-59730 at 4; CL-

MGEX-59932 at 2; CL-MGEX-60301 at 1; CL-MGEX-59610 at 2-3; CL-MGEX-

60936 at 2-3; CL-NCFC-59942 at 6; CL-NGFA-59956 at 3.

\566\ Revision of Speculative Position Limits, 57 FR 12770,

12766 (Apr. 13, 1992). See also Revision of Speculative Position

Limits and Associated Rules, 63 FR 38525, 38527 (July 17, 1998). Cf.

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729 (there may be

range of spot month limits that maximize policy objectives).

Table III-B-14--CME and MGEX Agricultural Contracts--Non-Spot Months

------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Open interest Unique persons above limit Reportable

---------------------------------------------------------------- Initial limit level persons in

Core-referenced futures contract level -------------------------------- market-- all

Year Futures Swaps Total All months Single month months

------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Corn (C)........................................................ 1 1,829,359 359,715 2,189,074 62,400 * * 2,606

2 1,779,977 641,014 2,420,991

Oats (O)........................................................ 1 10,097 646 10,743 5,000 0 0 173

2 11,223 480 11,703

Rough Rice (RR)................................................. 1 10,585 362 10,948 5,000 0 0 281

2 12,769 4 12,773

Soybeans (S).................................................... 1 973,037 109,858 1,082,895 31,900 6 4 2,503

2 962,636 235,679 1,198,315

Soybean Meal (SM)............................................... 1 422,611 71,887 494,498 16,900 5 4 978

2 463,549 134,399 597,948

Soybean Oil (SO)................................................ 1 421,114 55,265 476,379 16,700 5 4 1,034

2 464,373 125,106 589,478

Wheat (W)....................................................... 1 1,072,107 162,999 1,235,105 32,800 * * 1,867

2 1,010,342 222,420 1,232,762

Wheat (MWE)..................................................... 1 67,653 1,944 69,596 [dagger] 5,000 10 7 342

2 66,608 3,079 69,687 12,000 0 0

Wheat (KW)...................................................... 1 169,059 9,436 178,495 [dagger] 8,100 9 8 718

2 216,236 29,563 245,799 12,000 * *

------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Year 1 = July 1, 2014 to June 30, 2015

Year 2 = July 1, 2015 to June 30, 2016

Reproposed speculative position limit levels are shown in bold.

[dagger] Application of the 10, 2.5 percent formula would result in a level lower than the level adopted by the Commission in 2011.

* Denotes fewer than 4 persons.

b. Softs

The Commission is reproposing non-spot month speculative position

limit levels for the CC, KC, CT, OJ, SB, SF and LC \567\ core

referenced futures contracts based on the 10, 2.5 percent open interest

formula.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\567\ One commenter expressed concern that too high non-spot

month limit levels could lead to a repeat of convergence problems

experienced by certain contracts and that ``the imposition of all

months combined limits in continuously produced non-storable

commodities such as livestock . . . will reduce the liquidity needed

by hedgers in deferred months who often manage their risk using

strips comprised of multiple contract months.'' CL-AFBF-59730 at 3-

4. One commenter requested that the Commission withdraw its proposal

regarding non-spot month limits, citing, among other things, the

Commission's previous approval of exchange rules lifting all-months-

combined limits for live cattle contracts ``to ensure necessary

deferred month liquidity.'' CL-CME-59718 at 4. Another commenter

expressed concern that non-spot month limits would have a negative

impact on live cattle market liquidity. CL-CMC-59634 at 12-13. See

also CL-CME-59718 at 41.

[[Page 96767]]

Table III-B-15--Softs and Other Agricultural Contracts--Non-Spot Month

Limit Levels

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Previously

proposed Reproposed

Contract limit level speculative

\568\ limit level

------------------------------------------------------------------------

CC...................................... 7,100 10,200

KC...................................... 7,100 8,800

CT...................................... 8,800 9,400

OJ...................................... 2,900 5,000

SB...................................... 23,500 38,400

SF...................................... 1,200 7,000

LC...................................... 12,900 12,200

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Set forth below is a summary of the impact analysis for softs and

live cattle.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\568\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75839-40

(App. D to part 150--Initial Position Limit Levels).

Table III-B-16--Softs and Other Agricultural Contracts--Non-Spot Months

------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Open interest Unique persons above limit Reportable

---------------------------------------------------------------- Initial limit level persons in

Core-referenced futures contract level -------------------------------- market-- all

Year Futures Swaps Total All months Single month months

------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Cocoa (CC)...................................................... 1 240,984 11,257 252,240 10,200 12 7 682

2 273,134 56,853 329,987

Coffee C (KC)................................................... 1 211,051 24,164 235,215 8,800 6 * 1,175

2 223,885 51,846 275,731

Cotton No. 2 (CT)............................................... 1 238,580 35,102 273,682 9,400 13 8 1,000

2 239,321 60,477 299,798

FCOJ-A (OJ)..................................................... 1 16,883 121 17,004 5,000

* * 242

2 16,336 5 16,341

Sugar No. 11 (SB)............................................... 1 1,016,271 211,994 1,228,265 38,400 14 9 874

2 1,077,452 382,816 1,460,268

Sugar No. 16 (SF)............................................... 1 8,385 0 8,385 7,000 * 0 22

2 9,608 0 9,608

Live Cattle (LC)................................................ 1 387,896 23,626 411,522 12,200 9 * 1,436

2 350,147 52,330 402,478

------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Year 1 = July 1, 2014 to June 30, 2015. Year 2 = July 1, 2015 to June 30, 2016. Reproposed speculative position limit levels are shown in bold.

* Denotes fewer than 4 persons.

c. Metals

The Commission is reproposing non-spot month speculative position

limit levels for the GC, SI, PL, PA, and HG core referenced futures

contracts based on the 10, 2.5 percent open interest formula.\569\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\569\ One commenter was concerned that applying the 10, 2.5

percent formula to open interest for gold would result in a lower

non-spot month limit level than the spot month limit level, and

urged the Commission to ``apply a consistent methodology to both

spot and non-spot months.'' CL-WGC-59558 at 5.

[[Page 96768]]

Table III-B-17--CME Metals Contracts--Non-Spot Month Limit Levels

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Previously Reproposed

Contract proposed speculative

limit level limit level

------------------------------------------------------------------------

GC...................................... 21,500 19,500

SI...................................... 6,400 7,600

PL...................................... 5000 5,000

PA...................................... 5000 5,000

HG...................................... 5,600 7,800

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Set forth below is a summary of the impact analysis for

metals.\570\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\570\ One commenter expressed concern that imposing non-spot

position limits on copper would negatively affect liquidity as

evidenced by the number of unique persons affected. CL-CMC-59634 at

13, n. 26. Another commenter cited the number of unique traders with

all-months overages as shown in the open interest data for the GC,

SI and PL contracts in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal as

an indication that ``the impact of the Commission's non-spot-month

position limits is random and arbitrarily inflexible with no

relationship to preventing excessive speculation or manipulation.''

CL-CME-59718 at 41.

Table III-B-18--CME Metals Contracts--Non-Spot Months

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Open interest Unique persons above limit Reportable

Core-referenced futures --------------------------------------------------------- Initial limit level persons in

contract level -------------------------------- market--all

Year Futures Swaps Total All months Single month months

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Gold (GC)...................... 1 618,738 47,727 666,465 19,500 19 17 1,557

2 667,495 36,029 703,525

Silver (SI).................... 1 218,028 9,867 227,895 7,600 15 18 1,023

2 203,645 3,510 207,155

Platinum (PL).................. 1 70,151 21,566 91,717 5,000 26 26 842

2 70,713 2,285 72,997

Palladium (PA)................. 1 37,488 1,929 39,417 5,000 * * 580

2 28,276 823 29,099

Copper (HG).................... 1 170,784 22,859 193,643 7,800 19 12 1,457

2 186,525 47,365 233,890

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Year 1 = July 1, 2014 to June 30, 2015

Year 2 = July 1, 2015 to June 30, 2016

Reproposed speculative position limit levels are shown in bold.

* Denotes fewer than 4 persons.

d. Energy

The Commission is reproposing non-spot month speculative position

limit levels for the NG, CL, HO, and RB core referenced futures

contracts based on the 10, 2.5 percent open interest formula.\571\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\571\ One commenter suggested deriving non-spot month limit

levels for the CL, HO, and RB referenced contracts from the usage

ratios for U.S. crude oil and oil products rather than open interest

and expressed concern that ``unnecessarily low limits will hamper

legitimate hedging activity.'' CL-Citadel-59717 at 7-8. Another

commenter suggested setting limit levels based on customary position

size. CL-APGA-59722 at 6. This commenter also supported setting the

single month limit at two-thirds of the all months combined limit in

order to relieve market congestion as traders exit or roll out of

the next to expire month into the spot month. CL-APGA-59722 at 7.

[[Page 96769]]

Table III-B-19--CME Energy Contracts--Non-Spot Month Limit Levels

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Previously Reproposed

Contract proposed limit speculative

level limit level

------------------------------------------------------------------------

NG...................................... 149,600 200,900

CL...................................... 109,200 148,800

HO...................................... 16,100 21,300

RB...................................... 11,800 15,300

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Set forth below is a summary of the impact analysis for energy

contracts.

Table III-B-20--CME Energy Contracts--Non-Spot Months

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Open interest Unique persons above limit Reportable

Core-referenced futures --------------------------------------------------------- Initial limit level persons in

contract level -------------------------------- market--all

Year Futures Swaps Total All months Single month months

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Natural Gas (NG)............... 1 4,919,841 2,866,128 7,785,969 200,900 * 0 1,846

2 4,628,471 3,331,141 7,959,612

Light Sweet Crude (CL)......... 1 4,071,681 1,587,450 5,659,130 148,800 0 0 2,673

2 4,130,131 1,744,137 5,874,268

NY Harbor ULSD (HO)............ 1 638,040 138,360 776,400 21,300 6 * 760

2 587,796 65,721 653,518

RBOB Gasoline (RB)............. 1 448,598 81,822 530,420 15,300 8 7 837

2 505,849 30,477 536,327

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Year 1 = July 1, 2014 to June 30, 2015.

Year 2 = July 1, 2015 to June 30, 2016.

Reproposed speculative position limit levels are shown in bold.

* Denotes fewer than 4 persons.

6. Subsequent Levels of Limits

The Commission notes that many of the comments referenced above,

regarding setting initial position limits, are also discussed below,

regarding re-setting levels of limits.

a. General Procedure for Re-Setting Levels of Limits

Commission Proposal: The Commission proposed in Sec. 150.2(e)(2)

that it would fix subsequent levels of speculative position limits no

less frequently than every two calendar years, in accordance with the

procedures in Sec. 150.2(e)(3) for spot-month limits and Sec.

150.2(e)(3) for non-spot-month limits, discussed below.\572\ The

Commission proposed it would publish such subsequent levels on its Web

site.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\572\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75728.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: Regarding Sec. 150.2(e)(2), commenters

requested the Commission review the level of limits more frequently

than every two years to address changes that may occur within the

commodities markets.\573\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\573\ CL-Public Citizen-59648 at 5; CL-AFR-59711 at 2; CL-IECA-

59713 at 3; CL-Better Markets-60325 at 2-3; CL-Better Markets-60401

at 19-20; CL-CMOC-59720 at 3; CL-Cota-59706 at 2; CL-RF-60372 at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

this provision as previously proposed in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, and reiterates that it will fix subsequent levels no

less frequently than every two calendar years. The Commission is not

proposing to establish a procedural requirement to reset limit levels

more frequently than every two years, because as the frequency of reset

increases, the burdens on market participants to update compliance

systems and strategies, and on exchanges to submit deliverable supply

estimates and reset exchange limit levels, also increase. The

Commission believes that a two year timetable should reduce burdens on

market participants while still maintaining limits based on recent

market data. Should higher limit levels be desired, exchanges or market

participants may petition the Commission to change limit levels within

the two year period.

b. Re-setting Levels of Spot-Month Limits

Commission Proposal: The Commission proposed in Sec. 150.2(e)(3)

to reset each spot month limit at a level no greater than one-quarter

of the estimated spot-month deliverable supply, based on the estimate

of deliverable supply provided by the exchange listing the core

referenced futures contract. The Commission proposed that it could, in

its discretion, rely on its own estimate of deliverable supply. The

Commission further proposed that, alternatively, it could set spot-

month limits based on the recommended level of the exchange listing the

core referenced futures contract, if lower than 25 percent of estimated

deliverable supply.\574\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\574\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75728.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: Commenters generally recommended the Commission

enhance predictability and reduce uncertainty for market participants,

by either restricting how much adjustment would be made to the position

limit level, or having the discretion to not alter position limit

[[Page 96770]]

levels, for example, if there have not been problems with

convergence.\575\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\575\ CL-FIA-60303 at 8, Agricultural Advisory Committee Meeting

Transcript at 126-134 (Dec. 9, 2014).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commenters were divided regarding the proposed methodology for

computing spot month position limit levels (which is calculated by

determining a figure that is no more than 25 percent of estimated

deliverable supply).\576\ Several commenters stated that the proposed

formula for setting spot month limits based on 25 percent of

deliverable supply results in spot month position limits that would be

too high and may result in contract performance issues.\577\ Other

commenters thought the formula results in spot-month position limits

that would be too low and hinder market liquidity.\578\ Yet another

requested that the Commission do further research to determine whether

deliverable supply or open interest was a better means of setting spot

month position limits, and apply the same metric (deliverable supply or

open interest) to spot month limits and to non-spot month limits.\579\

Several commenters recommended that the Commission consider an

alternative means of limiting excessive speculation, that is, by

setting position limits at a level low enough to restore a hedger

majority in open interest in each core referenced futures

contract.\580\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\576\ E.g., CL-WGC-59558 at 5; CL-MFA-60385 at 4-6; CL-ISDA/

SIFMA-59611 at 3, 31, 55-56, and 63-64; CL-MGEX-59610 at 2; CL-NGFA-

59681 at 4-5.

\577\ See, e.g., CL-WGC-59558 at 5; CL-Public Citizen-60313 at

1; CL-Tri-State-59682 at 1-2; CL-AFR-59711 at 2; CL-WEED-59628 at 1;

CL-Industrial Energy Consumers of America-59671 at 3; CL-CMOC-59720

at 3; CL-IATP-60394 at 2; CL-NGFA-59681 at 4-5.

\578\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 55; CL-Armajaro-59729 at 1; CL-CAM-

60097 at 3-4.

\579\ CL-WGC-59558 at 5.

\580\ E.g., CL-IATP-60323 at 5; CL-IATP-60394 at 2; CL-RF-60372

at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In estimating deliverable supply, some commenters recommended that

the Commission include supply that is subject to long-term supply

contracts, arguing that such supply can be readily made available for

futures delivery.\581\ One commenter recommended that the Commission

permit the inclusion in the deliverable supply calculation of supplies

that can be readily transported to the futures delivery location.\582\

Another commenter recommended that the deliverable supply estimate

should include related commodities that a DCM allows to be used to

liquidate a futures position through an EFP transaction.\583\ One

commenter recommended that the deliverable supply estimate for natural

gas should include supplies that are available at other major locations

in addition to the specific futures delivery location of Erath,

Louisiana, because commercials at these locations use the futures

contract for hedging and price basing and basing spot month limits on a

more limited delivery area would be too restrictive.\584\ In estimating

deliverable supply, one commenter recommended that the Commission not

include supplies that do not meet delivery specifications.\585\ The

same commenter said that DCMs should provide documentation if including

long term supply agreements in deliverable supply estimates to enable

the Commission to verify the information. The commenter expressed

concern about financial holding companies' ability to own, warehouse

and trade physical commodities and urged the Commission to assess how

such firms might affect deliverable supply.\586\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\581\ CL-FIA-59595 at 3, 9-10; CL-NGSA-59941 at 15.

\582\ CL-MFA-59606 at 18; CL-MFA-60385 at 6.

\583\ CL-MSCGI-59708 at 2, 11.

\584\ CL-CAM-60097 at 3-4.

\585\ CL-IATP-60323 at 6.

\586\ CL-IATP-60323 at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission is reproposing to reset each

spot-month limit, in its discretion, either: Based on 25 percent of

deliverable supply as estimated by an exchange listing the core

referenced futures contract; to the existing spot-month position limit

level (that is, not changing such level); or to the recommended level

of the exchange listing the core referenced futures contract, but not

greater than 25 percent of estimated deliverable supply. In the

alternative, if the Commission elects to rely on its own estimate of

deliverable supply, it will first publish that estimate for comment in

the Federal Register.

Thus, the Commission accepts the commenter's recommendation that

the Commission have discretion to retain current spot-month position

limit levels. In this regard, the Commission provides, in reproposed

Sec. 150.2(e)(3)(ii)(B), that an exchange need not submit an estimate

of deliverable supply, if the exchange provides notice to the

Commission, not less than two calendar months before the due date for

its submission of an estimate, that it is recommending the Commission

not change the spot-month limit, and the Commission accepts such

recommendation.

The Commission notes that it has long used deliverable supply as

the basis for spot month position limits due to concerns regarding

corners, squeezes, and other settlement-period manipulative activity.

By restricting derivative positions to a proportion of the deliverable

supply of the commodity, spot month position limits reduce the

possibility that a market participant can use derivatives, including

referenced contracts, to affect the price of the cash commodity (and

vice versa). Limiting a speculative position based on a percentage of

deliverable supply also restricts a speculative trader's ability to

establish a leveraged position in cash-settled derivative contracts,

diminishing that trader's incentive to manipulate the cash settlement

price. Commenters did not provide evidence that would suggest that the

open interest formula would respond more effectively to these concerns,

and the Commission does not believe that using open interest would be

preferable for calculating spot-month position limit levels.

In addition, setting the limit levels at no greater than 25 percent

of deliverable supply has historically been effective on both the

federal and exchange level to combat corners and squeezes. In the

preamble to the final rules for vacated Part 151, the Commission noted

that the 25 percent of deliverable supply formula appears to ``work

effectively as a prophylactic tool to reduce the threat of corners and

squeezes and promote convergence without compromising market

liquidity.'' Commenters did not provide evidence to support claims that

this historical formula is no longer effective.

In response to concerns that 25 percent of deliverable supply may

result in a limit level that is too high, the Commission notes that

exchanges can and often do--and are permitted under reproposed Sec.

150.5(a) to--set limits at a level lower than 25 percent of estimated

deliverable supply, which allows the exchanges to alter exchange-set

limits easily based on changing market conditions.

In response to commenters' suggestion to restore a hedger majority,

the Commission notes such an alternative may fail the requirements of

CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B)(iv) to ensure sufficient liquidity for bona

fide hedgers. Hedgers may not be transacting on opposite sides of the

market simultaneously and, thus, need speculators to provide liquidity.

Simply changing the proportion of hedgers in the market does not mean

that the markets would operate more efficiently for bona fide hedgers.

In addition, in order to adopt the commenter's suggestion, the

Commission would need to reintroduce the withdrawn '03 series forms

which required traders to identify which positions were speculative and

which were hedging, since any entity,

[[Page 96771]]

even a commercial end-user, can establish speculative positions.

In response to commenters' suggestions regarding methods for

estimating deliverable supply, the Commission notes that deliverable

supply estimates are calculated and submitted by DCMs. Guidance for

calculating deliverable supply can be found in Appendix C to part 38.

Amendments to part 38 are beyond the scope of this rulemaking. However,

such guidance already provides that deliverable supply calculations are

estimates based on what ``reasonably can be expected to be readily

available'' (including estimates of long-term supply that can be shown

to be regularly made available for futures delivery).

c. Re-Setting Levels of Non-Spot-Month Limits

Commission Proposal--General Procedure: For setting subsequent

levels of non-spot month limits no less frequently than every two

calendar years, the Commission proposed in Sec. 150.3(e)(4) to use the

open interest formula: 10 percent of the first 25,000 contracts and 2.5

percent of the open interest thereafter (10, 2.5 percent formula).\587\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\587\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received and Commission Response: ``In order to enhance

the predictability and reduce uncertainty in business planning,'' one

commenter recommended that the Commission ``adjust limits gradually and

by no more than a minimum percentage in one biennial cycle.'' \588\ The

Commission declines this suggestion because, as explained below, the

Commission is reproposing a minimum non-spot month limit level of 5,000

contracts; market participants would be certain that in no circumstance

would the limit level fall below that figure. Also, because exchanges

can set limits at levels below the federal limit level, a change in the

federal limit may not have an effect on exchange limit levels.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\588\ CL-FIA-60303 at 8. This commenter did not recommend any

specific percentage limitation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters recommended that the Commission review the

levels of position limits more frequently than once every two years to

address changes that may occur within the commodities markets.\589\ In

response these concerns, the Commission notes that exchanges may set

limits at a level lower than the federal limits in order to more

readily adapt to changing market conditions. Should higher limit levels

be desired, exchanges may petition the Commission or the Commission may

determine to change limit levels within the two year period. Thus, the

flexibility to change limit levels more frequently than every two years

is already permitted by the reproposed rules and the Commission is not

changing the timeline.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\589\ E.g., CL-Public Citizen-59648 at 5 (annually); CL-AFR-II

at 2 (greater frequency); CL-Better Markets-60325 at 2-3

(``[b]iennial updates . . . are completely inadequate''); CL-Better

Markets-59716 at 34 (biennial updates values ``the input of swap

dealers and their trade groups over that of commercial hedgers'');

CL-CMOC-59720 at 3 (annual consultation with hedgers and end users);

CL-RF-60372 at 3 (``review position limits every six months'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter recommended that the Commission ``adopt final rules

that give the Commission the flexibility to increase position limits

immediately or with little delay so that the market can accurately

respond to external forces without violating position limits'' or, in

the alternative, ``include peak open interest levels beyond the most

recent two years when it determines the level of open interest on which

to base position limits.\590\ In response, the Commission notes that

using peak open interest figures, as opposed to an average, as

reproposed, may not necessarily represent an accurate portrait of

current market conditions. Using the most recent two years of data is

designed to ensure that the non-spot-month limit levels are set

relative to the current size of the market.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\590\ CL-MFA-59606 at 21.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters expressed the view that the proposed limits

based on the open interest formula would result in limit levels that

are too high and would not accomplish the goal of reducing excessive

speculation.\591\ In response, the Commission believes the open

interest formula provides a level that is low enough to reduce the

potential for excessive speculation and market manipulation without

unduly impairing liquidity for bona fide hedgers. Under the rules

reproposed today, both the Commission and the exchanges would have

flexibility to impose non-spot month limit levels at the greater of the

open interest formula, the spot month limit level, or 5,000 contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\591\ E.g., CL-Tri-State-59682 at 1-2; CL-A4A-59714 at 3; CL-

Better Markets-59716 at 24; CL-APGA-59722 at 3, 6; CL-AFBF-59730 at

3; CL-NGFA-59681 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters expressed the view that the proposed limits

based on the open interest formula would result in limit levels for

dairy contracts that are too low and would restrict hedging use by

limiting liquidity.\592\ The Commission responds that it is deferring

the imposition of position limits on the Class III Milk contract, as

discussed below.\593\ The Commission also observes that reproposed

Sec. 150.9 permits market participants to apply directly to the

exchanges to obtain an exemption to exceed speculative position limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\592\ E.g., CL-U.S. Dairy-59597 at 4, 6; CL-Hood-59582; CL-

McCully-59592 at 1; CL-Rice Dairy-59601 at 1; CL-Agri-Mark-59609 at

1-2; CL-Jacoby-59622 at 1; CL-Pedestal-59630 at 2; CL-Darigold-59651

at 1-2; CL-Traditum-59655 at 1; CL-Leprino-59707 at 2; CL-IDFA-59771

at 1-2; CL-Fonterra-59608 at 1-2; CL-NCFC-59613 at 6; CL-NMPF-59936

at 2; CL-DFA-59621 at 7-8; CL-Glanbia Foods-60316 at 1; CL-Leprino

Foods-59707 at 2; CL-NMPF-59936 at 2.

\593\ Some commenters urged the Commission to establish an

individual month position limit in Class III Milk equal to the spot

month limit but no less than 3,000 contracts net, and an all-months-

limit as a multiple of four times the spot month limit, to foster

needed liquidity in the non-spot months. See, e.g., CL-NCFC-59942 at

6. Another commenter urged an all-months-limit in Class III Milk of

ten times the spot month limit for a similar reason. CL-U.S. Dairy-

59597 at 4. These comments are now moot.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters recommended that the Commission consider an

alternative means of limiting speculative traders, by setting position

limits at a level low enough to restore a hedger majority in open

interest in each core referenced futures contract.\594\ As discussed

above, the Commission is concerned that ``restoring'' a hedger majority

may not ensure sufficient liquidity for bona fide hedgers. Hedgers may

not be transacting on opposite sides of the market simultaneously and,

thus, need speculators to provide liquidity. Simply changing the

proportion of hedgers in the market does not mean that the markets

would operate more efficiently for bona fide hedgers. In addition, in

order to implement this suggestion, the Commission would need to

reintroduce the long defunct '03 series forms which required traders to

identify which positions were speculative and which were hedging,

because any entity, even a commercial end-user, can establish

speculative positions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\594\ E.g., CL-IATP-60323 at 5; CL-IATP-60394 at 2; CL-RF-60372

at 3; CL-A4A-59686 at 4; CL-Better Markets-59716 at 5; CL-Better

Markets-60325 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter noted that the open interest formula permits a

speculator to hold a larger percentage of open interest in a smaller

commodity market and thus the formula's entire rationale seems

``arbitrary . . . and . . . capricious.'' \595\ The Commission

acknowledges that, because of the way the 10, 2.5 percent formula

works, a speculator in a market with open interest of fewer than 25,000

contracts may have a larger share of the open interest than a

speculator in a market with an open interest of greater

[[Page 96772]]

than 25,000 contracts. The Commission responds that it is by design

that the 10, 2.5 percent open interest formula provides that a

speculator may hold a larger percentage of total open interest in a

smaller market, potentially providing liquidity for bona fide hedgers

in such a smaller market. As open interest increases, the 2.5% marginal

increase results in limit levels that become a progressively smaller

percentage of total open interest, essentially placing a greater

emphasis on deterring market manipulation and protecting the price

discovery process in a larger market.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\595\ CL-USCF-59644 at 3-4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter suggested that the Commission use a 10, 5 percent

open interest formula rather than a 10, 2.5 percent formula as

proposed, arguing that the 10, 5 percent formula has worked well for

certain agricultural futures markets and should be applied more

broadly. Alternatively, this commenter said that Commission should use

the 10, 5 percent formula for at least spread positions.\596\ The

Commission notes the 10, 2.5 percent formula has produced limit levels

that should sufficiently maximize the CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B) criteria,

and the Commission does not believe increasing the marginal percentage

is necessary. A larger limit such as would be produced from a 10, 5

percent formula may not adequately prevent excessive speculation. In

the preamble to the proposed rules, the Commission noted that the 10,

2.5 percent formula was first proposed in 1992, and the commenter has

not provided sufficient justification for moving away from this

established standard.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\596\ CL-Working Group-59693 at 62.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter recommended that the Commission consider commodity-

related ratios in establishing limits, such as the ratio between crude

oil and its products, diesel (30 percent) and gasoline (50 percent),

rather than on separate open interest formulas applied to each.\597\ In

response, the Commission notes setting limit levels based on the open

interest of a related commodity may result in limit levels that are too

large to be effective in the smaller commodity markets. For example,

based on the levels proposed in this release in Appendix D,

implementing a limit for NYMEX RBOB Gasoline equal to 50 percent of the

crude oil limit, as suggested by the commenter, would result in a limit

almost 10 times the size otherwise indicated by the open interest

formula, and would equal almost 28 percent of total average open

interest in the RBOB referenced contract. Further, hedgers with

positions in multiple contracts could establish positions in various

ratios without violating a position limit, provided they comply with

the bona fide hedging position definition and any applicable

requirements. The Commission also notes that the process in reproposed

Sec. 150.10 exempting certain spread positions may allow speculators

some flexibility in inter- and intra-commodity spreads for the purpose

of providing liquidity to bona fide hedgers.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\597\ CL-Citadel-59717 at 7-8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter suggested the Commission consider setting position

limits on ``customary position size'' which had been used for setting

non-spot month limits by the Commission in the past and which the

commenter argues is a more effective means of curtailing large

speculative positions.\598\ In response, the Commission believes the

10, 2.5 percent formula has been effective in preventing excessive

speculation without unduly limiting liquidity for bona fide hedgers.

The Commission notes when the ``customary position size'' methodology

was used to set non-spot-month limit levels, such levels were below the

levels established using 10, 2.5 percent formula.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\598\ CL-APGA-59722 at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal Regarding General Procedure for Re-Setting

Levels of Non-Spot Month Limits: The Commission has determined to

repropose the 10, 2.5 percent formula, generally as proposed in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, for the reasons discussed

above. However, the Commission has determined, in response to requests

by commenters requesting wheat parity, as discussed above, to provide

that it may determine not to change the level of a non-spot month

limit. This would permit, for example, the Commission to continue to

retain a level of 12,000 contracts for the non-spot month limits in the

KW and MWE contracts, even if average open interest did not exceed

405,000 contracts (which is the level that, when applying the 10, 2.5

percent formula, would result in a limit of 12,000 contracts).

Commission Proposal for Time Periods, Data Sources, Publication and

Minimum Levels for Re-Setting Levels of Non-Spot Month Limits: Under

proposed in Sec. 150.2(e)(4)(i) and (ii), the Commission would

estimate average open interest in referenced contracts using data

reported for each of the last two calendar years pursuant to parts 16,

20, and/or 45.\599\ The Commission also proposed under Sec.

150.2(e)(4)(iii) to publish on the Commission's Web page estimates of

average open interest in referenced contracts on a monthly basis to

make it easier for market participants to estimate changes in levels of

position limits.\600\ Finally, the Commission proposed under Sec.

150.2(e)(4)(iv) to establish minimum non-spot month levels of 1,000

contracts for agricultural commodity contracts and 5,000 contracts for

exempt commodity contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\599\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75734.

\600\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received and Commission Response: Regarding the time

period for average open interest, as noted above, one commenter

recommended that the Commission, as an alternative, ``include peak open

interest levels beyond the most recent two years when it determines the

level of open interest on which to base position limits.'' \601\ In

response, the Commission notes that using peak open interest figures,

as opposed to an average, as reproposed, may not necessarily represent

an accurate portrait of current market conditions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\601\ CL-MFA-59606 at 21.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Regarding data sources for average open interest, several

commenters noted that the open interest data used by the Commission in

determining the non-spot month limits was not complete since it did not

include all OTC swaps data and that the Commission should correct this

deficiency before it sets the limits using the open interest

formula.\602\ In response, the Commission notes it used futures-

equivalent open interest for swaps reported under part 20, in

determining the initial non-spot month limits, as discussed above, and

believes this data also is acceptable for re-setting limit levels, as

reproposed.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\602\ E.g., CL-DBCS-59569 at 6; CL-FIA-59595 at 14; CL-EEI-60386

at 11; CL-MFA-59606 at 5, 20, 22-23; CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 29,

including footnote 108; CL-CMC-59634 at 13; CL-Olam-59658 at 3; CL-

COPE-59662 at 22; CL-Calpine-59663 at 4; CL-Chamber-59684 at 5; CL-

NFP-59690 at 20; CL-Just Energy-59692 at 4; CL-Working Group-59693

at 62; CL-Working Group-60396 at 8-10; CL-Citadel-59717 at 4-5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission received no comments regarding publication of

average open interest.

Regarding minimum levels for non-spot month limits, some commenters

urged the Commission to afford itself the flexibility to set non-spot

month limits at least as high as the spot-month position limit, rather

than base the non-spot month limit strictly on the open interest

formula in cases where the latter would result in a relatively small

limit that would hinder liquidity.\603\ The Commission accepts these

[[Page 96773]]

commenters' recommendation. Upon consideration of proposing minimum

initial non-spot month limits, as discussed above, the Commission is

removing the distinction between agricultural and exempt commodities.

This change would establish a minimum non-spot month limit level of

5,000 contracts in either agricultural or exempt commodities.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\603\ CL-ICE-59966 at 6; CL-U.S. Dairy-59597 at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to repropose

these provisions generally as proposed in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, but with the changes described above to provide

flexibility for a higher minimum level of non-spot month limits.

7. Deferral of Limits on Cash-Settled Core Referenced Futures Contracts

Commission Proposal:

The Commission proposed, but is not reproposing, positon limits on

three cash-settled core referenced futures contracts: CME Class III

Milk; CME Feeder Cattle; and CME Lean Hogs.\604\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\604\ Each of these contracts is cash settled to a U.S.

Department of Agriculture price series; Feeder Cattle and Lean Hogs

settle to a CME-calculated index of daily USDA livestock prices,

while Class III Milk settles to the monthly USDA Class III Milk

price.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: Commenters raised concerns with these cash-

settled contracts and how they fit within the federal position limits

regime. While many of these concerns were raised in the context of the

dairy industry, they apply to all three cash-settled core referenced

futures contracts. Concerns raised include: (1) How to apply spot month

limits in a contract that is cash-settled; \605\ (2) the ``five-day

rule'' for bona fide hedging; \606\ and (3) the length of the spot

month period.\607\ Commenters contended that the Commission's rationale

in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal focused on concerns with

physical-delivery contracts, which the commenters believe do not apply

to cash-settled core referenced futures contracts because there is no

physical delivery process and because the contracts settle to

government-regulated price series (through the USDA).\608\ Commenters

were concerned that the Commission's ``one-size-fits-all'' approach

discriminates against participants in dairy and livestock because the

spot-month limit is effectively smaller compared to the separate spot-

month limits for physical-delivery and cash-settled contracts in other

commodities.\609\ Several commenters suggested limit levels that do not

follow the proposed formulae for determining limit levels for both spot

and non-spot-month limits due to the unique aspects of cash-settled

core referenced futures contracts, including the relatively large cash

market and trading strategies not found in other core referenced

futures markets.\610\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\605\ CL-Rice Dairy-59960 at 1; CL-US Dairy-59597 at 3-4; CL-

NMPF-59652 at 4; CL-DFA-59948 at 4-5.

\606\ CL-NMPF-59652 at 5; CL-DFA-59948 at 8.

\607\ CL-NGSA-59674 at 44; CL-ICE-59669 at 5-6.

\608\ See, e.g., CL-US Dairy-59597 at 3-4.

\609\ CL-DFA-59948 at 6.

\610\ CL-Rice Dairy-59601 at 1; CL-US Dairy-59597 at 3; CL-NMPF-

59652 at 4; CL-DFA-59948 at 4-5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Determination: The Commission, as part of the phased

approach to implementing position limits on all physical commodity

derivative contracts, is deferring action so that it may, at a later

date: (1) Clarify the application of limits to cash-settled core

referenced futures contracts; and (2) consider further which method to

use to determine a level for a spot-month limit for a cash-settled core

referenced futures contract. The Commission notes that the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal discussed spot-month limits primarily in

the context of protecting the price discovery process by preventing

corners and squeezes.\611\ There was limited discussion of cash-settled

core referenced futures contracts.\612\ The Commission did not propose

alternate means of calculating limit levels for cash-settled core

referenced futures contracts in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\611\ For example, the Commission stated that concerns regarding

corners and squeezes are most acute in the markets for physical-

delivery contracts in the spot month. December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, 78 FR at 75737.

\612\ See, e.g., December 2013 Position Limits Proposal 78 FR at

75688, including n. 82.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

C. Sec. 150.3--Exemptions

1. Current Sec. 150.3

Statutory authority: CEA section 4a(c)(1) exempts positions that

are shown to be bona fide hedging positions, as defined by the

Commission, from any Commission rule establishing speculative position

limits under CEA section 4a(a).\613\ In addition, CEA section 4a(a)(1)

authorizes the Commission to exempt transactions normally know to the

trade as ``spreads.'' \614\ Further, CEA section 4a(a)(7) authorizes

the Commission to exempt any person, contract, or transaction from any

position limit requirement the Commission establishes.\615\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\613\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(c)(1). Section 737 of the Dodd-Frank Act did

not substantively change CEA section 4a(c)(1) (renumbering existing

provision by inserting ``(1)'' after ``(c)'').

\614\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(1). Section 737 of the Dodd-Frank Act did

not change the Commission's authority to exempt spreads under CEA

section 4a(a)(1).

\615\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(7). Section 737 of the Dodd-Frank Act added

CEA section 4a(a)(7). The Commission interprets CEA section 4a(a)(7)

to provide the Commission with plenary authority to grant exemptive

relief from position limits, consistent with the purposes of the

CEA. Specifically, under Section 4a(a)(7), the Commission ``by rule,

regulation, or order, may exempt, conditionally or unconditionally,

any person, or class of persons, any swap or class of swaps, any

contract of sale of a commodity for future delivery or class of such

contracts, any option or class of options, or any transaction or

class of transactions from any requirement it may establish . . .

with respect to position limits.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Current exemptions: The three existing exemptions in current Sec.

150.3(a), promulgated prior to the enactment of the Dodd-Frank Act, are

part of the Commission's regulatory framework for speculative position

limits.\616\ First, current Sec. 150.3(a)(1) exempts positions shown

to be bona fide hedging positions from federal position limits.\617\

Second, current Sec. 150.3(a)(3) exempts spread positions between

single months of a futures contract (and/or, on a futures-equivalent

basis, options) outside of the spot month, provided a trader's spread

position in any single month does not exceed the all-months limit.\618\

Third, under current Sec. 150.3(a)(4), positions carried for an

eligible entity \619\ in the separate account of an independent account

controller (``IAC'') \620\ that manages customer positions need not be

aggregated with the other positions owned or controlled by that

eligible entity (the ``IAC exemption'').\621\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\616\ For completeness, the Commission notes it previously

provided an exemption in Sec. 150.3(a)(2) for spreads of futures

positions which offset option positions. However, the Commission

removed and reserved that provision once it was rendered obsolete by

the Commission determination to impose speculative limits on a

trader's net position in futures and options combined, rather than

separately. 58 FR 17973 at 17979 (April 7, 1993).

\617\ 17 CFR 150.3(a)(1). The term bona fide hedging position is

currently defined at 17 CFR 1.3(z) (2010). As discussed above, the

Commission is reproposing a new definition of bona fide hedging

position in Sec. 150.1.

\618\ The Commission clarifies that a spread position in this

context means a short position in a single month of a futures

contract and a long position in another contract month of that same

futures contract, outside of the spot month, in the same crop year.

The short and/or long positions may also be in options on that same

futures contract, on a futures equivalent basis. Such spread

positions, when combined with any other net positions in the single

month, must not exceed the all-months limit set forth in current

Sec. 150.2, and must be in the same crop year. 17 CFR 150.3(a)(3).

\619\ ``Eligible entity'' is defined in current 17 CFR 150.1(d).

\620\ ``Independent account controller'' is defined in current

17 CFR 150.1(e).

\621\ 17 CFR 150.3(a)(4). See also discussion of the IAC

exemption in the 2016 Final Aggregation Rule.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96774]]

2. Proposed Sec. 150.3

In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed a number of organizational and substantive amendments to Sec.

150.3, generally resulting in an increase in the number of exemptions

to speculative position limits. First, the Commission proposed to amend

the three exemptions from federal speculative limits contained in

current Sec. 150.3. These previously proposed amendments would update

cross references, relocate the IAC exemption and consolidate it with

the Commission's separate proposal to amend the aggregation

requirements of Sec. 150.4,\622\ and delete the calendar month spread

provision which is unnecessary under changes to Sec. 150.2 that would

set the level of each single month position limit to that of the all-

months position limit. Second, the Commission proposed to add

exemptions from the federal speculative position limits for financial

distress situations, certain spot-month positions in cash-settled

referenced contracts, and grandfathered pre-Dodd-Frank and transition

period swaps. Third, the Commission proposed to revise recordkeeping

and reporting requirements for traders claiming any exemption from the

federal speculative position limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\622\ See November 2013 Aggregation Proposal. See also 2016

Final Aggregation Rule.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. Proposed Amendments to Existing Exemptions

Proposed Rule: In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission proposed to update cross-references within Sec. 150.3 to

reflect other changes in part 150. Specifically, the Commission

proposed: To update references to the bona fide hedging definition to

Sec. 150.1 from Sec. 1.3(z); to require that those filing for

exemptive relief must meet the reporting requirements in part 19; and

to add a cross-reference to aggregation provisions in proposed Sec.

150.4.

The Commission also proposed to move the existing IAC exemption to

Sec. 150.4, thereby deleting the current exemption in Sec.

150.3(a)(4). The Commission also proposed to delete the spread

exemption in current Sec. 150.3, because it noted that the proposed

non-spot month limits rendered such an exemption unnecessary.\623\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\623\ Under the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, DCMs

and SEFs that are trading facilities would have authority to grant

spread exemptions to both exchange and federal position limits. See

infra discussion of Sec. Sec. 150.5 and 150.10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed to conform Sec. 150.3(a) to accommodate processes proposed in

other sections of part 150. Specifically, the Commission proposed under

Sec. 150.3(a)(1)(i) exemptions for those bona fide hedging positions

that have been recognized by a DCM or SEF in accordance with proposed

Sec. Sec. 150.9 and 150.11. The Commission also proposed under Sec.

150.3(a)(1)(iv) exemptions for those spread positions that have been

recognized by a DCM or SEF in accordance with proposed Sec. 150.10.

Recognition of other positions exempted under proposed Sec. 150.3(e)

was re-numbered as subsection (v) from subsection (iv) of Sec.

150.3(a)(1) of the 2013 Position Limits Proposal.

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on the

proposed conforming changes to Sec. 150.3.\624\ The Commission

addresses comments on the IAC exemption in its final rule amending the

aggregation policy under Sec. 150.4, published separately.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\624\ The Commission received many comments on the changes to

the bona fide hedging definition in Sec. 150.1 and the processes

for exchange recognition of exemptions in Sec. Sec. 150.9-11. See

discussion of the bona fide hedging definition, above, and of the

processes in Sec. Sec. 150.9-11, below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission is reproposing these

amendments as previously proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal.

b. Positions Which May Exceed Limits--Sec. 150.3(a)

Proposed Rule: In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission listed positions which may exceed limits in proposed Sec.

150.3(a). Such positions included: (i) Bona fide hedging positions as

defined in Sec. 150.1; (ii) financial distress positions exempted

under Sec. 150.3(b); (iii) conditional spot month limit positions

exempted under Sec. 150.3(c); and (iv) other positions exempted under

Sec. 150.3(e). Proposed Sec. 150.3(a) also provided that all such

positions may exceed limits only if recordkeeping requirements in Sec.

150.3(g) are met and any applicable reporting requirements in part 19

are met.

In the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed to revise Sec. 150.3(a) to include, in addition to bona fide

hedging positions as defined in Sec. 150.1, positions that are

recognized by a DCM or SEF in accordance with Sec. 150.9 or Sec.

150.11 as well as spread positions recognized by a DCM or SEF in

accordance with Sec. 150.10.

Comments Received: The Commission received many comments on the

definition of bona fide hedging in Sec. 150.1, as well as on the

processes proposed in Sec. Sec. 150.9-11.\625\ The Commission

addresses those comments in the discussion of the definition of bona

fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1, above, and in the discussion of

the processes proposed in Sec. Sec. 150.9-11, below. The Commission

did not receive comments specific to the conforming revisions to Sec.

150.3(a).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\625\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.3(a)

as previously proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

with conforming changes consistent with the reproposed definition of a

bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1, which includes positions

that are recognized by a DCM or SEF in accordance with reproposed Sec.

150.9 or Sec. 150.11, or by the Commission, and conforming changes

consistent with the process for spread positions recognized by a DCM or

SEF in accordance with reproposed Sec. 150.10, or by the Commission.

c. Proposed Additional Exemptions From Position Limits

i. Financial Distress Exemption--Sec. 150.3(b)

Proposed Rule: The Commission proposed to add in Sec. 150.3(b) an

exemption from position limits for market participants in financial

distress circumstances, upon the Commission's approval of a specific

request.\626\ For example, the Commission recognized that, in periods

of financial distress, it may be beneficial for a financially sound

market participant to take on the positions (and corresponding risk) of

a less stable market participant. The Commission explained that it has

historically provided an exemption from position limits in these types

of situations in order to avoid sudden liquidations that could

potentially reduce liquidity, disrupt price discovery, and/or increase

systemic risk. The Commission therefore proposed to codify this

historical practice.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\626\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75736.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: One commenter requested the non-exclusive

circumstances for the financial distress exemption be clarified by

adding ``bud not limited to'' after the word ``include'' to permit

other situations not listed.\627\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\627\ CL-CME-59718 at 71.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: In response to the commenter, the Commission

clarifies that the circumstances under which a financial distress

exemption may be claimed include, but are not limited to, the specific

scenarios in the definition. However, the Commission believes that the

proposed definition

[[Page 96775]]

sufficiently articulates that the list of potential circumstances for

claiming the financial distress exemption is non-exclusive, and,

therefore, is reproposing the definition as previously proposed.

ii. Pre-Enactment and Transition Period Swaps Exemption--Sec. 150.3(d)

Proposed Rule: In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission proposed to provide an exemption from federal position

limits for (1) pre-enactment swaps, defined as swaps entered into prior

to July 21, 2010 (the date of the enactment of the Dodd-Frank Act of

2010), so long as the terms of which have not expired as of that date,

and (2) transition period swaps, defined as swaps entered into during

the period commencing July 22, 2010 and ending 60 days after the

publication of the final position limit rules in the Federal Register,

the terms of which have not expired as of that date. The Commission

also proposed to allow both pre-enactment and transition period swaps

to be netted with commodity derivative contracts acquired more than 60

days after publication of the final rules in the Federal Register for

purposes of complying with non-spot-month position limits.\628\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\628\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75738.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: One commenter suggested that ``grandfathering''

relief should be extended to pre-existing positions, and should also

permit the pre-existing positions to be increased after the effective

date of the limit. The commenter also suggested that the Commission

should permit the risk associated with a pre-existing position to be

offset through roll of a position from a prompt month into a deferred

contract month.\629\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\629\ CL-AMG-59709 at 2, 18-19.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission declines to accept the

commenter's recommendation regarding increasing positions, because

allowing pre-existing positions to be increased after the effective

date of the limits effectively would create a loophole for exceeding

position limits. Further, the Commission declines the commenter's

recommendation to permit a roll of a pre-existing position, because

that would permit a market participant to extend indefinitely the

holding of a speculative economic exposure in commodity derivative

contracts exempt from position limits, frustrating the intent of

speculative position limits. The Commission notes, however, that

reproposed Sec. 150.3(d), like the previous proposal, allows for

netting of pre- and post-effective date positions, allowing a market

participant to offset the risk of the position provided the offsetting

position is not held into a spot month. The Commission is reproposing

Sec. 150.3(d) as proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal.

iii. Previously Granted Exemptions--Sec. 150.3(f)

Proposed Rule: The Commission proposed in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal that exemptions previously granted by the

Commission under Sec. 1.47 for swap risk management would not apply to

new swap positions entered into after the effective date of the final

rule. The Commission noted that the proposed rules revoke the

previously granted exemptions for risk management positions for such

new swaps. Therefore, risk management positions that offset such new

swaps would be subject to federal position limits, unless another

exemption applied. The Commission explained that these risk management

positions are inconsistent with the revised definition of bona fide

hedging contained in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal and the

purposes of the Dodd-Frank Act amendments to the CEA.\630\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\630\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75740.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: A number of commenters urged the Commission not

to deny risk-management exemptions for financial intermediaries who

utilize referenced contracts to offset the risks arising from the

provision of diversified commodity-based returns to the intermediaries'

clients.\631\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\631\ CL-FIA-59595 at 5, 34-35; CL-AMG-59709 at 2, 12-15; CL-

CME-59718 at 67-69.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In contrast, other commenters noted that the proposed rules

``properly refrain'' from providing a general exemption to financial

firms seeking to hedge their financial risks from the sale of

commodity-related instruments such as index swaps, ETFs, and ETNs

because such instruments are ``inherently speculative'' and may

overwhelm the price discovery function of the derivative market.\632\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\632\ CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 8; CL-Better Markets-60325 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: As discussed above in the clarifications to

the bona fide hedging position definition, the Commission now proposes

to expand the relief in Sec. 150.3(f) by: (1) Clarifying that such

previously granted exemptions may apply to pre-existing financial

instruments that are within the scope of existing Sec. 1.47

exemptions, rather than only to pre-existing swaps; and (2) recognizing

exchange-granted non-enumerated exemptions in non-legacy commodity

derivatives outside of the spot month (consistent with the Commission's

recognition of risk management exemptions outside of the spot month),

and provided such exemptions are granted prior to the compliance date

of the final rule, and apply only to pre-existing financial instruments

as of the effective date of the final rule. These two changes are

intended to reduce the potential for market disruption by forced

liquidations, since a market intermediary would continue to be able to

offset risks of pre-effective-date financial instruments, pursuant to

previously-granted federal or exchange risk management exemptions.

iv. Non-Enumerated Hedging Positions--Sec. 150.3(e)

Proposed Rule: In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission noted that it previously permitted a person to file an

application seeking approval for a non-enumerated position to be

recognized as a bona fide hedging position under Sec. 1.47. The

Commission proposed to delete Sec. 1.47 for several reasons described

in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal.\633\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\633\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75738-9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Proposed Sec. 150.3 provided that a person that engages in risk-

reducing practices commonly used in the market, that the person

believes may not be included in the list of enumerated bona fide

hedging positions, may apply to the Commission for an exemption from

position limits. As previously proposed, market participants would be

guided in Sec. 150.3(e) first to consult proposed Appendix C to part

150 to see whether their practices fell within a non-exhaustive list of

examples of bona fide hedging positions as defined under proposed Sec.

150.1.

A person engaged in risk-reducing practices that are not enumerated

in the revised definition of bona fide hedging position in previously

proposed Sec. 150.1 may use two different avenues to apply to the

Commission for relief from federal position limits: The person may

request an interpretative letter from Commission staff pursuant to

Sec. 140.99 \634\ concerning the applicability

[[Page 96776]]

of the bona fide hedging position exemption, or the person may seek

exemptive relief from the Commission under CEA section 4a(a)(7).\635\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\634\ 17 CFR 140.99 defines three types of staff letters--

exemptive letters, no-action letters, and interpretative letters--

that differ in scope and effect. An interpretative letter is written

advice or guidance by the staff of a division of the Commission or

its Office of the General Counsel. It binds only the staff of the

division that issued it (or the Office of the General Counsel, as

the case may be), and third-parties may rely upon it as the

interpretation of that staff. See description of CFTC Staff Letters,

available at http://www.cftc.gov/lawregulation/cftcstaffletters/index.htm.

\635\ See supra discussion of CEA section 4a(a)(7).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed Sec. Sec. 150.9, 150.10, and 150.11 which provided

alternative processes that would permit eligible DCMs and SEFs to

provide relief for non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions, certain

spread positions, and anticipatory bona fide hedging positions,

respectively.\636\ However, the Commission did not propose to alter or

delete Sec. 150.3 because the Commission determined to provide

multiple avenues for persons seeking exemptive relief.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\636\ See infra discussion of these alternative processes in

Sec. 150.9, Sec. 150.10, and Sec. 150.11.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: One commenter requested that the Commission

provide a spread exemption from federal position limits for certain

soft commodities, reasoning that there was a ``lack of fungibility of

certain soft commodities . . . [because] inventories of various

categories vary widely in terms of marketability over time.'' The

commenter also stated that such a spread exemption would allow for

effective competition for the ownership of certified inventories that

in turn helps to maintain a close relationship between the cash and

futures markets.\637\ Another commenter recommended the Commission

recognize calendar spread netting, and not place any limits on the

same, because speculators provide liquidity in deferred months to

hedgers and offset, in part, that exposure with shorter dated

contracts.\638\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\637\ CL-CMC-59718 at 15.

\638\ CL-Citadel-59717 at 8-9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: Both of these comments were submitted in

response to the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, well in advance

of the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal. Spread exemptions

such as those described by the commenters are addressed in Sec.

150.10, discussed below. The Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.3(e)

as previously proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal.

d. Proposed Conditional Spot Month Limit Exemption--Sec. 150.3(c)

Conditional spot month limit exemptions to exchange-set spot-month

position limits for natural gas contracts were adopted in 2009, after

the ICE submitted such an exemption as part of its certification of

compliance with core principles required of exempt commercial markets

(``ECMs'') on which significant price discovery contracts (``SPDCs'')

were traded.\639\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\639\ CFTC Reauthorization Act of 2008 (``Farm Bill'',

incorporated as Title XIII of the Food, Conservation and Energy Act

of 2008, Public Law 110-246, 112 Stat. 1624 (June 18, 2008))

expanded the Commission's authority with respect to ECMs by creating

a new regulatory category: ECMs on which significant price discovery

contracts (``SPDCs'') were traded. The Farm Bill authorized the

Commission to designate an ECM contract as a SPDC if the Commission

determined, under criteria established in the Act, that the contract

performed a significant price discovery function. When the

Commission made such a determination, the ECM on which the SPDC was

traded would be required to assume, with respect to that contract,

all the responsibilities and obligations of a registered entity

under the Commission's regulations and the Act. This process was

invalidated and deleted by changes to the Act made under the Dodd-

Frank Act of 2010.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As ICE developed its rules in order to comply with the ECM SPDC

requirements,\640\ ICE expressed concerns regarding the impact of

position limits on the open interest in its LD1 contract. ICE

demonstrated that as the open interest declines in the physical-

delivery New York Mercantile Exchange Inc. (``NYMEX'') Henry Hub

Natural Gas Futures (``NYMEX NG'') contract approaching expiration,

open interest increases rapidly in the cash-settled ICE NG LD1

contract, and suggested that the ICE NG LD1 contract served an

important function for hedgers and speculators who wished to recreate

or hedge the NYMEX NG contract price without being required to make or

take delivery. ICE stated that it believed there are ``significant and

material distinctions between the design and use of'' the NYMEX NG

contract and the ICE NG LD1 contract, and those distinctions were most

pronounced at expiration. Further, ICE stated that, due to the size of

some positions in the cash-settled ICE NG LD1 contract, the impact to

the market of an equivalent limit could impair the ability for market

participants to adjust their positions in an orderly fashion to come

into compliance. For these reasons, ICE requested that the Commission

consider an alternative to the Commission's acceptable practice that

spot month position limits for the NG LD1 contract should be equivalent

to the spot month position limits in the NYMEX NG contract.\641\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\640\ On March 16, 2009, the Commission adopted final rules

implementing the provisions of the Farm Bill. 74 FR 12179 (March 23,

2009). These regulations became effective on April 22, 2009. Among

other things, the rules established procedures by which the

Commission would make and announce its determination as to whether a

particular contract served a significant price discovery function.

On July 24, 2009, the Commission issued an order finding that ICE's

Henry Financial LD1 Fixed Price contract (``NG LD1 contract'')

performed a significant price discovery function and, thus, that ICE

was a registered entity with respect to the NG LD1 contract, subject

to all provisions of the Act applicable to registered entities,

including compliance with certain core principles. 74 FR 37988 (July

30, 2009).

As required after the designation of the NG LD1 contract as a

SPDC, ICE submitted a demonstration of their compliance with the

required core principles. One of the core principles with which ICE

was required to comply under the Farm Bill ECM SPDC rules concerned

position limits and position accountability rules for the

contract(s) designated as SPDC(s). See Section 13201(C)(ii)(IV) of

the Farm Bill (implemented in Section 2(h)(7) of the Act).

\641\ See 17 CFR part 36, App. B, Core Principle IV(c)(3)

(2010). 74 FR 12177 (April 22, 2009).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After discussion with both the Commission's Division of Market

Oversight and NYMEX, ICE submitted and certified rule amendments

implementing position limits and position accountability rules for the

ICE NG LD1 contract. Specifically, ICE imposed a spot-month position

limit and non-spot-month position accountability levels equal to those

of the economically equivalent NYMEX NG contract. ICE also adopted a

rule for a larger conditional position limit for traders who: (1)

Agreed not to maintain a position in the NYMEX NG futures contract

during the last three trading days, and (2) agreed to show ICE their

complete book of Henry Hub related positions.\642\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\642\ ICE also imposed related aggregation, bona fide hedging,

and other exemption rules for the ICE NG LD1 contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In June 2009, the Commission also received self-certified rule

amendments from CME Group, Inc. (``CME'') regarding position limits and

position accountability levels for the cash-settled NYMEX Henry Hub

Financial Last Day Futures (HH) contract and related cash-settled

contracts.\643\ The rules, as amended, established spot month position

limits for the NYMEX HH contract as well as certain related cash-

settled contracts so as to be consistent with the requirements for the

SPDC contract on ICE. In the rule certification documents, CME stated

that it was amending its position limits rules for the HH contract in

anticipation of ICE's new rules. In February 2010, the conditional spot

month limit exemptions on NYMEX and ICE went into effect.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\643\ New York Mercantile Exchange, Inc. Submission #09.103

(June 2, 2009): Notification of Amendments to NYMEX Rules 9A.27 and

9A.27A to Establish Hard Expiration Position Limits for Certain

Natural Gas Financially Settled Contracts. Previously, NYMEX did not

have spot-month limits on its HH contract and related cash-settled

contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Proposed Rules: In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

[[Page 96777]]

Commission proposed a conditional spot month limit exemption for all

commodities subject to federal limits under proposed Sec. 150.2. That

proposed rule was identical to the rule proposed in the Part 151

Proposal, with the exception that the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal did not include any restriction on trading in the cash

market.\644\ In proposing the conditional spot month limit exemption in

proposed Sec. 150.3(c), the Commission stated its preliminary belief

that the current exemption in natural gas markets has served ``to

further the purposes Congress articulated for position limits'' and

that the exemption ``would not encourage price discovery to migrate to

the cash-settled contracts in a way that would make the physical-

delivery contract more susceptible to sudden price movements near

expiration.'' \645\ In addition, the Commission noted that it has

observed repeatedly that open interest levels in physical-delivery

contracts ``naturally decline leading up to and during the spot month,

as the contract approaches expiration'' because ``both hedgers and

speculators exit the physical-delivery contract in order to, for

example, roll their positions to the next contract month or avoid

delivery obligations.'' \646\ The Commission also stated its

preliminary belief that ``it is unlikely that the factors keeping

traders in the spot month physical-delivery contract will change due

solely to the introduction of a higher cash-settled limit,'' as traders

participating in the physical-delivery contract in the spot month are

``understood to have a commercial reason or need to stay in the spot

month.'' \647\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\644\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75736-38.

\645\ Id. at 75737.

\646\ Id. at 75770.

\647\ Id. at 75770, n. 782.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received many comments regarding

the conditional spot month limit exemption. These comments revealed

little to no consensus among market participants, exchanges, and

industry groups regarding spot-month position limits in cash-settled

contracts.

Several commenters supported the higher spot-month limit (or no

limit at all) for cash-settled contracts, but opposed the restriction

on holding a position in the physical-delivery referenced contract to

obtain the higher limit for various reasons, including: The view that

there is no discernible reason for the restriction in the first place;

the belief that it provides a negative impact on liquidity in the

physical delivery contract; and the view that it prevents commercials

from taking advantage of the higher limit given their need to have some

exposure in a physical delivery referenced contract during the spot

month.\648\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\648\ E.g., CL-FIA-59595 at 3 and 11; CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 9-10;

CL-MFA-59606 at 5 and 19-20; CL-AIMA-59618 at 2; CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611

at 31; CL-BG Group-59656 at 7; CL-BG Group-59937 at 5-6; CL-COPE-

59662 at 23; CL-NGSA-59673 at 38-39; CL-NGSA-59941 at 3-4; CL-

IECAssn-59957 at 9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter said that the conditional spot month position limit

exemption for gold is not supported by sufficient research, could

decouple the cash-settled contract from the physical-delivery contract,

and could lead to lower liquidity in the physical-delivery contract and

higher price volatility.\649\ Several commenters opposed a spot-month

position limit for cash-settled contracts that is higher than the limit

for physical-delivery contracts for various reasons including: The

higher limit does not address the problem of excessive speculation; the

higher limit would reduce liquidity in the physical-delivery contract;

and the conditional limit is not restrictive enough and should include

a restriction on holdings of the physical commodity as had been

proposed in vacated part 151.\650\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\649\ CL-WGC-59558 at 4.

\650\ E.g., CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 7; CL-AFR-59711 at 2; CL-A4A-

59714 at 3; CL-Working Group-59693 at 59-60; CL-IECA-59713 at 3-4;

CL-Better Markets-60401 at 17-18; CL-CME-59971 at 3; CL-CME-60307 at

4-5; CL-CME-60406 at 2; CL-CMOC-59720 at 3-6; CL-APGA-59722 at 8;

CL-OSEC-59972 at 7; CL-RF-60372 at 3; CL-IATP-59701 at 5; CL-IATP-

59704 at 6; CL-IATP-60394 at 2; CL-NGFA-59681 at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters expressed the view that a market participant

holding a trade option position, which presumably would be considered a

physical delivery referenced contract, should not be precluded from

using the conditional spot-month limit exemption because trade options

are functionally equivalent to a forward contract and the conditional

exemption does not restrict holding forwards.\651\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\651\ E.g., CL-FIA-59595 at 20; CL-COPE-59662 at 23; CL-EEI-

EPSA-60926 at 7, CL-EEI-Sup-60386 at 3-4; CL-Working Group-59693 at

59-60.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter supported the conditional spot month limit exemption

provided that the Commission modifies its proposal to allow

independently-operated subsidiaries to hold positions in physical-

delivery contracts if the subsidiary engages in separate and

independent trading activities, shares no employees, and is not jointly

directed in its trading activity with other subsidiaries by the parent

company.\652\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\652\ CL-SEMP-59926 at 4-6; CL-SEMP-60384 at 5-6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some commenters supported the continuation of the practice of DCMs

separately establishing and maintaining their own conditional spot

month limits and not aggregating cash-settled limits across exchanges

and the OTC market, arguing that the resultant aggregated limit will be

unnecessarily restrictive and result in lower liquidity and increased

volatility.\653\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\653\ E.g., CL-IECAssn-59713 at 30-31; CL-ICE-59966 at 4-5; CL-

ICE-59962 at 4-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some commenters expressed the view that the filing of daily Form

504 reports to satisfy the conditional spot month limit exemption was

burdensome, and recommended less frequent reporting such as monthly

reports \654\ or no reporting at all.\655\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\654\ CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 10; CL-ICE-59669 at 7.

\655\ CL-COPE-59662 at 24.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Two exchanges which currently permit a conditional spot month limit

exemption, CME and ICE, have each submitted several comments regarding

the exemption, some in direct response to the other exchange's

comments. This back-and-forth nature of the disagreement surrounding

the conditional spot month limit exemption has been significant and, on

many aspects of the previously proposed exemption, the comments have

been in direct opposition to each other. CME submitted a comment letter

in response to the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal that

reiterated its belief that the conditional limit would drain liquidity

from the physical-delivery contract; \656\ ICE responded that nothing

in the natural gas market has suggested that the physical-delivery

contract has been harmed.\657\ ICE noted that CME's current conditional

limit benefits CME's own cash-settled natural gas contracts; \658\ CME

responded that it opposes any conditional limit framework even though

such opposition could work ``to the detriment of CME Group's commercial

interests in certain of its cash-settled markets.'' \659\ CME stated

its belief that the CEA necessitates ``one-to-one limit treatment and

similar exemptions'' for both physical-delivery and cash-settled

contracts within a particular commodity; \660\ ICE suggested that

removing or reducing the conditional limit would ``disrupt present

market practice.'' \661\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\656\ CL-CME-60926 at 4.

\657\ CL-ICE-61009 at 1.

\658\ Id.

\659\ CL-CME-61008 at 2.

\660\ Id. at 3.

\661\ CL-ICE-61009 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ICE also submitted a series of charts, using CFTC Commitment of

Traders

[[Page 96778]]

Report data, illustrating the opposite: That spot-month open interest

and volume in the physical-delivery contract (the NYMEX NG) have

actually increased since the introduction of the conditional spot month

limit.\662\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\662\ Id. at 3-6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

CME stated its opposition to the conditional limits ``as a matter

of statutory law,'' opining that CEA section 4(b) does not allow the

imposition of the conditional limit.\663\ CME believes that the

conditional limit contained in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal ``contravenes Congress's intent behind the statutory

`comparability' requirement'' in multiple ways, and that neither ICE

nor the Commission has ``addressed these aspects of [CEA section

4(b)].'' \664\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\663\ CL-CME-61008 at 2-3. CEA section 4(b)(1)(B)(ii)(1) imposes

requirements on a foreign board of trade (``FBOT'') as a condition

of providing U.S. persons direct access to the electronic trading

and order-matching systems of the FBOT with respect to a contract

that settles against any price of one or more contracts listed for

trading on a registered entity. Such FBOT must adopt position limits

for contract(s) that are ``comparable'' to the position limits

adopted by the registered entity for the contract(s) against which

the FBOT contract settles. 7 U.S.C. 6(b)(1)(B)(ii)(1), codified in

17 CFR 48.8(c)(1)(ii)(A).

\664\ CL-CME-61008 at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ICE replied that the Commission ``has no basis to modify the

current conditional limit level'' because the markets ``have functioned

efficiently and effectively'' and the Commission should not ``change

the status quo.'' \665\ ICE continued that the conditional limit of

five times the physical-delivery contract's spot-month limit ``appears

to be arbitrary and likely insufficient'' and opined that the

Commission has not indicated how it arrived at that figure or how such

a level ``strikes the right balance between supporting liquidity and

diminishing undue burdens.'' \666\ ICE concluded that the conditional

exemption ``must be maintained at no less than the current levels.''

\667\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\665\ CL-ICE-61022 at 2.

\666\ Id.

\667\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: After taking into consideration all the

comments it received regarding the conditional spot-month limit

exemption, the Commission is reproposing the conditional spot-month

limit exemption in natural gas markets only. The Commission believes

the volume of comments regarding the conditional spot-month limit

exemption indicates the importance of careful and thoughtful analysis

prior to finalizing policy with respect to conditional spot-month limit

exemptions in other cash-settled referenced contracts. In particular,

the considerations may vary, and should be considered in relation to

the particular commodity at issue. As such, the Commission believes it

is prudent to proceed cautiously in expanding the conditional spot-

month limit exemption beyond the natural gas markets where it is

currently employed. The Commission encourages exchanges and/or market

participants who believe that the Commission should extend the

conditional spot-month limit exemption to additional commodities to

petition the Commission to issue a rule pursuant to Sec. 13.2 of the

Commission's regulations.\668\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\668\ 17 CFR 13.2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With respect to natural gas cash-settled referenced contracts, the

reproposed rules allow market participants to exceed the position limit

provided that such positions do not exceed 10,000 contracts and the

person holding or controlling such positions does not hold or control

positions in the spot-month natural gas physical-delivery referenced

contract (NYMEX NG). Persons relying upon this exemption must file Form

504 during the spot month.\669\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\669\ See infra discussion of part 19 and Form 504, below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission observes that the conditional exemption level of

10,000 contracts is equal to five times the federal natural gas spot-

month position limit level of 2,000 contracts. The conditional

exemption level is also equal to the sum of the current conditional

exemption levels for each of the NYMEX HH contract and the ICE NG LD1

contract. The Commission believes the level of 10,000 contracts

provides relief for market participants who currently may hold or

control 5,000 contracts in each of these two cash-settled natural gas

futures contracts and an unlimited number of cash-settled swaps, while

still furthering the purposes of the Dodd-Frank Act's amendments to CEA

section 4a.

The Commission is proposing the fixed figure of 10,000 contracts,

rather than the variable figure of five times the spot-month position

limit level, in order to avoid confusion in the event NYMEX were to set

its spot-month limit in the physical-delivery NYMEX NG contract at a

level below 2,000 contracts.

The Commission provides, for informational purposes, summary

statistical information that it considered in declining to extend the

conditional spot-month limit exemption beyond the natural gas

referenced contract. The four tables below present the number of unique

persons that held positions in commodity derivative contracts greater

than or equal to the specified levels, as reported to the Commission

under the large trader reporting systems for futures and swaps, for the

period July 1, 2014 to June 30, 2016. The table also presents counts of

unique reportable persons, whether reportable under part 17 (futures

and future option contracts) or under part 20 (swap contracts). The

method the Commission used to analyze this large trader data is

discussed above, under Sec. 150.2.

The four tables group commodities only for convenience of

presentation. In each table, the term ``25% DS'' means 25 percent of

the deliverable supply as estimated by the exchange listing the core

referenced futures contract and verified as reasonable by the

Commission. Similarly, ``15% DS'' means 15 percent of estimated

deliverable supply. An asterisk (``*'') means that fewer than four

unique persons were reported. ``CME proposal'' means the level

recommended by the CME Group for the spot-month limit. MGEX submitted a

recommended spot-month limit level that is slightly less than 25

percent of estimated deliverable supply but did not affect the reported

number of unique persons; no other exchange recommended a spot-month

level of less than 25 percent of estimated deliverable supply.

For the first group of commodities, there was no unique person in

the cash-settled referenced contracts whose position would have

exceeded 25 percent of the exchange's estimated deliverable supply.

Moreover, no unique person held a position in the cash-settled

referenced contracts that would have exceeded the reproposed spot-month

limits discussed under Sec. 150.2, above, that are lower than 25

percent of the exchange's estimated deliverable supply.

[[Page 96779]]

Table III-B-21--CME Group and MGEX Agricultural Contracts

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Number of unique persons >= Number of reportable persons

level in market

Position limit ---------------------------------------------------------------

Core-referenced futures contract Basis of spot-month level level Spot month

Spot month physical Spot month All months

cash settled delivery only

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Corn...................................... CME proposal................ 600 0 36 1,050 2,606

(CBOT current limit 600).................. 25% DS...................... 900 0 20 .............. ..............

Oats...................................... CME proposal................ 600 0 0 33 173

(CBOT current limit 600).................. 25% DS...................... 900 0 0 .............. ..............

Soybeans.................................. CME proposal................ 600 0 22 929 2,503

(CBOT current limit 600).................. 25% DS...................... 1,200 0 14 .............. ..............

Soybean Meal.............................. CME proposal................ 720 0 14 381 978

(CBOT current limit 720).................. 25% DS...................... 2,000 0 (*) .............. ..............

Soybean Oil............................... CME proposal................ 540 0 21 397 1,034

(CBOT current limit 540).................. 25% DS...................... 3,400 0 0 .............. ..............

Wheat (CBOT).............................. CME proposal................ 600 0 11 444 1,867

(CBOT current limit 600).................. 25% DS...................... 1,000 0 6 .............. ..............

Wheat (MGEX).............................. Parity w/CME proposal....... 600 0 (*) 102 342

(MGEX current limit 600).................. Approx. 25% DS.............. 1,000 0 (*) .............. ..............

Wheat (KCBT).............................. CME proposal................ 600 0 4 250 718

(KCBT current limit 600).................. 25% CBOT DS................. 1,000 0 (*) .............. ..............

25% DS...................... 3,000 0 (*) .............. ..............

Rough Rice................................ CME proposal................ 600 0 0 91 281

(CBOT current limit 600).................. 25% DS...................... 2,300 0 0 .............. ..............

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

For the second group of commodities, there was no unique person in

the cash-settled referenced contracts whose position would have

exceeded 25 percent of the exchange's estimated deliverable supply or,

in the case of Live Cattle, the current exchange limit level of 450

contracts. Moreover, other than in the Sugar No. 11 contract, no unique

person held a position in the cash-settled referenced contracts that

would have exceeded 15 percent of the exchange's estimated deliverable

supply. For informational purposes, the table also shows for Live

Cattle that no unique person held a position in the cash-settled

referenced contracts that would have exceeded 60 percent of the

exchange's current spot-month limit of 450 contracts.\670\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\670\ The Commission notes that 60 percent of the 450 contract

spot-month limit is analogous to the counts presented for 15 percent

of estimated deliverable supply. That is, 60 percent of 25 percent

equals 15 percent.

Table III-B-22--Other Agricultural Contracts and ICE Futures U.S. Softs

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Number of unique persons >= Number of unique persons in

level market

Position limit ---------------------------------------------------------------

Core-referenced futures contract Basis of spot-month level level Spot month

Spot month physical Spot month All months

cash settled delivery only

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Cotton No. 2.............................. 15% DS...................... 960 0 (*) 122 1,000

(ICE current limit 300)................... 25% DS...................... 1,600 0 0 .............. ..............

Cocoa..................................... 15% DS...................... 3,300 0 0 164 682

(ICE current limit 1,000)................. 25% DS...................... 5,500 0 0 .............. ..............

Coffee.................................... 15% DS...................... 1,440 0 (*) 336 1,175

(ICE current limit 500)................... 25% DS...................... 2,400 0 (*) .............. ..............

Orange Juice.............................. 15% DS...................... 1,680 0 0 38 242

(ICE current limit 300)................... 25% DS...................... 2,800 0 0 .............. ..............

Live Cattle............................... 60% Current Limit........... 225 0 33 616 1,436

(CME current limit 450)................... Current limit *............. 450 0 0 .............. ..............

Sugar No. 11.............................. 15% DS...................... 13,980 (*) 10 443 874

(ICE current limit 5,000)................. 25% DS...................... 23,300 0 (*) .............. ..............

Sugar No. 16.............................. 15% DS...................... 4,200 0 0 12 22

(ICE current limit 1,000)................. 25% DS...................... 7,000 0 0 .............. ..............

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

For the third group of energy commodities, there were a number of

unique persons in the cash-settled referenced contracts whose position

would have exceeded 25 percent of the exchange's estimated deliverable

supply. For energy commodities other than natural gas, there were fewer

than 20 unique persons that had cash-settled positions in excess of the

reproposed spot-month limit levels, each based on 25 percent of

deliverable supply, as discussed above under Sec. 150.2. However, for

natural gas referenced contracts, 131 unique persons had cash-settled

positions in excess of the reproposed spot-month limit level of 2,000

contracts. As can be observed in the table below, only 20 unique

persons had cash-settled referenced contract positions that would have

exceeded the

[[Page 96780]]

reproposed natural gas conditional spot-month limit level of 10,000

contracts. Thus, a conditional spot-month limit exemption in natural

gas referenced contracts potentially would provide relief to a

substantial number of market participants, each of whom did not have a

position that was extraordinarily large in relation to other traders'

positions in cash-settled referenced contracts.

Table III-B-23--Energy Contracts

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Nunber of unique persons >= Number of unique persons in

level market

Position limit ---------------------------------------------------------------

Core-referenced futures contract Basis of spot-month level level Spot month

Spot month physical Spot month All months

cash settled delivery only

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Crude Oil, Light Sweet (WTI).............. CME proposal *.............. 6,000 19 8 1,773 2,673

(NYMEX current limit...................... 25% DS...................... 10,400 16 (*) .............. ..............

3,000 contracts).......................... 50% DS...................... 20,800 (*) 0 .............. ..............

Gasoline Blendstock (RBOB)................ CME proposal................ 2,000 23 14 463 837

(NYMEX current limit...................... 25% DS...................... 6,800 (*) 0 .............. ..............

1,000 contracts).......................... 50% DS...................... 13,600 0 0 .............. ..............

Natural Gas............................... 25% DS...................... 2,000 131 16 1,400 1,846

(NYMEX current limit...................... 50% DS...................... 4,000 77 (*) .............. ..............

1,000 contracts).......................... Current single exchange 5,000 65 (*) .............. ..............

conditional spot-month

limit exemption.

Conditional spot-month limit 10,000 20 0 .............. ..............

exemption.

ULSD (HO)................................. CME proposal................ 2,000 24 11 470 760

(NYMEX current limit...................... 25% DS...................... 2,900 15 5 .............. ..............

1,000 contracts).......................... 50% DS...................... 5,800 5 0 .............. ..............

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

* For WTI, CME Group recommended a step-down spot-month limit of 6,000/5,000/4,000 contracts in the last three days of trading.

For the fourth group of metal commodities, there were a few unique

persons in the cash-settled referenced contracts whose position would

have exceeded the reproposed levels of the spot-month limits, based on

the CME Group's recommended levels, as discussed above under Sec.

150.2. However, there were fewer than 20 unique persons that had cash-

settled positions in excess of the reproposed spot-month limit levels

for metal commodities; this is in marked contrast to the 131 unique

persons who had cash-settled positions in excess of the reproposed

spot-month limit for natural gas contracts. The Commission, in

consideration of the distribution of unique persons holding positions

in cash-settled metal commodity contracts across the 24 calendar months

of its analysis, particularly in platinum,\671\ is of the view that the

spot-month limit level, as discussed above under Sec. 150.2, and

without a conditional spot-month limit exemption, is within the range

of acceptable limit levels that, to the maximum extent practicable, may

achieve the statutory policy objectives in CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\671\ As can be observed in the open interest table discussed

under Sec. 150.2, above, the Commission notes that open interest in

cash-settled platinum contracts was markedly lower in the second 12-

month review period (year 2), than in the first 12-month review

period (year 1).

Table III-B-24--Metal Contracts (COMEX Division of NYMEX)

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Number of unique persons >= Number of unique persons in

level market

Position limit ---------------------------------------------------------------

Core-referenced futures contract Basis of spot-month level level Spot month

Spot month physical Spot month All months

cash settled delivery only

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Copper.................................... CME proposal................ 1,000 0 (*) 493 1,457

(current limit 1,000)..................... 25% DS...................... 1,100 0 (*) .............. ..............

Gold...................................... CME proposal................ 6,000 (*) (*) 518 1,557

(current limit 3,000)..................... 25% DS...................... 11,200 0 0 .............. ..............

Palladium................................. CME proposal................ 100 6 14 164 580

(current limit 100)....................... 25% DS...................... 900 0 0 .............. ..............

Platinum.................................. CME proposal................ 500 13 (*) 235 842

(current limit 500)....................... 25% DS...................... 900 10 (*) .............. ..............

50% DS...................... 1,800 (*) 0 .............. ..............

Silver.................................... CME proposal................ 3,000 0 0 311 1,023

(current limit 1,500)..................... 25% DS...................... 5,600 0 0 .............. ..............

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96781]]

e. Proposed Recordkeeping and Special Call Requirements--Sec. 150.3(g)

and Sec. 150.3(h)

Proposed Rules: As proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, Sec. 150.3(g) specifies recordkeeping requirements for

persons who claim any exemption set forth in Sec. 150.3. Persons

claiming exemptions under previously proposed Sec. 150.3 must maintain

complete books and records concerning all details of their related

cash, forward, futures, options and swap positions and transactions.

Furthermore, such persons must make such books and records available to

the Commission upon request under previously proposed Sec. 150.3(h),

which would preserve the ``special call'' rule set forth in current

Sec. 150.3(b). This ``special call'' rule would have required that any

person claiming an exemption under Sec. 150.3 must, upon request,

provide to the Commission such information as specified in the call

relating to the positions owned or controlled by that person; trading

done pursuant to the claimed exemption; the commodity derivative

contracts or cash market positions which support the claim of

exemption; and the relevant business relationships supporting a claim

of exemption.

The Commission noted that the previously proposed rules concerning

detailed recordkeeping and special calls are designed to help ensure

that any person who claims any exemption set forth in Sec. 150.3 can

demonstrate a legitimate purpose for doing so.\672\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\672\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75741.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission did not receive any comments on

the recordkeeping provisions in Sec. 150.3(g) as proposed in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal. With respect to previously

proposed Sec. 150.3(h), one commenter opposed the ``special call''

provision because, in the commenter's opinion, it is ``too passive.''

The commenter advocated, instead, a revision requiring persons claiming

an exemption to maintain books and records on an ongoing basis and

provide information to the Commission on a periodic and automatic

basis, because even if the Commission lacked staff and resources to

review the submitted material in real-time, Commission staff would have

detailed historical data for use in compliance audits. This commenter

stated that since required records are likely to be kept in an

electronic format, the more frequent reporting requirement would not be

considered burdensome.\673\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\673\ CL-O SEC-59972 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission believes the previously

proposed recordkeeping and ``special call'' provisions in Sec.

150.3(g) and Sec. 150.3(h), respectively, are sufficient to limit

abuse of exemptions without causing undue burdens on market

participants. The Commission is reproposing these sections generally as

proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal. The Commission

is clarifying, in reproposed Sec. 150.3(g)(2), that the bona fides of

the pass-through swap counterparty may be determined at the time of the

transaction or, alternatively, at such later time that the counterparty

can show the swap position to be a bona fide hedging position. As

previously proposed, such bona fides could only be determined at the

time of the transaction, as opposed to at a later time.

D. Sec. 150.5--Exchange-Set Speculative Position Limits and Parts 37

and 38

1. Background

As discussed above, the Commission currently sets and enforces

position limits pursuant to its broad authority under CEA section

4a,\674\ and does so only with respect to certain enumerated

agricultural products.\675\ As the Commission explained above and in

the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,\676\ section 735 of the

Dodd-Frank Act amended section 5(d)(1) of the CEA to explicitly provide

that the Commission may mandate the manner in which DCMs must comply

with the core principles.\677\ However, Congress limited the exercise

of reasonable discretion by DCMs only where the Commission has acted by

regulation.\678\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\674\ CEA section 4a, as amended by the Dodd-Frank Act, provides

the Commission with broad authority to set position limits,

including an extension of its position limits authority to swaps

positions. 7 U.S.C. 6a. See supra discussion of CEA section 4a.

\675\ The position limits on these agricultural contracts are

referred to as ``legacy'' limits, and the listed commodities are

referred to as the ``enumerated'' agricultural commodities. This

list of enumerated agricultural contracts includes Corn (and Mini-

Corn), Oats, Soybeans (and Mini-Soybeans), Wheat (and Mini-wheat),

Soybean Oil, Soybean Meal, Hard Red Spring Wheat, Hard Winter Wheat,

and Cotton No. 2. See 17 CFR 150.2.

\676\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75748.

\677\ Specifically, the Dodd-Frank Act amended DCM core

principle 1 to include the condition that ``[u]nless otherwise

determined by the Commission by rule or regulation,'' boards of

trade shall have reasonable discretion in establishing the manner in

which they comply with the core principles. See CEA section

5(d)(1)(B); 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(1)(B).

\678\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75748.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Dodd-Frank Act also amended DCM core principle 5. As amended,

DCM core principle 5 requires that, for any contract that is subject to

a position limitation established by the Commission pursuant to CEA

section 4a(a), the DCM ``shall set the position limitation of the board

of trade at a level not higher than the position limitation established

by the Commission.'' \679\ Moreover, the Dodd-Frank Act added CEA

section 5h to provide a regulatory framework for Commission oversight

of SEFs.\680\ Under SEF core principle 6, which parallels DCM core

principle 5, Congress required that SEFs that are trading facilities

adopt for each swap, as is necessary and appropriate, position limits

or position accountability.\681\ Furthermore, Congress required that,

for any contract that is subject to a Federal position limit under CEA

section 4a(a), the SEF shall set its position limits at a level no

higher than the position limitation established by the Commission.\682\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\679\ See CEA section 5(d)(5)(B) (amended 2010), 7 U.S.C.

7(d)(5)(B).

\680\ See CEA section 5h, 7 U.S.C. 7b-3.

\681\ CEA section 5h(f)(6), 7 U.S.C. 7b-3(f)(6); see also

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75748.

\682\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. Summary

As explained in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,\683\ to

implement the authority provided by section 735 of the Dodd-Frank Act

amendments to CEA sections 5(d)(1) and 5h(f)(1), the Commission

evaluated its pre-Dodd-Frank Act regulations and approach to oversight

of DCMs, which had consisted largely of published guidance and

acceptable practices, with the aim of updating them to conform to the

new Dodd-Frank Act regulatory framework. Based on that review, and

pursuant to the authority given to the Commission in amended sections

5(d)(1) and 5h(f)(1) of the CEA, which permit the Commission to

determine, by rule or regulation, the manner in which boards of trade

and SEFs, respectively, must comply with the core principles,\684\ the

Commission in its December 2013 Position Limit Proposal, proposed

several updates to Sec. 150.5 to promote compliance with DCM core

principle 5 and SEF core principle 6 governing position limitations or

accountability.\685\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\683\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75754.

\684\ See CEA sections 5(d)(1)(B) and 5h(f)(1)(B); 7 U.S.C.

7(d)(1)(B) and 7b-3(f)(1)(B).

\685\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75754.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

First, the Commission proposed amendments to the provisions of

Sec. 150.5 to include SEFs and swaps. Second, the Commission proposed

to codify rules and revise acceptable practices for

[[Page 96782]]

compliance with DCM core principle 5 and SEF core principle 6 within

amended Sec. 150.5(a) for contracts subject to the federal position

limits set forth in Sec. 150.2. Third, the Commission proposed to

codify rules and revise guidance and acceptable practices for

compliance with DCM core principle 5 and SEF core principle 6 within

amended Sec. 150.5(b) for contracts not subject to the federal

position limits set forth in Sec. 150.2. Fourth, the Commission

proposed to amend Sec. 150.5 to implement uniform requirements for

DCMs and SEFs that are trading facilities relating to hedging

exemptions across all types of contracts, including those that are

subject to federal limits. Fifth, the Commission proposed to require

DCMs and SEFs that are trading facilities to have aggregation policies

that mirror the federal aggregation provisions.\686\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\686\ Id. Aggregation exemptions can be used, in effect, as a

way for a trader to acquire a larger speculative position. As noted

in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

believes that it is important that the aggregation rules set out, to

the extent feasible, ``bright line'' standards that are capable of

easy application by a wide variety of market participants while not

being susceptible to circumvention. December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, 78 FR at 75754, n. 660.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition to the changes to the provisions of Sec. 150.5

proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

also noted that it had, in response to the Dodd-Frank Act, previously

published several earlier rulemakings that pertained to position

limits, including in a notice of proposed rulemaking to amend part 38

to establish regulatory obligations that each DCM must meet in order to

comply with section 5 of the CEA, as amended by the Dodd-Frank

Act.\687\ In addition, as noted above, the Commission had published a

proposal to replace part 150 with a proposed part 151, which was later

finalized before being vacated.\688\ In the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, the Commission pointed out that as it was originally

proposed, Sec. 38.301 would require each DCM to comply with the

requirements of part 151 as a condition of its compliance with DCM core

principle 5.\689\ When the Commission finalized Dodd-Frank updates to

part 38 in 2012, it adopted a revised version of Sec. 38.301 with an

additional clause that requires DCMs to continue to meet the

requirements of part 150 of the Commission's regulations--the current

position limit regulations--until such time that compliance would be

required under part 151.\690\ At that time, the Commission explained

that this clarification would ensure that DCMs were in compliance with

the Commission's regulations under part 150 during the interim period

until the compliance date for the new position limits regulations of

part 151 would take effect.\691\ The Commission further explained that

its new regulation, Sec. 38.301, was based on the Dodd-Frank

amendments to the DCM core principles regime, which collectively would

provide that DCM discretion in setting position limits or position

accountability levels was limited by Commission regulations setting

position limits.\692\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\687\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75753; see also Core Principles and Other Requirements for

Designated Contract Markets, 75 FR 80572 (Dec. 22, 2010) (``2010

Part 38 Proposed Rule'').

\688\ See supra discussion under Part I.B (discussing the

Commission's adoption of part 151,subsequently vacated).

\689\ 2010 Part 38 Proposed Rule at 80585.

\690\ Core Principles and Other Requirements for Designated

Contract Markets, 77 FR 36611, 36639 (Jun. 19, 2012) (``Final Part

38 Rule''). The Commission mandated in final Sec. 38.301 that, in

order to comply with DCM core principle 5, a DCM must ``meet the

requirements of parts 150 and 151 of this chapter, as applicable.''

See also 17 CFR 38.301.

\691\ Final Part 38 Rule at 36639.

\692\ Id. (discussing the Dodd-Frank amendments to the DCM core

principles); see also CEA sections 5(d)(1) and 5(d)(5), as amended

by the Dodd-Frank Act.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Similarly, as the Commission noted in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal,\693\ when in 2010 the Commission proposed to adopt a

regulatory scheme applicable to SEFs, it proposed to require that SEFs

establish position limits in accordance with the requirements set forth

in part 151 of the Commission's regulations under proposed Sec.

37.601.\694\ The Commission pointed out that it had revised Sec.

37.601 in the SEF final rulemaking, to state that until such time that

compliance was required under part 151, a SEF may refer to the guidance

and/or acceptable practices in Appendix B of part 37 to demonstrate to

the Commission compliance with the requirements of SEF core principle

6.\695\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\693\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75753.

\694\ Core Principles and Other Requirements for Swap Execution

Facilities, 76 FR 1214 (Jan. 7, 2011) (``SEF final rulemaking'').

Current Sec. 37.601 provides requirements for SEFs that are trading

facilities to comply with SEF core principle 6 (Position Limits or

Accountability), while the guidance to SEF core principle 6

(Position Limits or Accountability) in Appendix B to part 37, cites

to part 151.

\695\ Core Principles and Other Requirements for Swap Execution

Facilities, 78 FR 33476 (June 4, 2013). Current Sec. 37.601

provides requirements for SEFs that are trading facilities to comply

with SEF core principle 6 (Position Limits or Accountability).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission noted

that in light of the District Court vacatur of part 151, the Commission

proposed to amend Sec. 37.601 to delete the reference to vacated part

151. The amendment would have instead required that SEFs that are

trading facilities meet the requirements of part 150, which would be

comparable to the DCM requirement, since, as proposed in the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, Sec. 150.5 would apply to commodity

derivative contracts, whether listed on a DCM or on a SEF that is a

trading facility. At the same time, the Commission would have amended

Appendix B to part 37, which provides guidance on complying with core

principles, both initially and on an ongoing basis, to maintain SEF

registration.\696\ Since the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

required that SEFs that are trading facilities meet the requirements of

part 150, the proposed amendments to the guidance regarding SEF core

principle 6 reiterated that requirement. The Commission noted that for

SEFs that are not trading facilities, to whom core principle 6 would

not be applicable under the statutory language, part 150 should have

been considered as guidance.\697\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\696\ Appendix B to Part 37--Guidance on, and Acceptable

Practices in, Compliance with Core Principles.

\697\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75753.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

More recently, the Commission issued the 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal to revise and amend certain parts of the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal based on comments received on the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal,\698\ viewpoints expressed during a

Roundtable on Position Limits,\699\ several Commission advisory

committee meetings that each provided a focused forum for participants

to discuss some aspects of the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal,\700\ and information obtained in the course of ongoing

Commission

[[Page 96783]]

review of SEF registration applications.\701\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\698\ Comments on the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal are

accessible on the Commission's Web site at http://comments.cftc.gov/PublicComments/CommentList.aspx?id=1436.

\699\ A transcript of the June 19, 2014 Roundtable on Position

Limits is available on the Commission's Web site at http://www.cftc.gov/idc/groups/public/@swaps/documents/dfsubmission/dfsubmission_061914-trans.pdf.

\700\ Information regarding the December 9, 2014 and September

22, 2015 meetings of the Agricultural Advisory Committee, sponsored

by Chairman Massad, is accessible on the Commission's Web site at

http://www.cftc.gov/About/CFTCCommittees/AgriculturalAdvisory/aac_meetings. Information regarding February 26, 2015 and the July

29, 2015 meetings of the Energy & Environmental Markets Advisory

Committee (``EEMAC''), sponsored by Commission Giancarlo, is

accessible on the Commission's Web site at http://www.cftc.gov/About/CFTCCommittees/EnergyEnvironmentalMarketsAdvisory/emac_meetings.

\701\ Added by the Dodd-Frank Act, section 5h(a) of the CEA, 7

U.S.C. 7b-3, requires SEFs to register with the Commission. See

generally ``Core Principles and Other Requirements for Swap

Execution Facilities,'' 78 FR 33476 (Aug. 5, 2013). Information

regarding the SEF application process is available on the

Commission's Web site at http://www.cftc.gov/IndustryOversight/TradingOrganizations/SEF2/sefhowto.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed to delay for exchanges that lack access to sufficient swap

position information the requirement to establish and monitor position

limits on swaps at this time by: (i) Adding Appendix E to part 150 to

provide guidance regarding Sec. 150.5; and (ii) revising guidance on

DCM Core Principle 5 and SEF Core Principle 6 that corresponds to that

proposed guidance regarding Sec. 150.5.\702\ In addition, the

Commission in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal proposed

new alternative processes for DCMs and SEFs to recognize certain

positions in commodity derivative contracts as non-enumerated bona fide

hedges or enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedges, as well as to

exempt from federal position limits certain spread positions, in each

case subject to Commission review.\703\ Moreover, the Commission

proposed that DCMs and SEFs could recognize and exempt from exchange

position limits certain non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions,

enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedges, and certain spread

positions.\704\ To effectuate the latter proposals, the Commission

proposed amendments to Sec. 150.3 and new Sec. 150.9, 150.10, and

150.11, as well as corresponding amendments to Sec. 150.5(a)(2) and

150.5(b)(5).\705\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\702\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38459-62. See also DCM Core Principle 5, Position Limitations or

Accountability (contained in CEA section 5(d)(5), 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(5))

and SEF Core Principle 6, Position Limits or Accountability

(contained in CEA section 5h(f)(6), 7 U.S.C. 7b-3(f)(6)).

\703\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38467-76 (providing for recognition of certain positions in

commodity derivative contracts as non-enumerated bona fide hedges),

at 38480-81 (providing for recognition of certain positions in

commodity derivatives contracts as enumerated anticipatory bona fide

hedges); and at 38476-80 (providing for exemptions from federal

position limits for certain spread positions).

\704\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38482.

\705\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38504-13. The 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal did not

address the changes to Sec. Sec. 37.601 or 38.301 proposed in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. Discussion

As discussed in greater detail below, the Commission has determined

to repropose Sec. 150.5 largely as proposed in the December 2013

Position Limit Proposal and as revised in the 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal. In addition, the Commission has determined to

repropose the previously proposed amendments to Sec. 37.601 and Sec.

38.301.\706\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\706\ The Commission did not receive any comments regarding the

proposed changes to Sec. 37.601 and Sec. 38.301.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some changes were made to Sec. 150.5 in response to concerns

raised by commenters; other changes to the reproposed regulation are to

conform to changes made in other sections. For example, in reproposing

Sec. 150.5(b)(1) and (2), the Commission has determined to make

certain changes to the acceptable practices for establishing the levels

of individual non-spot or all-months combined position limits for

futures and future option contracts that are not subject to federal

limits. The changes to reproposed Sec. 150.5(b)(1) and (2) correspond

to changes to reproposed Sec. 150.2(e)(4)(iv) discussed above, for

establishing the levels of individual non-spot or all-months combined

positions limits for futures and future option contracts that are

subject to federal limits. Moreover, several non-substantive changes

were made in response to commenter requests to provide greater

clarity.\707\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\707\ See the removal of the provisions regarding excluded

commodities from Sec. 150.5(b) and their placement in a new section

(c), which addresses only excluded commodities. In addition to the

reorganization of the excluded commodity provisions, changes were

made to those provisions to track changes made in other sections or

paragraphs and to address concerns raised by commenters and

confusion that became apparent in the comment letters.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The essential features of the changes to reproposed Sec. 150.5 are

discussed below.

a. Treatment of Swaps on SEFs and DCMs

i. December 2013 Position Limits Proposal. As explained above, CEA

section 4a(a)(5), as amended by the Dodd-Frank Act, requires federal

position limits for swaps that are ``economically equivalent'' to

futures and options that are subject to mandatory position limits under

CEA section 4a(a)(2).\708\ The CEA also requires in SEF Core Principle

6 that a SEF that is a trading facility: (i) Set its exchange-set limit

on swaps at a level no higher than that of the federal position limit;

and (ii) monitor positions established on or through the SEF for

compliance with the federal position limit and any exchange-set

limit.\709\ Similarly, for all contracts subject to a federal position

limit, including swaps, DCMs, under DCM Core Principle 5, must set a

position limit no higher than the federal limit.\710\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\708\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75681-5 (the Commission interpret the statute to mandate that the

Commission impose limits on futures, options, and swaps, in

agricultural and exempt commodities).

\709\ CEA section 5h(f)(6)(B), 7 U.S.C. 7b-3(f)(6) (SEF Core

Principle 6B). The Commission codified SEF Core Principle 6, added

by the Dodd-Frank Act, in Sec. 37.600 of its regulations, 17 CFR

37.600. See generally Core Principles and Other Requirements for

Swap Execution Facilities, 78 FR 33476, 33533-34 (June 4, 2013).

\710\ CEA section 5(d)(5), 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(5) (DCM Core Principle

5). The Commission codified DCM Core Principle 5, as amended by the

Dodd-Frank Act, in Sec. 38.300 of its regulations, 17 CFR 38.300.

See Core Principles and Other Requirements for Designated Contract

Markets, 77 FR 36612, 36639 (June 19, 2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal specified that federal

position limits would apply to referenced contracts,\711\ whether

futures or swaps, regardless of where the futures or swaps positions

are established.\712\ Consistent with DCM Core Principle 5 and SEF Core

Principle 6, the Commission at Sec. 150.5(a)(1) previously proposed

that for any commodity derivative contract that is subject to a

speculative position limit under Sec. 150.2, a DCM or SEF that is a

trading facility shall set a speculative position limit no higher than

the level specified in Sec. 150.2.'' \713\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\711\ Under the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

``referenced contracts'' are defined as futures, options,

economically equivalent swaps, and certain foreign board of trade

contracts, in physical commodities, and are subject to the proposed

federal position limits. See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

78 FR at 75825.

\712\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75826

(previously proposed Sec. 150.2).

\713\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75754-8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Comments Received to December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

Several comment letters on previously proposed Sec. 150.5

recommended that the Commission not require SEFs to establish position

limits.\714\ Two noted that because SEF participants may use more than

one derivatives clearing organization (``DCO''), a SEF may not know

when a position has been offset.\715\ Further, during the ongoing SEF

registration process,\716\ a number of

[[Page 96784]]

persons applying to become registered as SEFs told the Commission that

they lack access to information that would enable them to knowledgeably

establish position limits or monitor positions.\717\ As the Commission

observed in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, this

information gap would also be a concern for DCMs in respect of

swaps.\718\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\714\ CL-CMC-59634 at 14-15, CL-FIA-60392 at 10. One comment

letter stated that SEFs should be exempt from the requirement to set

positions limits because SEFs are in the early stages of development

and could be harmed by limits that restrict liquidity. CL-ISDA/

SIFMA-59611 at 35.

\715\ CL-CMC-59634 at 14-15, CL-FIA-60392 at 10.

\716\ Under CEA section 5h(a)(1), no person may operate a

facility for trading swaps unless the facility is registered as a

SEF or DCM. 7 U.S.C. 7b-3(a)(1). A SEF must comply with core

principles, including Core Principle 6 regarding position limits, as

a condition of registration. CEA section 5h(f)(1), 7 U.S.C. 7b-

3(f)(1).

\717\ For example, in a submission to the Commission under part

40 of the Commission's regulations, BGC Derivative Markets, L.P.

states that ``[t]he information to administer limits or

accountability levels cannot be readily ascertained. Position limits

or accountability levels apply market-wide to a trader's overall

position in a given swap. To monitor this position, a SEF must have

access to information about a trader's overall position. However, a

SEF only has information about swap transactions that take place on

its own Facility and has no way of knowing whether a particular

trade on its facility adds to or reduces a trader's position. And

because swaps may trade on a number of facilities or, in many cases,

over-the-counter, a SEF does not know the size of the trader's

overall swap position and thus cannot ascertain whether the trader's

position relative to any position limit. Such information would be

required to be supplied to a SEF from a variety of independent

sources, including SDRs, DCOs, and market participants themselves.

Unless coordinated by the Commission operating a centralized

reporting system, such a data collection requirement would be

duplicative as each separate SEF required reporting by each

information source.'' BGC Derivative Markets, L.P., Rule Submission

2015-09 (Oct. 6, 2015).

\718\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38460.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iii. 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal

As explained above, in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, the Commission proposed to temporarily delay for DCMs and

SEFs that are trading facilities, which lack access to sufficient swap

position information, the requirement to establish and monitor position

limits on swaps by: (i) Adding Appendix E to part 150 to provide

guidance regarding Sec. 150.5; and (ii) revising guidance on DCM Core

Principle 5 and SEF Core Principle 6 that corresponds to that guidance

regarding Sec. 150.5.\719\ At that time, the Commission acknowledged

that, if an exchange does not have access to sufficient data regarding

individual market participants' open swap positions, then it cannot

effectively monitor swap position limits, and expressed its belief that

most exchanges do not have access to sufficient swap position

information to effectively monitor swap position limits.\720\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\719\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38459-62.

\720\ Id. at 38460. The Commission acknowledged that one SEF

that may have access to sufficient swap position information by

virtue of systems integration with affiliates that are CFTC

registrants and shared personnel. This SEF requires that all of its

listed swaps be cleared on an affiliated DCO, which reports to an

affiliated SDR. 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38459; see also 38460, n. 32.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In this regard, the Commission expressed its belief that an

exchange would have or could have access to sufficient swap position

information to effectively monitor swap position limits if, for

example: (1) It had access to daily information about its market

participants' open swap positions; or (2) it knows that its market

participants regularly engage in large volumes of speculative trading

activity, including through knowledge gained in surveillance of heavy

trading activity, that would cause reasonable surveillance personnel at

an exchange to inquire further about a market participant's intentions

\721\ or total open swap positions.\722\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\721\ Id. at 38460-61. For instance, heavy trading activity

might cause an exchange to ask whether a market participant is

building a large speculative position or whether the heavy trading

activity is merely the result of a market participant making a

market across several exchanges.

\722\ Id. at 38461. See 17 CFR 45.3, 45.4, and 45.10. See

generally CEA sections 4r (reporting and recordkeeping for uncleared

swaps) and 21 (swap data repositories), 7 U.S.C. 6r and 24a,

respectively. The Commission also observed that, unlike futures

contracts, which are proprietary to a particular DCM and typically

clear at a single DCO affiliated with the DCM, swaps in a particular

commodity are not proprietary to any particular trading facility or

platform. Market participants may execute swaps involving a

particular commodity on or subject to the rules of multiple

exchanges or, in some circumstances, OTC. Further, under the

Commission regulations, data with respect to a particular swap

transaction may be reported to any swap data repository (``SDR'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission noted that it is possible that an exchange could

obtain an indication of whether a swap position established on or

through a particular exchange is increasing a market participant's swap

position beyond a federal or exchange-set limit, if that exchange has

data about some or all of a market participant's open swap position

from the prior day and combines it with the transaction data from the

current day, to obtain an indication of the market participant's

current open swap position.\723\ The indication would alert the

exchange to contact the market participant to inquire about that

participant's total open swap position.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\723\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38461. The Commission observed, moreover, by way of example, that

part 20 swaps data is a source that identifies a market

participant's reported open swap positions from the prior trading

day. So an exchange with access to part 20 swaps date could use it

to add to any swap positions established on or through that exchange

during the current trading day to get an indication of a potential

position limit violation. Nonetheless, that market participant may

have conducted other swap transactions in the same commodity, away

from a particular exchange, that reduced its swap position. Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission expressed its belief that although this indication

would not include the market participant's activity transacted away

from that particular exchange, such monitoring would comply with CEA

section 5h(f)(6)(B)(ii). However, the Commission observed that

exchanges generally do not currently have access to a data source that

identifies a market participant's reported open swap positions from the

prior trading day. With only the transaction data from a particular

exchange, it would be impracticable, if not impossible, for that

exchange to monitor and enforce position limits for swaps.\724\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\724\ Id. The Commission also noted that an exchange could

theoretically obtain swap position data directly from market

participants, for example, by requiring a market participant to

report its swap positions, as a condition of trading on the

exchange. The Commission observed, however, that it is unlikely that

a single exchange would unilaterally impose a swaps reporting regime

on market participants. Id. at 38461, n. 36. The Commission

abandoned the approach of requiring market participants to report

futures positions directly to the Commission many years ago. Id.;

see also Reporting Requirements for Contract Markets, Futures

Commission Merchants, Members of Exchanges and Large Traders, 46 FR

59960 (Dec. 8, 1981). Instead, the Commission and DCMs rely on a

large trader reporting system where futures positions are reported

by futures commission merchants, clearing members and foreign

brokers. See generally part 19 of the Commission's regulations, 17

CFR part 19. See also, for example, the discussion of an exchange's

large trader reporting system in the Division of Market Oversight

Rule Enforcement Review of the Chicago Mercantile Exchange and the

Chicago Board of Trade, July 26, 2013, at 24-7, available at http://www.cftc.gov/idc/groups/public/@iodcms/documents/file/rercmecbot072613.pdf.

Further, as noted above, exchanges do not have authority to

demand swap position data from derivative clearing organizations or

swap data repositories; nor do exchanges have general authority to

demand market participants' swap position data from clearing members

of DCOs or swap dealers (as the Commission does under part 20). 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38461, n. 36.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also acknowledged in the 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal that it has neither

[[Page 96785]]

required any DCO \725\ or SDR \726\ to provide such swap data to

exchanges,\727\ nor provided any exchange with access to swaps data

collected under part 20 of the Commission's regulations.\728\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\725\ Core principle M for DCOs addresses information sharing

for risk management purposes, but does not address information

sharing with exchanges for other purposes. CEA section 5b(c)(2)(M),

7 U.S.C. 7a-1(c)(2)(M), and Sec. 39.22, 17 CFR 39.22. The

Commission has access to DCO information relating to trade and

clearing details under Sec. 39.19, 17 CFR 39.19, as is necessary to

conduct its oversight of a DCO. However, the Commission has not used

its general rulemaking authority under CEA section 8a(5), 7 U.S.C.

12a(5), to require DCOs to provide registered entities access to

swap information, although the Commission could impose such a

requirement by rule. CEA section 5b(c)(2)(A)(i), 7 U.S.C. 7a-

1(c)(2)(A)(i).

\726\ An SDR has a duty to provide direct electronic access to

the Commission, or a designee of the Commission who may be a

registered entity (such as an exchange). CEA section 21(c)(4), 7

U.S.C. 24a(c)(4). See 76 FR 54538 at 54551, n. 141 (Sept. 1, 2011).

However, the Commission has not designated any exchange as a

designee of the Commission for that purpose. Further, the Commission

has not used its general rulemaking authority under CEA section

8a(5), 7 U.S.C. 12a(5), to require SDRs to provide registered

entities (such as exchanges) access to swap information, although

the Commission could impose such a requirement by rule. CEA section

21(a)(3)(A)(ii), 7 U.S.C. 24a(a)(3)(A)(ii). For purposes of

comparison, the Securities and Exchange Commission (``SEC'') noted

with regard to security-based swaps when it finalized its rules

implementing its similar provision (which it described as a

``statutory requirement that security-based SDRs conditionally

provide data to certain regulators and other authorities''), ``that

one or more self-regulatory organizations potentially may seek such

access under this provision.'' Access to Data Obtained by Security-

Based Swap Data Repositories, 81 FR 60585, 50588 (Sept. 2, 2016).

The SEC estimated that ``up to 30 domestic entities potentially

might enter into such MOUs or other arrangements, reflecting the

nine entities specifically identified by statute or the final rules,

and up to 21 additional domestic governmental entities or self-

regulatory organizations that may seek access to such data.'' Id. at

60593.

\727\ As the Commission noted in the 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal, even if such information were to be made available

to exchanges, the swaps positions would need to be converted to

futures-equivalent positions for purposes of monitoring position

limits on a futures-equivalent basis. 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38461. See also December 2013 Positions

Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 78 FR75825 (describing the proposed

definition of futures-equivalent); 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal at 38461 (describing amendments to that proposed

definition).

\728\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38461. The part 20 swaps data is reported in futures equivalents,

but does not include data specifying where reportable positions in

swaps were established.

The Commission stated in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal that it preliminarily had decided not to use the swaps data

then reported under part 20 for purposes of setting the initial

levels of the proposed single and all-months-combined positions

limits due to concerns about the reliability of such data. December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75533. The Commission also

stated that it might use part 20 swaps data should it determine such

data to be reliable, in order to establish higher initial levels in

a final rule. Id. at 75734.

However, as the Commission noted in the 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal, the quality of part 20 swaps data does

appear to have improved somewhat since the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, although some reports continue to have significant

errors. The Commission stated that it is possible that it will be

able to rely on swap open positions data, given adjustments for

obvious errors (e.g., data reported based on a unit of measure, such

as an ounce, rather than a futures equivalent number of contracts),

to establish higher initial levels of non-spot month limits in a

final rule. 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38461.

Moreover, the quality of the data regarding reportable positions

in swaps may have improved enough for the Commission to be able to

rely on it when monitoring market participants' compliance with the

proposed federal position limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission stated that in light of the foregoing, it was

proposing a delay in implementation of exchange-set limits for swaps

only, and only for exchanges without sufficient swap position

information.\729\ After consideration of the circumstances described

above, and in an effort to accomplish the policy objectives of the

Dodd-Frank Act regulatory regime, including to facilitate trade

processing of any swap and to promote the trading of swaps on

SEFs,\730\ the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal amended the

guidance in the appendices to parts 37 and 38 of the Commission's

regulations regarding SEF core principle 6 and DCM core principle 5,

respectively. According to the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, the revised guidance clarified that an exchange need not

demonstrate compliance with SEF core principle 6 or DCM core principle

5 as applicable to swaps until it has access to sufficient swap

position information, after which the guidance would no longer be

applicable.\731\ For clarity, the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal included the same guidance in a new Appendix E to proposed

part 150 in the context of the Commission's proposed regulations

regarding exchange-set position limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\729\ Id.

\730\ See, e.g., CEA sections 5h(b)(1)(B) and 5h(e), 7 U.S.C.

7b-3(b)(1)(B) and 7b-3(e), respectively.

\731\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38461. The Commission stated that once the guidance was no longer

applicable, a DCM or a SEF would be required to file rules with the

Commission to implement the relevant position limits and demonstrate

compliance with Core Principle 5 or 6, as appropriate. The

Commission also noted that, for the same reasons regarding swap

position data discussed above in respect of CEA section 5h(f)(6)(B),

the guidance proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal would temporarily relieve SEFs of their statutory

obligation under CEA section 5h(f)(6)(A). Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Although the Commission proposed to temporarily relieve exchanges

that do not now have access to sufficient swap position information

from having to set position limits on swaps, it also noted that nothing

in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal would prevent an

exchange from nevertheless establishing position limits on swaps, while

stating that it does seem unlikely that an exchange would implement

position limits before acquiring sufficient swap position information

because of the ensuing difficulty of enforcing such a limit. The

Commission expressed its belief that providing delay for those

exchanges that need it both preserved flexibility for subsequent

Commission rulemaking and allowed for phased implementation of

limitations on swaps by exchanges, as practicable.\732\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\732\ As the Commission noted above, although the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal proposed position limits

relief to SEFs and to DCMs in regards to swaps, it did not propose

any alteration to the definition of referenced contract (including

economically equivalent swaps) that was proposed in December 2013.

See also December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75825.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Additionally, the Commission observed that courts have authorized

relieving regulated entities of their statutory obligations where

compliance is impossible or impracticable,\733\ and noted its view that

it would be impracticable, if not impossible, for an exchange to

monitor and enforce position limits for swaps with only the transaction

data from that particular exchange.\734\ The Commission expressed its

belief that, accordingly, it was reasonable to delay implementation of

this discrete aspect of position limits, only with respect to swaps

position limits, and only for exchanges that lacked access to

sufficient swap position information. This approach, the Commission

believed, would further the policy objectives of the Dodd-Frank Act

regulatory regime, including the facilitation of trade processing of

swaps

[[Page 96786]]

and the promotion of trading swaps on SEFs. Finally, the Commission

noted that while this approach would delay the requirement for certain

exchanges to establish and monitor exchange-set limits on swaps, under

the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, federal position limits

would apply to swaps that are economically equivalent to futures

contracts subject to federal position limits.\735\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\733\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38462. See also id. at n. 44 (See, e.g., Ass'n of Irritated

Residents v. EPA, 494 F.3d 1027, 1031 (D.C. Cir. 2007) (allowing

regulated entities to enter into consent agreements with EPA--

without notice and comment--that deferred prosecution of statutory

violation until such time as compliance would be practicable);

Catron v. County Bd. Of Commissioners v. New Mexico Fish & Wildlife

Serv., 75 F.3d 1429, 1435 (10th Cir.1966) (stating that `Compliance

with [the National Environmental Protection Act] is excused when

there is a statutory conflict with the agency's authorizing

legislation that prohibits or renders compliance impossible.' '')).

The Commission noted, moreover, that ``it is axiomatic that courts

will avoid reading statutes to reach absurd or unreasonable

consequences'' (citing, as an example, Griffin v. Oceanic

Contractors, Inc., 458 U.S. 564 (1982)), and pointed out that to

require an exchange to monitor position limits on swaps, when it

currently has extremely limited visibility into a market

participant's swap position, was, arguably, absurd and certainly

appeared unreasonable. 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal,

81 FR at 38462, n. 44.

\734\ Id. at 38462.

\735\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iv. Comments Received to 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal

Several commenters addressed the Commission's proposed guidance on

exchange-set limits on swaps.\736\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\736\ E.g., CL-FIA-60937 at 1,6; CL-WMBA-60945 at 1-2; CL-AFR-

60953 at 2; CL-RER2-60962 at 1; CL-Better Markets-60928 at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Regarding insufficient swap data, four commenters agreed that SEFs

and DCMs lack access to sufficient swap position data to set exchange

limits on swaps, and as such, the commenters support the Commission's

decision to delay the position limit monitoring requirements for SEFs

that are trading facilities and DCMs.\737\ In addition, one commenter

recommended that the Commission provide notice for public comments

prior to implementing any determination that a DCM or SEF has access to

sufficient swap position data to set exchange limits on swaps.\738\

Further, two commenters recommended that the Commission identify a

plan, to address the insufficient data issues, that goes beyond

``simply exempting affected exchanges.'' \739\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\737\ CL-FIA-60937 at 2, 5-6; CL-WMBA-60945 at 1-2; CL-AFR-60953

at 2; CL-RER2-60962 at 1.

\738\ CL-FIA-60937 at 2, 5-6.

\739\ CL-AFR-60953 at 2; CL-RER2-60962 at 1.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

On the other hand, one commenter asserted that there should be no

delay in implementing position limits for swaps because, according to

the commenter, the Commission has access to sufficient swap data it

needs to implement position limits.\740\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\740\ CL-Better Markets-60928 at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

v. Commission Determination

The Commission has determined to repropose the treatment of swaps

and SEFs as previously proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal for the reasons given above.\741\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\741\ For purposes of clarity, the Commission is reproposing the

guidance to provide for a temporarily delay for DCMs and SEFs that

are trading facilities that lack access to sufficient swap position

information the requirement to establish and monitor position limits

on swaps by reproposing as proposed in the 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal: (i) Appendix E to Part 150 to provide

guidance regarding reproposed Sec. 150.5; and (ii) guidance on DCM

Core Principle 5 and SEF Core Principle 6 that corresponds to that

reproposed guidance regarding Sec. 150.5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Regarding the comments recommending that the Commission identify a

plan to address the insufficient data issues that goes beyond ``simply

exempting affected exchanges,'' the Commission may consider granting

DCMs and SEFs, as self-regulatory organizations, access to part 20 data

or SDR data at a later time.

In addition, regarding the comment that the Commission already has

access to sufficient swap data in order to implement position limits,

the Commission points out that it proposes to adopt a phased approach

to updating its position limits regime.\742\ In conjunction with this

phased approach, the Commission believes that at this time it should

limit its implementation of position limits for swaps to those that are

referenced contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\742\ As the Commission noted in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, ``a phased approach will (i) reduce the potential

administrative burden by not immediately imposing position limits on

all commodity derivative contracts in physical commodities at once,

and (ii) facilitate adoption of monitoring policies, procedures and

systems by persons not currently subject to positions limits (such

as traders in swaps that are not significant price discovery

contracts).'' 78 FR 75680.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Sec. 150.5(a)--Requirements and Acceptable Practices for Commodity

Derivative Contracts That Are Subject to Federal Position Limits

i. December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

Several requirements were added to Sec. 150.5(a) in the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal to which a DCM or SEF that is a trading

facility must adhere when setting position limits for contracts that

are subject to the federal position limits listed in Sec. 150.2.\743\

Previously proposed Sec. 150.5(a)(1) specified that a DCM or SEF that

lists a contract on a commodity that is subject to federal position

limits must adopt position limits for that contract at a level that is

no higher than the federal position limit.\744\ Exchanges with cash-

settled contracts price-linked to contracts subject to federal limits

would also be required to adopt those limit levels.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\743\ As discussed above, 17 CFR 150.2 provides limits for

specified agricultural contracts in the spot month, individual non-

spot months, and all-months-combined.

\744\ As previously proposed, Sec. 150.5(a)(1) is in keeping

with the mandate in core principle 5 as amended by the Dodd-Frank

Act. See CEA section 5(d)(1)(B), 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(1)(B). SEF core

principle 6 parallels DCM core principle 5. Compare CEA section

5h(f)(5), 7 U.S.C. 7b-3(f)(5) with CEA section 5(d)(5), 7 U.S.C.

7(d)(5).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Previously proposed Sec. 150.5(a)(3) would have required a DCM or

SEF that is a trading facility to exempt from speculative position

limits established under Sec. 150.2 a swap position acquired in good

faith in any pre-enactment and transition period swaps, in either case

as defined in Sec. 150.1.\745\ However, previously proposed Sec.

150.5(a)(3) would allow a person to net such a pre-existing swap with

post-effective date commodity derivative contracts for the purpose of

complying with any non-spot-month speculative position limit. Under

previously proposed Sec. 150.5(a)(4)(i), a DCM or SEF that is a

trading facility must require compliance with spot month speculative

position limits for pre-existing positions in commodity derivatives

contracts other than pre-enactment or transition period swaps, while

previously proposed Sec. 150.5(a)(4)(ii) provides that a non-spot-

month speculative position limit established under Sec. 150.2 would

not apply to any commodity derivative contract acquired in good faith

prior to the effective date of such limit.\746\ As proposed in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, however, such a pre-existing

commodity derivative contract position must be attributed to the person

if the person's position is increased after the effective date of such

limit.\747\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\745\ The Commission previously proposed to exercise its

authority under CEA section 4a(a)(7) to exempt pre-Dodd-Frank and

transition period swaps from speculative position limits (unless the

trader elected to include such a position to net with post-effective

date commodity derivative contracts). Such a pre-existing swap

position would be exempt from initial spot month speculative

position limits. December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75756, n. 674.

\746\ See previously proposed 150.5(a)(4)(ii). See also CEA

section 22(a)(5)(B), added by section 739 of the Dodd-Frank Act.

\747\ See previously proposed 150.5(a)(4)(ii). Notwithstanding

any pre-existing exemption adopted by a DCM or SEF that applied to

speculative position limits in non-spot months, under the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, a person holding pre-existing

commodity derivative contracts (except for pre-existing swaps as

described above) would be required to comply with spot month

speculative position limits. However, nothing in previously proposed

Sec. 150.5(a)(4) would override the exclusion of pre-Dodd-Frank and

transition period swaps from speculative position limits. December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75756, n. 675.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Under the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

had proposed to require DCMs and SEFs that are trading facilities to

have aggregation polices that mirror the federal aggregation

provisions.\748\ Therefore,

[[Page 96787]]

previously proposed Sec. 150.5(a)(5) required DCMs and SEFs that are

trading facilities to have aggregation rules that conformed to the

uniform standards listed in Sec. 150.4.\749\ As noted in the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, aggregation policies that vary from

exchange to exchange would increase the administrative burden on a

trader active on multiple exchanges, as well as increase the

administrative burden on the Commission in monitoring and enforcing

exchange-set position limits.\750\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\748\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75754,

75756. As noted above, aggregation exemptions can be used, in

effect, as a way for a trader to acquire a larger speculative

position, and the Commission believes that it is important that the

aggregation rules set out, to the extent feasible, ``bright line''

standards that are capable of easy application by a wide variety of

market participants while not being susceptible to circumvention.

The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal also noted that ``. . .

position aggregation exemptions, if not uniform with the

Commission's requirements, may serve to permit a person to obtain a

larger position on a particular DCM or SEF than would be permitted

under the federal limits. For example, if an exchange were to grant

an aggregation position to a corporate person with aggregate

positions above federal limits, that exchange may permit such person

to be treated as two or more persons. The person would avoid

violating exchange limits, but may be in violation of the federal

limits. The Commission believes that a DCM or SEF, consistent with

its responsibilities under applicable core principles, may serve an

important role in ensuring compliance with federal positions limits

and thereby protect the price discovery function of its market and

guard against excessive speculation or manipulation. In the absence

of uniform . . . position aggregation exemptions, DCMs or SEFs may

not serve that role. December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR

at 75754. See also 2016 Final Aggregation Rule (regarding amendments

to 150.4, which were approved by the Commission in a separate

release concurrently with this reproposed rulemaking).

\749\ Under the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 17 CFR

150.5(g) would be replaced with previously proposed Sec.

150.5(a)(5) which referenced 17 CFR 150.4 as the regulation

governing aggregation for contracts subject to federal position

limits.

\750\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75755.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A DCM or SEF that is a trading facility would have continued to be

free to enforce position limits that are more stringent that the

federal limits. The Commission clarified in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal that federal spot month position limits do not to apply

to physical-delivery contracts after delivery obligations are

established.\751\ Exchanges generally prohibit transfer or offset of

positions once long and short position holders have been assigned

delivery obligations. Previously proposed Sec. 150.5(a)(6) clarified

acceptable practices for a DCM or SEF that is a trading facility to

enforce spot month limits against the combination of, for example, long

positions that have not been stopped, stopped positions, and deliveries

taken in the current spot month.\752\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\751\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75756.

The Commission stated that, therefore, federal spot month position

limits do not apply to positions in physical-delivery contracts on

which notices of intention to deliver have been issued, stopped long

positions, delivery obligations established by the clearing

organization, or deliveries taken. Id. at 75756, n. 678.

\752\ Id. at 75756. The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

noted, for example, that an exchange might restrict a speculative

long position holder that otherwise would obtain a large long

position, take delivery, and seek to re-establish a large long

position in an attempt to corner a significant portion of the

deliverable supply or to squeeze shorts. Previously proposed Sec.

150.5(b)(9) set forth the same acceptable practices for contracts

not subject to federal limits. Id. at 75756, n. 679.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Comments Received to December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

Regarding Proposed Sec. 150.5(a)

One commenter recommended that exchanges be required to withdraw

their position accountability and position limit regimes in deference

to any federal limits and to conform their position limits to the

federal limits so that a single regime will apply across

exchanges.\753\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\753\ CL-DBCS-59569 at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Two commenters recommended that the Commission clarify that basis

contracts would be excluded from exchange-set limits in order to

provide consistency since such contracts are excluded from the

Commission's definition of referenced contract and thus are not subject

to Federal limits.\754\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\754\ CL-FIA-59595 at 41; CL-Nodal-59695 at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter recommended that DCMs and SEFs that are trading

facilities be given more discretion, particularly with respect to non-

referenced contracts, over aggregation requirements.\755\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\755\ CL-AMG-59709 at 2, 10-11.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iii. 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal

In the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed to amend Sec. 150.5(a)(2) as it was proposed in the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal.\756\ The amendments would permit

exchanges to recognize non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions under

Sec. 150.9, to grant spread exemptions from federal limits under Sec.

150.10, and to recognize certain enumerated anticipatory bona fide

hedging positions under Sec. 150.11, each as contained in the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal. In conjunction with those

amendments, the Commission proposed corresponding changes to Sec.

150.3 and Sec. 150.5(a)(2).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\756\ As noted above, the changes to Sec. 150.3 as proposed in

the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal would have provided for

recognition of enumerated bona fide hedge positions, but would not

have exempted any spread positions from federal limits. For any

commodity derivative contracts subject to federal position limits,

Sec. 150.5(a)(2) as proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal would have established requirements under which exchanges

could recognize exemptions from exchange-set position limits,

including hedge exemptions and spread exemptions. See also 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38482.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For example, Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(i), as proposed in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal, required that any exchange rules providing

for hedge exemptions for commodity derivatives contracts subject to

federal position limits conform to the definition of bona fide hedging

position as defined in the amendments to Sec. 150.1 contained in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal. But because the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal incorporated the bona fide

hedging position definition and provided for spread exemptions in

150.3(a)(1)(i), the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal proposed

instead to cite to Sec. 150.3 in Sec. 150.5(a)(2).\757\ Similarly,

the application process provided for in Sec. 150.5(a)(2) was amended

to conform to the requirement in proposed Sec. 150.10 and Sec. 150.11

that exchange rules providing for exemptions for commodity derivatives

contracts subject to federal position limits require that traders

reapply on at least an annual basis. In addition, the changes to Sec.

150.5(a)(2) clarified that exchanges may deny an application, or limit,

condition, or revoke any exemption granted at any time.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\757\ As proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(i) provides that a DCM or SEF that is a

trading facility ``may grant exemptions from any speculative

position limits it sets under paragraph (a)(1) of this section,

provided that such exemptions conform to the requirements specified

in Sec. 150.3.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Similarly, the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal amended

previously proposed Sec. 150.5(b) to require that exchange rules

provide for recognition of a non-enumerated bona fide hedge ``in a

manner consistent with the process described in Sec. 150.9(a).''

Addressing the granting of spread exemptions for contracts not subject

to federal position limits, the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal integrates in the standards of CEA section 4a(a)(3), providing

that exchanges should take into account those standards when

considering whether to grant spread exemptions. Finally, the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal clarified that for excluded

commodities, the exchange can grant certain exemptions provided under

paragraphs Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(i) and (b)(5)(ii) in addition to the risk

management exemption previously proposed in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal.\758\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\758\ See Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(D) (stating that for excluded

commodities, a DCM or SEF may grant, pursuant to rules submitted to

the Commission, ``the exemptions under paragraphs (b)(5)(i) and

(b)(5)(ii)(A) through (C)''). While the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal numbered the provisions applicable to excluded

commodities as Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(ii)(E), the 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal renumbered the provision as Sec.

150.5(b)(5)(ii)(D).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96788]]

iv. Comments Received on the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal

Regarding Sec. 150.5(a)

While comments were submitted on the 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal that addressed the proposed changes to the definitions

under Sec. 150.1, as well as to the proposed exchange processes for

recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedges and anticipatory hedges,

and for granting spreads exemptions under proposed Sec. Sec. 150.9,

150.11, and 150.10, respectively, all of which indirectly affect Sec.

150.5(a), very few comments specifically addressed Sec. 150.5(a).

Comments received on the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal

regarding the other sections are addressed in the discussions of those

sections.\759\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\759\ One example of an issue raised by several commenters

concerns the application procedures in Sec. Sec. 150.9(a)(4),

150.10(a)(4), and 150.11(a)(3), which requires market participants

to apply for recognition or an exemption in advance of exceeding the

limit. See, e.g., CL-FIA-60937 at 4, 13; CL-CME-60926 at 12; CL-ICE-

60929 at 11, 20-21; CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 10-11; CL-EEI-EPSA-60925

at 4; CL-ISDA-60931 at 13; and CL-CMC-60950 at 3. For example, ICE

requested the insertion of a provision for exchanges to recognize

exemptions retroactively due to ``unforeseen hedging needs,'' and

also stated that certain exchanges currently utilize a similar rule

and it is ``critical in reflecting commercial hedging needs that

cannot always be predicted in advance.'' CL-ICE-60929 at 11.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter urged the Commission to allow exchanges to maintain

their current authority to set speculative limits for both spot month

and all-months combined limits below federal limits to ensure that

convergence continues to occur.\760\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\760\ CL-NGFA-60941 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

While the Commission's retention of what is often referred to as

the five-day rule \761\ was included only in the revised definition of

bona fide hedging position under Sec. 150.1,\762\ several commenters

addressed the five-day rule in the context of Sec. 150.5 as proposed

in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal.\763\ According to

the commenters, the decision of whether to apply the five-day rule to a

particular contract should be delegated to the exchanges because the

exchanges are in the best position to evaluate facts and circumstances,

and different markets have different dynamics and needs.\764\ In

addition, one commenter requested that the Commission specifically

authorize exchanges to grant bona fide hedging position and spread

exemptions during the last five days of trading or less.\765\ Two

commenters suggested, as an alternative approach if the five-day rule

remains, that the Commission instead rely on tools available to

exchanges to address concerns, such as exchanges requiring gradual

reduction of the position (``step down'' requirements) or revoking

exemptions to protect the price discovery process in core referenced

futures contracts approaching expiration.\766\ Another commenter argued

that in spite of any five-day rule that is adopted, exchanges should be

allowed to recognize non-enumerated bona fide hedging exemptions during

the last five trading days for enumerated strategies that are otherwise

subject to the five-day rule and the discretion to grant exemptions for

hedging strategies that would otherwise be subject to the five-day

rule.\767\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\761\ The Commission's current definition of ``bona fide hedging

transactions and positions,'' under Sec. 1.3(z), applies the

``five-day rule'' in Sec. 1.3(z)(2) subsections (i)(B), (ii)(C),

(iii), and (iv). Under those sections of the ``five-day rule,'' no

such positions and transactions were maintained in the five last

days of trading. See Sec. 1.3(z).

\762\ As noted in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

(which did not change in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal), the Commission previously proposed to delete Sec. 1.3(z)

and replace it with a new definition in Sec. 150.1 of ``bona fide

hedging position.'' And, as noted above, the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal retained the five-day rule. The previously proposed

definition was built on the Commission's history and was grounded

for physical commodities in the new requirements of CEA section

4a(c)(2) as amended by the Dodd-Frank Act. December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75706.

\763\ E.g., CL-NCGA-ASA-60917 at 1-2; CL-CME-60926 at 14-15; CL-

ICE-60929 at 7-8; CL-ISDA-60931 at 11; CL-CCI-60935 at 3; CL-MGEX-

60936 at 4; CL-Working Group-60947 at 5, 7-9; CL-IECAssn-60949 at 7-

9; CL-CMC-60950 at 9-14; CL-NCC-ACSA-60972 at 2. No comments on the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal specifically addressed the

``five-day rule'' in the context of Sec. 150.5.

\764\ See, e.g, CL-ISDA-60931 at 10; CL-CCI-60935 at 3; CL-MGEX-

60936 at 11; CL-Working Group-60947 at 7-9.

\765\ CL-CMC-60950 at 11-12.

\766\ CL-Working Group-60947 at 8; CL-IECAssn-60949 at 7-9.

\767\ CL-CME-60926 at 6, 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One issue raised by several commenters \768\ that did not directly

address Sec. 150.5 concerns the application procedures in Sec. Sec.

150.9(a)(4), 150.10(a)(4), and 150.11(a)(3), which require market

participants to apply for recognition or an exemption in advance of

exceeding the limit.\769\ For example, one commenter requested the

insertion of a provision permitting exchanges to recognize exemptions

retroactively due to ``unforeseen hedging needs''; this commenter also

stated that certain exchanges currently utilize a similar rule and it

is ``critical in reflecting commercial hedging needs that cannot always

be predicted in advance.'' \770\ Another commenter requested that the

Commission allow exchanges to recognize a bona fide hedge exemption for

up to a five-day retroactive period in circumstances where market

participants need to exceed limits to address a sudden and unforeseen

hedging need.\771\ That commenter stated that CME and ICE currently

provide mechanisms for such recognition, which are used infrequently

but are nonetheless important. According to that commenter, ``[t]o

ensure that such allowances will not diminish the overall integrity of

the process, two effective safeguards under the current exchange-

administered processes could continue to be required. First, the

exchange rules could continue to require market participants making use

of the retroactive application to demonstrate that the applied-for

hedge was required to address a sudden and unforeseen hedging need. . .

. Second, if the emergency hedge recognition is not granted, the

exchange rules could continue to require the applicant to immediately

unwind its position and also deem the applicant to have been in

violation for any period in which its position exceeded the applicable

limits.\772\ While these comments address other sections, the

Commission will respond to these comments in explaining its reproposal

of Sec. 150.5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\768\ CL-FIA-60937 at 4, 13; CL-CME-60926 at 12; CL-ICE-60929 at

11, 20-21; CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 10-11; CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 4; CL-

ISDA-60931 at 13; and CL-CMC-60950 at 3.

\769\ See 150.9(a)(4) (requiring each person intending to exceed

position limits to, among other things, ``receive notice of

recognition from the designated contract market or swap execution

facility of a position as a non-enumerated bona fide hedge in

advance of the date that such position would be in excess of the

limits then in effect pursuant to section 4a of the Act.'')

\770\ CL-ICE-60929 at 11.

\771\ CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 10-11.

\772\ Id. at 11 (footnote omitted).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

v. Commission Determination Regarding Sec. 150.5(a)

The Commission has determined to repropose Sec. 150.5(a) as

proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal for the

reasons provided above with some changes, as detailed below.\773\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\773\ For example, the Commission is reproposing the following

sections as previously proposed without change for the reasons

provided above: Sec. 150.5(a)(1); Sec. 150.5(a)(3) (Pre-enactment

and transition period swap positions), Sec. 150.5(a)(4) (Pre-

existing positions), and Sec. 150.5(a)(6) (Additional acceptable

practices); no substantive comments were received regarding those

sections.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96789]]

Although the Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.5(a)(1), in

response to the comment that the exchanges should conform their

position limits to the federal limits so that a single position limit

and accountability regime apply across exchanges,\774\ the Commission

believes that exchanges may find it prudent in the course of monitoring

position limits to impose lower (that is, more restrictive) limit

levels. The flexibility for exchanges to set more restrictive limits is

granted in CEA section 4a(e), which provides that if an exchange

establishes limits on a contract, those limits shall be set at a level

no higher than the level of any limits set by the Commission. This

expressly permits an exchange to set lower limit levels than federal

limit levels. The reproposed rules track this statutory provision.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\774\ But see CL-NGFA-60941 at 2 (urging the Commission to allow

exchanges to maintain their current authority to set speculative

limits for both spot month and all-months combined limits below

federal limits).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For purposes of clarification in response to comments on the

treatment of basis contracts, the reproposed rules provide a singular

definition of ``referenced contract'' which, as stated by the

commenters, excludes ``basis contracts.'' For commodities subject to

federal limits under reproposed Sec. 150.2, the definition of

referenced contract remains the same for federal and exchange-set

limits and may not be amended by exchanges. An exchange could, but is

not required to, impose limits on any basis contract independently of

the federal limit for the commodity in question, but a position in a

basis contract with an independent, exchange-set limit would not count

for the purposes of the federal limit.\775\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\775\ The Commission notes that its singular definition of

``referenced contract'' that excludes ``basis contracts'' applies

not only to Sec. 150.5(a), but also to Sec. 150.5(b). Separately,

the Commission notes that in the future, it may determine to subject

basis contracts to a separate class limit in order to discourage

potential manipulation of the outright price legs of the basis

contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of comments regarding Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(i)

(Grant of exemption),\776\ as proposed in the 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal, the Commission is reproposing it with

modifications. Reproposed Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(i) provides that any

exchange may grant exemptions from any speculative position limits it

sets under paragraph Sec. 150.5(a)(1), provided that such exemptions

conform to the requirements specified in Sec. 150.3, and provided

further that any exemptions to exchange-set limits not conforming to

Sec. 150.3 are capped at the level of the applicable federal limit in

Sec. 150.2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\776\ See, e.g., CL-ICE-60929 at 2-4, 7-8; CL-Working Group-

60947 at 14.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that under the 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

exchanges could adopt position accountability at a level lower than the

federal limit (along with a position limit at the same level as the

federal limit); in such cases, the exchange would not need to grant

exemptions for positions no greater than the level of the federal

limit. Under the Reproposal, exchanges could choose, instead, to adopt

a limit lower than the federal limit; in such a case, the Commission

would permit the exchange to grant an exemption to the exchange's lower

limit, where such exemption does not conform to Sec. 150.3, provided

that such exemption to an exchange-set limit is capped at the level of

the federal limit. Such a capped exemption would basically have the

same effect as if the exchange set its speculative position limit at

the level of the federal limit, as required under DCM core principle

5(B) and SEF core principle 6(B)(1).\777\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\777\ 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(5) and 7 U.S.C. 7b-3(f)(6).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In regards to the five-day rule, the Commission notes that the

reproposed rule does not apply the prudential condition of the five-day

rule to non-enumerated hedging positions. The Commission considered the

recommendations that the Commission: Allow exchanges to recognize a

bona fide hedge exemption for up to a five-day retroactive period in

circumstances where market participants need to exceed limits to

address a sudden and unforeseen hedging need; specifically authorize

exchanges to grant bona fide hedge and spread exemptions during the

last five days of trading or less, and/or delegate to the exchanges for

their consideration the decision of whether to apply the five-day rule

to a particular contract after their evaluation of the particular facts

and circumstances. As reproposed, and as discussed in connection with

the definition of bona fide hedging position,\778\ the five-day rule

would only apply to certain positions (pass-through swap offsets,

anticipatory and cross-commodity hedges).\779\ However, in regards to

exchange processes under Sec. 150.9, Sec. 150.10, and Sec. 150.11,

the Commission would allow exchanges to waive the five-day rule on a

case-by-case basis.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\778\ See the discussion regarding the five-day rule in

connection with the definition of bona fide hedging position in the

discussion of Sec. 150.9 (Process for recognition of positions as

non-enumerated bona fide hedges).

\779\ See Sec. 150.1, definition of bona fide hedging position

sections (2)(ii)(A), (3)(iii), (4), and (5) (Other enumerated

hedging position). To provide greater clarity as to which bona fide

hedge positions the five-day rule applies, the reproposed rules

reorganize the definition.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition, the Commission proposes to amend Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(ii)

(Application for exemption). The reproposed rule would permit exchanges

to adopt rules that allow a trader to file an application for an

enumerated bona fide hedging exemption within five business days after

the trader assumed the position that exceeded a position limit.\780\

The Commission expects that exchanges will carefully consider whether

allowing such retroactive recognition of an enumerated bona fide

hedging exemption would, as noted by one commenter, diminish the

overall integrity of the process.\781\ In addition, the Commission

cautions exchanges to carefully consider whether to adopt in those

rules the two safeguards recommended by that commenter: (i) Requiring

market participants making use of the retroactive application to

demonstrate that the applied-for hedge was required to address a sudden

and unforeseen hedging need; and (ii) providing that if the emergency

hedge recognition was not granted, exchange rules would continue to

require the applicant to unwind its position in an orderly manner and

also would deem the applicant to have been in violation for any period

in which its position exceeded the applicable limits.\782\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\780\ The Reproposal includes a similar modification to Sec.

150.5(b)(5)(i).

\781\ CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 10-11.

\782\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Concerning the comment recommending greater discretion be given

DCMs and SEFs that are trading facilities with respect to aggregation

requirements, the Commission reiterates its belief in the benefits of

requiring exchanges to conform to the federal standards on aggregation,

including lower burden and less confusion for traders active on

multiple exchanges,\783\ efficiencies in administration for both

exchanges and the Commission, and the prevention of a ``race-to-the-

bottom'' wherein exchanges compete over lower standards. The Commission

notes that the provision regarding aggregation in reproposed Sec.

150.5(a)(5) incorporates by reference Sec. 150.4 and thus would, on a

continuing basis, reflect any changes made to the aggregation standard

provided in the section.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\783\ The Commission's belief is supported by requests from

multiple traders for industry-wide, standard aggregation

requirements.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96790]]

c. Sec. 150.5(b)--Requirements and Acceptable Practices for Commodity

Derivative Contracts That Are Not Subject to Federal Position Limits

i. December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

The Commission set forth in Sec. 150.5(b), as proposed in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, requirements and acceptable

practices that would generally update and reorganize the set of

acceptable practices listed in current Sec. 150.5 as they relate to

contracts that are not subject to the federal position limits,

including physical and excluded commodities.\784\ As discussed above,

the Commission also proposed to revise Sec. 150.5 to implement uniform

requirements for DCMs and SEFs that are trading facilities relating to

hedging exemptions across all types of commodity derivative contracts,

including those that are not subject to federal position limits. The

Commission further proposed to require DCMs and SEFs that are trading

facilities to have uniform aggregation polices that mirrored the

federal aggregation provisions for all types of commodity derivative

contracts, including for contracts that were not subject to federal

position limits.\785\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\784\ For position limits purposes, Sec. 150.1(k), as proposed

in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, would define

``physical commodity'' to mean any agricultural commodity, as

defined in 17 CFR 1.3, or any exempt commodity, as defined in

section 1a(20) of the Act. Excluded commodity is defined in section

1a(19) of the Act.

\785\ As Commission noted at that time, hedging exemptions and

aggregation policies that vary from exchange to exchange would

increase the administrative burden on a trader active on multiple

exchanges, as well as increase the administrative burden on the

Commission in monitoring and enforcing exchange-set position limits.

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75756.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The previously proposed revisions to DCM and SEF acceptable

practices generally concerned how to: (1) Set spot-month position

limits; (2) set individual non-spot month and all-months-combined

position limits; (3) set position limits for cash-settled contracts

that use a referenced contract as a price source; (4) adjust position

limit levels after a contract has been listed for trading; and (5)

adopt position accountability in lieu of speculative position

limits.\786\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\786\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75757.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For spot months under the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

for a derivative contract that was based on a commodity with a

measurable deliverable supply, previously proposed Sec.

150.5(b)(1)(i)(A) updated the acceptable practice in current Sec.

150.5(b)(1) whereby spot month position limits should be set at a level

no greater than one-quarter of the estimated deliverable supply of the

underlying commodity.\787\ Previously proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(1)(i)(A)

clarified that this acceptable practice for setting spot month position

limits would apply to any commodity derivative contract, whether

physical-delivery or cash-settled, that has a measurable deliverable

supply.\788\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\787\ As proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

Sec. 150.5(b)(1)(i)(A) was consistent with the Commission's

longstanding policy regarding the appropriate level of spot-month

limits for physical delivery contracts. These position limits would

be set at a level no greater than 25 percent of estimated

deliverable supply. The spot-month limits would be reviewed at least

every 24 months thereafter. The 25 percent formula narrowly targeted

the trading that may be most susceptible to, or likely to

facilitate, price disruptions. The goal for the formula, as noted in

the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal release, was to minimize

the potential for corners and squeezes by facilitating the orderly

liquidation of positions as the market approaches the end of trading

and by restricting swap positions that may be used to influence the

price of referenced contracts that are executed centrally. December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75756, n. 686.

\788\ The Commission noted in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal that, in general, the term ``deliverable supply'' means the

quantity of the commodity meeting a derivative contract's delivery

specifications that can reasonably be expected to be readily

available to short traders and saleable to long traders at its

market value in normal cash marketing channels at the derivative

contract's delivery points during the specified delivery period,

barring abnormal movement in interstate commerce. Previously

proposed Sec. 150.1 would define commodity derivative contract to

mean any futures, option, or swap contract in a commodity (other

than a security futures product as defined in CEA section 1a(45)).

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75756, n. 687.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For a derivative contract that was based on a commodity without a

measurable deliverable supply, the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal proposed for spot months, in Sec. 150.5(b)(1)(i)(B), to

codify as guidance that the spot month limit level should be no greater

than necessary and appropriate to reduce the potential threat of market

manipulation or price distortion of the contract's or the underlying

commodity's price.\789\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\789\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75757.

The Commission noted that this descriptive standard is largely based

on the language of DCM core principle 5 and SEF core principle 6.

The Commission does not suggest that an excluded commodity

derivative contract that is based on a commodity without a

measurable supply should adhere to a numeric formula in setting spot

month position limits. Id. at 75757, n. 688.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Under previously proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(1)(ii)(A), the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal preserved the existing acceptable

practice in current Sec. 150.5(b)(2) whereby individual non-spot or

all-months-combined levels for agricultural commodity derivative

contracts that are not subject to the federal limits should be no

greater than 1,000 contracts at initial listing. As then proposed, the

rule would also codify as guidance that the 1,000 contract limit should

be taken into account when the notional quantity per contract is no

larger than a typical cash market transaction in the underlying

commodity, or reduced if the notional quantity per contract is larger

than a typical cash market transaction. Additionally, the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal proposed in Sec. 150.5(b)(1)(ii)(A), to

codify for individual non-spot or all-months-combined, that if the

commodity derivative contract was substantially the same as a pre-

existing DCM or SEF commodity derivative contract, then it would be an

acceptable practice for the DCM or SEF that is a trading facility to

adopt the same limit as applies to that pre-existing commodity

derivative contract.\790\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\790\ The Commission noted that ``in this context,

`substantially the same' means a close economic substitute. For

example, a position in Eurodollar futures can be a close economic

substitute for a fixed-for-floating interest rate swap.'' December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75757.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In Sec. 150.5(b)(1)(ii)(B), the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal preserved the existing acceptable practice for individual non-

spot or all-months-combined in exempt and excluded commodity derivative

contracts, set forth in current Sec. 150.5(b)(3), for DCMs to set

individual non-spot or all-months-combined limits at levels no greater

than 5,000 contracts at initial listing.\791\ Previously proposed Sec.

150.5(b)(1)(ii)(B) would codify as guidance for exempt and excluded

commodity derivative contracts that the 5,000 contract limit should be

applicable when the notional quantity per contract was no larger than a

typical cash market transaction in the underlying commodity, or should

be reduced if the notional quantity per contract was larger than a

typical cash market transaction. Additionally, previously proposed

Sec. 150.5(b)(1)(ii)(B) would codify a new acceptable practice for a

DCM or SEF that is a trading facility to adopt the same limit as

applied to the pre-existing contract if the new commodity contract was

substantially the same as an existing contract.\792\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\791\ In contrast, 17 CFR 150.5(b)(3) lists this as an

acceptable practice for contracts for ``energy products and non-

tangible commodities.'' Excluded commodity is defined in CEA section

1a(19), and exempt commodity is defined CEA section 1a(20).

\792\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75757.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal provided in Sec.

150.5(b)(1)(iii)

[[Page 96791]]

that if a commodity derivative contract was cash-settled by referencing

a daily settlement price of an existing contract listed on a DCM or

SEF, then it would be an acceptable practice for a DCM or SEF to adopt

the same position limits as the original referenced contract, assuming

the contract sizes are the same. Based on its enforcement experience,

the Commission expressed the belief that limiting a trader's position

in cash-settled contracts in this way would diminish the incentive to

exert market power to manipulate the cash-settlement price or index to

advantage a trader's position in the cash-settled contract.\793\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\793\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75757. As

the Commission noted with respect to cash-settled contracts where

the underlying product is a physical commodity with limited

supplies, thus enabling a trader to exert market power (including

agricultural and exempt commodities), the Commission has viewed the

specification of speculative position limits to be an essential term

and condition of such contracts in order to ensure that they are not

readily susceptible to manipulation, which is the DCM core principle

3 requirement. Id. at 75757, n. 692.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In previously proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(2)(i)(A), the Commission was

updating the acceptable practices in current Sec. 150.5(c) for

adjusting limit levels for the spot month.\794\ For a derivative

contract that was based on a commodity with a measurable deliverable

supply, previously proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(2)(i)(A) maintained the

acceptable practice in current Sec. 150.5(c) to adjust spot month

position limits to a level no greater than one-quarter of the estimated

deliverable supply of the underlying commodity, but would apply this

acceptable practice to any commodity derivative contract, whether

physical-delivery or cash-settled, that has a measurable deliverable

supply. For a derivative contract that was based on a commodity without

a measurable deliverable supply, previously proposed Sec.

150.5(b)(2)(i)(B) would codify as guidance that the spot month limit

level should not be adjusted to levels greater than necessary and

appropriate to reduce the potential threat of market manipulation or

price distortion of the contract's or the underlying commodity's price.

In addition, the December 2013 Position Limit Proposal would have

codified in Sec. 150.5(b)(2)(i)(A) a new acceptable practice that spot

month limit levels be reviewed no less than once every two years.\795\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\794\ Id. at 75757.

\795\ Id. at 75757-58.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal explained that then

proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(2)(ii) maintained as an acceptable practice the

basic formula set forth in current Sec. 150.5(c)(2) for adjusting non-

spot-month limits at levels of no more than 10% of the average combined

futures and delta-adjusted option month-end open interest for the most

recent calendar year up to 25,000 contracts, with a marginal increase

of 2.5% of the remaining open interest thereafter.\796\ Previously

proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(2)(ii) would also maintain as an alternative

acceptable practice the adjustment of non-spot-month limits to levels

based on position sizes customarily held by speculative traders in the

contract.\797\ Previously proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(3) generally updated

and reorganized the existing acceptable practices in current Sec.

150.5(e) for a DCM or SEF that is a trading facility to adopt position

accountability rules in lieu of position limits, under certain

circumstances, for contracts that are not subject to federal position

limits. As noted in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, this

section would reiterate the DCM's authority, with conforming changes

for SEFs, to require traders to provide information regarding their

position when requested by the exchange.\798\ In addition, previously

proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(3) would codify a new acceptable practice for a

DCM or SEF to require traders to consent to not increase their position

in a contract if so ordered, as well as a new acceptable practice for a

DCM or SEF to require traders to reduce their position in an orderly

manner.\799\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\796\ Id. at 75758.

\797\ Id.

\798\ Id. Cf. 17 CFR 150.5(e)(2)-(3).

\799\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75758.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal would maintain under

Sec. 150.5(b)(3)(i) the acceptable practice for a DCM or SEF to adopt

position accountability rules outside the spot month, in lieu of

position limits, for an agricultural or exempt commodity derivative

contract that: (1) Had an average month-end open interest of 50,000 or

more contracts and an average daily volume of 5,000 or more contracts

during the most recent calendar year; (2) had a liquid cash market; and

(3) was not subject to federal limits in Sec. 150.2--provided,

however, that such DCM or SEF that is a trading facility should adopt a

spot month speculative position limit with a level no greater than one-

quarter of the estimated spot month deliverable supply.\800\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\800\ The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal noted that 17

CFR 150.5(e)(3) applies this acceptable practice to a ``tangible

commodity, including, but not limited to metals, energy products, or

international soft agricultural products.'' Id. at 75758. It also

cited to the comparison of the ``minimum open interest and volume

test'' in proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(3)(A) to that in current Sec.

150.5(e)(3). Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal would maintain in Sec.

150.5(b)(3)(ii)(A) the acceptable practice for a DCM or SEF to adopt

position accountability rules in the spot month in lieu of position

limits for an excluded commodity derivative contract that had a highly

liquid cash market and no legal impediment to delivery.\801\ For an

excluded commodity derivative contract without a measurable deliverable

supply, previously proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(3)(ii)(A) would codify an

acceptable practice for a DCM or SEF to adopt position accountability

rules in the spot month in lieu of position limits because there was

not a deliverable supply that was subject to manipulation. However, for

an excluded commodity derivative contract that had a measurable

deliverable supply, but that may not be highly liquid and/or was

subject to some legal impediment to delivery, previously proposed Sec.

150.5(b)(3)(ii)(A) set forth an acceptable practice for a DCM or SEF to

adopt a spot-month position limit equal to no more than one-quarter of

the estimated deliverable supply for that commodity, because the

estimated deliverable supply may be susceptible to manipulation.\802\

Furthermore, the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal in Sec.

150.5(b)(3)(ii) would remove the ``minimum open interest and volume''

test for excluded commodity derivative contracts generally.\803\

Finally, the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal would codify in

Sec. 150.5(b)(3)(ii)(B) an acceptable practice for a DCM or SEF to

adopt position accountability levels for an excluded commodity

derivative contract in lieu of position limits in the individual non-

spot month or all-months-combined.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\801\ Id.

\802\ Id.

\803\ Id. The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal pointed out

that the ``minimum open interest and volume'' test, as presented in

17 CFR 150.5(e)(1)-(2), need not be used to determine whether an

excluded commodity derivative contract should be eligible for

position accountability rules in lieu of position limits in the spot

month. Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal added in Sec.

150.5(b)(3)(iii) a new acceptable practice for an exchange to list a

new contract with position accountability levels in lieu of position

limits if that new contract was substantially the same as an existing

contract that was currently listed for trading on an exchange that had

already

[[Page 96792]]

adopted position accountability levels in lieu of position limits.\804\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\804\ See supra discussion of what is meant by ``substantially

the same'' in this context. See also December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, 78 FR at 75757, n. 690.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As previously proposed, Sec. 150.5(b)(4) would maintain the

acceptable practice that for contracts not subject to federal position

limits, DCMs and SEFs should calculate trading volume and open interest

in the manner established in current Sec. 150.5(e)(4).\805\ The

Commission stated in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal that

then proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(4) would build upon these standards by

accounting for swaps in referenced contracts on a futures-equivalent

basis.\806\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\805\ As noted in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

for SEFs, trading volume and open interest for swaptions should be

calculated on a delta-adjusted basis. See id. at 75758, n. 697.

\806\ See id. at 75698-99 (defining ``Futures-equivalent'' in

Sec. 150.1 to account for swaps in referenced contracts).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As noted above, under the December 2013 Position Limits proposal,

the Commission proposed to require DCMs and SEFs to have uniform

hedging exemptions and aggregation polices that mirror the federal

aggregation provisions for all types of commodity derivative contracts,

including for contracts that are not subject to federal position

limits. The Commission explained that hedging exemptions and

aggregation policies that vary from exchange to exchange would increase

the administrative burden on a trader active on multiple exchanges, as

well as increase the administrative burden on the Commission in

monitoring and enforcing exchange-set position limits.\807\ Therefore,

the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal in Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(i)

would require any hedge exemption rules adopted by a designated

contract market or a swap execution facility that is a trading facility

to conform to the definition of bona fide hedging position in

previously proposed Sec. 150.1.\808\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\807\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75756. See also supra regarding Sec. 150.5(a)(5).

\808\ The requirement proposed in Sec. 150.5(b)(8) that DCMs

and SEFs have uniform aggregation polices that mirror the federal

aggregation provisions is addressed below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal also set forth in Sec.

150.5(b)(5)(ii) acceptable practices for DCMs and SEFs to grant

exemptions from position limits for positions, other than bona fide

hedging positions, in contracts not subject to federal limits. The

exemptions in Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(ii) under the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal generally tracked the exemptions then proposed in Sec.

150.3; acceptable practices were suggested based on the same logic that

underpinned those exemptions.\809\ The acceptable practices

contemplated that a DCM or SEF might grant exemptions under certain

circumstances for financial distress, intramarket and intermarket

spread positions (discussed above), and qualifying cash-settled

contract positions in the spot month.\810\ Previously proposed Sec.

150.5(b)(5)(ii)(E) also set forth an acceptable practice for a DCM or

SEF to grant for contracts on excluded commodities, a limited risk

management exemption pursuant to rules submitted to the Commission, and

consistent with the guidance in new Appendix A to part 150.\811\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\809\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75735-41, 75827-28. See also supra discussion of the Sec. 150.3

exemptions.

\810\ See id.

\811\ As the Commission noted, previously proposed Appendix A to

part 150 ``is intended to capture the essence of the Commission's

1987 interpretation of its definition of bona fide hedge

transactions to permit exchanges to grant hedge exemptions for

various risk management transactions. See Risk Management Exemptions

From Speculative Position Limits Approved Under Commission

Regulation 1.61, 52 FR 34633, Sep. 14, 1987.'' The Commission also

specified that such exemptions be granted on a case-by-case basis,

subject to a demonstrated need for the exemption, required that

applicants for these exemptions be typically engaged in the buying,

selling, or holding of cash market instruments, and required the

exchanges to monitor the exemptions they granted to ensure that any

positions held under the exemption did not result in any large

positions that could disrupt the market. Id. See also December 2013

Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75756, n. 683.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal provided in Sec.

150.5(b)(6)-(7) acceptable practices relating to pre-enactment and

transition period swap positions (as those terms were defined in

previously proposed Sec. 150.1),\812\ as well as to commodity

derivative contract positions acquired in good faith prior to the

effective date of mandatory federal speculative position limits.\813\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\812\ See supra discussion of pre-enactment and transition

period swap positions.

\813\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75756,

75831.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Additionally, for any contract that is not subject to federal

position limits, previously proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(8) required the DCM

or SEF that is a trading facility to conform to the uniform federal

aggregation provisions.\814\ As noted above, aggregation policies that

vary from exchange to exchange would increase the administrative burden

on a trader active on multiple exchanges, as well as increase the

administrative burden on the Commission in monitoring and enforcing

exchange-set position limits. The requirement generally mirrored the

requirement in Sec. 150.5(a)(5) for contracts that are subject to

federal position limits by requiring the DCM or SEF that is a trading

facility to have aggregation rules that conform to previously proposed

Sec. 150.4.\815\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\814\ Proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(7) would replace 17 CFR 150.5(g)

as it relates to contracts that are not subject to federal position

limits.

\815\ Id. at 75756.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Comments Received to December 2013 Position Limits Proposal

Regarding Sec. 150.5(b)

Three commenters on previously proposed regulation Sec. 150.5

recommended that the Commission not require SEFs to establish position

limits.\816\ Two noted that because SEF participants may use more than

one derivatives clearing organization (``DCO''), a SEF may not know

when a position has been offset.\817\ Further, during the ongoing SEF

registration process,\818\ a number of entities applying to become

registered as SEFs told the Commission that they lacked access to

information that would enable them to knowledgeably establish position

limits or monitor positions.\819\ The Commission observes that this

[[Page 96793]]

information gap would also be a concern for DCMs in respect of swaps.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\816\ CL-CMC-59634 at 14-15; CL-FIA-60392 at 10; and CL-ISDA/

SIFMA-59611 at 35. One commenter stated that SEFs should be exempt

from the requirement to set positions limits because SEFs are in the

early stages of development and could be harmed by limits that

restrict liquidity. CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 35.

\817\ CL-CMC-59634 at 14-15; and CL-FIA-60392 at 10.

\818\ Under CEA section 5h(a)(1), no person may operate a

facility for trading swaps unless the facility is registered as a

SEF or DCM. 7 U.S.C. 7b-3(a)(1). A SEF must comply with core

principles, including Core Principle 6 regarding position limits, as

a condition of registration. CEA section 5h(f)(1), 7 U.S.C. 7b-

3(f)(1).

\819\ For example, in a submission to the Commission under part

40 of the Commission's regulations, BGC Derivative Markets, L.P.

states that ``[t]he information to administer limits or

accountability levels cannot be readily ascertained. Position limits

or accountability levels apply market-wide to a trader's overall

position in a given swap. To monitor this position, a SEF must have

access to information about a trader's overall position. However, a

SEF only has information about swap transactions that take place on

its own Facility and has no way of knowing whether a particular

trade on its facility adds to or reduces a trader's position. And

because swaps may trade on a number of facilities or, in many cases,

over-the-counter, a SEF does not know the size of the trader's

overall swap position and thus cannot ascertain whether the trader's

position relative to any position limit. Such information would be

required to be supplied to a SEF from a variety of independent

sources, including SDRs, DCOs, and market participants themselves.

Unless coordinated by the Commission operating a centralized

reporting system, such a data collection requirement would be

duplicative as each separate SEF required reporting by each

information sources.'' BGC Derivative Markets, L.P., Rule Submission

2015-09 (Oct. 6, 2015).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter expressed the view that deliverable supply

calculations used to establish spot month limits should be based on

commodity specific actual physical transport/transmission, generation

and production.\820\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\820\ CL-EDF-60398 at 6-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter urged the Commission to allow the listing exchange to

set non-spot month limits at least as high as the spot-month position

limit, rather than base the non-spot month limit strictly on the open

interest formula.\821\ Another commenter recommended that the

Commission remove from Sec. 150.5(b)(1)(ii)(B) the provision setting a

5,000 contract limit for non-spot-month or all-months-combined

accountability levels for exempt commodities, because that level may

not be appropriate for all markets; instead, the Commission should rely

on the exchanges to set accountability levels for exempt commodity

markets.\822\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\821\ CL-ICE-59962 at 7.

\822\ CL-Nodal-59695 at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter recommended that DCMs be permitted to establish

position accountability levels in lieu of position limits outside of

the spot month.\823\ The commenter recommended that the administration

of position accountability should be coordinated with the Commission

and other DCMs to the extent that a market participant holds positions

on more than one DCM.\824\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\823\ CL-FIA-59595 at 5, 39 and 41; see also CL-FIA-60303 at 3-

4.

\824\ CL-FIA-60392 at 9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iii. 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal

In the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed to revise Sec. 150.5(b)(5) from what was proposed in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal; proposed Sec. 150.5(b)

establishes requirements and acceptable practices that pertain to

commodity derivative contracts not subject to federal position

limits.\825\ The proposed revisions to Sec. 150.5(b)(5) would, under

the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, permit exchanges, in

regards to commodity derivative contracts not subject to federal

position limits, to recognize non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions, as well as spreads. Moreover, the exchanges would no longer

be prohibited from recognizing spreads during the spot month.\826\

Instead, as the Commission noted in the 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal, what it was proposing would, in part, maintain the

status quo: Exchanges that currently recognize spreads in the spot

month under current Sec. 150.5(a) would be able to continue to do so.

Rather than a prohibition, the exchanges would be responsible for

determining whether recognizing spreads, including spreads in the spot

month, would further the policy objectives in section 4a(a)(3) of the

Act.\827\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\825\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38482.

\826\ Id. at 38482, 38506-7. Compare December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75830.

\827\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38482, 38506-07.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iv. Comments Received to 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal

Regarding Sec. 150.5(b)

Exchange-Administered Exemptions Under Sec. 150.5(b)

Several commenters requested clarification as to the application of

exchange-administered exemption requests to non-referenced contracts

generally under Sec. 150.5(b).\828\ In addition, several commenters

raised concerns with the requirement in Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(i) that the

exchanges provide exemptions ``in a manner consistent with the process

described in Sec. 150.9(a).'' \829\ Similarly, according to one

commenter, the exchanges should not be bound to the same exemption

process provided under proposed CFTC Regulation 150.9 when

administering exemptions from exchange-set limits. Rather, the

commenter recommended that the Commission: ``(i) not adopt proposed

CFTC Regulation 150.5(b)(5)(i) in any final rule issued in this

proceeding or (ii) clarify that the phrase `in a manner consistent with

the process described in [proposed CFTC Regulation] 150.5(b)(5)(i)'

does not mean that the Exchanges must apply the virtually identical

process for recognizing non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions

under proposed CFTC Regulation 150.9(a) to their exemption process for

exchange-set speculative position limits.'' \830\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\828\ CMC, for example, requested that the Commission clarify

that exchange-granted hedge exemption procedures would be

``applicable if, and to the extent that, the exchange granted

exemption exceeds federally established speculative position limits

and not otherwise.'' CL-CMC-60950 at 14. According to CME, on the

other hand, proposed section 150.5(b) was unclear and ambiguous and

so should be reproposed. For example, CME stated that the proposal

was ``riddled with ambiguities and potential oversights,'' and, in

connection with non-referenced contracts under section 150.5(b), CME

also stated ``the scope of exchange discretion under proposed

section 150.9(a) is unclear. Thus, exchanges could be bound by the

five-day rule in recognizing as NEBFH positions certain enumerated

hedge strategies for non-referenced contracts, despite the same

five-day rule limitation not applying in similar scenarios today.''

CL-CME-60926 at 14-15.

\829\ CL-CME-60926 at 14-15; CL-Working Group-60947 at 14; and

CL-ICE-60929 at 8. For example, CME stated that requiring exchanges

to recognize non-enumerated bona fide hedge positions for non-

referenced contracts ``in a manner consistent with the process

described in Sec. 150.9(a)'' appears to ``break with historical

practice in administering NEBFHs for non-referenced contracts,'' and

``would appear to impose new burdensome and unnecessary compliance

obligations on market participants that do not exist today.'' CL-

CME-60926 at 14-15.

\830\ CL-Working Group-60947 at 14.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter stated that the Commission should remove the

requirements of Sec. 150.5(b) that apply the exemption procedures of

Sec. 150.9 to exemptions granted for contracts in excluded commodities

and physical commodities that are not subject to federal position

limits. In support of this request, the commenter maintained that

exchange exemption programs have been operating successfully without

the need for such rules, and exchanges do not require additional

guidance from the Commission on how to assess recognitions under the

2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal and that rule enforcement

reviews are adequate.\831\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\831\ CL-ICE-60929 at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Treatment of Spread and Anticipatory Hedge Exemptions Under Sec.

150.5(b)

Several commenters requested that the Commission clarify that

spread and anticipatory hedge exemptions are unnecessary for excluded

commodities and other products not subject to federal limits. For

example, one commenter seeks clarity regarding the application of Sec.

150.5(b) to spread exemption and anticipatory hedge exemption requests,

stating that ``[p]roposed section 150.5(b) is silent with respect to

anticipatory hedges contemplated under the process in proposed section

150.11, and makes no reference in proposed section 150.5(b)(5)(ii)(C)

to the process in proposed section 150.10 when describing spread

exemptions an exchange may recognize. The Commission must clarify

whether it intends that market participants and exchanges may avail

themselves of such processes in applying for and recognizing exemptions

from exchange limits for non-referenced contracts.'' \832\ On the other

hand, in the associated footnote, the same commenter observes

``[h]owever, in its cost-benefit analysis, the Commission notes that

proposed section 150.11 `works in concert with' `proposed Sec.

150.5(b)(5), with the effect that recognized anticipatory enumerated

[[Page 96794]]

bona fide hedging positions may exceed exchange-set position limits for

contracts not subject to federal position limits.' '' \833\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\832\ CL-CME-60926 at 15.

\833\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter urges the Commission to clarify that spread and

anticipatory hedge exemptions are unnecessary for excluded commodities

and other products not subject to federal limits. In this regard, the

commenter seeks the removal of requirements found in Sec.

150.5(b).\834\ A third commenter states that extending the requirements

for exchange hedge exemption rules to contracts on excluded commodities

is ``clearly an error'' that needs to be rectified, stating that there

was no discussion of this expansion in the preamble to the

Supplemental. According to the commenter, ``there is no basis in the

Dodd-Frank amendments to the CEA for this extension of the Commission's

authority over exchange position limits on excluded commodities. To the

contrary, that authority is clearly limited to position limits on

contracts on physical commodities.'' \835\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\834\ CL-CMC-60950 at 14.

\835\ CL-ISDA-60931 at 11.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Reporting Requirements Under Sec. 150.5(b)

According to one commenter, the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal does not provide any explanation regarding the Commission's

need to receive from the exchanges the same exemption reports for non-

referenced contracts that it would receive for referenced contracts.

The commenter states that the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal characterizes exchange submissions of exemption recipient

reports to the CFTC as ``support[ing] the Commission's surveillance

program, by facilitating the tracking of non-enumerated bona fide

hedging positions recognized by the exchange, and helping the

Commission to ensure that an applicant's activities conform to the

terms of recognition that the exchange has established.'' \836\ While

acknowledging that the Commission has a surveillance obligation with

respect to federal limits, the commenter maintains that, ``the same

obligation has never before existed with respect to exchange-set limits

for non-referenced contracts, and does not exist today.'' \837\ The

commenter also states that the Commission has misinterpreted its

mandate and therefore should drop this unnecessary reporting

requirement and related procedures with respect to non-referenced

contracts.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\836\ CL-CME-60926 at 15, quoting the 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38475.

\837\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Five-Day Rule Under Sec. 150.5(b)

As noted above, several commenters \838\ addressed the five-day

rule, suggesting that the decision whether to apply the five-day rule

to a particular contract should be delegated to the exchanges as the

exchanges are in the best position to evaluate facts and circumstances,

and different markets have different dynamics and needs.\839\ And,

specifically in connection with non-referenced contracts under Sec.

150.5(b), one commenter states that, as it believes that the scope of

exchange discretion under proposed section 150.9(a) is unclear,

``exchanges could be bound by the five-day rule in recognizing as non-

enumerated bona fide hedging positions certain enumerated hedge

strategies for non-referenced contracts, despite the same five-day rule

limitation not applying in similar scenarios today.'' \840\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\838\ E.g., CL-NCGA-ASA-60917 at 1-2; CL-CME-60926 at 14-15; CL-

ICE-60929 at 7-8; CL-ISDA-60931 at 11; CL-CCI-60935 at 3; CL-MGEX-

60936 at 4; CL-Working Group-60947 at 5, 7-9; CL-IECAssn-60949 at 7-

9; CL-CMC-60950 at 9-14; CL-NCC-ACSA-60972 at 2.

\839\ See, e.g, CL-ISDA-60931 at 10; CL-CCI-60935 at 3; CL-MGEX-

60936 at 11; CL-Working Group-60947 at 7-9.

\840\ CL-CME-60926 at 14-15.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comment Letter Received After the Close of the Comment Period for the

2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal Regarding Limit Levels Under

Sec. 150.5(b)

One commenter noted that when the CEA addresses ``linked

contracts'' in CEA section 4(b)(1)(B)(ii)(I), in relation to FBOTS, it

provides that the Commission may not permit an FBOT to provide direct

access to participants located in the United States unless the

Commission determines that the FBOT (or the foreign authority

overseeing the FBOT) adopts position limits that are comparable to the

position limits adopted by the registered entity for the contract(s)

against which the FBOT contract settles.\841\ According to the

commenter, CEA section 4(b), which was added by the Dodd-Frank Act,

``contains an explicit Congressional endorsement of `comparable' ''

limits for cash-settled contracts in relation to the physically-

delivered contracts to which they are linked.\842\ The statutory

definition of ``linked contract,'' the commenter stated, ``mirrors the

definition of `referenced contract' in the Commission's 2013 position

limits proposal: Both definitions capture cash-settled contracts that

are `linked' to the price of a physically-delivered contract traded on

a DCM (referred to as a `core referenced futures contract' in the

proposal).'' \843\ That commenter stated that the only place in the CEA

which addresses how to treat a cash-settled contract and its

physically-delivered benchmark contract for position limit purposes is

in CEA section 4(b), claiming that ``Congress unmistakably wanted the

two trading instruments to be treated `comparably.' '' \844\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\841\ See CL-CME-61007 at 2-4; CL-CME-61008 at 2-3.

\842\ See CL-CME-61007 at 2.

\843\ Id. at 3. CME claims that the underlying Congressional

intent is clear, stating that whether a cash-settled contract is

called a ``linked contract'' or a ``referenced contract,'' ``the

limit levels and hedge exemptions for that contract and the related

physically-delivered contract must be `comparable.'' Id.

\844\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition, according to the commenter, when the Commission, in

response to the Dodd-Frank Act provisions regarding FBOTs in amended

CEA section 4(b), adopted final Sec. 48.8(c)(1)(ii)(A), ``it

acknowledged that a linked contract and its physically-delivered

benchmark contract `create a single market' capable of being affected

through trading in either of the linked or physically-delivered

markets,'' and further noted that the Commission ``observed that the

price discovery process would be protected by `ensuring that [ ] linked

contracts have position limits and accountability provisions that are

comparable to the corresponding [DCM] contracts [to which they are

linked].' '' \845\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\845\ Id. . The Commission notes that CME

incorrectly attributed preamble language as pertaining to Sec.

48.8(c)(1)(ii)(A), which addresses statutory requirements, when it

stated that the Commission ``acknowledged that a linked contract and

its physically-delivered benchmark contract `create a single market'

capable of being affected through trading in either of the linked or

physically-delivered markets'' as this discussion actually addressed

the Commission's adoption of its second set of conditions for linked

contracts, found in Sec. 48.8(c)(2) (Other Conditions on Linked

Contracts).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iv. Commission Determination Regarding Sec. 150.5(b)

The Commission has determined to repropose Sec. 150.5(b) generally

as proposed in the the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, for

the reasons stated above, with specific exceptions discussed

below.\846\ An overall non-substantive change has been made in

reproposing Sec. 150.5 pertaining to excluded commodities. To provide

[[Page 96795]]

greater clarity regarding which provisions concern excluded

commodities, the Commission proposes to move all provisions applying to

excluded commodities from Sec. 150.5(b) into Sec. 150.5(c). As the

Commission observed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

``CEA section 4a(a) only mandates position limits with respect to

physical commodity derivatives (i.e., agricultural commodities and

exempt commodities).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\846\ The Commission is reproposing the following sections

without further discussion, for the reasons provided above, since no

substantive comments were received: Sec. 150.5(b)(6)(Pre-enactment

and transition period swap positions), Sec. 150.5(b)(7) (Pre-

existing positions), and Sec. 150.5(b)(9) (Additional acceptable

practices).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Additionally, the Commission proposes to make some substantive

revisions specific to excluded commodities in what was previously Sec.

150.5 (b), addressed in the discussion of Sec. 150.5(c).

Limit Levels for Commodity Derivative Contracts in a Physical Commodity

Not Subject to Federal Limits

In response to the comment regarding the method for calculating

deliverable supply, the Commission notes that guidance for calculating

deliverable supply can be found in Appendix C to part 38. Amendments to

part 38 are beyond the scope of this rulemaking. However, that guidance

already provides that deliverable supply calculations are estimates

based on what ``reasonably can be expected to be readily available'' on

a monthly basis based on a number of types of data from the physical

marketing channels, as suggested by the commenter, and these

calculations are done for each month and each commodity separately.

Furthermore, much of Sec. 150.5(b) reiterates longstanding guidance

and acceptable practices for DCMs, rather than proposing new concepts

for administering limits on contracts that are not subject to federal

limits under Sec. 150.2.

The Commission agrees with the commenter urging the Commission to

allow exchanges to set non-spot month limits at least as high as the

spot-month position limit, in the event the open interest formula would

result in a limit level lower than the spot month. Accordingly,

consistent with the recommended revisions to the initial limit level

listings for contracts subject to federal limits found in Sec.

150.2(e)(4)(iv), the Commission proposes to revise Sec.

150.5(b)(2)(ii) to allow exchanges to set non-spot month limit levels

at the maximum of the spot month limit level, the level derived from

the 10/2.5% formula, or 5,000 contracts. To conform with those

revisions, the Commission also proposes to revise Sec.

150.5(b)(1)(ii)(A)-(B) to remove the distinction between agricultural

and exempt commodities.

Regarding the commenter who expressed concern regarding

requirements for accountability levels for exempt commodities, the

Commission notes that the provisions set forth guidance and acceptable

practices for exchanges in setting position limit levels and

accountability levels and, as guidance and acceptable practices, are

not binding regulations. Under the Commission's guidance, an initial

non-spot month limit level of no more than 5,000 is viewed as suitable.

Similarly, in response to the commenter who recommended that DCMs

be permitted to establish position accountability levels in lieu of

position limits outside the spot month and coordinate the

administration of such levels with the Commission and other DCMs, the

Commission agrees that position accountability may be permitted for

certain physical commodity derivative contracts. Reproposed Sec.

150.5(b)(3), therefore, provides guidance and acceptable practices

concerning exchange adoption of position accountability outside the

spot month for contracts having an average month-end open interest of

50,000 contracts and an average daily volume of 5,000 or more contracts

during the most recent calendar year and a liquid cash market. The

Commission again notes that guidance and acceptable practices do not

establish mandatory means of compliance. As such, in regards to meeting

the specified volume and open interest thresholds in Sec. 150.5(b)(3),

the Commission notes that the guidance in Sec. 150.5(b)(3)(i) may not

be the only circumstances under which sufficiently high liquidity may

be shown to exist for the establishment of position accountability

levels in lieu of position limits.

The December 2013 Position Limits Proposal provided in Sec.

150.5(b)(1)(iii) that if a commodity derivative contract was cash-

settled by referencing a daily settlement price of an existing contract

listed on a DCM or SEF, then it would be an acceptable practice for a

DCM or SEF to adopt the same position limits as the original referenced

contract, assuming the contract sizes are the same.\847\ However, the

Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.5(b)(1)(iii) with a modification:

While the previously proposed guidance in Sec. 150.5(b)(1)(iii)

provided that the exchange should adopt the ``same'' spot-month,

individual non-spot month, and all-months combined limit levels as the

original price referenced contract, the Commission is reproposing Sec.

150.5(c)(1)(iii) to provide that the limit levels should, instead, be

``comparable.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\847\ The Commission expressed the belief that, based on its

enforcement experience, limiting a trader's position in cash-settled

contracts in this way would diminish the incentive to exert market

power to manipulate the cash-settlement price or index to advantage

a trader's position in the cash-settled contract. See December 2013

Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75757. As the Commission noted

with respect to cash-settled contracts where the underlying product

is a physical commodity with limited supplies, thus enabling a

trader to exert market power (including agricultural and exempt

commodities), the Commission has viewed the specification of

speculative position limits to be an essential term and condition of

such contracts in order to ensure that they are not readily

susceptible to manipulation, which is the DCM core principle 3

requirement. Id. at 75757, n. 692.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As pointed out by one commenter,\848\ the CEA establishes a

comparability standard for linked FBOT contracts in CEA section

4(b)(1)(B)(ii)(I), when it provides that the Commission may not permit

an FBOT to provide direct access to participants located in the United

States unless the Commission determines that the FBOT (or the foreign

authority overseeing the FBOT) adopts position limits that are

``comparable to'' the position limits adopted by the registered entity

for the contract(s) against which the FBOT contract settles.\849\ In

addition, as noted by the commenter, the Commission, in adopting Sec.

48.8(c)(2), recognized that the comparability standard and its

associated requirements would protect the price discovery process by

ensuring that the linked contracts and the U.S. contracts to which they

are linked ``have position limits and accountability provisions that

are comparable to the corresponding [DCM] contracts [to which they are

linked].' '' \850\ The Commission notes that this change will better

align Sec. 150.5(b)(1)(iii) with the statute and with the standard

provided in Sec. 48.8(c).\851\ Moreover, use of

[[Page 96796]]

``comparable'' rather than ``same'' limit levels provides exchanges

with a more flexible standard based on statutory language.\852\ This

change also provides a standard that is consistent with existing

practice for domestic contracts that are linked to the price of a

physical-delivery contract.\853\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\848\ See, e.g., CL-CME-61007 at 2-4; CL-CME-61008 at 2-3.

\849\ CL-CME-61007 at 2. ``Registered entities'' are defined in

CEA section 1a(40) as DCMs, DCOs, SEFs, SDRs, notice-registered DCMs

under CEA section 5f, and any electronic trading facility upon which

a contract is executed or traded which the Commission has determined

is a significant price discovery contract. According to CME, CEA

Section 4(b) ``contains an explicit Congressional endorsement of

`comparable' '' limits for cash-settled contracts in relation to the

physically-delivered contracts to which they are linked. See CL-CME-

61007 at 2.

\850\ CL-CME-61007 at 3. See 76 FR 80674, 80685, 80697 (Dec. 23,

2011). See also Sec. 48.8(c)(1)(ii)(A).

\851\ The comparability standard is also used in determinations

as to which foreign DCOs are subject to comparable, comprehensive

supervision and regulation by the appropriate government authority

in the DCO's home country. See CEA section 5b)(h). See also the

Commission's Notice of Comparability Determination for Certain

Requirements Under the European Market Infrastructure Regulation, 81

FR 15260 (Mar. 22, 2016).

\852\ As the Commission explained in preamble to final part 48

in connection with comparability determinations, ``[t]he

Commission's determination of the comparability of the foreign

regulatory regime to which the FBOT applying for registration is

subject will not be a ``line by line'' examination of the foreign

regulator's approach to supervision of the FBOTs it regulates.

Rather, it will be a principles-based review conducted in a manner

consistent with the part 48 regulations pursuant to which the

Commission will look to determine if that regime supports and

enforces regulatory objectives in the oversight of the FBOT and the

clearing organization that are substantially equivalent to the

regulatory objectives supported and enforced by the Commission in

its oversight of DCMs and DCOs.'' 76 FR 80674, 80680 (Dec. 23,

2011). See also Sec. 48.5(d)(5).

\853\ For example, both CME and ICE currently have conditional

spot-month limit exemptions for cash-settled natural gas contracts

at a level up to five times the level of the spot-month limit level

on CME's economically-equivalent NYMEX Henry Hub Natural Gas

(physical-delivery) futures contract to which they settle.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission proposes to revise Sec. 150.5(b)(4)(B) regarding

the calculation of open interest for use in setting exchange-set

speculative position limits to provide that a DCM or SEF that is a

trading facility would include swaps in their open interest calculation

only if such entities are required to administer position limits on

swap contracts of their facilities. This revision clarifies and

harmonizes Sec. 150.5(b)(4)(B) with the relief in Appendix E to part

150, as well as in appendices to parts 37 and 38, which delays for DCMs

and SEFs that are trading facilities and lack access to sufficient swap

position information the requirement to establish and monitor position

limits on swaps at this time. This approach conforms Sec. 150.5(b)

with other proposed changes regarding the treatment of swaps.\854\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\854\ As noted above, the relief was proposed in the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38459-62. See also

DCM Core Principle 5, Position Limitations or Accountability

(contained in CEA section 5(d)(5), 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(5)) and SEF Core

Principle 6, Position Limits or Accountability (contained in CEA

section 5h(f)(6), 7 U.S.C. 7b-3(f)(6)).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Exchange--Administered Exemptions for Commodity Derivative Contracts in

a Physical Commodity Not Subject to Federal Limits

The Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(i) with

modifications to clarify that it is guidance rather than a regulatory

requirement. In addition, as modified, it provides that under exchange

rules allowing a trader to file an application for an enumerated bona

fide hedging exemption, the application should be filed no later than

five business days after the trader assumed the position that exceeded

a position limit.\855\ As noted above, the Commission expects that

exchanges will carefully consider whether allowing retroactive

recognition of an enumerated bona fide hedging exemption would, as

noted by one commenter, diminish the overall integrity of the process,

and should carefully consider whether to adopt in those rules the two

safeguards noted: (i) To continue to require market participants making

use of the retroactive application to demonstrate that the applied-for

hedge was required to address a sudden and unforeseen hedging need; and

(ii) providing that if the emergency hedge recognition was not granted,

exchange rules would continue to require the applicant to promptly

unwind its position and also would deem the applicant to have been in

violation for any period in which its position exceeded the applicable

limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\855\ The modification made to Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(i) is similar

manner to its the Commission's modification of Sec.

150.5(a)(2)(ii), but, as mentioned, Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(i) is guidance

rather than a regulatory requirement.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Additionally, the Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(i)

with modifications to clarify, as requested by commenters,\856\ that

the exchanges have reasonable discretion as to whether they apply to

their exemption process from exchange-set speculative position limits,

a virtually identical process as provided for recognizing non-

enumerated bona fide hedging positions under CFTC Regulation 150.9(a).

As explained in the discussion regarding the changes to the bona fide

hedging definition under Sec. 150.1, the Commission is proposes a

phased approach with respect to the definition of a bona fide hedging

position applicable to physical commodities.\857\ The Commission

recognizes that exchanges, under Sec. 150.9, may need to adapt their

current process to recognize non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions

for commodity derivative contracts that are subject to a federal

position limit under Sec. 150.2, or adopt a new one. In turn, market

participants will need to seek recognition of a non-enumerated bona

fide hedge from an exchange under that new process. In light of this

implementation issue, the Commission proposes to limit the mandatory

scope of the new definition of bona fide hedging position to contracts

that are subject to a federal position limit.\858\ This means that the

Commission would permit exchanges to maintain both their current bona

fide hedging position definition and their existing processes for

recognizing non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions for physical

commodity contracts not subject to federal limits under Sec. 150.2.

The Commission notes an exchange may, but need not, adopt for physical

commodities not subject to federal limits the new bona fide hedging

position definition and the new process to recognize non-enumerated

bona fide hedging positions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\856\ See CL-Working Group-60947 at 14; see also CL-ICE-60929 at

8, 32. As previously proposed, Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(i) provides, ``(i)

Hedge exemption. Any hedge exemption rules adopted by a designated

contract market or swap execution facility that is a trading

facility must conform to the definition of bona fide hedging

position in Sec. 150.1 or provide for recognition as a non-

enumerated bona fide hedge in a manner consistent with the process

described in Sec. 150.9(a).''

\857\ See also December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75725 (stating ``[t]he Commission is proposing a phased approach to

implement the statutory mandate. The Commission is proposing in this

release to establish speculative position limits on 28 core

referenced futures contracts in physical commodities. The Commission

anticipates that it will, in subsequent releases, propose to expand

the list of core referenced futures contracts in physical

commodities. The Commission believes that a phased approach will (i)

reduce the potential administrative burden by not immediately

imposing position limits on all commodity derivative contracts in

physical commodities at once, and (ii) facilitate adoption of

monitoring policies, procedures and systems by persons not currently

subject to positions limits (such as traders in swaps that are not

significant price discovery contracts.). . . . Thus, in the first

phase, the Commission generally is proposing limits on those

contracts that it believes are likely to play a larger role in

interstate commerce than that played by other physical commodity

derivative contracts.'').

\858\ See also supra discussion under regarding the bona fide

hedging position definition.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition, the Commission is proposing that, for enumerated bona

fide hedging positions, exchange rules may allow traders to file an

application for an enumerated bona fide hedging exemption within five

business days after the trader assumed the position that exceeded a

position limit.

Finally, as to Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(ii) (Other exemptions), the

Commission did not receive any comments regarding Sec.

150.5(b)(5)(ii)(A) (Financial distress), and is reproposing this

exemption without change.

Conditional Spot Month Limit Exemption for Commodity Derivative

Contracts in a Physical Commodity Not Subject to Federal Limits

While the conditional spot month limit exemption is addressed in

more detail under Sec. 150.3, after consideration of comments, the

Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(ii)(B) with a

modification.\859\ The December 2013

[[Page 96797]]

Position Limits Proposal proposed guidance that an exchange may adopt a

conditional spot month position limit exemption for cash-settled

contracts, with one of two provisos being that such positions should

not exceed five times the level of the spot-month limit specified by

the exchange that lists the physical-delivery contract to which the

cash-settled contracts were directly or indirectly linked.\860\ As

reproposed, the guidance recommends that such conditional exemptions

should not exceed two times the level of the spot-month limit specified

by the exchange that lists the applicable physical-delivery contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\859\ Most comments concerning the conditional spot month limit

were submitted by CME and ICE; recent letters include: CL-CME-61007;

CL-ICE-61009; CL-CME-61008; CL-ICE-60929; CL-CME-60926.

\860\ The second proviso included in Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(ii)(B)

was that the person holding or controlling the positions should not

hold or control positions in such spot-month physical-delivery

contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After review of comments and an impact analysis regarding the

federal limits, the Commission believes that a five-times conditional

exemption is too large, other than in natural gas because, in the

markets that the Commission proposes to subject to federal limits, the

Commission observed few or no market participants with positions in

cash-settled contracts in the aggregate that exceed 25 percent of

deliverable supply in the spot month. This is so even though cash-

settled contracts that are swaps are not currently subject to position

limits. A five-times conditional exemption would not ensure liquidity

for bona fide hedgers in the spot month for cash-settled contracts

because there appear to be few or no positions that large (other than

in natural gas). Consequently, and in light of the other three policy

objectives of CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B), the Commission reproposes a more

cautious approach.\861\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\861\ As noted above, it is the Commission's responsibility

under CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B) to set limits, to the maximum extent

practicable, in its discretion, that, in addition to ensuring

sufficient market liquidity for bona fide hedgers, diminish,

eliminate or prevent excessive speculation; deter and prevent market

manipulation, squeezes, and corners; and ensure that the price

discovery function of the underlying market is not disrupted.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Since transactions of large speculative traders may tend to cause

unwarranted price changes, exchanges should exercise caution in

determining whether such conditional exemptions are warranted; for

example, an exchange may determine that a conditional exemption is

warranted because such a speculative trader is demonstrably providing

liquidity for bona fide hedgers. Where an exchange may not have access

to data regarding a market participant's cash-settled positions away

from a particular exchange, such exchange should require, for any

conditional spot-month limit exemption it grants, that a trader report

promptly to such exchange the trader's aggregate positions in cash-

settled contracts, physical-delivery contracts, and cash market

positions.

As noted above, under reproposed Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(ii)(B), an

exchange has the choice of whether or not to adopt a conditional spot

month position limit exemption for cash-settled contracts that are not

subject to federal limits. As also discussed above regarding reproposed

Sec. 150.3(c), the Commission is not proposing a conditional spot-

month limit for agricultural contracts subject to federal limits under

reproposed Sec. 150.2. Further, the Commission notes that the current

cash-settled natural gas spot month limit rules of two commenters, CME

Group (which operates NYMEX) and ICE, both include the same spot-month

limit level and the same conditional spot-month limit exemption. In

each case the current cash-settled conditional exemption is five times

the limit for the physical-delivery contract. Such natural gas

contracts would be subject to federal limits under reproposed Sec.

150.2, so the guidance in reproposed Sec. 150.5(b) would not be

applicable to those contracts.\862\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\862\ The Commission notes that reproposed Sec.

150.5(b)(5)(ii)(B) retains both of the recommended provisos,

although, as noted above, the guidance recommends that such

positions should not exceed two times the level of the spot-month

limit specified by the exchange that lists the applicable physical-

delivery contract, rather than five times.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Treatment of Spread and Anticipatory Hedge Exemptions for Commodity

Derivative Contracts in a Physical Commodity Not Subject to Federal

Limits

In regards to the exemption for intramarket and intermarket spread

positions under Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(ii)(C), the comments received

concerned the exchange process for providing spread exemptions under

Sec. 150.10. The Commission addresses those comments below in its

discussion of Sec. 150.10, and is reproposing Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(ii)(C)

as proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal.

The Commission points out, however, that reproposed Sec.

150.5(b)(5)(ii)(C) would apply only to physical commodity derivative

contracts, and would not apply to any derivative contract in an

excluded commodity. Furthermore, as noted above, reproposed Sec.

150.5(b)(5)(ii)(C) provides guidance rather than rigid requirements.

Instead, under Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(ii)(C), exchanges should take into

account whether granting a spread exemption in a physical commodity

derivative would, to the maximum extent practicable, ensure sufficient

market liquidity for bona fide hedgers, and not unduly reduce the

effectiveness of position limits to diminish, eliminate, or prevent

excessive speculation; deter and prevent market manipulation, squeezes,

and corners; and ensure that the price discovery function of the

underlying market is not disrupted.\863\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\863\ As noted in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

the guidance is consistent with the statutory policy objectives for

position limits on physical commodity derivatives in CEA section

4a(a)(3)(B). See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

38464. The Commission interprets the CEA as providing it with the

statutory authority to exempt spreads that are consistent with the

other policy objectives for position limits, such as those in CEA

section 4a(a)(3)(B). Id. CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B) provides that the

Commission shall set limits to the maximum extent practicable, in

its discretion--to diminish, eliminate, or prevent excessive

speculation as described under this section; to deter and prevent

market manipulation, squeezes, and corners; to ensure sufficient

market liquidity for bona fide hedgers; and to ensure that the price

discovery function of the underlying market is not disrupted.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Five-Day Rule for Commodity Derivative Contracts in a Physical

Commodity Not Subject to Federal Limits

While the Commission's determination regarding the five-day rule is

addressed elsewhere,\864\ the Commission points out that, as discussed

in connection with the definition of bona fide hedging position and in

relation to exchange processes under Sec. 150.9, Sec. 150.10, and

Sec. 150.11, and as noted above in connection with Sec. 150.5(a), the

five-day rule would only apply to certain enumerated positions (pass-

through swap offsets, anticipatory, and cross-commodity hedges),\865\

rather than when determining whether to recognize as non-enumerated

bona fide hedging positions certain non-enumerated hedge strategies for

non-referenced contracts. As reproposed, therefore, Sec. 150.5(b)

would apply the five-day rule only to pass-through swap offsets,

anticipatory, and cross-commodity hedges. However, in regards to

exchange processes under Sec. 150.9, Sec. 150.10, and Sec. 150.11,

the Commission

[[Page 96798]]

proposes to allow exchanges to waive the five-day rule on a case-by-

case basis.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\864\ See the discussion regarding the five-day rule in

connection with the definition of bona fide hedging position and the

discussion of Sec. 150.9 (Process for recognition of positions as

non-enumerated bona fide hedges).

\865\ See Sec. 150.1 definition of bona fide hedging position,

sections (2)(ii)(A), (3)(iii), (4), and (5) (Other enumerated

hedging position). To provide greater clarity as to which bona fide

hedging positions the five-day rule applies, the reproposed rules

reorganize the definition.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As the Commission cautioned above, exchanges should carefully

consider whether to recognize a position as a bona fide hedge or to

exempt a spread position held during the last few days of trading in

physical-delivery contracts. The Commission points to the tools that

exchanges currently use to address concerns during the spot month; as

two commenters observed, current tools include requiring gradual

reduction of the position (``step down'' requirements) or revoking

exemptions to protect the price discovery process in core referenced

futures contracts approaching expiration. Consequently, under the

reproposed rule, exchanges may recognize positions, on a case-by-case

basis in physical-delivery contracts that would otherwise be subject to

the five-day rule, as non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions, by

applying the exchanges experience and expertise in protecting its own

physical-delivery market.

Reporting Requirements for Commodity Derivative Contracts in a Physical

Commodity Not Subject to Federal Limits

In response to the comment questioning the proposed reporting

requirements by a claim that, ``while the Commission has a surveillance

obligation with respect to federal limits, the same obligation has

never before existed with respect to exchange-set limits for non-

referenced contracts, and does not exist today,'' \866\ the Commission

points out, as it did in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, that the Futures Trading Act of 1982 ``gave the Commission,

under section 4a(5) [since redesignated as section 4a(e)] of the Act,

the authority to directly enforce violations of exchange-set,

Commission-approved speculative position limits in addition to position

limits established directly by the Commission through orders or

regulations.'' \867\ And, since 2008, it has also been a violation of

the Act for any person to violate an exchange position limit rule

certified by the exchange.\868\ To address any confusion that might

have led to such a comment, the Commission reiterates, under CEA

section 4a(e), its authority to enforce violations of exchange-set

speculative position limits, whether certified or Commission-approved.

As the Commission explained in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, exchanges, as SROs, do not act only as independent, private

actors.\869\ In fact, to repeat the explanation provided by the

Commission in 1981, when the Act is read as a whole, ``it is apparent

that Congress envisioned cooperative efforts between the self-

regulatory organizations and the Commission. Thus, the exchanges, as

well as the Commission, have a continuing responsibility in this matter

under the Act.'' \870\ The 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal

pointed out that the ``Commission's approach to its oversight of its

SROs was subsequently ratified by Congress in 1982, when it gave the

CFTC authority to enforce exchange set limits.'' \871\ In addition, as

the Commission observed in 2010, and reiterated in the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, ``since 1982, the Act's

framework explicitly anticipates the concurrent application of

Commission and exchange-set speculative position limits.'' \872\ The

Commission further noted that the ``concurrent application of limits is

particularly consistent with an exchange's close knowledge of trading

activity on that facility and the Commission's greater capacity for

monitoring trading and implementing remedial measures across

interconnected commodity futures and option markets.'' \873\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\866\ CL-CME-60926 at 15.

\867\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38466, n. 85 (quoting the Federal Speculative Position Limits for

Referenced Energy Contracts and Associated Regulations, 75 FR 4144,

4145 (Jan. 36, 2010)).

\868\ See Futures Trading Act of 1982, Public Law 97-444, 96

Stat. 2299-30 (1983) (amending CEA section 4a by including, in what

was then a new CEA section 4a(5), since been re-designated as CEA

section 4a(e) ``. . . It shall be a violation of this chapter for

any person to violate any bylaw, rule, regulation, or resolution of

any contract market, derivatives transaction execution facility, or

other board of trade licensed, designated, or registered by the

Commission or electronic trading facility with respect to a

significant price discovery contract fixing limits on the amount of

trading which may be done or positions which may be held by any

person under contracts of sale of any commodity for future delivery

or under options on such contracts or commodities, if such bylaw,

rule, regulation, or resolution has been approved by the Commission

or certified by a registered entity pursuant to section 7a-2(c)(1)

of this title: Provided, That the provisions of section 13(a)(5) of

this title shall apply only to those who knowingly violate such

limits.'').

\869\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38465-66.

\870\ Establishment of Speculative Position Limits, 46 FR 50938,

50939 (Oct. 16, 1981). As the Commission noted at that time that

``[s]ince many exchanges have already implemented their own

speculative position limits on certain contracts, the new rule

merely effectuates completion of a regulatory philosophy the

industry and the Commission appear to share.'' Id. at 50940.

\871\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38466. See also Futures Trading Act of 1982, Public Law 97-444, 96

Stat. 2299-30 (1983). In 2010, the Commission noted that the 1982

legislation ``also gave the Commission, under section 4a(5) of the

Act, the authority to directly enforce violations of exchange-set,

Commission-approved speculative position limits in addition to

position limits established directly by the Commission through

orders or regulations.'' Federal Speculative Position Limits for

Referenced Energy Contracts and Associated Regulations, 75 FR 4144,

4145 (Jan. 36, 2010) (``2010 Position Limits Proposal for Referenced

Energy Contracts''). Section 4a(5) has since been re-designated as

section 4a(e) of the Act.

\872\ 2010 Position Limits for Referenced Energy Contracts at

4145; see also 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38466.

\873\ See 2010 Position Limits for Referenced Energy Contracts,

75 FR at 4145; see also 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal,

81 FR at 38466.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission retains the power to approve or disapprove the rules

of exchanges, under standards set out pursuant to the CEA, and to

review an exchange's compliance with the exchange's rules, by way of

additional examples of the Commission's continuing responsibility in

this matter under the Act.

v. Commission Determination Regarding Sec. 150.5(c)

As noted above, in an overall non-substantive change made in

reproposing Sec. 150.5, the Commission moved all provisions applying

to excluded commodities from Sec. 150.5(b) into reproposed Sec.

150.5(c) to provide greater clarity regarding which provisions concern

excluded commodities. The Commission has determined to repropose the

rule largely as proposed for excluded commodities (previously under

Sec. 150.5(b)), for the reasons noted above, with certain changes

discussed below.\874\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\874\ The Commission is reproposing the following sections

without further discussion, for the reasons provided above, because

it received no substantive comments: Sec. 150.5(c)(6) (Pre-

enactment and transition period swap positions), Sec. 150.5(c)(7)

(Pre-existing positions), and Sec. 150.5(b)(9) (Additional

acceptable practices).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Limit Levels for Excluded Commodities

The Commission is reproposing the provisions under Sec.

150.5(c)(1) regarding levels of limits for excluded commodities as

modified and reproposed under Sec. 150.5(b)(1),\875\ to reference

excluded commodities and to remove provisions that were solely

addressed to agricultural commodities.\876\ These provisions generally

provide guidance rather than rigid requirements; the guidance for

levels of limits remains the same for

[[Page 96799]]

excluded commodities as for all other commodity derivative contracts

that are not subject to the limits set forth in reproposed Sec. 150.2,

including derivative contracts in a physical commodity as defined in

reproposed Sec. 150.1.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\875\ As reproposed, Sec. 150.5(c)(1)(iii), like Sec.

150.5(b)(1)(iii), provides that the spot-month, individual non-spot

month, and all-months combined limit levels should be ``comparable''

rather than the ``same.''

\876\ See supra for discussion of the modifications made to the

reproposed provisions of Sec. 150.5(b)(1) as compared to the

December 2103 Position Limits Proposal; the explanation provided

above also pertains to the inclusion of those modifications in

reproposed Sec. 150.5(c)(1).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Similarly, as to adjustment of limit levels for excluded commodity

derivative contracts under Sec. 150.5(c)(2), the reproposed provisions

are modified to reference only excluded commodities and to remove

provisions that were solely addressed to agricultural commodities. As

reproposed, Sec. 150.5(c)(2)(i) provides guidance that the spot month

position limits for excluded commodity derivative contracts ``should be

maintained at a level that is necessary and appropriate to reduce the

potential threat of market manipulation or price distortion of the

contract's or the underlying commodity's price or index.''

The Commission did not receive comments regarding Sec.

150.5(c)(3). The guidance in Sec. 150.5(c)(3), on exchange adoption of

position accountability levels in lieu of speculative position limits,

has been reproposed as was previously proposed in Sec. 150.5(b)(3),

modified to remove provisions under Sec. 150.5(b)(3)(i), which were

solely addressed to physical commodity derivative contracts, and to

reference excluded commodities.

As to the calculation of open interest for use in setting exchange-

set speculative position limits for excluded commodities, the

Commission is reproposing, in Sec. 150.5(c)(4), the same guidance for

excluded commodities that is being reproposed under Sec. 150.5(b)(4)

as for all other commodity derivative contracts that are not subject to

the limits set forth in Sec. 150.2, including the modification to

provide that a DCM or SEF that is a trading facility would include

swaps in its open interest calculation only if such entity is required

to administer position limits on swap contracts of its facility.

Exchange--Administered Exemptions for Excluded Commodities

In regards to hedge exemptions, the Commission is reproposing in

new Sec. 150.5(c)(5)(i) for contracts in excluded commodities a

modification of what was previously proposed in Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(i)

that eliminates the guidance that exchanges ``may provide for

recognition of a non-enumerated bona fide hedge in a manner consistent

with the process described in Sec. 150.9(a).'' That provision was

intended to apply only to physical commodity contracts and not to

exemptions granted by exchanges for contracts in excluded

commodities.\877\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\877\ In addition, as noted above, the Commission is reproposing

Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(i) with a modification that clarifies that this

provision is guidance in the case of commodity derivatives contracts

in a physical commodity not subject to federal limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As noted above, in reproposing the definition of bona fide hedging

position, the Commission is clarifying that an exchange may otherwise

recognize as bona fide any position in a commodity derivative contract

in an excluded commodity, so long as such recognition is pursuant to

such exchange's rules. Although the Commission's standards in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal applied the incidental test and

the orderly trading requirements to all commodities, the Commission, as

previously described, proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal to remove both those standards from the definition of bona

fide hedging position.\878\ Moreover, the reproposed definition of bona

fide hedging position would provide only that the position is either:

(i) Enumerated in the definition (in paragraphs (3), (4), or (5)) and

meets the economically appropriate test; or (ii) recognized by an

exchange under rules previously submitted to the Commission.\879\ The

Commission's standards for recognizing a position as a bona fide hedge

in an excluded commodity, therefore, would not include the additional

requirements applicable to physical commodities subject to federal

limits. Consequently, as reproposed, the exchanges would have

reasonable discretion to comply with core principles regarding position

limits on excluded commodities so long as the exchange does so pursuant

to exchange rules previously submitted to the Commission under Part 40.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\878\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, definition

of bona fide hedging position (amending the definition previously

proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal), 78 FR at

38463-64, 38505-06.

\879\ The economically appropriate test has historically been

interpreted primarily in the context of physical commodities, rather

than applied to excluded commodities.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition, in conjunction with the amendments to the definition

of bona fide hedging positions in regards to excluded commodities,\880\

the Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.5(c)(5)(ii), proposed as Sec.

150.5(b)(5)(ii)(D) in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal,

with no further modification, to afford greater flexibility for

exchanges when granting exemptions for excluded commodities. The 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal provided, in addition to granting

exemptions under paragraphs (b)(5)(ii)(A), (b)(5)(ii)(B), and

(b)(5)(ii)(C) of Sec. 150.5, that exchanges may grant a ``limited''

risk management exemptions pursuant to rules consistent with the

guidance in Appendix A of part 150. As reproposed, Sec.

150.5(c)(5)(ii) eliminates the modifier ``limited'' from the risk

management exemptions, and provides merely that exchanges may grant, in

addition to the exemptions under paragraphs (b)(5)(ii)(A),

(b)(5)(ii)(B), and (b)(5)(ii)(C), risk management exemptions pursuant

to rules submitted to the Commission, ``including'' for a position that

is consistent with the guidance in Appendix A of part 150.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\880\ In each case pursuant to rules submitted to the

Commission, consistent with the guidance in Appendix A of this part.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In regards to the provisions addressing applications for exemptions

for positions in excluded commodities, the Commission is modifying what

was copied from Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(iii) to provide, under Sec.

150.5(c)(5)(iii), simply that an exchange may allow a person to file an

exemption application for excluded commodities after the person assumes

the position that exceeded a position limit.

Finally, in reproposing the aggregation provision for excluded

commodities under Sec. 150.5(c)(8), the Commission is not merely

mirroring the aggregation provision as previously proposed in Sec.

150.5(b)(8). As noted above, the reproposed aggregation provisions for

physical commodity derivatives contracts, whether under Sec.

150.5(a)(8) or Sec. 150.5(b)(8), provide that exchanges must have

aggregation provisions that conform to Sec. 150.4. Reproposed Sec.

150.5(c)(8), consistent with the rest of reproposed Sec. 150.5(c),

would instead provide guidance, that exchanges ``should'' have

aggregation rules for excluded commodity derivative contracts that

conform to Sec. 150.4.

E. Part 19--Reports by Persons Holding Bona Fide Hedge Positions

Pursuant to Sec. 150.1 of This Chapter and by Merchants and Dealers in

Cotton

1. Current Part 19

The market and large trader reporting rules are contained in parts

15 through 21 of the Commission's regulations.\881\ Collectively, these

reporting rules effectuate the Commission's market and financial

surveillance programs by enabling the Commission to gather information

concerning the size and composition of the commodity futures, options,

and swaps markets, thereby permitting the Commission to monitor and

enforce the speculative position

[[Page 96800]]

limits that have been established, among other regulatory goals. The

Commission's reporting rules are implemented pursuant to the authority

of CEA sections 4g and 4i, among other CEA sections. Section 4g of the

Act imposes reporting and recordkeeping obligations on registered

entities, and obligates FCMs, introducing brokers, floor brokers, and

floor traders to file such reports as the Commission may require on

proprietary and customer positions executed on any board of trade.\882\

Section 4i of the Act requires the filing of such reports as the

Commission may require when positions equal or exceed Commission-set

levels.\883\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\881\ 17 CFR parts 15-21.

\882\ See CEA section 4g(a); 7 U.S.C. 6g(a).

\883\ See CEA section 4i; 7 U.S.C. 6i.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Current part 19 of the Commission's regulations sets forth

reporting requirements for persons holding or controlling reportable

futures and option positions ``which constitute bona fide hedging

positions as defined in [Sec. ] 1.3(z)'' and for merchants and dealers

in cotton holding or controlling reportable positions for future

delivery in cotton.\884\ In the several markets with federal

speculative position limits--namely those for grains, the soy complex,

and cotton--hedgers that hold positions in excess of those limits must

file a monthly report pursuant to part 19 on CFTC Form 204: Statement

of Cash Positions in Grains,\885\ which includes the soy complex, and

CFTC Form 304 Report: Statement of Cash Positions in Cotton.\886\ These

monthly reports, collectively referred to as the Commission's ``series

'04 reports,'' must show the trader's positions in the cash market and

are used by the Commission to determine whether a trader has sufficient

cash positions that justify futures and option positions above the

speculative limits.\887\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\884\ See 17 CFR part 19. Current part 19 cross-references a

provision of the definition of reportable position in 17 CFR

15.00(p)(2). As discussed below, that provision would be

incorporated into proposed Sec. 19.00(a).

\885\ Current CFTC Form 204: Statement of Cash Positions in

Grains is available at http://www.cftc.gov/idc/groups/public/@forms/documents/file/cftcform204.pdf.

\886\ Current CFTC Form 304 Report: Statement of Cash Positions

in Cotton is available at http://www.cftc.gov/idc/groups/public/@forms/documents/file/cftcform304.pdf.

\887\ In addition, in the cotton market, merchants and dealers

file a weekly CFTC Form 304 Report of their unfixed-price cash

positions, which is used to publish a weekly Cotton On-call report,

a service to the cotton industry. The Cotton On-Call Report shows

how many unfixed-price cash cotton purchases and sales are

outstanding against each cotton futures month.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. Amendments to Part 19

In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed to amend part 19 so that it would conform to the Commission's

proposed changes to part 150.\888\ First, the Commission proposed to

amend part 19 by adding new and modified cross-references to proposed

part 150, including the new definition of bona fide hedging position in

proposed Sec. 150.1. Second, the Commission proposed to amend Sec.

19.00(a) by extending reporting requirements to any person claiming any

exemption from federal position limits pursuant to proposed Sec.

150.3. The Commission proposed to add new series '04 reporting forms to

effectuate these additional reporting requirements. Third, the

Commission proposed to update the manner of part 19 reporting. Lastly,

the Commission proposed to update both the type of data that would be

required in series '04 reports as well as the timeframe for filing such

reports.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\888\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75741-75746.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: One commenter acknowledges concerns presented by

Commission staff at the Staff Roundtable that exemptions from position

limits be limited to prevent abuse, but does not believe that the

adoption of additional recordkeeping or reporting rules or the

development of costly infrastructure is required because statutory and

regulatory safeguards already exist or are already proposed in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, noting that: (i) The series '04

forms as well as DCM exemption documents will be required of market

participants, who face significant penalties for false reporting, and

the Commission may request additional information if the information

provided is unsatisfactory; and (ii) market participants claiming a

bona fide hedging exemption are still subject to anti-disruptive

trading prohibitions in CEA section 4c(a)(5), anti-manipulation

prohibitions in CEA sections 6(c) and 9(c), the orderly trading

requirement in proposed Sec. 150.1, and DCM oversight. The commenter

stated that these requirements comprise a ``thorough and robust

regulatory structure'' that does not need to be augmented with new

recordkeeping, reporting, or other obligations to prevent misuse of

hedging exemptions.\889\ A second commenter echoed that additional

recordkeeping or reporting obligations are unnecessary and would create

unnecessary regulatory burdens.\890\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\889\ CL-Working Group-59959 at 3-4.

\890\ CL-NFP-60393 at 15-16.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter stated that the various forms required by the

regime, while not lengthy, represent significant data collection and

categorization that will require a non-trivial amount of work to

accurately prepare and file. The commenter claimed that a comprehensive

position limits regime could be implemented with a ``far less

burdensome'' set of filings and requested that the Commission review

the proposed forms and ensure they are ``as clear, limited, and

workable'' as possible to reduce burden. The commenter stated that it

is not aware of any software vendors that currently provide solutions

that can support a commercial firm's ability to file the proposed

forms.\891\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\891\ CL-COPE-59662 at 24; CL-COPE-60932 at 10; CL-EEI-EPSA-

60925 at 9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter recommended that the Commission eliminate the series

'04 reports in light of the application and reporting requirements laid

out in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal. The commenter

asserted that the application requirements are in addition to the

series '04 forms, which the commenter claims ``only provide the

Commission with a limited surveillance benefit.'' \892\ Another

commenter raised concerns regarding forms filed under part 19 and the

data required to be filed with exchanges under Sec. Sec. 150.9-11. The

commenter stated that the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal

requires that ``those exceeding the federal limits file the proposed

forms including Form 204'' but lacks ``meaningful guidance'' regarding

the data that must be maintained ``effectively in real-time'' to

populate the forms.\893\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\892\ CL-FIA-60937 at 17.

\893\ CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters requested that the Commission create user-

friendly guidebooks for the forms so that all entities can clearly

understand any required forms and build the systems to file such forms,

including providing workshops and/or hot lines to improve the

forms.\894\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\894\ CL-COPE-59662 at 24; CL-COPE-60932 at 10; CL-ASR-60933 at

4; CL-Working Group-60947 at 17-18; CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter expressed concern for reporting requirements in

conflict with other regulatory requirements (such as FASB ASC

815).\895\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\895\ CL-U.S. Dairy-59597 at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Finally, two commenters recommended modifying or removing the

requirement to certify series '04 reports as ``true and correct''. One

commenter suggested that the requirement be removed due to the

difficulty of making such a certification

[[Page 96801]]

and the fact that CEA section 6(c)(2) already prohibits the submission

of false or misleading information.\896\ Another noted that the

requirement to report very specific information relating to hedges and

cash market activity involves data that may change over time. The

commenter suggested the Commission adopt a good-faith standard

regarding ``best effort'' estimates of the data when verifying the

accuracy of Form 204 submissions and, assuming the estimate of physical

activity does not otherwise impact the bona fide hedge exemption (e.g.

cause the firm to lose the exemption), not penalize entities for

providing the closest approximation of the position possible.\897\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\896\ See CL-CMC-59634 at 17.

\897\ CL-Working Group-59693 at 65.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission responds to specific comments

regarding the content and timing of the series '04 forms and other

concerns below. The Commission agrees with the commenters that the

forms should be clear and workable, and offers several clarifications

and amendments below in response to comments about particular aspects

of the series '04 reports.

The Commission notes that the information required on the series

'04 reports represents a trader's most basic position data, including

the number of units of the cash commodity that the firm has purchased

or sold, or the size of a swap position that is being offset in the

futures market. The Commission believes this information is readily

available to traders, who routinely make trading decisions based on the

same data that is required on the series '04 reports. The Commission is

proposing to move to an entirely electronic filing system, allowing for

efficiencies in populating and submitting forms that require the same

information every month. Most traders who are required to file the

series '04 reports must do so for only one day out of the month,

further lowering the burden for filers. In short, the Commission

believes potential burdens under the Reproposal have been reduced

wherever possible while still providing adequate information for the

Commission's Surveillance program. For market participants who may

require assistance in monitoring for speculative position limits and

gathering the information required for the series '04 reports, the

Commission is aware of several software companies who, prior to the

vacation of the Part 151 Rulemaking, produced tools that could be

useful to market participants in fulfilling their compliance

obligations under the new position limits regime.

The Commission notes that the reporting obligations proposed in the

2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal are intended to be

complimentary to, not duplicative of, the series '04 reporting forms.

In particular, the Commission notes the distinction between Form 204

enumerated hedging reporting and exchange-based non-enumerated hedging

reporting. The 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal provides

exchanges with the authority to require reporting from market

participants. That is, regarding an exchange's process for non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position recognition, the exchange has

discretion to implement any additional reporting that it may require.

The Commission declines to eliminate series '04 reporting in response

to the commenters because, as noted throughout this section, the data

provided on the forms is critical to the mission of the Commission's

Surveillance program to detect and deter manipulation and abusive

trading practices in physical commodity markets.

In response to the commenters that requested guidebooks for the

series '04 reporting forms, the Commission believes that it is less

confusing to ensure that form instructions are clear and detailed than

it is to provide generalized guidebooks that may not respond to

specific issues. The Commission has clarified the sample series `04

forms found in Appendix A to part 19, including instructions to such

forms, and invites comments in order to avoid future confusion.

Specifically, the Commission has added instructions regarding how to

fill out the trader identification section of each form; reorganized

instructions relating to individual fields on each form; edited the

examples of each form to reduce confusion and match changes to

information required as described in this section; and clarified the

authority for the certifications made on the signature/authorization

page of each form.

The Commission's longstanding experience with collecting and

reviewing Form 204 and Form 304 has shown that many questions about the

series '04 reports are specific to the circumstances and trading

strategies of an individual market participant, and do not lend

themselves to generalization that would be helpful to many market

participants.

The Commission also notes, in response to the commenter expressing

concerns about other regulatory requirements, the policy objectives and

standards for hedging under financial accounting standards differ from

the statutory policy objectives and standards for hedging under the

Act. Because of this, reporting requirements, and the associated

burdens, would also differ between the series '04 reports and

accounting statements.

Finally, the Commission is proposing to amend the certification

language found at the end of each form to clarify that the

certification requires nothing more than is already required of market

participants in section 6(c)(2) of the Act. In response to the

commenters' request for a ``best effort'' standard, the Commission

added the phrase ``to the best of my knowledge'' preceding the

certification from the authorized representative of the reporting

trader that the information on the form is true and correct. The

Commission has also added instructions to each form clarifying what is

required on the signature/authorization page of each form. The

Commission notes that, in the recent past, the Division of Market

Oversight has issued advisories and guidance on proper filing of series

'04 reports, and the Division of Enforcement has settled several cases

regarding lack of accuracy and/or timeliness in filing series '04

forms.\898\ The Commission believes the certification language is an

important reminder to reporting traders of their responsibilities to

file accurate information under several sections of the Act, including

but not limited to CEA section 6(c)(2).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\898\ See, e.g., ``Obligation of Reportable Market Participants

to File CFTC Form 204 Reports,'' CFTC Staff Advisory 13-42, July 8,

2013; and CFTC Dockets Nos. 16-21, 15-41, 16-07, 16-20.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. Amended cross references

Proposed Rule: As discussed above, in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, the Commission proposed to replace the definition of

bona fide hedging transaction found in Sec. 1.3(z) with a new proposed

definition of bona fide hedging position in proposed Sec. 150.1. As a

result, proposed part 19 would replace cross-references to Sec. 1.3(z)

with cross-references to the new definition of bona fide hedging

positions in proposed Sec. 150.1.

The Commission also proposed expanding Part 19 to include reporting

requirements for positions in swaps, in addition to futures and options

positions, for any part of which a person relies on an exemption. To

accomplish this, ``positions in commodity derivative contracts,'' as

defined in proposed Sec. 150.1, would replace ``futures and option

positions'' throughout amended

[[Page 96802]]

part 19 as shorthand for any futures, option, or swap contract in a

commodity (other than a security futures product as defined in CEA

section 1a(45)).\899\ This amendment was intended to harmonize the

reporting requirements of part 19 with proposed amendments to part 150

that encompass swap transactions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\899\ See discussion above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Proposed Sec. 19.00(a) would eliminate the cross-reference to the

definition of reportable position in Sec. 15.00(p)(2). The Commission

noted that the current reportable position definition essentially

identifies futures and option positions in excess of speculative

position limits. Proposed Sec. 19.00(a) would simply make clear that

the reporting requirement applies to commodity derivative contract

positions (including swaps) that exceed speculative position limits, as

discussed below.

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on the

proposed cross-referencing amendments.

Commission Reproposal: The Commission is repurposing the amended

cross-references in part 19, as originally proposed.

b. Persons required to report--Sec. 19.00(a)

Proposed Rule: Because the reporting requirements of current part

19 apply only to persons holding bona fide hedge positions and

merchants and dealers in cotton holding or controlling reportable

positions for future delivery in cotton, the Commission proposed to

extend the reach of part 19 by requiring all persons who wish to avail

themselves of any exemption from federal position limits under proposed

Sec. 150.3 to file applicable series '04 reports.\900\ The Commission

also proposed to require that anyone exceeding a federal limit who has

received a special call related to part 150 must file a series '04

form. Collection of this information would facilitate the Commission's

surveillance program with respect to detecting and deterring trading

activity that may tend to cause sudden or unreasonable fluctuations or

unwarranted changes in the prices of the referenced contracts and their

underlying commodities. By broadening the scope of persons who must

file series '04 reports, the Commission seeks to ensure that any person

who claims any exemption from federal speculative position limits can

demonstrate a legitimate purpose for doing so.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\900\ See 17 CFR part 19. Current part 19 cross-references the

definition of reportable position in 17 CFR 15.00(p).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Series '04 reports currently refers to Form 204 and Form 304, which

are listed in current Sec. 15.02.\901\ The Commission proposed to add

three new series '04 reporting forms to effectuate the expanded

reporting requirements of part 19.\902\ Proposed Form 504 would be

added for use by persons claiming the conditional spot-month limit

exemption pursuant to proposed Sec. 150.3(c).\903\ Proposed Form 604

would be added for use by persons claiming a bona fide hedge exemption

for either of two specific pass-through swap position types, as

discussed further below.\904\ Proposed Form 704 would be added for use

by persons claiming a bona fide hedge exemption for certain

anticipatory bona fide hedging positions.\905\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\901\ 17 CFR 15.02.

\902\ As noted in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

the Commission is avoiding the use of any form numbers with ``404''

to avoid confusion with the part 151 Rulemaking, which required

Forms 404, 404A, and 404S. See December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, 78 FR at 75742.

\903\ See supra discussion of proposed Sec. 150.3(c).

\904\ Proposed Form 604 would replace Form 404S (as contemplated

in vacated part 151).

\905\ The updated definition of bona fide hedging in proposed

Sec. 150.1 incorporates several specific types of anticipatory

transactions: Unfilled anticipated requirements, unsold anticipated

production, anticipated royalties, anticipated services contract

payments or receipts, and anticipatory cross-commodity hedges. See

paragraphs (3)(iii), (4)(i), (4)(iii), (4)(iv) and (5),

respectively, of the Commission's amended definition of bona fide

hedging transactions in proposed Sec. 150.1 as discussed above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on proposed

Sec. 19.00(a) regarding who must file series '04 reports.

Commission Reproposal: The Commission is reproposing the expansion

of Sec. 19.00(a), as originally proposed.

c. Manner of reporting--Sec. 19.00(b)

i. Excluding certain source commodities, products or byproducts of the

cash commodity hedged--Sec. 19.00(b)(1)

Proposed Rule: For purposes of reporting cash market positions

under current part 19, the Commission historically has allowed a

reporting trader to ``exclude certain products or byproducts in

determining his cash positions for bona fide hedging'' if it is ``the

regular business practice of the reporting trader'' to do so.\906\ The

Commission has proposed to clarify the meaning of ``economically

appropriate'' in light of this reporting exclusion of certain cash

positions.\907\ Therefore, in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, the Commission proposed in Sec. 19.00(b)(1) that a source

commodity itself can only be excluded from a calculation of a cash

position if the amount is de minimis, impractical to account for, and/

or on the opposite side of the market from the market participant's

hedging position.\908\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\906\ See 17 CFR 19.00(b)(1) (providing that ``[i]f the regular

business practice of the reporting trader is to exclude certain

products or byproducts in determining his cash position for bona

fide hedging . . . ., the same shall be excluded in the report'').

\907\ See supra discussion of the ``economically appropriate

test'' as it relates to the definition of bona fide hedging

position. In order for a position to be economically appropriate to

the reduction of risks in the conduct and management of a commercial

enterprise, the enterprise generally should take into account all

inventory or products that the enterprise owns or controls, or has

contracted for purchase or sale at a fixed price. For example, in

line with its historical approach to the reporting exclusion, the

Commission does not believe that it would be economically

appropriate to exclude large quantities of a source commodity held

in inventory when an enterprise is calculating its value at risk to

a source commodity and it intends to establish a long derivatives

position as a hedge of unfilled anticipated requirements.

\908\ Proposed Sec. 19.00(b)(1) adds a caveat to the

alternative manner of reporting: When reporting for the cash

commodity of soybeans, soybean oil, or soybean meal, the reporting

person shall show the cash positions of soybeans, soybean oil and

soybean meal. This proposed provision for the soybean complex is

included in the current instructions for preparing Form 204.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission explained in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal that the original part 19 reporting exclusion was intended to

cover only cash positions that were not capable of being delivered

under the terms of any derivative contract, an intention that

ultimately evolved to allow cross-commodity hedging of products and

byproducts of a commodity that were not necessarily deliverable under

the terms of any derivative contract. The Commission also noted that

the instructions on current Form 204 go further than current Sec.

19.00(b)(1) by allowing the exclusion of certain source commodities in

addition to products and byproducts, when it is the firm's normal

business practice to do so.

Comments Received: One commenter suggested the Commission expand

the provision in proposed Sec. 19.00(b)(1) that allows a reporting

person to exclude source commodities, products or byproducts in

determining its cash position for bona fide hedging to allow a person

to also exclude inventory and contracts of the actual commodity in the

course of his or her regular business practice. The commenter also

noted that proposed Sec. 19.00(b)(1) only permits this exclusion if

the amount is de minimis, despite there being ``many circumstances''

that make the inclusion of such source commodities irrelevant for

reporting purposes. The commenter requested that the Commission only

require a reporting person to calculate its cash positions in

accordance with its regular business practice and report the

[[Page 96803]]

cash positions that it considered in making its bona fide hedging

determinations.\909\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\909\ See CL-Working Group-60396 at 16-17; CL-Working Group-

60947 at 15-17.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission is reproposing Sec.

19.00(b)(1), as originally proposed, because the Commission is

concerned that adopting the commenter's request could lead to ``cherry-

picking'' a cash market position in an attempt to justify a speculative

position as a hedge. As noted in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, the Commission's clarification of the Sec. 19.00(b)(1)

reporting exclusion was proposed to prevent the definition of bona fide

hedging positions in proposed Sec. 150.1 from being swallowed by this

reporting rule. The Commission stated ``. . . it would not be

economically appropriate behavior for a person who is, for example,

long derivative contracts to exclude inventory when calculating

unfilled anticipated requirements. Such behavior would call into

question whether an offset to unfilled anticipated requirements is, in

fact, a bona fide hedging position, since such inventory would fill the

requirement. As such, a trader can only underreport cash market

activities on the opposite side of the market from her hedging position

as a regular business practice, unless the unreported inventory

position is de minimis or impractical to account for.'' \910\ If a

person were only required to report cash positions that are offset by

particular derivative positions, then the form would not provide an

indication as to whether the derivative position is economically

appropriate to the reduction of risk, making the inclusion of source

commodities very relevant for reporting purposes, contrary to the

commenter's suggestion.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\910\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75743. The Commission provided an example: ``By way of example, the

alternative manner of reporting in proposed Sec. 19.00(b)(1) would

permit a person who has a cash inventory of 5 million bushels of

wheat, and is short 5 million bushels worth of commodity derivative

contracts, to underreport additional cash inventories held in small

silos in disparate locations that are administratively difficult to

count.'' This person could instead opt to calculate and report these

hard-to-count inventories and establish additional short positions

in commodity derivative contracts as a bona fide hedge against such

additional inventories.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Because of these and other concerns, market participants have

historically been required to report cash market information in

aggregate form for the commodity as a whole, not the ``line item''

style of hedge reporting requested by the commenter (where firms report

cash trades by category, tranche, or corresponding futures position).

Further, since it is important for Surveillance purposes to receive a

snapshot of a market participant's cash market position, the series '04

forms currently require a market participant to provide relevant

inventories and fixed price contracts in the hedged (or cross-hedged)

commodity. The Commission believes it is necessary to maintain this

aggregate reporting in order for the Commission's Surveillance program

to properly monitor for position limit violations and to prevent market

manipulation.

Further, the Commission believes that firms may find reporting an

aggregate cash market position less burdensome than attempting to

identify portions of that position that most closely align with

individual hedge positions as, according to some commenters, many firms

hedge on a portfolio basis, making identifying the particular hedge

being used difficult.\911\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\911\ See CL-Working Group-59693 at 65.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Cross-commodity Hedges, Standards and Conversion Factors--Sec.

19.00(b)(2)-(3)

Proposed Rules: In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission proposed under Sec. 19.00(b)(2) instructions for reporting

a cash position in a commodity that is different from the commodity

underlying the futures contract used for hedging.\912\ The Commission

also proposed to maintain the requirement in Sec. 19.00(b)(3) that

standards and conversion factors used in computing cash positions for

reporting purposes must be made available to the Commission upon

request.\913\ The Commission clarified that such information would

include hedge ratios used to convert the actual cash commodity to the

equivalent amount of the commodity underlying the commodity derivative

contract used for hedging, and an explanation of the methodology used

for determining the hedge ratio. Finally, the Commission provided

examples of completed series '04 forms in proposed Appendix A to part

19 along with blank forms and instructions.\914\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\912\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75743. The proposed Sec. 19.00(b)(2) is consistent with provisions

in the current section, but would add the term commodity derivative

contracts (as defined in proposed Sec. 150.1). The proposed

definition of cross-commodity hedge in proposed Sec. 150.1 is

discussed above.

\913\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75743.

\914\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on proposed

Sec. Sec. 19.00(b)(2)-(3).

Commission Reproposal: The Commission is reproposing Sec. Sec.

19.00(b)(2)-(3), as originally proposed.

d. Information Required--Sec. 19.01(a)

i. Bona Fide Hedgers Reporting on Form 204--Sec. 19.01(a)(3)

Proposed Rule: Current Sec. 19.01(a) sets forth the data that must

be provided by bona fide hedgers (on Form 204) and by merchants and

dealers in cotton (on Form 304). The Commission proposed to continue

using Forms 204 and 304, which will feature only minor changes to the

types of data to be reported under Sec. 19.01(a)(3).\915\ These

changes include removing the modifier ``fixed price'' from ``fixed

price cash position;'' requiring cash market position information to be

submitted in both the cash market unit of measurement (e.g. barrels or

bushels) and futures equivalents; and adding a specific request for

data concerning open price contracts to accommodate open price pairs.

In addition, the monthly reporting requirements for cotton, including

the granularity of equity, certificated and non-certificated cotton

stocks, would be moved to Form 204, while weekly reporting for cotton

would be retained as a separate report made on Form 304 in order to

maintain the collection of data required by the Commission to publish

its weekly public cotton ``on call'' report.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\915\ The list of data required for persons filing on Forms 204

and 304 has been relocated from current Sec. 19.01(a) to proposed

Sec. 19.01(a)(3).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received several comments

regarding the proposed revisions to Form 204. These comments can be

grouped loosely into three categories: general comments on bona fide

hedge reporting; comments regarding the general information required on

Form 204; and comments regarding the more specific nature of the cash

market information required to be reported. The Commission responds to

each category separately below.

Comments: One commenter stated that CFTC should reduce the

complexity and compliance burden of bona fide hedging record keeping

and reporting by using a model similar to the current exchange-based

exemption process.\916\ The commenter also stated that the requirement

to keep records and file reports, in futures equivalents, regarding the

commercial entity's cash market contracts and derivative market

positions on a real-time basis globally, will be complex and impose a

significant compliance burden. The

[[Page 96804]]

commenter noted such records are not needed for commercial

purposes.\917\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\916\ CL-ASR-59668 at 3.

\917\ CL-ASR-59668 at 7; CL-ASR-60933 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter requested that the Commission provide for a single

hedge exemption application and reporting process, and should not

require applicants to file duplicative forms at the exchange and at the

Commission. The commenter noted its support for rules that would

delegate, to the exchanges, (1) the hedge exemption application and

approval process, and (2) hedge exemption reporting (if any is

required). The commenter argued that the exchanges, rather than the

Commission, have a long history with enforcing position limits on all

of their contracts and are in a much better position than the

Commission to judge the applicant's hedging needs and set an

appropriate hedge level for the hedge being sought. Thus, the commenter

suggested, the exchanges should be the point of contact for market

participants seeking hedge exemptions.\918\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\918\ CL-AGA-59935 at 13.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter requested that the Commission address all pending

requests for CEA 4a(a)(7) exemptions and respond to all requests for

bona fide hedging exemptions from the energy industry.\919\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\919\ CL-NFP-60393 at 15-16.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: In response to the first commenter, the

Commission notes that, while the exchange referred to by the commenter

does not have a reporting process analogous to Form 204, it does

require an application prior to the establishment of a position that

exceeds a position limit. In contrast, advance notice is not required

for most federal enumerated bona fide hedging positions.\920\ In the

Commission's experience, the series '04 reports have been useful and

beneficial to the Commission's Surveillance program and the Commission

finds no compelling reason to change the forms to conform to the

exchange's process. Further, the Commission notes that Form 204 is

filed once a month as of the close of business of the last Friday of

the month; it is not and has never been required to be filed on a real-

time basis globally. A market participant only has to file Form 204 if

it is over the limit at any point during the month, and the form

requires only cash market activity (not derivatives market positions).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\920\ The Commission notes that advance notice is required for

recognition of anticipatory hedging positions by the Commission. See

below for more discussion of anticipatory hedging reporting

requirements.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The second commenter was responding to questions raised at the

Energy and Environmental Markets Advisory Council Meeting in June 2014;

the Commission notes in response to that commenter that there is no

federal exemption application process for most enumerated hedges. For

non-enumerated hedges and certain enumerated anticipatory hedges, in

response to the EEMAC meeting and other comments from market

participants, the Commission proposed a single exchange based process

for recognizing bona fide hedges for both federal and exchange limits.

Under this process, proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, market participants would not be required to file with both

the exchange and the Commission.\921\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\921\ See supra the discussion of proposed Sec. Sec. 150.9 and

150.11.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Finally, in response to the commenter's request that the Commission

respond to pending requests for exemptions under CEA section 4a(a)(7),

the Commission notes that it responded to the outstanding section

4a(a)(7) requests in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal. In

particular, the Commission proposed to include some of the energy

industry's requests in the definition of bona fide hedging position and

declined to include other requests.\922\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\922\ The reasoning behind the Commission's determinations with

respect to previous requests for exemption under CEA section

4a(a)(7) is documented in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, 78 FR at 75719-75722. See also the definition of bona fide

hedging position discussed supra.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments: One commenter recommended that the Commission clarify

that column three of Form 204 should permit a market participant to

identify the number of futures-equivalent referenced contracts that

hedge an identified amount of cash-market positions, but without

separately identifying the positions in each referenced contract. The

commenter stated that separate identification would add to the

financial burden, but that it does not believe that it adds any benefit

to the Commission.\923\ Two commenters also recommended the Commission

remove from Form 204 the requirement for reporting non-referenced

contracts, noting that the Commission did not explain why a market

participant should report commodity derivative contracts that are not

referenced contracts.\924\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\923\ CL-FIA-59595 at 38.

\924\ The Commission notes that the commenters are referring to

titular language on column 3 of the example Form 204 found in

proposed Appendix A to part 19, which states ``Commodity Derivative

Contract or Referenced Contract'' as the information required in

that column. CL-FIA-59595 at 38; CL-Working Group-59693 at 65.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter also recommended that the Commission either delete or

make optional the identification of a particular enumerated position in

column two of Section A or provide a good-faith standard. The commenter

claimed that many energy firms hedge on a portfolio basis, and would

not be able to identify a particular enumerated position that applies

to the referenced contract position needing bona fide hedging

treatment.\925\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\925\ CL-Working Group-59693 at 65.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter asked for clarification regarding whether Section C

of Form 204, which requires information regarding cotton stocks, is

required of market participants in all commodities or just those in

cotton markets.\926\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\926\ CL-ASR-60933 at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter recommended that the Commission remove the

requirement in Form 204 to submit futures-equivalent derivative

positions, stating that the Commission did not explain why it needs to

obtain data on a market participant's futures-equivalent position as

part of proposed Form 204 in light of the presumption that the

Commission already has a market participant's future-equivalent

position from large-trader reporting rules and access to SDR data.\927\

Another commenter noted that Form 204 mixes units of measurement

between futures and cash positions and requested the Commission require

market participants to use either cash units or futures units. The

commenter noted that it's an easy conversion to make but that the

``mix'' of both units is confusing.\928\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\927\ CL-FIA-59595 at 37.

\928\ CL-ASR-60933 at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: With respect to the comments regarding

column three of Form 204, the Commission clarifies that Form 204 allows

filers to identify multiple referenced contracts used for hedging a

particular commodity cash position in the same line of Form 204.

Because position limits under Sec. 150.2 are to be imposed on

referenced contracts, cash positions hedged by such referenced

contracts should be reported on an aggregate basis, not separated out

by individual contract. However, the Commission declines to adopt the

commenters' recommendation to delete the phrase ``Commodity Derivative

Contract'' from the title of column three, because Sec. 19.00(a)(3)

allows the Commission to require filing of a series '04 form of anyone

holding a reportable position under Sec. 15.00(p)(1), which may

involve a commodity derivative contract that does not fit the

definition of referenced

[[Page 96805]]

contract.\929\ Further, the Commission can require a special call

respondent to file their response using the relevant series '04 form,

and the Form 204 may be filed in order to claim exemptions from

Sec. Sec. 150.3(b) or 150.3(d), exemptions which may not involve a

referenced contract. In sum, because the Commission may require the

filing of Form 204 for purposes other than bona fide hedging, the form

should include both ``Commodity Derivative Contract'' and, separately,

``Referenced Contract'' in the title of column three. To avoid further

confusion, the Commission has rephrased the wording of the column title

and amended the instructions to the form.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\929\ The Commission notes that Form 704 has been removed from

the list of series '04 forms that could be required under a special

call. This is a non-substantive change resulting from changes made

to Sec. 150.7, discussed infra.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With respect to column two of Form 204, the Commission is proposing

to adopt the commenter's recommendation to delete the requirement to

identify which paragraphs of the bona fide hedging definition are

represented by the hedged position. The requirement seemed to be

confusing to commenters who found it unclear whether the column

required the identification of all bona fide hedge definition

paragraphs used for the total cash market position or the

identification of separate cash positions for each paragraph used.

While the requirement was intended to provide insight into which

enumerated provision of the bona fide hedging definition was being

relied upon in order to provide context to the cash position, the

column was never intended to prevent multiple paragraphs being cited at

once. Given the confusion, the Commission is concerned that the

information in column two may not provide the intended information

while being burdensome to implement for both market participants and

Commission staff. For these reasons, the Commission is proposing to

delete column two of Form 204, and has updated the sample forms in

Appendix A to part 19 accordingly.

In response to the commenter requesting clarification regarding

Section C of Form 204, the Commission confirms that Section C is only

required of entities which hold positions in cotton markets that must

be reported on Form 204. Further, the Commission proposes that, in

order for the Commission to effectively evaluate the legitimacy of a

claimed bona fide hedging position, filers of Section C of Form 204

will be required to differentiate between equity stock held in their

capacities as merchants, producers, and/or agents in cotton. The

Commission has updated Section C of Form 204 and Sec.

19.01(a)(3)(vi)(A) to reflect this change. The Commission does not

believe this distinction will create any significant extra burden on

cotton merchants, as the Commission understands that many entities in

cotton markets will hold equity stocks in just one of the three

capacities required on the form.

The Commission notes in response to the last commenter that Form

204 does not require the futures equivalent value of derivative

positions but rather the futures equivalent of the cash position

underlying a hedged position (e.g., 20,000,000 barrels of crude oil is

equivalent to 20,000 futures equivalents, given a 1,000 barrel unit of

trading for the futures contract). The futures equivalent of the cash

position quantity is not available from any Commission data source

because cash positions are not reported to the Commission under, for

example, large trader reporting or swap data repository regulations.

The Commission is proposing to require firms to report both the cash

market unit of measurement and the futures equivalent measurement for a

position in order to easily identify the size of the position

underlying a hedge position, and has updated Sec. 19.01(a)(3),

instructions to the sample Form 204 in Appendix A to part 19, and the

field names on the Form 204 itself to clarify this requirement. The

Commission agrees with the commenter that it is an easy conversion to

make, and does not anticipate that this requirement will create any

significant extra burden on market participants. Obtaining the futures

equivalent information directly from the market participant--as opposed

to calculating it upon receipt of the form--is necessary particularly

with respect to cross-commodity hedging where calculating the hedging

ratio may not be as clear-cut. In its experience administering and

collecting Form 204, the Commission has noted much confusion regarding

whether cash market information should be reported in futures

equivalents or in cash market units. Currently, the form requires cash

market units, but the Commission has seen both units of measurement

used (sometimes on the same form), which requires Commission staff to

contact traders in order to validate the numbers on the form. The

Commission is proposing to require both in order to avoid such

confusion.

Comment: One commenter proposed modifications to the information

required to be reported on Form 204. Specifically, the commenter

suggested that the filer should be required to report the aggregate

quantity of cash positions that underlie bona fide hedging positions in

equivalent core referenced futures contract units, excluding all or

part of the commodity that it excludes in its regular business

practice. The commenter also suggested that if the filer is cross

hedging, the filer must also report the aggregated quantity of bona

fide hedge positions it is cross hedging in terms of the actual

commodity as well as specify the futures market in which it is

hedging.\930\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\930\ CL-Working Group-60947 at 17-18.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter suggested that the information required on Form

204 is ``ambiguous'' and asked the Commission to clarify what scope of,

for example, stocks or fixed price purchase and sales agreements must

be reported as well as what level of data precision is required.\931\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\931\ CL-COPE-60932 at 10. The commenter made the same requests

for clarification regarding the cash market information required on

Form 504; since the information is similar, the Commission is

responding here to the comment for both forms.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A commenter requested that the Commission allow hedges to be

reported on a ``macro'' basis (e.g. futures positions vs. cash

positions) as opposed to requiring the matching of individual physical

market transactions to enumerated bona fide hedges. The commenter

stated that performing specific linkage of individual physical

transactions to individual hedge transactions is burdensome and does

not provide any ``managerial or economic benefit.'' \932\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\932\ CL-ASR-60933 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In contrast, another commenter suggested that the Commission tailor

the series '04 reports to require ``only the information that is

required to justify the claimed hedge exemption.'' The commenter stated

that Form 204 appears to require a market participant to list all cash

market exposures, even if the exposures are not relevant to the bona

fide hedge exemption being claimed, which it believes would provide no

value to the Commission in determining whether a hedge was bona

fide.\933\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\933\ See CL-Working Group-60396 at 17.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter stated that because the prompt (spot) month for

certain referenced contracts will no longer trade as of the last Friday

of the month, a market participant that exceeds a spot-month position

limit who no longer has that spot-month position should not be required

to report futures-equivalent positions for referenced contract on Form

204.\934\ The commenter recommended that the Commission should require

a market

[[Page 96806]]

participant with a position in excess of a spot-month position limit to

report on Form 204 only the cash-market activity related to that

particular spot-month derivative position, and not to require it to

report cash-market activity related to non-spot-month positions where

it did not exceed a non-spot-month position limit; the commenter stated

that the burden associated with such a reporting obligation would

increase significantly.\935\ Separately, another commenter claimed that

Form 204 appears to address only non-spot-month position limits and

asked the Commission to clarify how it will distinguish reporting on

Form 204 that is related to a spot-month position limit versus a non-

spot-month position limit.\936\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\934\ CL-FIA-59595 at 37-38.

\935\ CL-FIA-59595 at 38.

\936\ CL-ASR-60933 at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter recommended that reporting rules require traders to

identify the specific risk being hedged at the time a trade is

initiated, to maintain records of termination or unwinding of a hedge

when the underlying risk has been sold or otherwise resolved, and to

create a practical audit trail for individual trades, to discourage

traders from attempting to mask speculative trades under the guise of

hedges.\937\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\937\ CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: In response to the modifications to Form 204

proposed by the commenter, the Commission notes that no modifications

are necessary because the form, as proposed, requires the reporting of

aggregated quantity of cash positions that underlie bona fide hedging

positions in equivalent core referenced futures contract units,

excluding a de minimis portion of the commodity, products, and

byproducts that it excludes in its regular business practice.\938\

Reproposed Form 204 also requires cross-hedgers to report the

aggregated quantity of bona fide hedging positions it is cross hedging

in terms of the actual commodity as well as specify the futures market

in which it is hedging.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\938\ See supra discussion of the exclusion of certain source

commodities, products, and byproducts of the cash commodity hedged

when reporting on Form 204.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission reproposes that the Form 204 requires a market

participant to report all cash market positions in any commodity in

which the participant has exceeded a spot-month or non-spot-month

position limit. Form 204 is not intended to match a firm's hedged

positions to underlying cash positions on a one-to-one basis; rather,

it is intended to provide a ``snapshot'' into the firm's cash market

position in a particular commodity as of one day during a month. The

information on this form is used for several purposes in addition to

reviewing hedged positions, including helping Surveillance analysts

understand changes in the market fundamentals in underlying commodity

markets.\939\ The Commission believes that adopting the commenters'

recommendations to require cash market information underlying a single

derivative hedge position would result in a more burdensome reporting

process for firms, particularly those who hedge on a portfolio basis.

Instead, the Commission is confirming that, as requested by the

commenter, cash market positions should be reported on an aggregated or

``macro'' basis.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\939\ In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission highlighted the importance of the data collected on Form

204 to its Surveillance program, stating that ``[c]ollection of this

information would facilitate the Commission's surveillance program

with respect to detecting and deterring trading activity that may

tend to cause sudden or unreasonable fluctuations or unwarranted

changes in the prices of the referenced contracts and their

underlying commodities.'' See December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, 78 FR at 75742.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that this ``snapshot'' requirement has

historically been--and is currently--required on Form 204 for the nine

legacy agricultural contracts. Further, the Commission understands that

exchange hedge application forms require similar cash position

information; firms that have applied to an exchange for hedge

exemptions in non-legacy contracts should already be familiar with

providing cash market information when they exceed a position limit or

a position accountability level.

The commenters that focus on the Form 204 as it relates to

exceeding either spot-month position limits or non-spot-month position

limits contrast each other: one believed Form 204 was to be filed in

response to exceeding only spot-month position limits and the other

that Form 204 was to be filed in response to exceeding only non-spot-

month position limits. However, the Commission has never distinguished

between spot-month limits and non-spot-month limits with respect to the

filing of Form 204. The Commission notes that, as discussed in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, Form 204 is used to review

positions that exceed speculative limits in general, not just in the

spot-month.\940\ Because of this, the Commission is not adopting the

commenter's recommendation to only require Form 204 when a market

participant exceeds a spot-month limit.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\940\ The Commission stated that the Form 204 ``must show the

trader's positions in the cash market and are used by the Commission

to determine whether a trader has sufficient cash positions that

justify futures and option positions above the speculative limits''

because the Commission is seeking to ``ensure that any person who

claims any exemption from federal speculative position limits can

demonstrate a legitimate purpose for doing so.'' See December 2013

Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75741-2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to the commenter who suggested the Commission require a

``practical audit trail'' for bona fide hedgers, the Commission notes

that other sections of the Commission's regulations provide rules

regarding detailed individual transaction recordkeeping as suggested by

the commenter.

ii. Cotton Merchants and Dealers Reporting on Form 304--Sec. 19.02

Proposed Rule: In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission proposed to continue to require the filing of Form 304,

which requires information on the quantity of call cotton bought or

sold, on a weekly basis. The Commission noted that Form 304 is required

in order for the Commission to produce its weekly cotton ``on call''

report.\941\ The Commission also proposed to relocate the list of

required information for Form 304 from current Sec. 19.01(a) to

proposed Sec. 19.01(a)(3).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\941\ The Commission's Weekly Cotton On-Call Report can be found

here: http://www.cftc.gov/MarketReports/CottonOnCall/index.htm.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission did not receive any comments on

the proposed changes to Form 304.

Commission Reproposal: The Commission is reproposing Form 304, as

originally proposed.

iii. Conditional Spot-Month Limit Exemption Reporting on Form 504--

Sec. 19.01(a)(1)

Proposed Rule: As proposed, Sec. 19.01(a)(1) would require persons

availing themselves of the conditional spot-month limit exemption

(pursuant to proposed Sec. 150.3(c)) to report certain detailed

information concerning their cash market activities for any commodity

specially designated by the Commission for reporting under Sec. 19.03

of this part. In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission noted its concern about the cash market trading of those

availing themselves of the conditional spot-month limit exemption and

so proposed to require that persons claiming a conditional spot-month

limit exemption must report on new Form 504 daily, by 9 a.m. Eastern

Time on the next business day, for each day that a person is over the

spot-month limit in certain

[[Page 96807]]

special commodity contracts specified by the Commission.

The Commission proposed to require reporting on new Form 504 for

conditional spot-month limit exemptions in the natural gas commodity

derivative contracts only.

Comments Received: One commenter stated its belief that the

information required on Form 504 is redundant of information required

on Form 204 and would overly burden hedgers.\942\ The commenter

suggested that, if the Commission decides to retain the conditional

spot-month limit exemption, and thereby Form 504, the Commission should

require only an affirmative representation from market participants

that they do not hold any physical delivery Referenced Contracts.\943\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\942\ CL-Working Group-59693 at 65-66.

\943\ CL-Working Group-59693 at 65-66.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter stated that Form 504 creates a burden for hedgers

to track their cash business and affected contracts and to create

systems to file multiple forms. The commenter noted its belief that

end-users/hedgers should never be subjected to the daily filing of

reports.\944\ Further, the commenter suggested the Commission delete

Form 504 entirely, asserting that it will be unnecessary if the

Commission adopts the commenter's separate cash settled limit idea (the

commenter proposed a higher cash settled limit with no condition on the

physical delivery market).\945\ Another commenter suggested deleting

the Form 504 because it believes that no matter how extensive the

Commission makes reporting requirements, the Commission will still need

to request additional information on a case-by-case basis to ensure

hedge transactions are legitimate.\946\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\944\ CL-COPE-59662 at 24.

\945\ CL-COPE-59662 at 24.

\946\ CL-NGFA-60941 at 7-8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A third commenter suggested that the Commission should modify the

data requirements for Form 504 in a manner similar to the approach used

by ICE Futures U.S. for natural gas contracts, that is, requiring a

description of a market participant's cash-market positions as of a

specified date filed in advance of the spot-month.\947\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\947\ CL-FIA-59595 at 37.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has tentatively determined

under Sec. 19.03 to designate the Henry Hub Natural Gas referenced

contracts for reporting of a conditional spot-month limit exemption

under Sec. 19.00(a)(1)(i).

In response to the first three commenters, the Commission

reiterates a key distinction between the Form 504 and the Form 204.

Form 504 is required of speculators that are relying upon the

conditional spot-month limit exemption. Form 204 is required for

hedgers that exceed position limits. To the extent a firm is hedging,

there is no requirement to file the Form 504.

In the unlikely event that a firm is both hedging and relying upon

the conditional spot-month limit exemption, the firm would be required

to file both forms at most one day a month, given the timing of the

spot-month in natural gas markets (the only market for which Form 504

will be required at first). In that event, however, the Commission

believes that requiring similar information on both forms should

encourage filing efficiencies rather than duplicating the burden. For

example, both forms require the filer to identify fixed price purchase

commitments; the Commission believes it is not overly burdensome for

the same firm to report such similar information on the Form 204 and

the Form 504, should a market participant ever be required to file both

forms.

The Commission is not adopting the commenters' recommendations to

delete the Form 504 or to require only an affirmative representation

that the condition of the conditional spot-month limit exemption has

been met (i.e. that the trader holds no position in physical delivery

referenced contracts). The Commission explained in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal that its primary motive in requiring the cash

market information required on Form 504 is the need to detect and deter

manipulative activities in the underlying cash commodity that might be

used to benefit a derivatives position (or vice-versa).\948\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\948\ Specifically, the Commission stated that ``[w]hile traders

who avail themselves of this exemption could not directly influence

particular settlement prices by trading in the physical-delivery

referenced contract, the Commission remains concerned about such

traders' activities in the underlying cash commodity.'' See December

2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75744.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to the third commenter, the Commission does not believe

that a description of a cash market position is sufficient to allow

Commission staff to administer its Surveillance program. Descriptions

are not as exact as reported information, and the Commission believes

the information gathered in daily Form 504 reports would be more

complete--and thus more beneficial--in determining compliance and

detecting and deterring manipulation.

The Commission notes that since the Commission is proposing to

limit the conditional spot month limit exemption to natural gas

markets, the Form 504 will only be required from participants in

natural gas markets who seek to avail themselves of the conditional

spot-month limit exemption and any corresponding burden will apply to

only those participants.

iv. Pass-Through Swap Exemption Reporting on Form 604--Sec.

19.01(a)(2)

Proposed Rule: As proposed, Sec. 19.01(a)(2) would require a

person relying on the pass-through swap exemption who holds either of

two position types to file a report with the Commission on new Form

604.\949\ The first type of position, filed on Section A of Form 604,

is a swap executed opposite a bona fide hedger that is not a referenced

contract and for which the risk is offset with referenced contracts

(e.g., cross commodity hedging positions). The second type of position,

filed on Section B of Form 604, is a cash-settled swap (whether or not

the swap is, itself, a referenced contract) executed opposite a bona

fide hedger that is offset with physical-delivery referenced contracts

held into a spot-month.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\949\ Under the definition of bona fide hedging position in

Section 4a(c)(2) of the Act, a person who uses a swap to reduce

risks attendant to a position that qualifies as a bona fide hedging

position may pass-through those bona fides to the counterparty, even

if the person's swap position is not in excess of a position limit.

As such, positions in commodity derivative contracts that reduce the

risk of pass-through swaps would qualify as bona fide hedging

positions. See supra discussion of the proposed definition of bona

fide hedging position.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

These reports on Form 604 would explain hedgers' needs for large

referenced contract positions and would give the Commission the ability

to verify the positions were a bona fide hedge, with heightened daily

surveillance of spot-month offsets. Persons holding any type of pass-

through swap position other than the two described above would report

on Form 204.\950\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\950\ Persons holding pass-through swap positions that are

offset with referenced contracts outside the spot month (whether

such contracts are for physical delivery or are cash-settled) need

not report on Form 604 because swap positions that are referenced

contracts will be netted with offsetting referenced contract

positions outside the spot month pursuant to proposed Sec.

150.2(b).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: The Commission received three comments regarding

Form 604, all from the same commenter. These comments and the

Commission's responses are detailed below.

Comment: One commenter recommended that the Commission remove the

requirement in Form 604 to submit futures-equivalent derivative

[[Page 96808]]

positions, claiming that the Commission did not explain why it needs to

obtain data on a market participant's futures-equivalent position as

part of proposed Form 604 in light of the commenter's presumption that

the Commission already has a market participant's future-equivalent

position from large-trader reporting rules and access to SDR data.\951\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\951\ CL-FIA-59595 at 37.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: In response to the commenter, the Commission

notes that futures-equivalent position information is necessary to

allow staff to match the offset futures position with the non-

referenced-contract swap position underlying the hedge because such

positions are not subject to part 20 reporting. The Commission notes

that Form 604 is filed outside of the spot month only if the swap

position being offset is not a referenced contract. Since only

referenced contracts are automatically netted for purposes of

determining compliance with position limits, the Commission would not

have knowledge or reason to net a pass-through swap position with the

participant's futures positions without the filing of Form 604. During

the spot month, the Commission notes that, while it has access to

referenced contract swap positions in part 20 data, the Commission

would not know that a particular swap forms the basis for a pass-

through swap offset exemption, and so again would not have knowledge or

reason to net a pass-through swap position with the participant's

futures position. Without Section B of Form 604 filed during the spot

month, the Commission may believe a firm is in violation of physical-

delivery spot month limits despite the firm being eligible for a pass-

through swap offset exemption. The Commission is proposing to require

the identification of a particular swap position and the offsetting

referenced contract position to alleviate concerns about the disruption

of the price discovery function of the underlying physical-delivery

contract during the spot month period.

Comment: The same commenter also noted that the spot-month for

certain referenced contracts will no longer trade as of the last Friday

of the month and so recommended that a market participant exceeding a

spot-month position limit who no longer has that spot-month position

should not be required to report futures-equivalent derivatives

positions for referenced contract on Form 604.\952\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\952\ CL-FIA-59595 at 37-38.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: As proposed, pass-through swap offsets that

last into the spot-month would be filed daily during the spot period,

not as of the last Friday of the month.\953\ Pass-through swap offset

positions outside of the spot-month are required to be filed as of the

last Friday of the month. The Commission expects that, in most cases,

the Form 604 would be filed outside of the spot-month which means only

Section A would need to be filed. That filing is required as of the

last Friday of the month, the same timeline that is required for the

Form 204, for convenience and ease of filing.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\953\ See supra discussion regarding the time and place of

filing series '04 reports.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comment: Finally, the commenter recommended that CFTC require a

market participant with a position in excess of a spot-month position

limit to report on Form 604 only the cash-market activity related to

that particular spot-month derivative position, and not to require it

to report cash-market activity related to non-spot-month positions

where it did not exceed a non-spot-month position limit, since the

burden associated with such a reporting obligation would increase

significantly.\954\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\954\ CL-FIA-59595 at 38.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission notes in response to the

commenter that neither Sections A nor B of Form 604 would require the

filer to report cash market activity.

This commenter makes the same remarks regarding Form 204, but the

Form 204 requires cash-market activity in a particular commodity

whereas the Form 604 requires information on a particular swap market

position.

The Commission is reproposing Form 604, as originally proposed.

e. Time and Place of Filing Reports--Sec. 19.01(b)

Proposed Rule: As proposed, Sec. 19.01(b)(1) would require all

reports except those submitted in response to special calls or on Form

504, Form 604 during the spot-month, or Form 704 to be filed monthly as

of the close of business on the last Friday of the month and not later

than 9 a.m. Eastern Time on the third business day following the last

Friday of the month.\955\ For reports submitted on Form 504 and Form

604 during the spot-month, proposed Sec. 19.01(b)(2) would require

filings to be submitted as of the close of business for each day the

person exceeds the limit during the spot period and not later than 9

a.m. Easter Time on the next business day following the date of the

report.\956\ Finally, proposed Sec. 19.01(b)(3) would require series

`04 reports to be transmitted using the format, coding structure, and

electronic data transmission procedures approved in writing by the

Commission or its designee.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\955\ The timeframe for filing Form 704 is included as part of

proposed Sec. 150.7. See supra for discussion regarding the filing

of Form 704.

\956\ In proposed Sec. 19.01(b)(2), the Commission

inadvertently failed to include reports filed under Sec.

19.00(a)(1)(ii)(B) (i.e. Form 604 during the spot month) in the same

filing timeframe as reports filed under Sec. 19.00(a)(1)(i) (i.e.

Form 504). The correct filing timeframe was described in multiple

places on the forms published in the Federal Register as part of the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: One commenter stated its support for the

proposed monthly, rather than daily, filing of Form 204.\957\ Another

commenter recommended an annual Form 204 filing requirement, rather

than a monthly filing requirement. The commenter noted that because the

general size and nature of its business is relatively constant, the

differences between each monthly report would be insignificant. The

commenter recommended the CFTC ``not impose additional costs of monthly

reporting without a demonstration of significant additional regulatory

benefits.'' The commenter noted its futures position typically exceeds

the proposed position limits, but such positions are bona fide hedging

positions. In addition to futures, the commenter noted it executes a

small notional volume of swaps as hedges of forward contracts.\958\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\957\ CL-Working Group-59693 at 65.

\958\ CL-DFA-59621 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Similarly, another commenter suggested that if the Commission does

not eliminate the forms in favor of the requirements in the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal the Commission should require

only an annual notice that details its maximum cash market exposure

that justifies an exemption, to be filed with the exchange.\959\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\959\ CL-FIA-60937 at 17.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter suggested that the reporting date for Form 204 should

be the close of business on the day prior to the beginning of the spot

period and that it should be required to filed no later than the 15th

day of the month following a month in which a filer exceeded a federal

limit to allow the market participant sufficient time to collect and

report its information.\960\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\960\ CL-Working Group-60947 at 17-18.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With regards to proposed Sec. 19.01(b)(2), one commenter

recommended CFTC change the proposed next-day reporting of Form 504 for

the conditional spot-month limit exemption and Form 604 for the pass-

through swap offsets during the spot-month, to a monthly basis, noting

[[Page 96809]]

market participants need time to generate and collect data and verify

the accuracy of the reported data. The commenter further stated that

CFTC did not explain why it needs the data on Form 504 or Form 604 on a

next-day basis.\961\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\961\ CL-FIA-59595 at 35.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another asserted that the daily filing requirement (Form 504) for

participants who rely on the conditional spot-month limit exemption

``imposes significant burdens and substantial costs on market

participants.'' The commenter urged a monthly rather than a daily

filing of all cash market positions, which the commenter claimed is

consistent with current exchange practices.\962\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\962\ CL-ICE-59669 at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission is reproposing Sec.

19.01(b)(1), as originally proposed, with some minor clarifications to

the language to make the text easier to follow. As discussed above, the

Commission believes that Form 204 provides a monthly ``snapshot'' of

the cash market positions of traders whose positions are in excess of

spot-month or non-spot-month speculative position limits and for that

reason it is necessary to provide its Surveillance program the ability

to detect and deter market manipulation and protect the price discovery

process. The Commission is retaining the last Friday of the month as

the required reporting date in order to avoid confusion and

uncertainty, particularly for those participants who already file Form

204 and thus are accustomed to that reporting date.

In response to the commenters' suggestions that Form 204 be filed

annually, the Commission notes that throughout the course of a year,

most commodities subject to federal position limits under proposed

Sec. 150.2 are subject to seasonality of prices as well as less

predictable imbalances in supply and demand such that an annual filing

would not provide Surveillance insight into cash market trends

underlying changes in the derivative markets. This insight is necessary

for Surveillance to determine whether price changes in derivative

markets are caused by fundamental factors or manipulative behavior.

Further, the Commission believes that an annual filing could actually

be more burdensome for firms, as an annual filing could lead to special

calls or requests between filings for additional information in order

for the Commission's Surveillance program to fulfill its responsibility

to detect and deter market manipulation. In addition, the Commission

notes that while one participant's positions may remain constant

throughout a year, the same is not true for many other market

participants. The Commission believes that varying the filing

arrangement depending on a particular market or market participant is

impractical and would lead to increased burdens for market participants

due to uncertainty regarding when each firm, or each firm by each

commodity, is supposed to file.

The Commission is reproposing, as originally proposed, the

provision in proposed Sec. 19.01(b)(2) to require next-day, daily

filing of Forms 504 and 604 in the spot-month. In response to the

commenter, the Commission notes that it described its rationale for

requiring Forms 504 and 604 daily during the spot-month in the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal.\963\ In order to detect and deter

manipulation during the spot-month, concurrent information regarding

the cash positions of a speculator holding a conditional spot-month

limit exemption (Form 504) or the swap contract underlying a large

offsetting position in the physical delivery contract (Form 604) is

necessary during the spot-month. Receiving Forms 504 or 604 before or

after the spot-month period would not help the Surveillance program to

protect the price discovery process of physical-delivery contracts and

to ensure that market participants have a qualifying pass-through swap

contract position underlying offsetting futures positions held during

the spot-month.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\963\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75744-5.

The Commission noted that its experience overseeing the ``dramatic

instances of disruptive trading practices in the natural gas

markets'' warranted enhanced reporting for that commodity during the

spot month on Form 504. The Commission noted its intent to wait

until it gained additional experience with limits in other

commodities before imposing enhanced reporting requirements for

those commodities. The Commission further noted that it was

concerned that a trader could hold an extraordinarily large position

early in the spot month in the physical-delivery contract along with

an offsetting short position in a cash-settled contract (such as a

swap), and that such a large position could disrupt the price

discovery function of the core referenced futures contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that, as reproposed, the Form 504 is required

only for the Natural Gas commodity, which has a 3-day spot period.\964\

Daily reporting of the Form 504 during the spot-month allows

Surveillance to monitor a market participant's cash market activity

that could impact or benefit their derivatives position. Given the

short filing period for natural gas and the importance of accurate

information during the spot-month, the Commission believes that

requiring the Form 504 to be filed daily provides an important benefit

that outweighs the potential burdens for filers

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\964\ Reproposed Sec. 150.3(c) provides a conditional spot-

month limit exemption only for the natural gas cash-settled

referenced contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As a practical matter, the Commission notes that the Form 604 is

collected during the spot-month only under particular circumstances,

i.e. for an offsetting position in physical delivery referenced

contracts during the spot-month. Because the ``five-day rule'' applies

to such positions, the spot-month filing of the Form 604 would only

occur in contracts whose spot-month period is longer than 5 days

(excluding, for example, energy contracts but including many

agricultural commodities).\965\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\965\ It should be noted, however that an exchange, using its

discretion, could require the filing of Form 604, for example, in an

energy contract, as part of the exchange's recognition of a non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position under Sec. 150.9, discussed

below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is reproposing Sec. Sec. 19.01(b)(1)-(2), as

originally proposed, with some minor clarifications to the language to

make the text easier to follow. The Commission inadvertently left out

of proposed Sec. 19.01(b)(2) a reference to the requirement to file

Section B of Form 604 (pass-through swap offsets held into the spot-

month). No commenter appeared to be confused about this requirement, as

the correct timeframe was described in multiple places on the forms

published in the Federal Register as part of the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, but to avoid future confusion the Commission has

modified the language--but not the substance--of Sec. 19.01(b)(1)-(2)

to clarify the time and place for filing series '04 reports.

Finally, the Commission is reproposing the electronic filing

requirement, as originally proposed.\966\ Further instructions on

submitting '04 reports will be available at http://www.cftc.gov/Forms/index.htm.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\966\ The Commission notes that the electronic filing

requirement was proposed in Sec. 19.01(b)(3) but due to other

changes within that section it is now located in Sec. 19.01(b)(4).

The substance of the requirement has not changed.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

F. Sec. 150.7--Reporting Requirements for Anticipatory Hedging

Positions

1. Reporting Requirements for Anticipatory Hedging Positions and New

Form 704

Proposed Rule: The Commission's revised definition of bona fide

hedging in Sec. 150.1 enumerates two new types of anticipatory bona

hedging positions. Two existing types of anticipatory hedges are being

continued from the existing definition of bona fide hedging in current

Sec. 1.3(z): Hedges of unfilled anticipated requirements and hedges of

[[Page 96810]]

unsold anticipated production, as well as anticipatory cross-commodity

hedges of such requirements or production.\967\ The revised Sec. 150.1

definition expands the list of enumerated anticipatory bona fide

hedging positions to include hedges of anticipated royalties and hedges

of anticipated services contract payments or receipts, as well as

anticipatory cross-commodity hedges of such contracts.\968\ As

discussed above, Sec. 1.48 has long required special reporting for

hedges of unfilled anticipated requirements and hedges of unsold

anticipated production because the Commission remains concerned about

distinguishing between anticipatory reduction of risk and speculation.

Such concerns apply equally to any position undertaken to reduce the

risk of anticipated transactions. Hence, the Commission proposed to

extend the special reporting requirements in proposed Sec. 150.7 for

all types of enumerated anticipatory hedges that appear in the

definition of bona fide hedging positions in proposed Sec. 150.1.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\967\ See current definition of bona fide hedging transactions

at 17 CFR 1.3(z)(2)(i)(B) and (ii)(C), respectively. Cross-commodity

hedges are permitted under 17 CFR 1.3(z)(2)(iv). Compare with

paragraphs (3)(iii) and (4)(i), respectively, of the definition of

bona fide hedging positions in proposed Sec. 150.1, discussed

above.

\968\ See sections (4)(iii), (4)(iv), and (5), respectively, of

the definition of bona fide hedging positions in Sec. 150.1,

discussed above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission proposed to add a new series '04 reporting form,

Form 704, to effectuate these additional and updated reporting

requirements for anticipatory hedges. Persons wishing to avail

themselves of an exemption for any of the anticipatory hedging

transactions enumerated in the updated definition of bona fide hedging

in Sec. 150.1 are required to file an initial statement on Form 704

with the Commission at least ten days in advance of the date that such

positions would be in excess of limits established in proposed Sec.

150.2. Advance notice of a trader's intended maximum position in

commodity derivative contracts to offset anticipatory risks allows the

Commission to review a proposed position before a trader exceeds the

position limits and, thereby, allows the Commission to prevent

excessive speculation in the event that a trader were to misconstrue

the purpose of these limited exemptions.\969\ The trader's initial

statement on Form 704 provides a detailed description of the person's

anticipated activity (i.e., unfilled anticipated requirements, unsold

anticipated production, etc.).\970\ Under proposed Sec. 150.7(b), the

Commission may reject all or a portion of the position as not meeting

the requirements for bona fide hedging positions under proposed Sec.

150.1. To support this determination, proposed Sec. 150.7(c) would

allow the Commission to request additional specific information

concerning the anticipated transaction to be hedged. Otherwise, Form

704 filings that conform to the requirements set forth in Sec. 150.7

would become effective ten days after submission. As proposed, Sec.

150.7(e) would require an anticipatory hedger to file a supplemental

report on Form 704 whenever the anticipatory hedging needs increase

beyond that in its most recent filing.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\969\ Further, advance filing may serve to reduce the burden on

a person who exceeds position limits and who may then otherwise be

issued a special call to determine whether the underlying

requirements for the exemption have been met. If the Commission were

to reject such an exemption, such a person would have already

violated position limits.

\970\ Proposed 150.7(d)(2) would require additional information

for cross hedges, for reasons discussed above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As proposed, Sec. 150.7(f) would add a requirement for any person

who files an initial statement on Form 704 to provide annual updates

that detail the person's actual cash market activities related to the

anticipated exemption. With an eye towards distinguishing bona fide

hedging of anticipatory risks from speculation, annual reporting of

actual cash market activities and estimates of remaining unused

anticipated exemptions beyond the past year would enable the Commission

to verify whether the person's anticipated cash market transactions

closely track that person's real cash market activities. In addition,

Sec. 150.7(g) would enable the Commission to review and compare the

actual cash activities and the remaining unused anticipated hedge

transactions by requiring monthly reporting on Form 204. Absent monthly

filing, the Commission would need to issue a special call to determine

why a person's commodity derivative contract position is, for example,

larger than the pro rata balance of her annually reported anticipated

production.

As is the case under current Sec. 1.48, Sec. 150.7(h) requires

that a trader's maximum sales and purchases must not exceed the lesser

of the approved exemption amount or the trader's current actual

anticipated transaction.

For purposes of simplicity, the special reporting requirements for

anticipatory hedges are located within the Commission's position limits

regime in part 150, and alongside the Commission's updated definition

of bona fide hedging positions in Sec. 150.1. Thus, the Commission is

proposing to delete the reporting requirements for anticipatory hedges

in current Sec. 1.48 because that section would be duplicative.

Comments Received: One commenter asserted that the reporting

requirements for anticipatory hedges of an operational or commercial

risk comprising an initial, supplementary and annual report are unduly

burdensome. The commenter recommended that the Commission require

either an initial and annual report or an initial and supplementary

report.\971\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\971\ CL-IECAssn-59679 at 11.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter suggested deleting the Form 704 because it

believes that no matter how extensive the Commission makes reporting

requirements, the Commission will still need to request additional

information on a case-by-case basis to ensure hedge transactions are

legitimate.\972\ The commenter suggested that the Commission should be

able to achieve its goal of obtaining enough information to determine

whether to request additional information using the Form 204 along with

currently collected data sources and so the additional burden of the

new series '04 reports outweighs the benefit to the Commission.\973\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\972\ CL-NGFA-60941 at 7-8.

\973\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters remarked on the cost associated with the

proposed Form 704. One commenter stated that the additional reporting

requirements, including new Form 704 to replace the reporting

requirements under current rule 1.48, and annual and monthly reporting

requirements under proposed rules 150.7(f) and 150.7(g) ``will impose

significant additional regulatory and compliance burdens on commercials

and believes that the Commission should consider alternatives,

including targeted special calls when appropriate.'' \974\ Another

commenter stated the reporting requirements for the series 04 forms is

overly burdensome and would impose a substantial cost to market

participants because while the proposal would require the Commission to

respond fairly quickly, it does not provide an indication of whether

the Commission will deem the requirement accepted if the Commission

doesn't respond within a time frame. The commenter is concerned that a

market participant may have to refuse business if it does not receive

an approved exemption in advance of a transaction.\975\ A third

commenter stated that Form 704 is ``commercially impracticable and

unduly burdensome'' because it would require filers to

[[Page 96811]]

``analyze each transaction to see if it fits into an enumerated hedge

category.'' The commenter is concerned that such ``piecemeal review''

would require a legal memorandum and the development of new software to

track positions and, since the Commission proposed that Form 704 to be

used in proposed Sec. 150.11, the burden associated with the form has

increased.\976\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\974\ CL-APGA-59722 at 10.

\975\ CL-EDF-59961 at 6.

\976\ CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter highlighted discrepancies between the instructions

for Form 704 and the data on the sample Form 704. The commenter noted

that instructions for column five request the ``Cash commodity same as

(S) or cross-hedged (C-H) with Core Reference Futures Contract (CFRC)''

while the sample Form 704 lists ``CL-NYMEX'' as the information

reported in that column. The commenter also noted that Form 704 has

eleven columns, while the sample Form 704 contains only ten columns,

omitting a column for ``Core Referenced Futures contract (CRFC).''

\977\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\977\ CL-FIA-59595 at 39.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The commenter also requested that the Commission clarify

instructions for column six of proposed Form 704 to permit a reasonable

estimate of anticipated production (or other anticipatory hedge) based

on commercial experience, in the event the market participant does not

have three years of data related to the anticipated hedge, for example,

of anticipated production of a newly developed well.\978\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\978\ CL-FIA-59595 at 39.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: As discussed in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, the Commission remains concerned about distinguishing

between anticipatory reduction of risk and speculation.\979\ Therefore,

the Commission is again proposing the requirement to file Form 704 for

anticipatory hedges. The Commission notes that most of the information

required on Form 704 is currently required under Sec. 1.48, and that

such information is not found in any other Commission data source,

including Form 204.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\979\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75746.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is proposing several changes to Sec. 150.7 in order

to make the requirements for Form 704 clearer and more concise. For

example, the Commission is adopting the commenter's suggestion to

require the initial statement and annual update but eliminate the

supplemental filing as proposed in Sec. 150.7(e). Current Sec. 1.48

contains a requirement for supplemental filings similar to proposed

Sec. 150.7(e), but unlike current Sec. 1.48, the proposed rules also

require monthly reporting on Form 204 and annual updates to the initial

statement. After considering the commenter's concerns, the Commission

believe the monthly reporting on Form 204 and annual updates on Form

704 will provide sufficient updates to the initial statement and is

deleting the supplemental filing provision in proposed Sec. 150.7(e)

to reduce the burden on filers as suggested by the commenter.

In addition, the Commission is combining the list of required

information on Form 704 into one section, since such information is

almost identical for the initial statement and the required annual

updates. In this Reproposal, two nearly identical lists of information

have been combined into one list in Sec. 150.7(d). This reorganization

is intended to make compliance with Sec. 150.7, including the filing

of Form 704, simpler and easier to understand for market participants.

Changes have been made throughout part 19 and part 150 to conform to

the deletion of the required supplemental filing and the reorganization

of Sec. 150.7. In particular, the Commission altered Sec. 19.01(a)(4)

to reflect the deletion of the supplemental update and to clarify that

persons required to file series '04 reports under Sec. 19.00(a)(1)(iv)

must file only Form 204 as required in Sec. 150.7(e).

Finally, the sample Form 704 found in Appendix A to part 19 has

also been updated to reflect the combination of the initial statement

and annual update into one section. Specifically, on proposed Form 704

had two sections: Section A required information regarding the initial

statement and supplemental updates and Section B was required for

annual updates. Due to the above-mentioned changes, Section B has been

deleted and Section A has been re-labeled as requiring information

regarding both the initial statement and the annual update. In order to

differentiate between a firm's initial statement and its annual updates

regarding the same, the Commission has added a check-box field that

requires traders to identify whether they are filing Form 704 to submit

an initial statement or to file the required annual update. The

Commission believes the addition of this field poses no significant

additional burden; rather, the Commission believes the changes to the

form, as discussed above, reduce burden to a far greater extent than a

minor addition of a check box adds burden.

In response to the commenter who suggested the Commission consider

target special calls and other alternatives to the annual and monthly

filings, the Commission believes these filings are critical to the

Commission's Surveillance program. Anticipatory hedges, because they

are by definition forward-looking, require additional detail regarding

the firm's commercial practices in order to ensure that a firm is not

using the provisions in proposed Sec. 150.7 to evade position limits.

In contrast, special calls are backward-looking and would not provide

the Commission's Surveillance program with the information needed to

prevent markets from being susceptible to excessive speculation.

However, the Commission expects the new filing requirements to be an

improvement over current practice under Sec. 1.48 because as facts and

circumstances change, Surveillance will have a more timely

understanding of the market participant's hedging needs.

The Commission notes in response to the commenter that Form 704 is

filed in anticipation of risk to be assumed at a future date; market

participants will need to provide a detailed description of anticipated

activity but there is no requirement to analyze individual transactions

or submit a memorandum.

The Commission also notes that concerns regarding a firm having to

decline business, because an exemption has not been approved, are

unwarranted. Series '04 reports (other than the initial statement of

Form 704) are self-effectuating and do not require Commission

notification to become effective. With respect to Form 704, the

Commission explained in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal that

if the Commission does not notify a market participant within the

timeframe indicated in Sec. 150.7(b), the filing becomes effective

automatically.\980\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\980\ See the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75746: ``Under proposed Sec. 150.7(b), the Commission may reject

all or a portion of the position as not meeting the requirements for

bona fide hedging positions under Sec. 150.1. . . . Otherwise, Form

704 filings that conform to the requirements set forth in proposed

Sec. 150.7 would become effective ten days after submission.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The commenter is correct in noting that there is an error on the

Sample Form 704 such that column five (``Core Referenced Futures

Contract (CRFC)'') was inadvertently omitted from the Sample Form

provided in the proposed rules. The Commission is amending the Sample

Form 704 in the reproposed rules to ensure it accurately reflects the

requirements of the Form 704 as described in Sec. 150.7(d). Further,

the Commission is deleting the condition that requires the specified

operating

[[Page 96812]]

period may not exceed one year for agricultural commodities, as end-

users in certain agricultural commodities may hedge their positions

several years out along the curve.

The Commission notes, in response to the commenter's concern

regarding column 6 of Form 704, that the requirement to file the past

three years of annual production is also in current Sec. 1.48.

Understanding the recent history of a firm's production is necessary to

ensure the requested anticipated hedging amount is reasonable. However,

the Commission notes that it may permit a reasonable, supported

estimate of anticipated production for less than three years of annual

production data, in the Commission's discretion, if a market

participant does not have three years of data. The Commission is

amending the form instructions to clarify that Commission staff could

determine that such an estimate is reasonable and so would be accepted.

Finally, the Commission notes that several references to other

provisions within part 150 contained in Sec. Sec. 150.7(b), 150.7(d),

and 150.7(h) were incorrectly cited in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal; the Commission is revising these paragraphs to ensure

all references are up-to-date and correct.

2. Delegation

Proposed Rule: In Sec. 150.7(i), the Commission proposed to

delegate to the Division of Market Oversight director or staff the

authority: To provide notice to a firm who has filed Form 704 that they

do not meet the requirements for bona fide hedging; to request

additional or updated information under Sec. 150.7(c); and to request

under Sec. 150.7(d)(2) information concerning the basis for and

derivation of conversion factors used in computing the position

information provided in Form 704.

Comments Received: The Commission received no comments on the

proposed delegation of authority under Sec. 150.7.

Commission Reproposal: The Commission is reproposing Sec.

150.7(i), as originally proposed.

G. Sec. 150.9--Process for Recognition of Positions as Non-Enumerated

Bona Fide Hedging Positions

1. Overview of Proposed Rules Related to Recognition of Bona Fide

Hedging Positions and Granting of Spread Exemptions

In the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

noted that it was proposing three sets of Commission rules under which

an exchange could take action to recognize certain bona fide hedging

positions and to grant certain spread exemptions, with regard to both

exchange-set and federal position limits.\981\ The Commission pointed

out that in each case, the proposed rules would establish a formal CFTC

review process that would permit the Commission to revoke all such

exchange actions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\981\ See generally 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal,

81 FR at 38464-82; the Commission incorporates herein its

explanation of its proposed adoption of Sec. Sec. 150.9, 150.10 and

150.11. Under the proposal, exchanges would be able to: (i)

Recognize certain non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions, i.e.,

positions that are not enumerated by the Commission's rules

(pursuant to proposed Sec. 150.9); (ii) grant exemptions to

position limits for certain spread positions (pursuant to proposed

Sec. 150.10); and (iii) recognize certain enumerated anticipatory

bona fide hedging positions (pursuant to proposed Sec. 150.11).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As the Commission observed at that time, its authority to permit

certain exchanges to recognize positions as bona fide hedging positions

is found, in part, in CEA section 4a(c)(1), and under CEA section

8a(5), which provides that the Commission may make such rules as, in

the judgment of the Commission, are reasonably necessary to effectuate

any of the provisions or to accomplish any of the purposes of the CEA.

CEA section 4a(c)(1) provides that no CFTC rule applies to

``transaction or positions which are shown to be bona fide hedging

transactions or positions,'' as those terms are defined by Commission

rule consistent with the purposes of the CEA.\982\ The Commission noted

that ``shown to be'' is passive voice, which could encompass either a

position holder or an exchange being able to ``show'' that a position

is entitled to treatment as a bona fide hedging position, and does not

specify that the Commission must determine in advance whether the

position or transaction was shown to be bona fide. The Commission

interpreted CEA section 4a(c)(1) to authorize the Commission to permit

certain SROs (i.e., DCMs and SEFs, meeting certain criteria) to

recognize positions as bona fide hedging positions for purposes of

federal limits, subject to Commission review.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\982\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38464.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission observed that for decades, exchanges have operated

as self-regulatory organizations, and pointed out further that these

self-regulatory organizations have been charged with carrying out

regulatory functions, including, since 2001, complying with core

principles, and operate subject to the regulatory oversight of the

Commission pursuant to the CEA as a whole, and more specifically, CEA

sections 5 and 5h.\983\ In addition, the Commission pointed out that as

self-regulatory organizations, exchanges do not act only as

independent, private actors; \984\ when the Act is read as a whole, as

the Commission noted in 1981, ``it is apparent that Congress envisioned

cooperative efforts between the self-regulatory organizations and the

Commission. Thus, the exchanges, as well as the Commission, have a

continuing responsibility in this matter under the Act.'' \985\ The

Commission

[[Page 96813]]

noted that its approach to its oversight of its SROs was subsequently

ratified by Congress in 1982, when it gave the CFTC authority to

enforce exchange set limits. Further, the Commission observed that as

it stated in 2010, ``since 1982, the Act's framework explicitly

anticipates the concurrent application of Commission and exchange-set

speculative position limits. The Commission further noted that the

`concurrent application of limits is particularly consistent with an

exchange's close knowledge of trading activity on that facility and the

Commission's greater capacity for monitoring trading and implementing

remedial measures across interconnected commodity futures and option

markets.' '' \986\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\983\ Id. at 38465. The Commission noted that CFTC Sec. 1.3(ee)

defines SRO to mean a DCM, SEF, or registered futures association

(such as the National Futures Association), and also pointed out

that under the Commission's regulations, self-regulatory

organizations have certain delineated regulatory responsibilities,

which are carried out under Commission oversight and which are

subject to Commission review. Id.

\984\ Id. The Commission stated that it ``views as instructive''

three examples of case law addressing grants of authority by an

agency (the Securities and Exchange Commission, the `SEC') to a

self-regulatory organization (`SRO') (in the SEC cases the SRO was

NASD, now FINRA), providing insight into the factors addressed by

the court regarding oversight of an SRO;

(i) In 1952, the Second Circuit reviewed an SEC order that

failed to set aside a penalty fixed by NASD suspending the defendant

broker-dealer from membership. Citing Sunshine Anthracite Coal Co.

v. Adkins, 310 U.S. 381 (1940), the Second Circuit found that, in

light of the statutory provisions vesting the SEC with power to

approve or disapprove NASD's rules according to reasonably fixed

statutory standards, and the fact that NASD disciplinary actions are

subject to SEC review, there was `no merit in the contention that

the Maloney Act unconstitutionally delegates power to the NASD.'

R.H. Johnson v. Securities and Exchange Commission, 198 F. 2d 690,

695 (2d Cir. 1952).

(ii) In 1977, the Third Circuit, in Todd & Co. v. Securities and

Exchange Commission (`Todd'), 557 F.2d 1008 (3rd Cir. 1977),

likewise concluded that the Act did not unconstitutionally delegate

legislative power to a private institution. The Todd court

articulated critical factors that kept the Maloney Act within

constitutional bounds. First, the SEC had the power, according to

reasonably fixed statutory standards, to approve or disapprove

NASD's rules before they could go into effect. Second, all NASD

judgments of rule violations or penalty assessments were subject to

SEC review. Third, all NASD adjudications were subject to a de novo

(non-deferential) standard of review by the SEC, which could be

aided by additional evidence, if necessary. Id. at 1012. Based on

these factors, the court found that `[NASD's] rules and its

disciplinary actions were subject to full review by the SEC, a

wholly public body, which must base its decision on its own

findings' and thus that the statutory scheme was constitutional. Id.

at 1012-13. See also First Jersey Securities v. Bergen, 605 F.2d 690

(1979), applying the same three-part test delineated in Todd, and

then upholding a statutory narrowing of the Todd test.

(iii) In 1982, the Ninth Circuit considered the

constitutionality of Congress' delegation to NASD in Sorrel v.

Securities and Exchange Commission, 679 F. 2d 1323 (9th Cir. 1982).

Sorrel followed R.H. Johnson, Todd and First Jersey in holding that

because the SEC reviews NASD rules according to reasonably fixed

standards, and the SEC can review any NASD disciplinary action, the

Maloney Act does not impermissibly delegate power to NASD.''

\985\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38465.

\986\ Id. at 38466.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also noted that under its proposal, it would retain

the power to approve or disapprove the rules of exchanges, under

standards set out pursuant to the CEA, and to review an exchange's

compliance with those rules.\987\ Moreover, the Commission observed

that it was not diluting its ability to recognize or not recognize bona

fide hedging positions or to grant or not grant spread exemptions, as

it reserved to itself the ability to review any exchange action, and to

review any application by a market participant to an exchange, whether

prior to or after disposition of such application by an exchange.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\987\ The Commission stated that ``In connection with

recognition of bona fide hedging positions, the Commission notes

that the statute is silent or ambiguous with respect to the specific

issue--whether the CFTC may authorize SROs to recognize positions as

bona fide hedging positions. CEA section 4a(c) provides that no

Commission rule establishing federal position limits applies to

positions which are shown to be bona fide hedging positions, as such

term shall be defined by the CFTC. As noted above, the `shown to be'

phrase is passive voice, which could encompass either a position

holder or an exchange being able to ``show'' that a position is

entitled to treatment as a bona fide hedge, and does not specify

that the Commission must be the party determining in advance whether

the position or transaction was shown to be bona fide; the

Commission interprets that provision to permit certain SROs (i.e.,

DCMs and SEFs, meeting certain criteria) to recognize positions as

bona fide hedges for purposes of federal limits when done so within

a regime where the Commission can review and modify or overturn such

determinations. Under the 2016 Position Limits Supplemental

Proposal, an SRO's recognition is tentative, because the Commission

would reserve the power to review the recognition, subject to the

reasonably fixed statutory standards in CEA section 4a(c)(2)

(directing the CFTC to define the term bona fide hedging position).

An SRO's recognition would also be constrained by the SRO's rules,

which would be subject to CFTC review under the proposal. The SROs

are parties that are subject to Commission authority, their rules

are subject to Commission review and their actions are subject to

Commission de novo review under the proposal--SRO rules and actions

may be changed by the Commission at any time.'' Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. Proposed Sec. 150.9--General

Proposed Rule: In light of DCM experience in granting non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position exemptions to exchange-set

position limits for futures contracts, and after consideration of

comments recommending exchange review of non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position requests, the Commission proposed to permit exchanges

to recognize non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions with respect to

the proposed federal speculative position limits. Under proposed Sec.

150.9, an exchange, as an SRO \988\ that is under Commission oversight

and whose rules are subject to Commission review,\989\ could establish

rules under which the exchange could recognize as non-enumerated bona

fide hedging positions, positions that meet the general definition of

bona fide hedging position in proposed Sec. 150.1, which implements

the statutory directive in CEA section 4a(c) for the general definition

of bona fide hedging positions in physical commodities.\990\ The

exchange's recognition would be subject to review by the Commission.

Exchange recognition of a position as a non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position would allow the market participant to exceed the

federal position limit to the extent that it relied upon the exchange's

recognition unless and until such time that the Commission notified the

market participant to the contrary.\991\ The Commission could issue

such a notification in accordance with the proposed review procedures.

That is, if a party were to hold positions pursuant to a non-enumerated

bona fide hedging position recognition granted by the exchange, such

positions would not be subject to federal position limits, unless or

until the Commission were to determine that such non-enumerated bona

fide hedging position recognition was inconsistent with the CEA or CFTC

regulations thereunder. Under this framework, the Commission would

continue to exercise its authority in this regard by reviewing an

exchange's determination and verifying whether the facts and

circumstances in respect of a derivative position satisfy the

requirements of the general definition of bona fide hedging position

proposed in Sec. 150.1.\992\ If the Commission determined that the

exchange-granted recognition was inconsistent with section 4a(c) of the

Act and the Commission's general definition of bona fide hedging

position in Sec. 150.1 and so notified a market participant relying on

such recognition, the market participant would be required to reduce

the derivative position or otherwise come into compliance with position

limits within a commercially reasonable amount of time.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\988\ As noted above, under the Commission's regulations, SROs

have certain delineated regulatory responsibilities, which are

carried out under Commission oversight and which are subject to

Commission review. See also 2016 Position Limits Supplemental

Proposal, n. 126 (describing reviews of DCMs carried out by the

Commission).

\989\ See CEA section 5c(c), 7 U.S.C. 7a-2(a) (providing

Commission with authority to review rules and rule amendments of

registered entities, including DCMs).

\990\ As previously noted, Congress has required in CEA section

4a(c) that the Commission, within specific parameters, define what

constitutes a bona fide hedging position for the purpose of

implementing federal position limits on physical commodity

derivatives, including, as previously stated, the inclusion in new

section 4a(c)(2) of a directive to narrow the bona fide hedging

definition for physical commodity positions from that currently in

Commission regulation Sec. 1.3(z). See 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal, nn. 32 and 105 and accompanying text; see also

December 2013 Positions Limits Proposal at 75705. In response to

that mandate, the Commission proposed in its December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal to add a definition of bona fide hedging position in

Sec. 150.1, to replace the definition in current Sec. 1.3(z). See

78 FR at 75706, 75823.

For the avoidance of doubt, the Commission is still reviewing

comments received on these provisions. The Commission is proposing

to finalize the general definition of bona fide hedging position

based on the standards of CEA section 4a(c), and may further define

the bona fide hedging position definition consistent with those

standards.

\991\ See generally the discussion of proposed Sec. 150.9(d)

and the requirements regarding the review of applications by the

Commission in the 2016 Position Limits Supplemental Proposal. The

Commission noted that exchange participation is voluntary, not

mandatory and that exchanges could elect not to administer the

process. Market participants could still request a staff

interpretive letter under Sec. 140.99 or seek exemptive relief

under CEA section 4a(a)(7), per the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal. The process does not protect exchanges or applicants from

charges of violations of applicable sections of the CEA or other

Commission regulations. For instance, a market participant's

compliance with position limits or an exemption thereto would not

confer any type of safe harbor or good faith defense to a claim that

he had engaged in an attempted manipulation, a perfected

manipulation or deceptive conduct; see the discussion of Sec. 150.6

(Ongoing application of the Act and Commission regulations) as

proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75746-7.

\992\ See the general discussion of the Commission's review

process proposed in Sec. 150.9(d); see also the requirement for a

weekly report, proposed in Sec. 150.9(c), which would support the

Commission's surveillance program by facilitating the tracking of

non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions recognized by exchanges,

keeping the Commission informed of the manner in which an exchange

is administering its procedures for recognizing such non-enumerated

bona fide hedging positions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission noted its belief that permitting exchanges to so

recognize non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions is consistent with

its statutory

[[Page 96814]]

obligation to set and enforce position limits on physical commodity

contracts, because the Commission would be retaining its authority to

determine ultimately whether any non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions so recognized is in fact a bona fide hedging position. The

Commission's authority to set position limits does not extend to any

position that is shown to be a bona fide hedging position.\993\

Further, most, if not all, DCMs already have a framework and

application process to recognize non-enumerated positions, for purposes

of exchange-set limits, as within the meaning of the general bona fide

hedging definition in Sec. 1.3(z)(1).\994\ The Commission has a long

history of overseeing the performance of the DCMs in granting

exemptions under current exchange rules regarding exchange-set position

limits \995\ and believed that it would be efficient and in the best

interest of the markets, in light of current resource constraints,\996\

to rely on the exchanges to initially process applications for

recognition of positions as non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions.

In addition, because many market participants are familiar with current

DCM practices regarding bona fide hedging positions, permitting DCMs to

build on current practice may reduce the burden on market participants.

Moreover, the Commission believed that the process outlined in the 2016

Position Limits Supplemental Proposal should reduce duplicative efforts

because market participants seeking recognition of a non-enumerated

bona fide hedging position would be able to file one application for

relief, only to an exchange, rather than to both an exchange with

respect to exchange-set limits and to the Commission with respect to

federal limits.\997\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\993\ CEA section 4a(c)(1), 7 U.S.C. 6a(c)(1). See also 2016

Position Limits Supplemental Proposal, n. 65.

\994\ Rulebooks for some DCMs can be found in the links to their

associated documents on the Commission's Web site at http://sirt.cftc.gov/SIRT/SIRT.aspx?Topic=TradingOrganizations.

\995\ The Commission based this view on its long experience

overseeing DCMs and their compliance with the requirements of CEA

section 5 and part 38 of the Commission's regulations, 17 CFR part

38. As the Commission noted in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, under part 38, a DCM must comply, on an initial and

ongoing basis, with twenty-three Core Principles established in

section 5(d) of the CEA, 7 U.S.C. 7(d), and part 38 of the CFTC's

regulations and with the implementing regulations under part 38. The

Division of Market Oversight's Market Compliance Section conducts

regular reviews of each DCM's ongoing compliance with core

principles through the self-regulatory programs operated by the

exchange in order to enforce its rules, prevent market manipulation

and customer and market abuses, and ensure the recording and safe

storage of trade information. These reviews are known as rule

enforcement reviews (``RERs''). Some periodic RERs examine a DCM's

market surveillance program for compliance with Core Principle 4,

Monitoring of Trading, and Core Principle 5, Position Limitations or

Accountability. On some occasions, these two types of RERs may be

combined in a single RER. Market Compliance can also conduct

horizontal RERs of the compliance of multiple exchanges in regard to

particular core principles. In conducting an RER, the Division of

Market Oversight (DMO) staff examines trading and compliance

activities at the exchange in question over an extended time period

selected by DMO, typically the twelve months immediately preceding

the start of the review. Staff conducts extensive review of

documents and systems used by the exchange in carrying out its self-

regulatory responsibilities; interviews compliance officials and

staff of the exchange; and prepares a detailed written report of

findings. In nearly all cases, the RER report is made available to

the public and posted on CFTC.gov. See materials regarding RERs of

DCMs at http://www.cftc.gov/IndustryOversight/TradingOrganizations/DCMs/dcmruleenf on the Commission's Web site. Recent RERs conducted

by DMO covering DCM Core Principle 5 and exemptions from position

limits have included the Minneapolis Grain Exchange, Inc. (``MGEX'')

(June 5, 2015), ICE Futures U.S. (July 22, 2014), the Chicago

Mercantile Exchange (``CME'') and the Chicago Board of Trade

(``CBOT'') (July 26, 2013), and the New York Mercantile Exchange

(May 19, 2008). While DMO may sometimes identify deficiencies or

make recommendations for improvements, it is the Commission's view

that it should be permissible for DCMs to process applications for

exchange recognition of positions as non-enumerated bona fide

hedging positions. Consistent with the fifteen SEF core principles

established in section 5h(f) of the CEA, 7 U.S.C. 7b-3(f), and with

the implementing regulations under part 37, 17 CFR part 37, the

Commission will perform similar RERs for SEFs. The Commission's

preliminary view is that it should be permissible for SEFs to

process applications as well, after obtaining the requisite

experience administering exchange-set position limits discussed

below. See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38469, n. 126 and accompanying text.

\996\ Since the enactment of the Dodd-Frank Act, Commissioners,

CFTC staff, and public officials have expressed repeatedly and

publicly that Commission resources have not kept pace with the

CFTC's expanded jurisdiction and increased responsibilities. The

Commission anticipates there may be hundreds of applications for

non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions. This is based on the

number of exemptions currently processed by DCMs. For example, under

the existing process, during the period from June 15, 2011 to June

15, 2012, the Market Surveillance Department of ICE Futures U.S.

received 142 exemption applications, 121 of which related to bona

fide hedging position requests, while 21 related to arbitrage or

cash-and-carry requests; 92 new exemptions were granted. Rule

Enforcement review of ICE Futures U.S., July 22, 2014, p. 40. Also

under the existing process, during the period from November 1, 2010

to October 31, 2011, the Market Surveillance Group from the CME

Market Regulation Department took action on and approved 420

exemption applications for products traded on CME and CBOT,

including 114 new exemptive applications, 295 applications for

renewal, 10 applications for increased levels, and one temporary

exemption on an inter-commodity spread. Rule Enforcement Review of

the Chicago Mercantile Exchange and the Chicago Board of Trade, July

26, 2013, p. 54. These statistics are now a few years old, and it is

possible that the number of applications under the processes

outlined in this proposal will increase relative to the number of

applications described in the RERs. The CFTC would need to shift

substantial resources, to the detriment of other oversight

activities, to process so many requests and applications and has

determined, as described below, to permit exchanges to process

applications initially. The Commission anticipates it will

regularly, as practicable, check a sample of the exemptions granted,

including in cases where the facts warrant special attention,

retrospectively as described below, including through RERs.

\997\ One commenter specifically requested that the Commission

streamline duplicative processes. CL-AGA-60382 at 12 (stating that

``AGA . . . urges the Commission to ensure that hedge exemption

requests and any hedge reporting do not require duplicative filings

at both the exchanges and the Commission, and therefore recommends

revising the rules to streamline the process by providing that an

applicant need only apply to and report to the exchanges, while the

Commission could receive any necessary data and applications by

coordinating data flow between the exchanges and the Commission.'').

See also CL-Working Group-60396 (explaining that ``To avoid

employing duplicative efforts, the Commission should simply rely on

DCMs to administer bona fide hedge exemptions from federal

speculative position limits as they carry out their core duties to

ensure orderly markets.'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received

Exchange Authority Under the Proposal

The Commission received some comments on its 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal that addressed concerns only marginally

responsive to that proposal; the Commission will address those comments

in connection with the relevant provisions.\998\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\998\ One commenter expressed the view that Class III milk

should not be subject to the prohibition on holding cross commodity

hedge positions in the spot month or during the last five days,

because it is a cash settled contract. CL-DFA-60927 at 5. The

Commission is addressing Class III milk separately.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters supported the Commission's proposal to allow

exchanges to recognize non-enumerated bona fide hedge positions with

respect to federal speculative position limits; \999\ on the other

hand, some commenters expressed views against any Commission

involvement in the exchange-administered exemption process. That is,

according to those commenters, exchanges should be given full

discretion or greater leeway to manage an exemption process without

Commission interference.\1000\ In addition, a commenter requested that

the Commission provide additional regulatory certainty for end-users,

including that the Commission should simply expand the DCM's current

authority to grant bona fide hedge exemptions and maintain the

Commission's current oversight role in respect of DCM processes and

rules under the DCM Core Principles.\1001\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\999\ CL-NMPF-60956 at 2; CL-ISDA-60931 at 6-7; CL-API-60939 at

4; CL-NFP-60942 at 6-8; and CL-IECAssn-60949 at 3-4.

\1000\ CL-CME-60926 at 7; CL-NGFA-60941 at 3.

\1001\ CL-NFP-60942 at 6-8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Similarly, some commenters expressed the view that there could be

circumstances where multiple

[[Page 96815]]

commercial firms face similar risks and require recognition of

positions as non-enumerated bona fide hedges for the same purpose, and

there should be a method for a generic recognition of non-enumerated

bona fide hedge positions for commercial firms meeting satisfy

specified facts and circumstances, allowing an exchange to announce

generic recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedges for hedgers that

satisfy certain facts and circumstances; to allow exchange to announce

generic recognition for hedgers that certain specified facts.\1002\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1002\ CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 9 (noting also that ``unlike a hedge

exemption, the exchanges are not granting a firm specific quantity

of bona fide hedging contracts but, rather, are validating the bona

fide nature of a hedge transaction''); CL-COPE-60932 at 8-9

(recommending that ``[t]he Supplemental NOPR should be revised to

permit the DCM to generically recognize a non-enumerated bona fide

hedge in cases where multiple commercial firms have sought a non-

enumerated bona fide hedge for a similar risk, based upon similar

circumstances.'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Others did not support providing exchanges with such authority.

Instead, those commenters asserted that only the Commission can

appropriately and comprehensively administer exemptions to federal

limits,\1003\ or cited concerns with respect to conflicts of interest

that could arise between for-profit exchanges and their exemption-

seeking customers.\1004\ In the alternative, several of these

commenters recommended that the Commission make any final non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position determinations, or that exchanges

have a limited advisory role with respect to granting exemptions. One

commenter expressed the view that it is concerned that the Commission's

constrained resources will prevent the Commission from effectively

overseeing self-regulatory organizations' recognition of bona fide

hedging position exemptions. The commenter suggested that the

Commission at least provide guidance regarding what is the Commission's

authority in the event that an exchange-managed position accountability

level fails in numerous contracts to prevent speculation, or raises

other concerns.\1005\ Further to this point, the commenter expressed

the view that it was concerned that granting exemptions from position

limits for swaps that are traded by high frequency trading strategies

will exacerbate price volatility to the detriment of commercial hedgers

by increasing momentum or rumor trading and the costs of hedging in

such a price volatile environment. The commenter believes that this

will impact the Commission's ability to review and oversee exchange

exemptions, especially if the Commission does not have access to open

interest swap data and the intra-day high frequency trading data to

determine whether such exchange-granted exemption is economically

appropriate.\1006\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1003\ CL-Better Markets-60928 at 3-5; CL-Public Citizen-60940

at 3; CL-PMAA-NEFI-60952 at 2; CL-AFR-60953 at 2-3; CL-RER1-60961 at

1.

\1004\ CL-Public Citizen-60940 at 3; CL-PMAA-NEFI-60952 at 2;

CL-RER2-60962 at 1; CL-AFR-60953 at 2-3; CL-RER1-60961 at 1; CL-

PMAA-NEFI-60952 at 2; CL-RER2-60962 at 1; CL-Better Markets-60928 at

3-5; CL-Public Citizen-60940 at 1-2; CL-AFR-60953 at 3-4.

\1005\ CL-IATP-60951 at 2.

\1006\ CL-IATP-60951 at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Implementation Timeline

Regarding implementation of final regulations, one commenter

requested that the CFTC provide a sufficient phase-in period for

exchanges to review non-enumerated hedges ahead of implementation

because it is hard to discern the number of current positions that will

not be considered bona fide hedging positions in the proposed rule

unless granted a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position e exemption

from an exchange.\1007\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1007\ CL-NCFC-60930 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal Regarding Sec. 150.9

As explained further below, in this Reproposal, the Commission is

adopting certain amendments to the proposed Sec. 150.9 and providing

certain clarifications. In response to various general comments and

recommendations for the non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

process, the Commission provides the following responses.

Exchange Authority Under Reproposed Sec. 150.9

In response to comments that the Commission should give exchanges

greater leeway or discretion for purposes of federal position limits in

the exemption process and expand DCM's current authority to grant bona

fide hedge exemptions, the Commission believes, as noted above, that it

would be an illegal delegation to give full discretion to exchanges to

recognize positions or transactions as bona fide hedging positions, for

purposes of federal position limits, without reasonably fixed statutory

standards (such as the requirement that exchanges use the Commission's

bona fide hedging position definition, which incorporates the standards

of CEA section 4a(c)), and with no ability for the Commission to make a

de novo review.\1008\ Instead, as observed above, the Commission

believes it has the authority to provide exchanges with the ability to

do so pursuant to reasonably fixed statutory standards and subject to

CFTC de novo review.\1009\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1008\ See supra section G.1. (discussing the Commission's

authority to adopt Sec. 150.9); see also discussion regarding

adoption of Sec. 150.9(d).

\1009\ As observed above, the Second Circuit found in Sunshine

Anthracite Coal Co. v. Adkins, that in light of statutory provisions

vesting the SEC with power to approve or disapprove NASD's rules

according to reasonably fixed statutory standards, and the fact that

NASD disciplinary actions are subject to SEC review, there was ``no

merit in the contention that the Maloney Act unconstitutionally

delegates power to the NASD.'' R.H. Johnson v. Securities and

Exchange Commission, 198 F. 2d 690, 695 (2d Cir. 1952). See supra

discussion under preamble section G.1; see also preamble discussion

regarding the adoption of Sec. 150.9(d).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Similarly, regarding requests to provide exchanges with a method

for a generic recognition of a non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position that allows an exchange to announce generic recognition of

non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions for hedgers that satisfy

certain facts and circumstances, the Commission notes that, as

discussed above, it would be an illegal delegation of Commission

authority to give full discretion to exchanges to recognize positions

or transactions as enumerated bona fide hedging positions without

reasonably fixed statutory standards, and without review by the

Commission, for purposes of federal position limits. Instead, the

Commission points out that any exchange can petition the Commission

under Sec. 13.2 for recognition of a typical position as an enumerated

bona fide hedging position if the exchange believes there is a fact

pattern that is so certain as to not require a facts and circumstances

review.

In this light, the Commission is reproposing a consistent approach,

subject to amendments described below, for processing recognitions of

bona fide hedging positions for purposes of federal position limits

(i.e., a standard process that the Commission, exchanges and market

participants know and understand). As was noted in the 2016 Position

Limits Proposal, the Commission believes that the consistent approach

under reproposed Sec. 150.9 should increase administrative certainty

for applicants seeking recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions in the form of reduced application-production time by market

participants and reduced response time by exchanges and reduce

duplicative efforts because applicants would be saved the expense of

applying to both an exchange for relief from exchange-set

[[Page 96816]]

position limits and to the Commission for relief from federal

limits.\1010\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1010\ See, e.g., 2016 Position Limits Proposal at 38470, 38488.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission, however, clarifies that exchanges can recognize

strategies as non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions for purposes

of federal position limits (including those that the Commission has not

enumerated) so long as a facts-and-circumstances review leads the

exchange to believe that such strategies meet the definition of bona

fide hedging position. Further, regarding comments that exchanges

should not have authority to grant exemptions, the Commission disagrees

and believes the exchange's experience administering position limits to

its actively traded contract, and the Commission's de novo review of

exchange determinations that positions are bona fide hedging positions

(afterwards) are adequate to guard against or remedy any conflicts of

interest. The Commission points out that it has had a long history of

cooperative enforcement of position limits with DCMs and, in addition

notes that when recognizing non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions

for purposes of federal limits, exchanges are required to use the

Commission's bona fide hedging position definition.\1011\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1011\ See Sec. 150.9(a)(1).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As to the concerns that allowing bona fide hedging position

determinations for swap positions that are traded by high frequency

trading strategies will exacerbate price volatility to the detriment of

commercial hedgers and impact the Commission's ability to review and

oversee exchange determinations (especially if the Commission does not

have access to open interest swap data and the intra-day high frequency

trading data to determine whether such exchange-granted determination

is economically appropriate), the Commission notes that it does have

access to open interest swap data, trade data and order data. The

Commission views its access to open interest swap data, trade data and

order data as well as its ability under Sec. 150.9 to review all

exchange recognitions as sufficient to allow it to carry out its

responsibilities under the Act.

General Reproposal Under Sec. 150.9

Regarding implementation timing, the Commission is proposing to

implement a delayed compliance date after publication of a final rule,

as discussed above.\1012\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1012\ See discussion under Proposed Compliance Date, above; see

also Sec. 150.2(e)(1).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)--Requirements for a Designated Contract

Market or Swap Execution Facility To Recognize Non-Enumerated Bona Fide

Hedging Positions

a. Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(1)

Proposed Rule

The Commission contemplated in proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(1) that

exchanges may voluntarily elect to process non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position applications by filing new rules or rule amendments

with the Commission pursuant to part 40 of the Commission's

regulations. The Commission anticipated that, consistent with current

practice, most exchanges will self-certify such new rules or rule

amendments pursuant to Sec. 40.6. The Commission expected that the

self-certification process should be a low burden for exchanges,

especially for those that already recognize non-enumerated positions

meeting the general definition of bona fide hedging position in Sec.

1.3(z)(1).\1013\ The Commission explained its view that allowing DCMs

to continue to follow current practice, and extend that practice to

exchange recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions for

purposes of the federal position limits, would permit the Commission to

more effectively allocate its limited resources to oversight of the

exchanges' actions.\1014\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1013\ DCMs currently process applications for exemptions from

exchange-set position limits for non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions and enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedges, as well as

for exemptions from exchange-set position limits for spread

positions, pursuant to CFMA-era regulatory guidance. See 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, n. 102, and accompanying

text. This practice continues because, among other things, the

Commission has not finalized the rules proposed in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal.

As noted above and as explained in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, while current Sec. 150.5 regarding exchange-set

position limits pre-dates the CFMA ``the CFMA core principles regime

concerning position limitations or accountability for exchanges had

the effect of undercutting the mandatory rules promulgated by the

Commission in Sec. 150.5. Since the CFMA amended the CEA in 2000,

the Commission has retained Sec. 150.5, but only as guidance on,

and acceptable practice for, compliance with DCM core principle 5.''

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75754.

The DCM application processes for bona fide hedging position

exemptions from exchange-set position limits generally reference or

incorporate the general definition of bona fide hedging position

contained in current Sec. 1.3(z)(1), and the Commission believes

the exchange processes for approving non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position applications are at least to some degree informed

by the Commission process outlined in current Sec. 1.47.

\1014\ If the Commission becomes concerned about an exchange's

general processing of non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

applications, the Commission may review such processes pursuant to a

periodic rule enforcement review or a request for information

pursuant to Sec. 37.5. Separately, under proposed Sec. 150.9(d),

the proposal provides that the Commission may review a DCM's

determinations in the case of any specific non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position application.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(1) provided that exchange rules must

incorporate the general definition of bona fide hedging position in

Sec. 150.1. It also provided that, with respect to a commodity

derivative position for which an exchange elects to process non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position applications, (i) the position

must be in a commodity derivative contract that is a referenced

contract; (ii) the exchange must list such commodity derivative

contract for trading; (iii) such commodity derivative contract must be

actively traded on such exchange; (iv) such exchange must have

established position limits for such commodity derivative contract; and

(v) such exchange must have at least one year of experience

administering exchange-set position limits for such commodity

derivative contract. The requirement for one year of experience was

intended as a proxy for a minimum level of expertise gained in

monitoring futures or swaps trading in a particular physical commodity.

The Commission believed that the exchange non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position process should be limited only to those exchanges that

have at least one year of experience overseeing exchange-set position

limits in an actively traded referenced contract in a particular

commodity because an individual exchange may not be familiar enough

with the specific needs and differing practices of the commercial

participants in those markets for which the exchange does not list any

actively traded referenced contract in a particular commodity. Thus, if

a referenced contract is not actively traded on an exchange that elects

to process non-enumerated bona fide hedging position applications for

positions in such referenced contract, that exchange might not be

incentivized to protect or manage the relevant commodity market, and

its interests might not be aligned with the policy objectives of the

Commission as expressed in CEA section 4a. The Commission expected that

an individual exchange will describe how it will determine whether a

particular listed referenced contract is actively traded in its rule

submission, based on its familiarity with the specific needs and

[[Page 96817]]

differing practices of the commercial participants in the relevant

market.\1015\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1015\ For example, a DCM (``DCM A'') may list a commodity

derivative contract (``KX,'' where ``K'' refers to contract and

``X'' refers to the commodity) that is a referenced contract,

actively traded, and DCM A has the requisite experience and

expertise in administering position limits in that one contract KX.

DCM A can therefore recognize non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions in contract KX. But DCM A is not limited to recognition of

just that one contract KX-DCM A can also recognize any other

contract that falls within the meaning of referenced contract for

commodity X. So a market participant could, for example, apply to

DCM A for recognition of a position in any contract that falls

within the meaning of referenced contract for commodity X. However,

that market participant would still need to seek separate

recognition from each exchange where it seeks an exemption from that

other exchange's limit for a commodity derivative contract in the

same commodity X.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission was also mindful that some market participants, such

as commercial end users in some circumstances, may not be required to

trade on an exchange, but may nevertheless desire to have a particular

derivative position recognized as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position. The Commission noted its belief that commercial end users

should be able to avail themselves of an exchange's non-enumerated bona

fide hedging position application process in lieu of requesting a staff

interpretive letter under Sec. 140.99 or seeking CEA section 4a(a)(7)

exemptive relief. This is because the Commission believed that

exchanges that list particular referenced contracts would have enough

information about the markets in which such contracts trade and would

be sufficiently familiar with the specific needs and differing

practices of the commercial participants in such markets in order to

knowledgeably recognize non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions for

derivatives positions in commodity derivative contracts included within

a particular referenced contract. The Commission also viewed this to be

consistent with the efficient allocation of Commission resources.

Consistent with the restrictions regarding the offset of risks

arising from a swap position in CEA section 4a(c)(2)(B), proposed Sec.

150.9(a)(1) would not permit an exchange to recognize a non-enumerated

bona fide hedging position involving a commodity index contract and one

or more referenced contracts. That is, an exchange may not recognize a

non-enumerated bona fide hedging position where a bona fide hedging

position could not be recognized for a pass through swap offset of a

commodity index contract.\1016\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1016\ This is consistent with the Commission's interpretation

in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal that CEA section

4a(c)(2)(b) is a direction from Congress to narrow the scope of what

constitutes a bona fide hedge in the context of index trading

activities. ``Financial products are not substitutes for positions

taken or to be taken in a physical marketing channel. Thus, the

offset of financial risks from financial products is inconsistent

with the proposed definition of bona fide hedging for physical

commodities.'' December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75740. See also the discussion of the temporary substitute test in

the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75708-9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments on Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(1)

Requirement That Exchanges Recognize Non-Enumerated Bona Fide Hedging

Positions Consistent With the General Bona Fide Hedging Definition

In connection with the requirement under Sec. 150.9 to apply the

bona fide hedging definition to recognitions, two commenters requested

that the Commission specifically allow exchanges to recognize

anticipatory merchandising as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions should the facts and circumstances warrant including those

rejected strategies [transactions or positions that fail to meet the

`change in value' requirement or the `economically appropriate

test'].\1017\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1017\ CL-ICE-60929 at 12; CL-Working Group-60947 at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter expressed the view that the Commission should

extend the process proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal to include risk management exemptions.\1018\ The commenter

acknowledged but disagrees with the Commission's view that such risk

management exemptions would not be allowed under the statutory

standards for a bona fide hedging position, and suggests that the

Commission could use CEA section 4a(a)(7) authority to provide

exemptions for risk management positions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1018\ CL-AMG-60946 at 6-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A commenter recommended that the rules clarify that the Exchanges

may recognize and grant exemptions on the basis of a strategy, or

hedging need, or a combination of strategies or hedging requirements

associated with managing an ongoing business.\1019\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1019\ CL-CCI-60935 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Separately, one commenter recommended that ``the Commission should

confirm that exchanges may continue to adopt their own rules for

exemptions from speculative position limits for futures contracts that

are subject to DCM limits, but not to federal limits,'' \1020\ while

two others stated that the Commission should confirm that the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal's ``prescriptive procedures''

will not apply to exemptions involving exchange-set limits lower than

federally-set levels, or where the exchanges set the limits

themselves.\1021\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1020\ CL-FIA-60937 at 4.

\1021\ CL-ICE-60929 at 7; CL-Working Group-60947 at 14.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Requests for Recognition of Non-Enumerated Bona Fide Hedging Positions

in the Spot Month

A commenter expressed the view that the Commission should not

``categorically prohibit exchanges from granting non-enumerated and

anticipatory hedge exemptions, as appropriate, during the spot month''

and reminded the Commission that orderly trading requirements remain

applicable to all positions, as provided under the bona fide hedging

position definition. The commenter further expressed the view that the

statutory definition of bona fide hedging position allows for such

recognition during the spot month and that a ``one-size-fits-all''

prohibition will ``unnecessarily restrict commercially reasonable

hedging activity during the spot month.'' \1022\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1022\ CL-ICE-60929 at 9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters were generally against the application of the

five-day rule to non-enumerated bona fide hedging position exemptions,

and recommended that the Commission authorize the exchanges to grant

non-enumerated hedge and spread exemptions during the last five days of

trading or the spot period, and other alternatives and proposed

regulation text.\1023\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1023\ CL-ICE-60929 at 22; CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 13; CL-CME-

60926 at 6 and 8; CL-API-60939 at 3; CL-FIA-60937 at 3 and 12; CL-

Working Group-60947 at 7-9; CL-NCC-ACSA-60972 at 2; CL-CMC-60950 at

9-11; CL-ISDA-60931 at 3 and 10; CL-CCI-60935 at 8-9; CL-MGEX-60936

at 11; CL-FIA-60937 at 10, 11; CL-MGEX-60936 at 11.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Standards Exchanges Must Meet To Provide Recognitions

Several commenters recommended that the Commission not adopt the

proposed ``active trading'' and ``one year experience'' requirements

regarding a DCM's qualification to administer exemptions from federal

position limits.\1024\ One commenter requested removal of the

``actively traded'' requirement, expressing concerns that, based on its

understanding, the requirement would impose an ``absolute prohibition''

on exchange-administered exemptions for new contracts of at least one

year.\1025\ Similarly, a commenter stated that the standard ``would

arbitrarily limit competition and operate

[[Page 96818]]

as a bar to the establishment of new exchanges and new contracts.''

\1026\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1024\ CL-CCI-60935 at 3-4; CL-CME-60926 at 13; CL-FIA-60937 at

9; CL-CMC-60950 at 3; CL-Working Group-60947 at 10; CL-IECAssn-60949

at 12-13.

\1025\ CL-CMC-60950 at 3.

\1026\ CL-IECAssn-60949 at 12-13.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the alternative, one commenter argues that one year of

experience in administering position limits in similar contracts within

a particular ``asset class'' would be a more reasonable

requirement.\1027\ In addition, a commenter expressed the view that the

Commission should not define ``actively traded'' in terms of minimum

monthly volume.\1028\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1027\ CL-CME-60926 at 14.

\1028\ CL-IECAssn-60949 at 13.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Previously Granted Hedge Exemptions

One commenter expressed the view that since the exchanges have been

working with commercial end user for several decades and currently have

a process under Sec. 1.3(z) that may contain specific scenarios that

work well and are not listed in the 2016 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission should deem every currently recognized hedge strategy by any

exchange as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position which would

eliminate disruption and encourage the autonomy of the exchanges.\1029\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1029\ CL-IECAssn-60949 at 11-12.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The commenter also expressed the view that, with respect to the

status of previously exchange-recognized non-enumerated bona fide

hedging positions for which such exchange no longer provides an annual

review, the non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions should remain a

non-enumerated bona fide hedging position and the participants

utilizing that strategy should have ample notice that the exchange will

no longer provide the annual review in order to allow time for the

individual entity to apply to the CFTC directly for a non-enumerated

bona fide hedging position exemption.\1030\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1030\ Id. at 12.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Recognition of OTC Positions as Bona Fide Hedges

Another commenter requested Commission clarification regarding an

exchange's obligation with respect to recognizing and monitoring non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position determinations for OTC positions.

The commenter cited to preamble language to support the possibility of

an obligation, but argued that the text of proposed Sec. 150.9 does

not mention or contemplate such requests for OTC positions. The

commenter also questioned whether such recognition is feasible given

the exchanges' lack of visibility into OTC markets.\1031\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1031\ CL-CME-60926 at 11-12.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal Regarding Sec. 150.9(a)(1) \1032\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1032\ See the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR

at 38469-71 (providing further explanation of proposed Sec.

150.9(a)(1)).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is reproposing the rule, as originally proposed,

subject to the amendments described below.

Requirement That Exchanges Recognize Non-Enumerated Bona Fide Hedging

Positions Consistent With the General Bona Fide Hedging Position

Definition

Regarding comments that the Commission should permit the

recognition of anticipatory merchandising as non-enumerated bona fide

hedging strategies, as noted above, while exchanges' recognition of

non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions must be consistent with the

Commission's bona fide hedging position definition, the Commission

agrees that exchanges should, in each case, make a facts-and-

circumstances determination as to whether to recognize an anticipatory

hedge as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, consistent with

the Commission's recognition ``that there can be a gradation of

probabilities that an anticipated transaction will occur.'' \1033\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1033\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75719.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to the request that the Commission expand the proposed

bona fide hedging position recognition process to include risk

management exemptions, the Commission notes that this suggestion is

contrary to the intent of Congress (to narrow the bona fide hedging

position definition to preclude commodity index hedging, a.k.a. risk

management exemptions).

Regarding comments requesting clarification on exchange authority

to recognize as bona fide hedging positions multiple hedging

strategies, the Commission clarifies that a single application to an

exchange can specify and apply to multiple hedging strategies or needs.

As to comments requesting clarification regarding whether the

proposed application process applies to exchange-set limits, the

Commission notes that the requirements of reproposed Sec. 150.9(a)

addresses processes for recognition of bona fide hedge positions for

purposes of federal limits and not exemption processes such as those

exchanges currently implement and oversee for any exchange-set limits.

In addition, such processes for exchange-set limits that are lower than

the federal limit could differ as long as the exemption provided by the

exchange is capped at the level of the applicable federal limit in

Sec. 150.2.\1034\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1034\ Similarly, as noted above, reproposed Sec.

150.5(a)(2)(i) provides that any exchange may grant exemptions from

any speculative position limits it sets under paragraph Sec.

150.5(a)(1), provided that such exemptions conform to the

requirements specified in Sec. 150.3, and provided further that any

exemptions to exchange-set limits not conforming to Sec. 150.3 are

capped at the level of the applicable federal limit in Sec. 150.2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Requests for Recognition of Non-Enumerated Bona Fide Hedging Positions

in the Spot Month

The Commission considered the recommendations that the Commission:

Allow exchanges to recognize a position as a bona fide hedging position

for up to a five-day retroactive period in circumstances where market

participants need to exceed limits to address a sudden and unforeseen

hedging need; specifically authorize exchanges to recognize positions

as bona fide hedging positions and grant spread exemptions during the

last five days of trading or less, and/or delegate to the exchanges for

their consideration the decision whether to apply the five-day rule to

a particular contract after their evaluation of the particular facts

and circumstances. As the Commission clarified above, the reproposed

rules do not apply the prudential condition of the five-day rule to

non-enumerated hedging positions other than to pass through swap

offsets.\1035\ Therefore, as reproposed, the five-day rule would only

apply to certain positions (pass-through swap offsets, anticipatory and

cross-commodity hedges).\1036\ However, to provide exchanges with

flexibility, in regards to exchange process under Sec. 150.9, the

Commission will allow exchanges to waive the five-day rule on a case-

by-case basis.\1037\ As the Commission noted above, it expects that

exchanges will carefully consider whether allowing retroactive

recognition of a positions as a non-enumerated bona fide hedge would,

as raised by one commenter, diminish the overall integrity of the

process. In

[[Page 96819]]

addition, the Commission also points out that exchanges should

carefully consider whether to adopt in those rules the two safeguards

noted by commenters: (i) Requiring market participants making use of

the retroactive application to demonstrate that the applied-for hedge

was required to address a sudden and unforeseen hedging need; and (ii)

providing that if the emergency hedge recognition was not granted,

exchange rules would continue to require the applicant to unwind its

position in an orderly manner and also would deem the applicant to have

been in violation for any period in which its position exceeded the

applicable limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1035\ See the discussion regarding the five-day rule in

connection with the definition of bona fide hedging position and in

the discussion of 150.9 (Process for recognition of positions as

non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions).

\1036\ See Sec. 150.1 definition of bona fide hedging position

sections (2)(ii)(A), (3)(iii), (4), and (5) (Other enumerated

hedging position). To provide greater clarity as to which bona fide

hedging positions the five-day rule applies, the reproposed rules

reorganize the definition.

\1037\ In addition, reproposed Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(ii)

(Application for exemption) permits exchanges to adopt rules that

allow a trader to file an application for an enumerated bona fide

hedging exemption within five business days after the trader assumed

the position that exceeded a position limit, and adopted a similar

modification to 150.5(b)(5)(i).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Standards Exchanges Must Meet To Provide Recognitions

Regarding comments on the ``active trading'' and ``one year of

experience'' requirements under proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(1)(v), as noted

in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal preamble \1038\ and

above, the Commission is not persuaded that an exchange with no active

trading and no experience would have their interests aligned with the

Commission's policy objectives in CEA section 4a. However, it is clear

from the comments that some interpreted the requirement as a narrower

standard than intended.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1038\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38471.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is, therefore, amending Sec. 150.9(a)(1)(v) to

clarify that the active one-year of experience requirement can be met

by any contract listed in the particular referenced contract.\1039\ As

such, the Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.9(a)(1)(v) to provide

that the exchange has at least one year of experience and expertise

administering position limits for ``a particular commodity'' rather

than for ``such commodity derivative contract.'' Further, in response

to concerns that the standard would limit competition and operate as a

bar to the establishment of new exchanges and new contracts, the

Commission notes that experience manifests in the people carrying out

surveillance in a commodity rather than in an institutional structure.

An exchange's experience could be demonstrated through the relevant

experience of the surveillance staff regarding the particular

commodity. In fact, the Commission has historically reviewed the

experience and qualifications of exchange regulatory divisions when

considering whether to designate a new exchange as a contract market or

to recognize a facility as a SEF; as such exchanges are new, staff

experience has clearly been gained at other exchanges.\1040\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1039\ Regarding the comment that the Commission should not

define ``actively traded,'' the Commission concurs, and notes that,

as proposed in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, this

interpretation will be left to the exchanges' reasonable discretion.

\1040\ For example, the Commission reviews the experience of

chief compliance officers when reviewing SEF applications. See Sec.

37.1501(b)(2) (``Qualifications of chief compliance officer. The

individual designated to serve as chief compliance officer shall

have the background and skills appropriate for fulfilling the

responsibilities of the position.'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition, regarding the Commission's authority to adopt this

standard, the Commission notes that CEA section 4a(c) provides that the

Commission ``shall'' define what constitutes a bona fide hedging

transaction or position. In light of this responsibility, the

Commission believes it is important that exchanges authorized to

recognize non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions have experience

(as indicated by their one year of experience regulating a particular

contract) and interests (as indicated by their actively traded

contract) that are aligned with the Commission's interests. The

commenter provides no alternatives to the one-year experience in the

actively traded contract as proxies for an exchange's interests being

aligned with that of the Commission.

The Commission clarifies, however, that an exchange can petition

the Commission, pursuant to Sec. 140.99, for a waiver of the one-year

experience requirement if such exchange believes that their experience

and interests are aligned with the Commission's interests with respect

to recognizing non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions.

Previously Granted Hedge Exemptions

With respect to comments regarding currently recognized exchange-

granted non-enumerated bona fide hedging position exemptions, as noted

above, the Commission believes the statutory directive to define bona

fide hedging position narrows the current Sec. 1.3(z)(1) definition.

As a result, currently recognized bona fide hedging strategies may not

meet the new narrower bona fide hedging position standards. While

certain strategies may not meet the definition of bona fide hedging

position reproposed in this rulemaking, to reduce the potential for

market disruption by forced liquidations, the Commission proposes, as

discussed above, to clarify and expand the relief in Sec. 150.3(f)

(previously granted exemptions) to grandfather previously granted risk-

management strategies applicable to previously established derivative

positions in commodity index contract.\1041\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1041\ As stated above, Sec. 150.3(f) provides (1) recognition

of the offset of the risk of a pre-existing financial instrument as

bona fide using a derivative position, including a deferred

derivative contract month entered after the effective date of a

final rule, provided a nearby derivative contract month is

liquidated (such recognition will not extend such relief to an

increase in positions after the effective date of a limit); (2)

possible application of previously granted exemptions to pre-

existing financial instruments that are within the scope of existing

Sec. 1.47 exemptions, rather than only to pre-existing swaps; and

(3) recognition of exchange-granted non-enumerated exemptions in

non-legacy commodity derivatives outside of the spot month

(consistent with the Commission's recognition of risk management

exemptions outside of the spot month), provided such exemptions are

granted prior to the compliance date of a final rule, and apply only

to pre-existing financial instruments as of the effective date of a

final rule. These last two were proposed to reduce the potential for

market disruption, since a market intermediary would continue to be

able to offset risks of pre-effective-date financial instruments,

pursuant to previously-granted federal or exchange risk management

exemptions. See supra discussion of the Commission's reproposed

definition for bona fide hedging position; see also the discussion

regarding the reproposed Sec. 150.3(f). In response to the comment

requesting that the Commission use its authority under CEA section

4a(a)(7) to provide exemptions for risk management positions, as

noted above, that appears contrary to Congressional intent to narrow

the definition of a bona fide hedging position.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Regarding comments that exchanges should be required to provide

additional notice or phase-out time for any bona fide hedging position

recognitions that may expire, the Commission notes that, under

reproposed Sec. 150.5, exchanges may issue recognition determinations

for one year only. As such a market participant is provided a one-year

notice for the potential expiration of the recognition of their

position as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, and may seek

recognition of the position from another (or the same) DCM, or from the

CFTC directly prior to the expiration of the one-year period. The

Commission is not proposing to authorize exchanges to provide an

unlimited recognition of positions as non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions, and is not proposing to require exchanges to provide further

notice to market participants prior to the expiration of previous

determinations.

Recognition of OTC Positions as Bona Fide Hedging Positions

Regarding comments requesting a clarification with respect to OTC

positions, the Commission clarifies that exchanges do not have an

obligation to monitor for compliance with OTC-only positions.

[[Page 96820]]

b. Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(2); Sec. 150.9(a)(3); and Sec.

150.9(a)(4)--Application Process

Proposed Rules. As proposed, Sec. 150.9(a)(2) would permit an

exchange to establish a less expansive application process for non-

enumerated bona fide hedging positions previously recognized and

published on such exchange's Web site than for non-enumerated bona fide

hedging positions based on novel facts and circumstances. This is

because the Commission believed that some lesser degree of scrutiny may

be adequate for applications involving recurring fact patterns, so long

as the applicants are similarly situated. However, the Commission

understood that DCMs currently use a single-track application process

to recognize non-enumerated positions, for purposes of exchange limits,

as within the meaning of the general bona fide hedging position

definition in Sec. 1.3(z)(1).\1042\ The Commission did not know

whether any exchange would elect to establish a separate application

process for non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions based on novel

versus non-novel facts and circumstances, or what the salient

differences between the two processes might be, or whether a dual-track

application process might be more likely to produce inaccurate results,

e.g., inappropriate recognition of positions that are not bona fide

hedging positions within the parameters set forth by Congress in CEA

section 4a(c).\1043\ In proposing to permit separate application

processes for novel and non-novel non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions, the Commission sought to provide flexibility for exchanges,

but will insist on fair and open access for market participants to seek

recognition of compliant positions as non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1042\ 17 CFR 1.3(z)(1).

\1043\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(c). The Commission noted that it could, under

the proposal, review determinations made by a particular exchange,

for example, that recognizes an unusually large number of bona fide

hedging positions, relative to those of other exchanges.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission believed that there is a core set of information and

materials necessary to enable an exchange to determine, and the

Commission to verify, whether the facts and circumstances attendant to

a position satisfy the requirements of CEA section 4a(c). Accordingly,

the Commission proposed to require in Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(i), (iii) and

(iv) that all applicants submit certain factual statements and

representations. Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(i) required a description

of the position in the commodity derivative contract for which the

application is submitted and the offsetting cash positions.\1044\

Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(iii) required a statement concerning the

maximum size of all gross positions in derivative contracts to be

acquired during the year after the application is submitted.\1045\

Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(iv) required detailed information regarding

the applicant's activity in the cash markets for the commodity

underlying the position for which the application is submitted during

the past three years.\1046\ These proposed application requirements are

similar to existing requirements for recognition under current Sec.

1.48 of a non-enumerated bona fide hedge.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1044\ See Sec. 1.47(b)(1), 17 CFR 1.47(b)(1), requiring a

description of the futures positions and the offsetting cash

positions.

\1045\ See Sec. 1.47(b)(4), 17 CFR 1.47(b)(4), requiring the

maximum size of gross futures positions which will be acquired

during the following year.

\1046\ See Sec. Sec. 1.47(b)(6), 1.48(b)(1)(i) and (2)(i), 17

CFR 1.47(b)(6), 1.48(b)(1)(i) and 2(i), requiring three years of

history of production or usage.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also proposed to require in Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(ii)

and (v) that all applicants submit detailed information to demonstrate

why the position satisfies the requirements of CEA section 4a(c) \1047\

and any other information necessary to enable the exchange to

determine, and the Commission to verify, whether it is appropriate to

recognize such a position as a non-enumerated bona fide hedge.\1048\

The Commission anticipated that such detailed information may include

both a factual and legal analysis indicating why recognition is

justified for such applicant's position. The Commission expected that

if the materials submitted in response to proposed Sec.

150.9(a)(3)(ii) are relatively comprehensive, requests for additional

information pursuant to proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(v) would be

relatively infrequent. Nevertheless, the Commission believed that it is

important to include the requirement in proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(v)

that applicants submit any other information necessary to enable the

exchange to determine, and the Commission to verify, that it is

appropriate to recognize a position as a non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position so that DCMs can protect and manage their markets.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1047\ Although many commenters have requested that the

Commission retain the pre-Dodd Frank Act standard contained in

current Sec. 1.3(z), 17 CFR 1.3(z), there is explicit and implicit

support in the comments on the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal for pegging what applicants must demonstrate to the current

statutory provision as amended by the Dodd-Frank Act. One commenter

requested that the Commission ``publicly clarify that hedge

positions are bona fide when they satisfy the hedge definition

codified by Congress in section 4a(c)(2) of the Act, as added by the

Dodd-Frank Act.'' CL-CME-59718 at 46. Another commenter supported a

``process for Commission approval of a `non-enumerated' hedge that .

. . complies with the statutory definition of the term `bona fide

hedge.' '' CL-NGSA-59673 at 2. CEA section 4a(c)(2) contains

standards for positions that constitute bona fide hedging positions.

The Commission expects that exchanges would consider the

Commission's relevant regulations and interpretations, when

determining whether a position satisfies the requirements of CEA

section 4a(c)(2). However, exchanges may confront novel facts and

circumstances with respect to a particular applicant's position,

dissimilar to facts and circumstances previously considered by the

Commission. In these cases, an exchange may request assistance from

the Commission; see the discussion of proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(8) in

the 2016 Position Limits Supplemental Proposal.

\1048\ See Sec. 1.47(b)(2), 17 CFR 1.47(b)(2), requiring

detailed information to demonstrate that the futures positions are

economically appropriate to the reduction of risk in the conduct and

management of a commercial enterprise. See also Sec. 1.47(b)(3), 17

CFR 1.47(b)(3), requiring, upon request, such other information

necessary to enable the Commission to determine whether a particular

futures position meets the requirements of the general definition of

bona fide hedging. Under current application processes, market

participants provide similar information to DCMs, make various

representations required by DCMs and agree to certain terms imposed

by DCMs with respect to exemptions granted. The Commission has

recognized that DCMs already consider any information they deem

relevant to requests for exemptions from position limits. See, e.g.,

Rule Enforcement Review of ICE Futures U.S., July 22, 2014, p. 41.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Under the proposal, the Commission would permit an exchange to

recognize a smaller than requested position for purposes of exchange-

set limits. For instance, an exchange might recognize a smaller than

requested position that otherwise satisfies the requirements of CEA

section 4a(c) if the exchange determines that recognizing a larger

position would be disruptive to the exchange's markets. This is

consistent with current exchange practice. This is also consistent with

DCM and SEF core principles. DCM core principle 5(A) provides that,

``[t]o reduce the potential threat of market manipulation or congestion

(especially during trading during the delivery month), the board of

trade shall adopt for each contract of the board of trade, as is

necessary and appropriate, position limitations or position

accountability for speculators.'' \1049\ SEF core principle 6(A)

contains a similar provision.\1050\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1049\ CEA section 5(d)(5)(A), 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(5)(A); Sec.

38.300, 17 CFR 38.300. The Commission proposed, consistent with

previous Commission determinations, a preliminary finding that

speculative position limits are necessary in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal. December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78

FR at 75685.

\1050\ CEA Section 5h(f)(6)(A), 7 U.S.C. 7b-3(f)(6)(A); Sec.

38.300, 17 CFR 38.300.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

By requiring in proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(3) that all applicants

submit a core set of information and materials, the Commission

anticipated that all exchanges would develop similar non-

[[Page 96821]]

enumerated bona fide hedging position application processes. However,

the Commission intended that exchanges have sufficient discretion to

accommodate the needs of their market participants. The Commission also

intended to promote fair and open access for market participants to

obtain recognition of compliant derivative positions as non-enumerated

bona fide hedges.

Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(4) set forth certain timing requirements

that an exchange must include in its rules for the non-enumerated bona

fide hedge application process. A person intending to rely on an

exchange's recognition of a position as a non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position would be required to submit an application in advance

and to reapply at least on an annual basis. This is consistent with

commenters' views and DCMs' current annual exemption review

process.\1051\ Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(4) would require an exchange to

notify an applicant in a timely manner whether the position was

recognized as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position or rejected,

including the reasons for any rejection.\1052\ On the other hand, and

consistent with the status quo, proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(4) would allow

the exchange to revoke, at any time, any recognition previously issued

pursuant to proposed Sec. 150.9 if the exchange determined the

recognition is no longer in accord with section 4a(c) of the Act.\1053\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1051\ See, e.g., statement of Ron Oppenheimer on behalf of the

Working Group (supporting an annual non-enumerated bona fide hedge

application), statement of Erik Haas, Director, Market Regulation,

ICE Futures U.S. (describing the DCM's annual exemption review

process), and statement of Tom LaSala, Chief Regulatory Officer, CME

Group (envisioning market participants applying for non-enumerated

bona fide hedge on a yearly basis), transcript of the EEMAC open

meeting, July 29, 2015, at 40, 53, and 58, available at http://www.cftc.gov/idc/groups/public/@aboutcftc/documents/file/emactranscript072915.pdf.

\1052\ See, e.g., statement of Ron Oppenheimer on behalf of the

Working Group (noting that exchanges retain the ability to revoke an

exemption if market circumstances warrant), transcript of the EEMAC

open meeting, July 29, 2015, at 57, available at http://www.cftc.gov/idc/groups/public/@aboutcftc/documents/file/emactranscript072915.pdf.

\1053\ As noted above, the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal did not impair the ability of any market participant to

request an interpretation under Sec. 140.99 for recognition of a

position as a bona fide hedging position if an exchange rejects

their recognition application or revokes recognition previously

issued. See 2016 Position Limits Supplemental Proposal, n. 78 and

accompanying text.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission did not propose to prescribe time-limited periods

(e.g., a specific number of days) for submission or review of non-

enumerated bona fide hedge applications. The Commission proposed only

to require that an applicant must have received recognition for a non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position before such applicant exceeds any

limit then in effect, and that the exchange administer the process, and

the various steps in the process, in a timely manner. This means that

an exchange must, in a timely manner, notify an applicant if a

submission is incomplete, determine whether a position is a non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position, and notify an applicant whether

a position will be recognized, or the application rejected. The

Commission anticipated that rules of an exchange may nevertheless set

deadlines for various parts of the application process. The Commission

does not believe that reasonable deadlines or minimum review periods

are inconsistent with the general principle of timely administration of

the application process. An exchange could also establish different

deadlines for a dual-track application process. The Commission believed

that the individual exchanges themselves are in the best position to

evaluate how quickly each can administer the application process, in

order best to accommodate the needs of market participants. In addition

to review of an exchange's timeline when it submits its rules for its

application process under part 40, the Commission would review the

exchange's timeliness in the context of a rule enforcement review.

Comments Received

One commenter expressed the view that it does not support different

application processes for novel and non-novel hedges.\1054\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1054\ CL-IECAssn-60949 at 14.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Two commenters expressed the view that the 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal should be revised to eliminate, to the maximum

extent possible, the ``overly prescriptive rules'' governing what

exchanges must collect from non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

applicants and instead give the exchanges more discretion and

flexibility to fashion non-enumerated bona fide hedging position rules

that are more closely aligned with current hedge approval

processes.\1055\ Conversely, another commenter recommended that the

Commission require a standardized and harmonized process across all

participating exchanges for non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

applications.\1056\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1055\ CL-ETP-60915 at 1; CL-MGEX-60936 at 5-6.

\1056\ CL-EDF-60944 at 1-3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter recommended that the Commission, to the greatest

extent possible, allow the exchanges to administer exemptions for non-

enumerated bona fide hedging positions, enumerated bona fide hedging

positions, and spread positions in the same manner as they have been to

date.\1057\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1057\ CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters recommended that the Commission not require

exchanges to demand and collect three years of cash market information

in order to process an entity's application for a non-enumerated bona

fide hedging exemption. According to the commenters, it would be

burdensome on both the applicant and the exchange, as well as

unnecessary and not authorized by the CEA.\1058\ As an alternative,

commenters cited practices currently authorized for, and practiced by,

the exchanges, and that typically only require applicants to provide

such data from the preceding year, though the market participant

requesting the hedge exemption must stand ready to provide further

supporting documentation for the requested exemption on request.\1059\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1058\ CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 10; CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 4; CL-ICE-

60929 at 8; 16, CL-COPE-60932 at 9; CL-CCI-60935 at 7; CL-COPE-60932

at 9; CL-FIA-60937 at 3; 12, CL-AGA-60943 at 6; CL-AMG-60946 at 3-4;

CL-Working Group-60947 at 11; CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 10; CL-CCI-60935

at 7; CL-CME-60926 at 9; CL-FIA-60937 at 3, 12; CL-Working Group-

60947 at 11 (footnotes omitted); and CL-ICE-60929 at 8, 16 (noting

that in many cases exchanges already have access to this data, or

can easily obtain it).

\1059\ CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 10; CL-CCI-60935 at 7; CL-CME-60926

at 9; CL-Working Group-60947 at 11 (footnotes omitted); CL-FIA-60937

at 3, 12; CL-Working Group-60947 at 11; CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 10;

CL-CCI-60935 at 7; CL-CME-60926 at 9; CL-AGA-60943 at 6; and CL-AMG-

60946 at 3-4 (recommending that exchanges have authority to, but not

be required to, collect up to 3 years of data).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter expressed the view that exchanges do not need the

``detailed information'' that the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal requires of market participants seeking an exchange-

administered hedge exemption. The commenter believes that requiring an

exemption applicant to perform its own legal and economic analysis

would be cost prohibitive and impractical. Further, the commenter

asserted that it is unclear whether an exchange could still grant an

exemption even if it disagrees with an applicant's analysis.\1060\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1060\ CL-CME-60926 at 9. See also CL-AMG-60946 at 4 (requesting

a clarification that that this demonstration (of how the position

meets the definition of a bona fide hedging position does not

require submission of legal opinion from counsel which would be

``unduly burdensome'' for market participants).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some commenters requested clarification regarding the proposed

Sec. 150.9(a)(3) requirement with respect to

[[Page 96822]]

the compilation of gross positions for every commodity derivative

contact that the applicant holds, and whether the proposed regulations

are intended to apply to an applicant's maximum size of all gross

positions for each and every commodity derivative contract the

applicant holds (as opposed to the maximum gross positions in the

commodity derivative contract(s) for which the exemption is

sought).\1061\ In addition, one commenter suggested that ``the

Commission should clarify that an application for a non-enumerated

hedge or spread exemption only must include derivative positions

related to the requested exemption.'' \1062\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1061\ CL-CCI-60935 at 6-7; and (CL-Working Group-60947 at 10).

\1062\ CL-FIA-60937 at 4, 13.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter expressed the view that it is concerned regarding how

exchanges should coordinate the granting of exemptions with respect to

contracts on the same underlying commodities that trade on different

exchanges, and requests guidance from the Commission on that

matter.\1063\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1063\ CL-ISDA-60931 at 6-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In connection with proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(4), several commenters

expressed the view that the Commission should allow exchanges to

recognize an enumerated or non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

exemption retroactively in circumstances where market participants need

to exceed limits to address a sudden and unforeseen hedging need.\1064\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1064\ See, e.g., CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 10-11; CL-EEI-EPSA-60925

at 4; CL-ICE-60929 at 11; CL-ISDA-60931 at 13; CL-FIA-60937 at 13;

CL-Working Group-60947 at 13-14; and CL-CME-60926 at 12.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal

The Commission has determined to repropose the rule, largely as

originally proposed, except that the Commission has revised the

regulatory text to: (i) Clarify what the statement must address under

Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(iii) and 150.9(a)(3)(iv); and (ii) require only one

year of history rather than three years in Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(iv), each

as described further below.

Regarding comments that the Commission should not have different

application processes for novel vs. non-novel products, (pursuant to

proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(2)) the Commission is clarifying that exchanges

are authorized but not required to have a different application process

for novel and non-novel hedge applications. Further, Sec. 150.9 does

not prevent industry from working together to adopt a universal

application for novel and non-novel hedges.

Regarding comments on current exchange processes for administering

exemptions, and comments regarding the information required in the

application process, reproposed Sec. 150.9 would require that

exchanges collect a minimum amount of information, and exchanges would

have discretion to require additional information. That is, Sec. 150.9

provides parameters for a basic application and processing process for

the recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions; the

parameters allow exchanges flexibility, while also facilitating

Commission review. Also, the Commission reiterates that reproposed

Sec. 150.9 addresses federal limits and not exchange exemption

processes, such as those exchanges currently implement and oversee for

any exchange-set limits. Such processes for exchange-set limits that

are lower than the federal limit could differ as long as the exemption

provided by the exchange is capped at the level of the applicable

federal limit in Sec. 150.2.

Regarding concerns that Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(ii), as proposed,

required an application to include a legal opinion or analysis for

exchange recognition of a position as a non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position, the Commission clarifies that the regulation does not

require applicants to obtain a legal opinion or analysis. Rather, under

Sec. 150.9(a)(3), it is the exchange's duty to make a determination

regarding whether a contract meets the application requirements; it may

ask for additional information than the minimum required if it

determines that further information is necessary to make its

determination. To further clarify this point, the Commission is

proposing the following change to Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(ii) to provide that

the exchange require at a minimum ``information to demonstrate why the

position satisfies the requirements of section 4a(c) of the Act and the

general definition of bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1,''

rather than ``detailed information.'' The same change is also being

proposed for Sec. 150.9(a)(3(iv) for the same reasons.

Regarding interpreting Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(iii) as requiring the

inclusion in a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position application of

a statement regarding the maximum gross positions to be acquired by the

applicant during the year after the application is submitted, the

Commission clarifies that the provision requires only information

related to the contract for which the application is submitted;

consequently, the Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(iii) to

require a ``statement concerning the maximum size of all gross

positions in derivative contracts for which the application is

submitted.'' The Commission further clarifies that the statement should

be based on a good faith estimate.

In addition, the Commission notes that the minimum information to

be required by the exchange under Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(iii), would be for

the gross position for the following year, since the applicant will

need to reapply each year for exchange recognition of its position as a

bona fide hedging position.

With respect to the condition that exchanges require applicants to

provide three years of data supporting their application, the

Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(iv) to require only one

year of data.

Regarding commenter concerns about whether or how exchanges should

coordinate in granting exemptions consistently across exchanges, the

reproposed rules would allow each exchange to use their own expertise

to decide which positions should be recognized as bona fide hedging

positions and what limit levels to impose for their venue. The

Commission notes that it serves in an oversight role to monitor

exchange determinations and position limits across exchanges. The

Reproposal does not require exchanges to coordinate with respect to

making such determinations; however, neither does reproposed Sec.

150.9 prohibit coordination.

Regarding application of the five-day rule to non-enumerated bona

fide hedging positions, as the Commission discussed above, the

Reproposal does not apply the prudential condition of the five-day rule

to non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions. As discussed in

connection with the definition of bona fide hedging position and in the

context of Sec. 150.5(a),\1065\ the five-day rule would only apply to

certain positions (pass-through swap offsets, anticipatory and cross-

commodity hedges).\1066\ However, in regards to exchange processes

under Sec. 150.9 (and Sec. 150.10, and Sec. 150.11), the Commission

is allowing exchanges to waive the five-day rule on a case-by-case

basis.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1065\ See 2016 Position Limits Supplemental Proposal for the

discussion regarding the five-day rule in connection with the

definition of bona fide hedging position and in the discussion of

Sec. 150.5 (Exchange-set speculative position limits).

\1066\ See Sec. 150.1 definition of bona fide hedging position

sections (2)(ii)(A), (3)(iii), (4), and (5) (Other enumerated

hedging position). As noted above, to provide greater clarity as to

which bona fide hedge positions the five-day rule applies, the

reproposed rules reorganize the definition.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Regarding exchanges' authority to retroactively recognize positions

as bona

[[Page 96823]]

fide hedging positions, reproposed Sec. 150.9(a)(5) would require an

applicant to receive exchange recognition in advance of the date that a

position would otherwise be in excess of a position limit. Thus, the

Reproposal would not permit retroactive recognition of a non-enumerated

bona fide hedging position. The Commission preliminarily does not

believe that it should authorize an exchange to recognize a non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position retroactively, as this may

diminish the ability of the Commission to review timely such an

exchange determination, potentially diminishing the utility of position

limits in preventing unwarranted price fluctuations.\1067\ By way of

contrast with regard to enumerated bona fide hedging positions, the

Commission expects that exchanges will carefully consider whether

allowing retroactive recognition of an enumerated bona fide hedging

exemption, under reproposed Sec. 150.5, would, as noted by one

commenter, diminish the overall integrity of the process. And the

exchanges should also consider whether to adopt in those rules the two

safeguards noted: (i) Requiring market participants making use of the

retroactive application to demonstrate that the applied-for hedge was

required to address a sudden and unforeseen hedging need; and (ii)

providing that if the emergency hedge recognition was not granted,

exchange rules would continue to require the applicant to unwind its

position in an orderly manner and also would deem the applicant to have

been in violation for any period in which its position exceeded the

applicable limits.\1068\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1067\ Current Sec. 1.47 requires a filing in advance for

Commission recognition of a position as a non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position.

\1068\ See 2016 Position Limits Supplemental Proposal discussion

regarding proposed Sec. 150.5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

c. Proposed 150.9(a)(5) and Commission Reproposal

Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(5) made it clear that the position will be

deemed to be recognized as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

when an exchange recognizes it; proposed Sec. 150.9(d) provided the

process through which the exchange's recognition would be subject to

review by the Commission.\1069\ As noted above, DCMs currently exercise

discretion with regard to exchange-set limits to approve exemptions

meeting the general definition of bona fide hedging position. The

Commission works cooperatively with DCMs to enforce compliance with

exchange-set speculative position limits. In the 2016 Position Limits

Supplemental Proposal, the Commission believed that a continuation of

this cooperative process, and an extension to the proposed federal

position limits, would be consistent with the policy objectives in CEA

section 4a(3)(B).\1070\ The Commission is reproposing Sec.

150.9(a)(5), as originally proposed.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1069\ See 2016 Position Limits Supplemental Proposal, nn. 121-

123 and accompanying text; see also the 2016 Position Limits

Supplemental Proposal discussion of proposed Sec. 150.9(d), review

of applications by the Commission. Exchange recognition of a

position as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position would allow

the market participant to exceed the federal position limit until

such time that the Commission notified the market participant to the

contrary, pursuant to the proposed review procedure that the

exchange action was dismissed. That is, if a party were to hold

positions pursuant to a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

recognition granted by the exchange, such positions would not be

subject to federal position limits, unless or until the Commission

were to determine that such non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position recognition is inconsistent with the CEA or CFTC

regulations thereunder. Under this framework, the Commission would

continue to exercise its authority in this regard by reviewing an

exchange's determination and verifying whether the facts and

circumstances in respect of a derivative position satisfy the

requirements of the Commission's general definition of bona fide

hedging position in Sec. 150.1. If the Commission determines that

the exchange-granted recognition is inconsistent with section 4a(c)

of the Act and the Commission's general definition of bona fide

hedging position in Sec. 150.1, a market participant would be

required to reduce the derivative position or otherwise come into

compliance with position limits within a commercially reasonable

amount of time.

\1070\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(3)(B).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

d. Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(6)

Proposed Rule: Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(6) required exchanges that

elect to process non-enumerated bona fide hedging position applications

to promulgate reporting rules for applicants who own, hold or control

positions recognized as non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions. The

Commission expected that the exchanges would promulgate enhanced

reporting rules in order to obtain sufficient information to conduct an

adequate surveillance program to detect and potentially deter

excessively large positions that may disrupt the price discovery

process. At a minimum, these rules should require applicants to report

when an non-enumerated bona fide hedging position has been established,

and to update and maintain the accuracy of such reports. These rules

should also elicit information from applicants that will assist

exchanges in complying with proposed Sec. 150.9(c) regarding exchange

reports to the Commission.

Comments Received: Several commenters did not support a Commission

requirement for additional filings with respect to non-enumerated bona

fide hedging positions to be held in the five day/spot month

period.\1071\ Commenters also requested that the Commission remove the

proposed requirement that an exchange must adopt enhanced reporting

rules for market participants that rely on exchange recognitions of

positions as non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions.\1072\

Generally, commenters suggested that any additional reporting

requirements be kept simple, streamlined and minimally

burdensome.\1073\ One commenter expressed the view that the Commission

should clarify certain aspects relating to the mechanics and content of

proposed reporting requirements for those seeking an exchange-

administered hedge exemption.\1074\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1071\ CL-IECAssn-60949 at 13; CL-NMPF-60956 at 2; CL-NCFC-60930

at 4-5; CL-ICE-60929 at 22; CL-ICE-60929 at 22; and CL-FIA-60937 at

18, 19.

\1072\ See, e.g., CL-FIA-60937 at 15; CL-CMC-60950 at 12-13; CL-

CCI-60935 at 7-8; CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 12-13; CL-MGEX-60936 at 6;

CL-ISDA-60931 at 10; CL-NGFA-60941 at 4; CL-Working Group-60947 at

12 (footnotes omitted); CL-AMG-60946 at 4-5; CL-CCI-60935 at 7-8;

CL-AGA-60943 at 6; CL-CMC-60950 at 12-13; and CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at

12-13 (expressing the view that, reporting of positions for non-

enumerated bona fide hedges should mirror the mechanism for

reporting EBFHs recognized by exchanges that utilize the process

where reports of such positions are made to the Commission with an

identical copy to be filed with the applicable exchange(s). See also

CL-MGEX-60936 at 5-6 (requesting that reporting and recordkeeping

requirements be removed or at least reduced unless there is a

demonstrated need for them and b) only exemptions granted in excess

of federal limits should require reporting to the Commission.); and

CL-AGA-60943 at 7 (commenting that ``because Exchanges may, at any

time, request records of hedgers' cash market and derivative

positions or other details and explanations concerning the

commercial risks being hedged, any Exchange surveillance function

can be met by exchange data inquiries, rather than by an affirmative

reporting obligation by a commercial hedger.'').

\1073\ CL-NFP-60942 at 6-8); and CL-FIA-60937 at 4, 15.

\1074\ CL-CME-60926 at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission has determined to amend and

clarify the proposal as follows. First, the Commission clarifies that

it does not require additional filings under Sec. 150.9(a)(6); rather,

it is in the exchanges' discretion to determine whether there is a

reporting requirement for a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position.

Consequently, the Commission is amending the regulation text to clarify

that exchanges are authorized to, rather than required to, determine

whether to require enhanced reporting, providing only that exchanges

that determine to process non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

applications shall have rules, submitted to the Commission under part

40, that require applicants ``to file reports pertaining to the use of

[[Page 96824]]

any such exemption that has been granted in the manner, form, and

frequency, as determined by the designated contract market or swap

execution facility.''

e. Proposed 150.9(a)(7)--Transparency to Market Participants

Proposed Rule: Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(7) required an exchange to

publish on its Web site, no less frequently than quarterly, a

description of each new type of derivative position that it recognizes

as a non-enumerated bona fide hedge. The Commission envisioned that

each description would be an executive summary. The 2016 Position

Limits Supplemental Proposal required that the description include a

summary describing the type of derivative position and an explanation

of why it qualifies as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position. The

Commission believed that the exchanges are in the best position when

quickly crafting these descriptions to accommodate an applicant's

desire for trading anonymity while promoting fair and open access for

market participants to information regarding which positions might be

recognized as non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions. The

Commission proposed to spot check these summaries pursuant to proposed

Sec. 150.9(e).

i. Comments Received

Several commenters proposed that the Commission clarify or confirm

that exchanges are not required to divulge confidential information

(such as trade secrets, intellectual property, the market participant's

identity or position) when providing the summary description of non-

enumerated bona fide hedge positions.\1075\ One commenter requested

``that the Commission explicitly provide in Rule 150.9(a)(7) that the

summaries must be published `in a manner that preserves the anonymity

of the applicant' and provide additional guidance regarding the types

of sensitive items that should be omitted from any summary, such as the

size of the position(s) taken or to be taken by the applicant or the

delivery point(s) or other information that might identify the

applicant.'' \1076\ Another commenter expressed the view that an

exchange should not be required to disclose its own internal analyses

when explaining its decision to grant an exemption for a derivative

position recognized as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position.\1077\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1075\ See, e.g., CL-ICE-60929 at 23; CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 14

(footnote omitted); CL-DFA-60927 at 6; CL-NCFC-60930 at 5; CL-IATP-

60951 at 6; CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 9; CL-COPE-60932 at 9; CL-DFA-60927

at 6; and CL-NCFC-60930 at 5.

\1076\ CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 14 (footnote omitted).

\1077\ CL-CME-60926 at 11.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: While the Commission is reproposing the

rule, as originally proposed, it clarifies that that any data published

pursuant to Sec. 150.9(a)(7) should not disclose the identity of, or

confidential information about, the applicant. Rather, any published

summaries are expected to be general (generic facts and circumstances)

and not include detail that would disclose trade secrets or

intellectual property.

f. Proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(8) and Commission Reproposal

Under proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(8), an exchange could elect to

request the Commission review a non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position application that raises novel or complex issues using the

process set forth in proposed Sec. 150.9(d).\1078\ If an exchange

makes a request pursuant to proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(8), the Commission,

as would be the case for an exchange, would not be bound by a time

limitation. This is because the Commission proposed only that non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position applications be processed in a

timely manner.\1079\ Essentially, this proposed provision largely

preserved the Commission's review process under current Sec.

1.47,\1080\ except that a market participant first seeks recognition of

a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position from an exchange.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1078\ Under proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(8), if the exchange

determines to request that the Commission consider the application,

the exchange must, under proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(4)(v)(C), notify an

applicant in a timely manner that the exchange has requested that

the Commission review the application. This provision provides the

exchanges with the ability to request Commission review early in the

review process, rather than requiring the exchanges to process the

request, make a determination and only then begin the process of

Commission review provided for under proposed Sec. 150.9(d). The

Commission noted that although most of its reviews would occur after

the exchange makes its determination, the Commission could, as

provided for in proposed Sec. 150.9(d)(1), initiate its review, in

its discretion, at any time.

\1079\ Novel facts and circumstances may present particularly

complex issues that could benefit from extended consideration, given

the Commission's current resource constraints.

\1080\ 17 CFR 1.47.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.9(a)(8), as originally

proposed.

4. Proposed Sec. 150.9(b)--Recordkeeping Requirements

Proposed Rule: Proposed Sec. 150.9(b) outlined the recordkeeping

requirements for exchanges that elected to process non-enumerated bona

fide hedging position applications under proposed Sec. 150.9(a).\1081\

The proposal required that exchanges maintain complete books and

records of all activities relating to the processing and disposition of

applications in a manner consistent with the Commission's existing

general regulations regarding recordkeeping.\1082\ In consideration of

the fact that DCMs currently recognize non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions which must be updated annually and that the proposal would

require annual updates, the Commission proposed that exchanges keep

books and records until the termination, maturity, or expiration date

of any recognition of a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position and

for a period of five years after such date. The Commission stated that

five years should provide an adequate time period for Commission

reviews, whether that be a review of an exchange's rule enforcement or

a review of a market participant's representations.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1081\ Id. Proposed Sec. 150.10(b) and Sec. 150.11(b) contain

substantially similar recordkeeping requirements regarding spread

exemptions and anticipatory hedge exemptions.

\1082\ Requirements regarding the keeping and inspection of all

books and records required to be kept by the Act or the Commission's

regulations are found at Sec. 1.31, 17 CFR 1.31. DCMs and SEFs are

already required to maintain records of their business activities in

accordance with the requirements of Sec. 1.31 and 17 CFR 38.951.

See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38474

(providing a more comprehensive discussion of proposed Sec.

150.9(b)).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Exchanges would be required to store and produce records pursuant

to current Sec. 1.31 of the Commission's regulations, and would be

subject to requests for information pursuant to other applicable

Commission regulations including, for example, Sec. 38.5. Consistent

with current Sec. 1.31, the Commission clarified its expectation that

the records would be readily accessible until the termination,

maturity, or expiration date of the recognition and during the first

two years of the subsequent five year period. In addition, the

Commission did not intend in proposed Sec. 150.9(b)(1) to create any

new obligation for an exchange to record conversations with applicants,

which includes their representatives; however, the Commission expected

that an exchange would preserve any written or electronic notes of

verbal interactions with such parties.

Finally, the Commission emphasized that parties who avail

themselves of exemptions under Sec. 150.3(a), as proposed in the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, would be subject to the

recordkeeping requirements of Sec. 150.3(g), as well as

[[Page 96825]]

requests from the Commission for additional information under Sec.

150.3(h), as each was proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal. The Commission noted that it might request additional

information, for example, in connection with review of an

application.\1083\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1083\ The Commission pointed out that in the December 2013

Position Limits Proposal, persons claiming exemptions under proposed

Sec. 150.3 must still ``maintain complete books and records

concerning all details of their related cash, forward, futures,

options and swap positions and transactions. Furthermore, such

persons must make such books and records available to the Commission

upon request under proposed Sec. 150.3(h), which would preserve the

`special call' rule set forth in current 17 CFR 150.3(b).'' 78 FR

75741 (footnote omitted).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission did not receive comments on

Sec. 150.9(b) (nor on Sec. 150.10(b) or Sec. 150.11(b)), and is

reproposing Sec. 150.9(b), as originally proposed, for the reasons

explained in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal.\1084\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1084\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38474.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

5. Proposed Sec. 150.9(c)--Exchange Reporting

Proposed Rule: Proposed Sec. 150.9(c)(1) required an exchange that

elected to process non-enumerated bona fide hedge applications to

submit a weekly report to the Commission.\1085\ The proposed report

would provide information regarding each commodity derivative position

recognized by the exchange as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position during the course of the week. Information provided in the

report would include the identity of the applicant seeking such an

exemption, the maximum size of the derivative position that was

recognized by the exchange as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position,\1086\ and, to the extent that the exchange determined to

limit the size of such bona fide hedging position under the exchange's

own speculative position limits program, the size of any limit

established by the exchange.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1085\ Id.

\1086\ The Commission noted that an exchange could determine to

recognize all, or a portion, of the commodity derivative position in

respect of which an application for recognition had been submitted,

as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, provided that such

determination was made in accordance with the requirements of

proposed Sec. 150.9 and was consistent with the Act and the

Commission's regulations. Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission envisioned that the proposed report would specify

the maximum size and/or size limitations by contract month and/or type

of limit (e.g., spot month, single month, or all-months-combined), as

applicable.\1087\ The proposed report would also provide information

regarding any revocation of, or modification to the terms and

conditions of, a prior determination by the exchange to recognize a

commodity derivative position as a non-enumerated bona fide hedge. In

addition, the report would include any summary of a type of recognized

non-enumerated bona fide hedge that was, during the course of the week,

published or revised on the exchange's Web site pursuant to proposed

Sec. 150.9(a)(7).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1087\ Under the proposal, an exchange could determine to

recognize all, or a portion, of the commodity derivative position in

respect of which an application for recognition has been submitted,

as an non-enumerated bona fide hedge, for different contract months

or different types of limits (e.g., a separate limit level for the

spot month). See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR

at 38474.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission noted that the proposed weekly report would support

its surveillance program by facilitating the tracking of non-enumerated

bona fide hedges recognized by exchanges,\1088\ keeping the Commission

informed of the manner in which an exchange was administering its

procedures for recognizing such positions. For example, the report

would make available to the Commission, on a regular basis, the

summaries of types of recognized non-enumerated bona fide hedges that

an exchange posts to its Web site pursuant to proposed Sec.

150.9(a)(7). This would facilitate any review by the Commission of such

summaries, pursuant to proposed Sec. 150.9(e), and would help to

ensure, if the Commission determines that revisions to a summary are

necessary, that such revisions were carried out in a timely manner by

the exchange.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1088\ The Commission stated that the exchange's assignment of a

unique identifier to each of the non-enumerated bona fide hedge

applications that the exchange received, and, separately, the

exchange's assignment of a unique identifier to each type of

commodity derivative position that the exchange recognized as a non-

enumerated bona fide hedge, would assist the Commission's tracking

process. Accordingly, the Commission suggested that, as a ``best

practice,'' the exchange's procedures for processing non-enumerated

bona fide hedge applications contemplate the assignment of such

unique identifiers. The Commission noted that under proposed Sec.

150.9(c)(1)(i), an exchange that assigned such unique identifiers

would be required to include the identifiers in the exchange's

weekly report to the Commission.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission noted that in certain instances, information

included in the proposed weekly report could prompt the Commission to

request records required to be maintained by an exchange pursuant to

proposed Sec. 150.9(b).\1089\ The 2016 Supplemental Position Limit

Proposal clarified that it was the Commission's expectation that the

summary would focus on the facts and circumstances upon which an

exchange based its determination to recognize a commodity derivative

position as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, or to revoke

or modify such recognition. The Commission also noted that it might

decide, in light of the information provided in the summary, or any

other information included in the proposed weekly report regarding the

position, that it should request the exchange's complete record of the

application for recognition of the position as an non-enumerated bona

fide hedge--in order to determine, for example, whether the application

presents novel or complex issues that merit additional analysis

pursuant to proposed Sec. 150.9(d)(2), or to evaluate whether the

disposition of the application by the exchange was consistent with

section 4a(c) of the Act and the general definition of bona fide

hedging position in Sec. 150.1.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1089\ For example, as proposed, for each derivative position

recognized by the exchange as a non-enumerated bona fide hedge, or

any revocation or modification of such recognition, the report would

include a concise summary of the applicant's activity in the cash

markets for the commodity underlying the position.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition, proposed 150.9(c)(2) required an exchange to submit to

the Commission any report made to the exchange by an applicant,

pursuant to proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(6), that notified the exchange that

the applicant owned or controlled a commodity derivative position that

the exchange had recognized as an non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position, at least monthly,\1090\ unless otherwise instructed by the

Commission.\1091\ The exchange's submission of these reports would

notify the Commission that an applicant had taken a commodity

derivative position recognized by the exchange as a non-enumerated bona

fide hedging position, and would also show the applicant's offsetting

positions in the cash markets. Requiring an exchange to submit these

reports to the Commission would therefore support

[[Page 96826]]

the Commission's surveillance program, by facilitating the tracking of

non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions recognized by the exchange,

and helping the Commission to ensure that an applicant's activities

conform to the terms of recognition that the exchange had established.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1090\ As proposed, the timeframe within which an applicant

would be required to report to the exchange would be established by

the exchange in its rules, as appropriate and in accordance with

proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(6). The Commission also pointed out that an

exchange could decide to require such reports from its participants

more frequently than monthly.

\1091\ As proposed, under Sec. 150.9(f)(1)(ii), the Commission

would delegate to the Director of the Commission's Division of

Market Oversight, or such other employee or employees as the

Director designated from time to time, the authority to provide

instructions regarding the submission to the Commission of

information required to be reported by an exchange pursuant to

proposed Sec. 150.9(c). See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, 81 FR at 38475.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Proposed Sec. 150.9(c)(3)(i) and (ii) would require an exchange,

unless instructed otherwise by the Commission, to submit weekly reports

under proposed Sec. 150.9(c)(1), and applicant reports under proposed

Sec. 150.9(c)(2). Proposed Sec. 150.9(c)(3)(i) and (ii) contemplated

that, in order to facilitate the processing of such reports, and the

analysis of the information contained therein, the Commission would

establish reporting and transmission standards, and that it may require

reports to be submitted to the Commission using an electronic data

format, coding structure and electronic data transmission procedures

approved in writing by the Commission, as specified on the Forms and

Submissions page at www.cftc.gov.\1092\ Proposed Sec. 150.9(c)(3)(iii)

would require such reports to be submitted to the Commission no later

than 9:00 a.m. Eastern time on the third business day following the

report date, unless the exchange was otherwise instructed by the

Commission.\1093\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1092\ The delegation proposed in Sec. 150.9(f)(1)(ii) would

also, in connection with proposed Sec. 150.9(c)(3), delegate to the

Director of the Commission's Division of Market Oversight, or such

other employee or employees as the Director designated from time to

time, the authority: (i) To provide instructions for the proposed

submissions; and (ii) to specify on the Forms and Submissions page

at www.cftc.gov the manner for submitting to the Commission

information required to be reported by an exchange pursuant to

proposed Sec. 150.9(c), and to determine the format, coding

structure and electronic data transmission procedures for submitting

such information. See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81

FR at 38475.

\1093\ For purposes of proposed Sec. 150.9(c)(2), the timeframe

set forth in proposed Sec. 150.9(c)(3)(iii) would be calculated

from the date of a exchange's submission to the Commission, and not

from the date of an applicant's report to the exchange.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: Several commenters expressed views against the

Sec. 150.9(c) reporting requirements, or requested that the Commission

reduce or alter the reporting requirements for exchanges.\1094\ One

commenter requested that the Commission clarify that proposed weekly

reporting requirements for exchanges only require reporting of the

``most essential information'' regarding exchange-administered hedge

exemptions.\1095\ As an alternative to the entire proposed exchange-

administered exemption reporting requirements, one commenter proposed

that exchanges provide a weekly report to the Commission summarizing

newly approved hedge exemptions.\1096\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1094\ CL-AMG-60946 at 3; CL-CME-60926 at 11; CL-ICE-60929 at 8-

9 and 16; and CL-CMC-60950 at 13-14.

\1095\ CL-CME-60926 at 11.

\1096\ CL-ICE-60929 at 8-9 and 16.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: The Commission is reproposing the rule,

largely as originally proposed, except that the Commission has revised

Sec. Sec. 150.9(c)(1)(i) and 150.9(c)(2) for purposes of

clarification. In regards to Sec. 150.9(c)(1)(i), the Commission is

clarifying that the reports required under (c)(1)(i) are those for each

commodity derivatives position that had been recognized that week and

for any revocation or modification of a previously granted recognition.

As to Sec. 150.9(c)(2), in response to commenters, the Commission

clarifies that exchanges are authorized under Sec. 150.9(c)(2), but

are not required, to determine whether to incorporate additional

reporting requirements in connection with its recognition of non-

enumerated bona fide hedging positions. If an exchange does determine

to require additional reporting, Sec. 150.9(c)(2) requires that the

exchange submit reports no less frequently than monthly.\1097\ In

addition, the Commission believes the weekly reporting requires only

the most essential information regarding exchange-administered

exemptions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1097\ As reproposed, Sec. 150.9(c)(2) also provides that

instead of submitting any such reports monthly, the Commission could

otherwise instruct the exchange otherwise.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

6. Proposed Sec. 150.9(d)--Review of Applications by the Commission

Proposed Rule: Proposed Sec. 150.9(d) provided for Commission

review of applications to ensure that the processes administered by the

exchange, as well as the results of such processes, were consistent

with the requirements of section 4a(c) of the Act and the Commission's

regulations thereunder.\1098\ The Commission proposed to review records

required to be maintained by an exchange pursuant to proposed Sec.

150.9(b); however, under the proposal the Commission could request

additional information under proposed Sec. 150.9(d)(1)(ii) if, for

example, the Commission found additional information was needed for its

own review.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1098\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38475-76. As the proposal noted, the Commission agreed with the

comment of one participant at the June 19, 2014 Roundtable on

Position Limits, who said that if the Commission were to permit

exchanges to administer a process for non-enumerated bona fide

hedging positions, the Commission should continue to do ``a certain

amount of de novo analysis and review.'' Id.

The Commission noted that, under the proposal, the SRO's

recognition was tentative, because the Commission would reserve the

power to review the recognition, subject to the reasonably fixed

statutory standards in CEA section 4a(c)(2) (directing the CFTC to

define the term bona fide hedging position) that are incorporated

into the Commission's proposed general definition of bona fide

hedging position in Sec. 150.1. The SRO's recognition would also be

constrained by the SRO's rules, which would be subject to CFTC

review under the proposal. The Commission pointed out that SROs are

parties subject to Commission authority, their rules are subject to

Commission review and their actions are subject to Commission de

novo review under the proposal--SRO rules and actions may be changed

by the Commission at any time. In addition, the Commission noted

that under the proposal, the exchange was required to make its

determination consistent with both CEA section 4a(c) and the

Commission's general definition of bona fide hedging position in

Sec. 150.1. Further, the Commission noted that CEA section 4a(c)(1)

requires a position to be shown to be bona fide as defined by the

Commission.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Under the proposal, the Commission could decide to review a pending

application prior to disposition by an exchange, but anticipated that

it would most likely wait to review applications until after some

action has already been taken by an exchange. As proposed, Sec.

150.9(d)(2) and (3) would require the Commission to notify the exchange

and applicable applicant that they had 10 business days from the date

of the request to provide any supplemental information. The Commission

noted that this approach provided the exchanges and the particular

market participant with an opportunity to respond to any issues raised

by the Commission.

During the period of any Commission review of an application, an

applicant could continue to rely upon any recognition previously

granted by the exchange. If the Commission determined that remediation

was necessary, the Commission would provide for a commercially

reasonable amount of time for the market participant to comply with

limits after announcement of the Commission's decision under proposed

Sec. 150.9(d)(4).\1099\ In determining a time, the Commission could

consider factors such as current market conditions and the protection

of price discovery in the market. Proposed Sec. 150.10(d) and Sec.

150.11(d) contain substantially similar requirements regarding review

of applications by the Commission of

[[Page 96827]]

spread exemptions and anticipatory hedge exemptions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1099\ The Commission noted a commercially reasonable time

period as necessary to exit the market in an orderly manner,

generally, ``would be less than one business day.'' 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38476, n. 168

(citing the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75713).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received: Several commenters were concerned about the

Commission review process and/or provided suggestions on how the

Commission should modify or limit its authority to review exchange-

granted exemptions.\1100\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1100\ CL-CMC-60950 at 14; CL-NFP-60942 at 6-8; CL-DFA-60927 at

1-2; CL-ICE-60929 at 5-8; CL-ISDA-60931 at 6-7; CL-AGA-60943 at 7;

CL-FIA-60937 at 2, 6, 7; CL-COPE-60932 at 7; CL-COPE-60932 at 7-8;

CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 10-11; CL-RER2-60962 at 1; CL-Public Citizen-

60940 at 2; and CL-MGEX-60936 at 7. See also CL-FIA-60937 at 7, 8;

CL-COPE-60932 at 7; CL-NGFA-60941 at 3; CL-ICE-60929 at 18; CL-API-

60939 at 4; CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 10-11; CL-IECAssn-60949 at 9-10

(recommending for an appeals process and/or notice and public

comment feature for the Commission review process); CL-FIA-60937 at

7, 8 (recommending that market participants have continued reliance

on any overturned exemption for one year after the overturn or

modification); CL-NGFA-60941 at 3 (suggesting that a vote by the

full Commission should be required on the ``weighty decision'' to

invalidate a hedge exemption after thorough analysis and careful

consideration); and CL-MGEX-60936 at 7 (expressing concerns that

there is legal uncertainty and lack of clarity in how the non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position process will work).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter requested that the Commission define in more detail,

in the final rule, how this review process will work.\1101\ Another

commenter recommended that exemptions granted by an exchange be given

deference by the Commission upon subsequent review, with reversal

occurring only when there is evidence of negligence or abuse, or when

it may lead to market disruption.\1102\ Four commenters suggested that

the Commission limit the time available for it to review a non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position exemption granted by an exchange

in an effort to provide regulatory certainty to entities relying on

that exemption.\1103\ Fourteen commenters expressed the view that a

``commercially reasonable'' amount of time for an entity to unwind its

position should not be limited to one business day or less. Instead,

these commenters advocated that the Commission or the exchange should

determine how long an entity has to unwind a position given the facts

and circumstances of each situation.\1104\ Three commenters expressed

the view that when the Commission reviews and affirms a non-enumerated

bona fide hedging position determination, such a determination should

result in a new enumerated bona fide hedging position.\1105\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1101\ CL-AFIA-60955 at 2.

\1102\ CL-MGEX-60936 at 7-8.

\1103\ CL-FIA-60937 at 3; CL-ICE-60929 at 18; CL-API-60939 at 4;

and CL-API-60939 at 1. See also CL-API-60939 at 1 (requesting that,

if the Commission conducts a review of an exchange granted non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position exemption, then the Commission

should limit the time period to 180 days to issue a decision to

overturn an exemption); CL-AGA-60943 at 8 (suggesting that the

Commission ``should adopt a rule that follows its current approach

under CFTC Rule 1.47); CL-IECAssn-60949 at 11-12 (recommending a

reasonable time period to unwind positions for which an exemption

has been overturned would help to allow the market to operate

smoothly); and CL-FIA-60937 at 7 (noting that the Commission should

``require an exchange to post a general description of a non-

enumerated hedge, spread, or anticipatory hedge exemption on its Web

site within 30 days of granting the exemption,'' and thereafter,

``the Commission should have 180 days to decide whether to review

and overturn or modify an exemption posted on an exchange's Web

site.'').

\1104\ See, e.g., CL-API-60939 at 4; CL-FIA-60937 at 3, 8; CL-

MGEX-60936 at 7-8; CL-ISDA-60931 at 7; CL-NGFA-60941 at 3; CL-NFP-

60942 at 8; CL-AGA-60943 at 2; CL-AGA-60943 at 7; CL-AMG-60946 at 5;

CL-ICE-60929 at 18; CL-CMC-60950 at 11; CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 13;

CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 10; and CL-ISDA-60931 at 7. See also CL-FIA-

60937 at 3, 8 (recommending the Commission consider ``(1) the size

of, and risks associated with, the participant's cash and related

derivative positions; (2) the risks created by the need to reduce

what will become an un-hedged cash market exposure; and (3) the

availability of sufficient liquidity to enable the market

participant to reduce the hedging and the underlying positions

without incurring losses solely as a result of being forced to

liquidate the hedge within a constrained timeframe.'').

\1105\ CL-COPE-60932 at 7; CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 11; and CL-COPE-

60932 at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some commenters opined that the Commission should instead

explicitly require Commission review and approval of all hedge

exemption requests received by an exchange.\1106\ These commenters

believe that the Commission should always make the final decision

regarding whether to grant a particular hedge exemption.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1106\ CL-Public Citizen-60940 at 2; and CL-RER2-60962 at 1.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal: After carefully considering the comments

received, the Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.9(d), as originally

proposed. The Commission believes the proposed de novo review of

exchange-granted non-enumerated bona fide hedging position exemptions

is adequate to maintain proper exchange oversight and to verify that

such exemptions provide fair and open access by all market

participants. Further, the Commission notes that it must maintain de

novo review on a case-by-case basis; otherwise, as discussed above, the

exchange exemption process may be considered an illegal delegation of

Commission authority to exchanges.\1107\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1107\ See also 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81

FR at38464-66 (discussing the Commission's authority to permit

certain exchanges to recognize positions as bona fide hedging

positions for purposes of federal limits, as well as the careful

provisions proposed in Sec. 150.9 to do so within the limitations

on its authority).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Regarding the recommendation that the Commission limit its

available time to review exchange granted exemptions, this limitation

may appear inconsistent with case law regarding authorizations for

self-regulatory organizations to make determinations, subject to de

novo agency review.\1108\ Regarding whether the Commission would expose

exchanges to undue regulatory penalties or uncertainty for exemptions

the Commission overturns, the Commission declines to speculate on any

actions that it may take, beyond the notice to the applicant. Regarding

giving entities a ``commercially reasonable'' time for an entity to

unwind their positions, the Commission has not proposed a fixed time

period, but would consider the facts and circumstances of each

situation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1108\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38465, n. 83. The recommendation might also unduly constrain agency

resources.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to comments that the Commission should create a new

enumerated hedge for any non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

determination the Commission reviews and affirms, the Commission

clarifies that under the de novo review standard, no deference is

provided to a prior determination; rather, the Commission will review

as if no decision has been previously made. This is the same as a

``hearing de novo.'' \1109\ The Commission also notes that, as

previously discussed, an exchange can petition under Sec. 13.2 for

Commission recognition of a generic position as an enumerated bona fide

hedging position, and that market participants have the flexibility of

two processes for recognition of a position as an enumerated bona fide

hedging position: (i) Request an exemptive, no-action or interpretative

letter under Sec. 140.99; and/or (ii) petition under Sec. 13.2 for

changes to Appendix B to part 150.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1109\ See Black's Law Dictionary 837 (10th ed. 2014) (defining

``hearing de novo'' as ``[a] reviewing court's decision of a matter

anew, giving no deference to a lower court's findings. A new hearing

of a matter, conducted as if the original hearing had not taken

place.'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The reproposed rule is confined to federal limits and does not

interfere with existing exemption processes that exchanges currently

implement and oversee with regard to exchange-set limits. Exchanges

remain bound by the bona fide hedging position definition in this part

for any recognition for purposes of federal limits. But, as noted

above, in regards to reproposed Sec. 150.9(a), exchange processes for

exchange-set limits that are lower than the federal limit could differ

as long as

[[Page 96828]]

the exemption provided by the exchange is capped at the level of the

applicable federal limit in Sec. 150.2.

Regarding requests to revise the Commission's review process (i.e.,

include an appeals process, provide notice and public comment

opportunity, require a vote by the Commission to overturn an exchange-

granted exemption, provide more detail on the review process), the

Commission notes that it has not proposed to delegate authority to

staff to overturn an exchange determination.

7. Proposed Sec. 150.9(e)--Review of summaries by the Commission

Proposed Rule: In connection with proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(7), for

the Commission to rely on the expertise of the exchanges to summarize

and post executive summaries of non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions to their respective Web sites, the Commission proposed, in

Sec. 150.9(e), to review such executive summaries to ensure the

summaries provided adequate disclosure to market participants of the

potential availability of relief from speculative position limits. The

Commission stated that it believed an adequate disclosure would include

generic facts and circumstances sufficient to alert similarly situated

market participants to the possibility of receiving recognition of a

non-enumerated bona fide hedging position. Such market participants

could then use that information to help evaluate whether to apply for

recognition of a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position. Thus, the

Commission noted, adequate disclosure should help ensure fair and open

access to the application process. Due to resource constraints, the

Commission pointed out that it might not be able to preclear each

summary, so it proposed to spot check executive summaries after the

fact.

Commission Reproposal

The Commission did not receive comments on Sec. 150.9(e) (nor on

Sec. 150.10(e)), and is reproposing Sec. 150.9(e), as originally

proposed, for the reasons explained in the 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal.\1110\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1110\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38476.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

8. Proposed Sec. 150.9(f)--Delegation of Authority

Proposed Rule

The Commission proposed to delegate certain of its authorities

under proposed Sec. 150.9 (and Sec. 150.10 and Sec. 150.11), to the

Director of the Commission's Division of Market Oversight, or such

other employee or employees as the Director designated from time to

time. In Sec. 150.9(f), the Commission proposed to delegate, until it

ordered otherwise, to the Director of the Division of Market Oversight

or such other employee or employees as the Director designated from

time to time, the authorities under certain parts of Sec. Sec.

150.9(a); 150.9(c); 150.9(d); and 150.9(e). As noted, similar

delegations were contained in proposed Sec. 150.10(f) and Sec.

150.11(e) for spread exemptions and enumerated anticipatory hedge

exemptions, respectively.

Proposed Sec. 150.9(f)(1)(i), Sec. 150.10(f)(1)(i) and Sec.

150.11(e)(1)(i) delegated the Commission's authority to the Division of

Market Oversight to provide instructions regarding the submission of

information required to be reported to the Commission by an exchange,

and to specify the manner and determine the format, coding structure,

and electronic data transmission procedures for submitting such

information. Proposed Sec. 150.9(f)(1)(v) and Sec. 150.10(f)(1)(v)

delegated the Commission's review authority under proposed Sec.

150.9(e) and Sec. 150.10(e), respectively, to DMO with respect to

summaries of types of recognized non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions, and types of spread exemptions, that were required to be

posted on an exchange's Web site pursuant to proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(7)

and Sec. 150.10(a)(7), respectively.

Proposed Sec. 150.9(f)(1)(i), Sec. 150.10(f)(1)(i) and Sec.

150.11(e)(1)(i) delegated the Commission's authority to the Division of

Market Oversight to agree to or reject a request by an exchange to

consider an application for recognition of an non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position or enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging position,

or an application for a spread exemption. Proposed Sec.

150.9(f)(1)(iii), Sec. 150.10(f)(1)(iii) and Sec. 150.11(e)(1)(iii)

delegated the Commission's authority to review any application for

recognition of a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position or

enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging position, or application for

a spread exemption, and all records required to be maintained by an

exchange in connection with such application. Proposed Sec.

150.9(f)(1)(iii), Sec. 150.10(f)(1)(iii) and Sec. 150.11(e)(1)(iii)

also delegated the Commission's authority to request such records, and

to request additional information in connection with such application

from the exchange or from the applicant.

Proposed Sec. 150.9(f)(1)(iv) and Sec. 150.10(f)(1)(iv) delegated

the Commission's authority, under proposed Sec. 150.9(d)(2) and Sec.

150.10(d)(2), respectively, to determine that an application for

recognition of an non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, or an

application for a spread exemption, required additional analysis or

review, and to provide notice to the exchange and the particular

applicant that they had 10 days to supplement such application.

The Commission did not propose to delegate its authority under

proposed Sec. 150.9(d)(3) or Sec. 150.10(d)(3) to make a final

determination as to the exchange's disposition. The Commission stated

that if an exchange's disposition raised concerns regarding consistency

with the Act or presents novel or complex issues, then the Commission

should make the final determination, after taking into consideration

any supplemental information provided by the exchange or the

applicant.\1111\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1111\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38482.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received

One commenter recommended that the Commission clarify the

delegation provisions referenced in RFC 31 by expressly stating that

``the Commission, not DMO, now and always will retain the ultimate

authority to grant or deny Exemption applications.'' \1112\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1112\ CL-Working Group-60947 at 22.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing the delegation provisions, as

originally proposed. With regard to the comment received, the

Commission notes that, as provided in both proposed and reproposed

Sec. 150.9(f)(3), it retains the authority to make the final

determination to grant or deny hedge exemption applications submitted

pursuant to this rulemaking. However, the Commission also points out

that any decisions of an existing Commission under this rulemaking

cannot effectively bind a future commission, since such future

Commission could amend or revoke such a rule.

H. Sec. 150.10--Process for Designated Contract Market or Swap

Execution Facility Exemption From Position Limits for Certain Spread

Positions

1. Background 150.10

In the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed to permit exchanges, by rule, to exempt from federal position

limits certain spread transactions, as authorized by CEA section

4a(a)(1),\1113\

[[Page 96829]]

and in light of the provisions of CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B) and CEA

section 4a(c)(2)(B).\1114\ In particular, CEA section 4a(a)(1) provides

the Commission with authority to exempt from position limits

transactions normally known to the trade as ``spreads'' or

``straddles'' or ``arbitrage'' or to fix limits for such transactions

or positions different from limits fixed for other transactions or

positions. The Commission noted that the Dodd-Frank Act amended the CEA

by adding section 4a(a)(3)(B), which now directs the Commission, in

establishing position limits, to ensure, to the maximum extent

practicable and in its discretion, ``sufficient market liquidity for

bona fide hedgers.'' \1115\ The Commission also noted that the Dodd-

Frank Act amendments to the CEA in section 4a(c)(2)(B) limited the

definition of a bona fide hedging position regarding positions (in

addition to those included under CEA section 4a(c)(2)(A)) \1116\

resulting from a swap that was executed opposite a counterparty for

which the transaction would qualify as a bona fide hedging transaction,

in the event the party to the swap is not itself using the swap as a

bona fide hedging transaction. In this regard, the Commission

interpreted this statutory definition to preclude spread exemptions for

a swap position that was executed opposite a counterparty for which the

transaction would not qualify as a bona fide hedging transaction.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1113\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(1) (authorizing the Commission to exempt

transactions normally known to the trade as ``spreads''). DCMs

currently process applications for exemptions from exchange-set

position limits for certain spread positions pursuant to CFMA-era

regulatory parameters. See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, 81 FR at 38467, n. 101.

The Commission pointed out that, in current Sec. 150.3(a)(3),

the Commission exempts spread positions ``between single months of a

futures contract and/or, on a futures-equivalent basis, options

thereon, outside of the spread month, in the same crop year,''

subject to certain limitations. 17 CFR 150.3(a)(3).

\1114\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(3)(B) and 7 U.S.C. 6a(c)(2)(B),

respectively.

\1115\ CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B) also directs the Commission, in

establishing position limits, to diminish, eliminate, or prevent

excessive speculation; to deter and prevent market manipulation,

squeezes, and corners; and to ensure that the price discovery

function of the underlying market is not disrupted.

\1116\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(c)(2)(A). As explained in the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38464, n. 66, CEA

section 4a(c)(2) generally requires the Commission to define a bona

fide hedging position as a position that in CEA section 4a(c)(2)(A):

Meets three tests (a position (1) is a substitute for activity in

the physical marketing channel, (2) is economically appropriate to

the reduction of risk, and (3) arises from the potential change in

value of current or anticipated assets, liabilities or services);

or, in CEA section 4a(c)(2)(B), reduces the risk of a swap that was

executed opposite a counterparty for which such swap would meet the

three tests.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As noted in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, prior

to the passage of the Dodd-Frank Act, the Commission exercised its

exemptive authority pertaining to spread transactions in promulgating

current Sec. 150.3. Current Sec. 150.3 provides that the position

limits set in Sec. 150.2 may be exceeded to the extent such positions

are spread or arbitrage positions between single months of a futures

contract and/or, on a futures-equivalent basis, options thereon,

outside of the spot month, in the same crop year; provided, however,

that such spread or arbitrage positions, when combined with any other

net positions in the single month, do not exceed the all-months limit

set forth in Sec. 150.2. In addition, the Commission has permitted

DCMs, in setting their own position limits under the terms of current

Sec. 150.5(a), to exempt spread, straddle or arbitrage positions or to

fix limits that apply to such positions that are different from limits

fixed for other positions.\1117\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1117\ Current Sec. 150.5 applies as non-exclusive guidance and

acceptable practices for compliance with DCM core principle 5. See

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75750-2; see also

2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38477, n. 173.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Under the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the exemption in

current Sec. 150.3(a)(3) for spread or arbitrage positions between

single months of a futures contract or options thereon, outside the

spot month would be deleted. As the Commission noted, the proposal

would instead maintain the current practice in Sec. 150.2 of setting

single-month limits at the same levels as all-months limits, which

would render the ``spread'' exemption unnecessary.\1118\ In particular,

the spread exemption set forth in current Sec. 150.3(a)(3) permits a

spread trader to exceed single month limits only to the extent of the

all months limit. Because the Commission, in current Sec. 150.2 and as

proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, sets single

month limits at the same level as all months limits, the existing

spread exemption would no longer provide useful relief.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1118\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75736; see also 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38477.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also noted that the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal would codify guidance in proposed Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(ii) to

allow an exchange to grant exemptions from exchange-set position limits

for intramarket and intermarket spread positions (as those terms were

defined in proposed Sec. 150.1) involving commodity derivative

contracts subject to the federal limits. To be eligible for the

exemption in proposed Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(ii), intermarket and

intramarket spread positions, under the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, would have to be outside of the spot month for physical

delivery contracts, and intramarket spread positions could not exceed

the federal all-months limit when combined with any other net positions

in the single month. As proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(iii) would require traders to apply to the

exchange for any exemption, including spread exemptions, from its

speculative position limit rules.

Several commenters responding to the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal requested that the Commission provide a spread exemption to

federal position limits.\1119\ Most of these commenters urged the

Commission to recognize spread exemptions in the spot month as well as

non-spot months.\1120\ Several of these commenters noted that the

Commission's proposal would permit exchanges to grant spread exemptions

for exchange-set limits in commodity derivative contracts subject to

federal limits, and recommended that the Commission establish a process

for granting such spread exemptions for purposes of Federal

limits.\1121\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1119\ See, e.g., CL-CMC-59634 at 15; CL-Olam-59658 at 7; CL-

CME-59718 at 69-71; CL-Citadel-59717 at 8, 9; CL-Armajaro-59729 at

2; and CL-ICEUS-59645 at 8-10.

\1120\ See CL-CMC-59634 at 15; CL-Olam-59658 at 7; CL-CME-59718

at 71; CL-Armajaro-59729 at 2; and CL-ICEUS-59645 at 8-10.

\1121\ See CL-Olam-59658 at 7; CL-CME-59718 at 71; CL-ICEUS-

59645 at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to these comments, the Commission proposed in its 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal \1122\ to permit exchanges to

process and grant applications for spread exemptions from federal

position limits. At that time, the Commission noted that most, if not

all, DCMs already have rules in place to process and grant applications

for spread exemptions from exchange-set position limits pursuant to

part 38 of the Commission's regulations (in particular, current

Sec. Sec. 38.300 and 38.301) and current Sec. 150.5. And, as noted

above, the Commission pointed out that it has a long history of

overseeing the performance of the DCMs in granting spread exemptions

under current exchange rules regarding exchange-set position limits and

believed that it would be efficient, and in the best interest of the

markets, in light of current resource constraints, to rely on the

exchanges to process applications for spread exemptions from federal

position limits. In addition, the

[[Page 96830]]

Commission stated that, because many market participants may be

familiar with current DCM practices regarding spread exemptions,

permitting DCMs to build on current practice may lower the burden on

market participants and reduce duplicative filings at the exchanges and

the Commission. The 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal noted

that this plan would permit exchanges to provide market participants

with spread exemptions, pursuant to exchange rules submitted to the

Commission; however, the Commission also pointed out that it would

retain the authority to review--and, if necessary, reverse--the

exchanges' actions.\1123\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1122\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38476-80.

\1123\ 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38477.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Proposed Sec. 150.10 and the public comments relevant to each

proposed subsection are discussed below.

2. Discussion

As discussed in greater detail below, the Commission is reproposing

Sec. 150.10, largely as originally proposed. Some changes were made in

response to concerns raised by commenters; other changes conform to

changes made in Sec. 150.9 or Sec. 150.11. Finally, several non-

substantive changes were made in response to commenter questions to

provide greater clarity.

a. Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(1)

Proposed Rule

The Commission contemplated in proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(1) that

exchanges could voluntarily elect to process spread exemption

applications, by filing new rules or rule amendments with the

Commission pursuant to part 40 of the Commission's regulations.\1124\

The process proposed under Sec. 150.10(a) was substantially similar to

that described above for proposed Sec. 150.9(a). For example, proposed

Sec. 150.10(a)(1) provided that, with respect to a commodity

derivative position for which an exchange elected to process spread

exemption applications, (i) the exchange must list for trading at least

one component of the spread or must list for trading at least one

contract that is a referenced contract included in at least one

component of the spread; and (ii) any such exchange contract must be

actively traded and subject to position limits for at least one year on

that exchange. As noted with respect to the process outlined above for

proposed Sec. 150.9(a), the Commission expressed its belief that that

an exchange should process spread exemptions only if it had at least

one year of experience overseeing exchange-set position limits in an

actively traded referenced contract that was in the same commodity as

that of at least one component of the spread. The Commission stated

that an exchange may not be familiar enough with the specific needs and

differing practices of the participants in those markets for which an

individual exchange did not list any actively traded referenced

contract in a particular commodity. If a component of a spread was not

actively traded on an exchange that elected to process spread exemption

applications, such exchange might not be incentivized to protect or

manage the relevant commodity market, and the interests of such

exchange might not be aligned with the policy objectives of the

Commission as expressed in CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B). The Commission

expected that an individual exchange would describe how it would

determine whether a particular component of a spread was actively

traded in its rule submission, based on its familiarity with the

specific needs and differing practices of the participants in the

relevant market.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1124\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38464, n. 63, regarding Commission authority to recognize spreads

under CEA section 4a(a)(1). Any action of the exchange to recognize

a spread, pursuant to rules filed with the Commission, would be

subject to review and revocation by the Commission.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Consistent with the restrictions regarding the offset of risks

arising from a swap position in CEA section 4a(c)(2)(B), proposed Sec.

150.10(a)(1) would not permit an exchange to recognize a spread between

a commodity index contract and one or more referenced contracts. That

is, an exchange could not grant a spread exemption where a bona fide

hedging position could not be recognized for a pass through swap offset

of a commodity index contract.\1125\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1125\ The Commission's interprets CEA section 4a(c)(2)(b) is a

mandate from Congress to narrow the scope of what constitutes a bona

fide hedging position in the context of index trading activities.

``Financial products are not substitutes for positions taken or to

be taken in a physical marketing channel. Thus, the offset of

financial risks from financial products is inconsistent with the

proposed definition of bona fide hedging for physical commodities.''

See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38471; see

also December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75740. See

also the discussion of the temporary substitute test. Id. at 75708-

9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission noted that for inter-commodity spreads in which

different components of the spread were traded on different exchanges,

the exemption granted by one exchange would be recognized by the

Commission as an exemption from federal limits for the applicable

referenced contract(s), but would not bind the exchange(s) that listed

the other components of the spread to recognize the exemption for

purposes of that other exchange(s)' position limits. In such cases, a

trader seeking such inter-commodity spread exemptions would need to

apply separately for a spread exemption from each exchange-set position

limit.

Comments Received

Two commenters recommended that the Commission should, to the

greatest extent possible, allow the exchanges to administer exemptions

for non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions, enumerated bona fide

hedges, and spread positions in the same manner as they have been to

date and allow exchanges to continue to independently evaluate

exemption applications by relying on the exchange's extensive knowledge

of the markets.\1126\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1126\ CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 9 and CL-IECAssn-60949 at 3-4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Five commenters recommended that the Commission not adopt the

``active trading'' and ``one year experience'' requirements as proposed

in the supplement regarding a DCM's qualification to administer

exemptions from federal position limits.\1127\ For a more detailed

discussion please see Sec. 150.9(a)(1) above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1127\ See, e.g., CL-CCI-60935 at 3-4; CL-FIA-60937 at 3; CL-

Working Group-60947 at 10; CL-IECAssn-60949 at 12-13; and CL-CME-

60926 at 13 (expressing that such qualification requirements could

have the unintended consequences of (1) harming the ability of

market participants to effectively manage their risk by preventing

the Exchanges from recognizing an otherwise appropriate exemption

from federal speculative position limits, and (2) stifling future

innovation in the development of new commodity derivative products

created to meet evolving market needs and demands). See also CL-FIA-

60937 at 9 (citing the following example: ``For example, CME's New

York Mercantile Exchange (``NYMEX'') recently listed the LOOP crude

oil storage futures contract (LPS) and IFUS recently listed the

world cotton futures contract (WCT). Assuming for purposes of

illustration that both of these futures contracts were Referenced

Contracts, under the Supplemental Proposal neither NYMEX nor IFUS

would be permitted to grant non-enumerated hedge, spread, or

anticipatory hedge exemptions during the first year of each

contract's existence notwithstanding the extensive experience of

these exchanges in administering limits on positions in a variety of

similar contracts.''), CL-CME-60926 at 14 (arguing that one year of

experience in administering position limits in similar contracts

within a particular ``asset class'' would be a more reasonable

requirement.), CL-FIA-60937 at 9 (expressing the view that ``the CEA

precludes the Commission from establishing limits that apply to

``bona fide hedge positions,'' and the ``definition of bona fide

hedging in CEA Section 4a(c)(2) does not include as relevant

criteria whether an exchange contract is actively traded or an

exchange has one year of prior experience administering limits on

positions in that contract.'' Thus, the CEA does not permit the one

year prerequisite.)

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Alternatively, several commenters expressed views against the

[[Page 96831]]

Commission authorizing exchanges to grant hedge and spread exemptions,

and cited concerns with respect to what they believe to be a conflict

of interest that could arise between for-profit exchanges and their

exemption-seeking customers. The commenters proposed, instead, that the

Commission make any final hedge and spread exemption

determinations.\1128\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1128\ See, e.g., CL-Public Citizen-60940 at 3; CL-PMAA-NEFI-

60952 at 2; CL-RER2-60962 at 1; CL-AFR-60953 at 2; CL-RER1-60961 at

1; CL-PMAA-NEFI-60952 at 2; CL-RER2-60962 at 1; CL-AFR-60953 at 2

and CL-Better Markets-60928 at 1-5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.10(a)(1), as originally

proposed with one clarification explained below. In reproposing Sec.

150.10(a)(1), the Commission provides a basic application process for

exchanges that elect to process spread exemption applications to

federal limits. This process allows exchanges flexibility while also

facilitating the Commission's review of exchange granted exemptions.

The Commission notes that exchanges have authority to determine whether

or not to apply the Sec. 150.10(a)(1) process to spread exemptions

from exchange-set limits that are lower than federal limits.

Regarding the comment that the one-year experience and active

trading qualification requirements could harm the ability for market

participants to effectively manage their risks because the

qualification requirements would limit the number of exchanges that

could grant exemptions,\1129\ the Commission clarifies that the one-

year experience and active trading requirement can be met by any

referenced contract in the particular commodity.\1130\ This feature

allows a broader number of exchanges to grant spread exemptions.

Furthermore, the Commission notes that an exchange with no active

trading and or experience in any referenced contract in the particular

commodity may not have their interests aligned with the CEA's policy

objectives for position limits, such as those in CEA section

4a(a)(3)(B).\1131\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1129\ As noted above, according to the commenter, the

qualification requirements would limit the number of exchanges that

could grant exemptions to those that list the relevant referenced

contract and manage position limits in that referenced contract

based on the exchanges experience and knowledge of the underlying

commodity market that referenced contract.

\1130\ As noted above, experience manifests in the people

carrying out surveillance in a commodity rather than in an

institutional structure. An exchange's experience would be provided

through the appropriate experience of the surveillance staff

regarding the particular commodity. In fact, the Commission has

historically reviewed the experience and qualifications of exchange

regulatory divisions when considering whether to designate a new

exchange as a contract market or to recognize a facility as a SEF;

as such exchanges are new, staff experience has clearly been gained

at other exchanges.

\1131\ CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B) provides that the Commission

shall set limits ``to the maximum extent practicable, in its

discretion--to diminish, eliminate, or prevent excessive speculation

as described under this section; to deter and prevent market

manipulation, squeezes, and corners; to ensure sufficient market

liquidity for bona fide hedgers; and to ensure that the price

discovery function of the underlying market is not disrupted.'' In

addition, CEA section 4a(a)(7) authorizes the Commission to exempt

any class of transaction from any requirement it may establish with

respect to position limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Finally, the Commission clarifies that an exchange can petition the

Commission for a waiver of the one-year experience requirement pursuant

to Sec. 140.99 of the Commission's regulations if such exchange

believes that their experience and interests are aligned with the

Commission's interests with respect to recognizing spread positions.

Regarding comments that the Commission should be the sole authority

to make a final hedge or spread exemption determination, or that the

Exchange's one-year of experience administering position limits to its

actively traded contract and the Commission's de novo review are

inadequate, the Commission disagrees. The Commission believes the

exchange's one year of experience administering position limits to its

actively traded contract,\1132\ and the Commission's de novo review of

granted exemptions (afterwards) are adequate to guard against or remedy

any conflicts of interest. Also, the Commission notes that Sec.

150.10(a)(4)(vi) requires exchanges should take into account whether

granting a spread exemption in a physical commodity derivative would,

to the maximum extent practicable, ensure sufficient market liquidity

for bona fide hedgers, and not unduly reduce the effectiveness of

position limits to: Diminish, eliminate, or prevent excessive

speculation; deter and prevent market manipulation, squeezes, and

corners; and ensure that the price discovery function of the underlying

market is not disrupted.\1133\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1132\ To avoid confusion, the Commission reiterates that

experience manifests in the people carrying out surveillance in a

commodity rather than in an institutional structure. An exchange's

experience would be provided through the appropriate experience of

the surveillance staff regarding the particular commodity.

\1133\ As noted in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, the guidance is consistent with the statutory policy

objectives for position limits on physical commodity derivatives in

CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B). See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, 81 FR at 38464. The Commission interprets the CEA as

providing it with the statutory authority to exempt spreads that are

consistent with the other policy objectives for position limits,

such as those in CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B). Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(2)

Proposed Rule

Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(2) specifies a non-exclusive list of the

type of spreads that an exchange might exempt from position limits,

including calendar spreads; quality differential spreads; processing

spreads (such as energy ``crack'' or soybean ``crush'' spreads); and

product or by-product differential spreads. The Commission pointed out

that this list was not exhaustive, but reflected common types of spread

activity that might enhance liquidity in commodity derivative markets,

thereby facilitating the ability of bona-fide hedgers to put on and

offset positions in those markets. For example, trading activity in

many commodity derivative markets is concentrated in the nearby

contract month, but a hedger might need to offset risk in deferred

months where derivative trading activity may be less active. A calendar

spread trader could provide such liquidity without exposing himself or

herself to the price risk inherent in an outright position in a

deferred month. Processing spreads can serve a similar function. For

example, a soybean processor might seek to hedge his or her processing

costs by entering into a ``crush'' spread, i.e., going long soybeans

and short soybean meal and oil. A speculator could facilitate the

hedger's ability to do such a transaction by entering into a ``reverse

crush'' spread (i.e., going short soybeans and long soybean meal and

oil). Quality differential spreads, and product or by-product

differential spreads, may serve similar liquidity-enhancing functions

when spreading a position in an actively traded commodity derivatives

market such as CBOT Wheat against a position in another actively traded

market, such as MGEX Wheat.

The Commission anticipated that a spread exemption request might

include spreads that were ``legged in,'' that is, carried out in two

steps, or alternatively were ``combination trades,'' that is, all

components of the spread were executed simultaneously.

This proposal, the Commission observed, would not limit the

granting of spread exemptions to positions outside the spot month,

unlike the existing spread exemption provisions in current Sec.

150.3(a)(3), or in Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(ii) as proposed in the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal. The proposal responded to specific

requests of commenters to permit spread exemptions in the spot month.

The Commission pointed out

[[Page 96832]]

that the CME, for example, recommended ``the Commission reaffirm in

DCMs the discretion to apply their knowledge of individual commodity

markets and their judgement, as to whether allowing intermarket spread

exemptions in the spot month for physical-delivery contracts is

appropriate.'' \1134\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1134\ CL-CME-59718 at 71. See also 2016 Supplemental Position

Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38478.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission proposed to revise the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal in the manner described above because, as it noted in the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal as well as in the examples above,

permitting spread exemptions in the spot month may further one of the

four policy objectives set forth in section 4a(a)(3)(b) of the Act: To

ensure sufficient market liquidity for bona fide hedgers.\1135\ This

policy objective, the Commission observed, was incorporated into the

proposal in its requirements that: (i) The applicant provide detailed

information demonstrating why the spread position should be exempted

from position limits, including how the exemption would further the

purposes of CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B); \1136\ and (ii) the exchange would

determine whether the spread position (for which a market participant

was seeking an exemption) would further the purposes of CEA section

4a(a)(3)(B).\1137\ Moreover, the Commission pointed out that it was

retaining the ability to review the exchange rules as well as to review

how an exchange enforces those rules.\1138\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1135\ CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B)(iii); 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(3)(B)(iii).

See also the discussion of proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(3)(ii), below.

\1136\ See proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(3)(ii).

\1137\ See proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(4)(vi); see also 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38478.

\1138\ The Commission pointed out that it could, for example,

revoke or confirm exchange-granted exemptions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also discussed that it was concerned, among other

things, about protecting the price discovery process in the core

referenced futures contracts, particularly as those contracts approach

expiration. Accordingly, as an alternative, the Commission considered

whether to prohibit an exchange from granting spread exemptions that

would be applicable during the lesser of the last five days of trading

or the time period for the spot month.\1139\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1139\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38478.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received

Several commenters expressed the view that exchanges must be

allowed to use their experience to determine whether to grant spread

exemptions in the spot month--including within the last five days of

trading. Commenters expressed the view that allowing exchanges to grant

spread exemptions in the spot months/last five days would provide

liquidity to the market and help convergence between cash and futures

markets.\1140\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1140\ CL-ICE-60929 at 24; CL-IECAssn-60949 at 15; and CL-ADM-

60934 at 6-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Eight commenters expressed the view that the Commission should not

impose the five-day rule for spread positions in the expiring spot

month contract.\1141\ The commenters argued that to impose the five-day

rule would adversely affect liquidity in the futures market and impair

convergence between cash and futures markets and thus the price

discovery function of the futures market. The commenters also expressed

the view that the Commission's concerns about trading activity in the

final days of an expiring futures contract can best be addressed by

existing exchange and Commission surveillance programs and the

Commission's ``special call'' authority to request information from

market participants.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1141\ CL-NCGA-ASA-60917 at 1-2; CL-CME-60926 at 3; CL-ICE-60929

at 9; and CL-AFIA-60955 at 2; CL-NGFA-60941 at 5-7; CL-ISDA-60931 at

10; CL-NCFC-60930 at 3-4; and CL-Working Group-60947 at 7-9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter expressed the view that the Commission should not

apply the five-day rule to certain enumerated bona fide hedging

positions under proposed Sec. 150.1(3)-(4), cross-commodity hedges

under proposed Sec. 150.1(5), or to non-enumerated bona fide hedge, or

spread exemptions. Instead, the Commission should permit the Exchanges

to determine the facts and circumstances where a market participant may

be permitted to hold a physical-delivery referenced contract in the

spot month as part of a position that is exempt from federal

speculative position limits.\1142\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1142\ CL-CCI-60935 at 8-9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter expressed that it ``would support the

applicability of the spread exemption through the end of the month,

without limiting the exemption during the current month.'' In that

regard, the commenter (an exchange) noted that its ``futures contracts

on electricity settle to the independent, spot market overseen by the

ISO/RTO markets.'' The commenter argued that ``since the settlement

prices are determined in the ISO/RTO markets, trading during the last

five days of the spot month has no impact on final settlement prices''

on either the exchange or the ISO/RTO spot markets. The commenter noted

that ``bona fide hedgers rely on the ability to hold positions through

the end of the current month, which has very low volume traded for

monthly power contracts. Restrictions on spread exemptions during the

last five days of trading may force market participants to exit their

position during a period of lower liquidity--more than 99% of trading

volume occurs outside the current (spot) month'' on its exchange.\1143\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1143\ CL-Nodal-60948 at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter expressed that it is concerned that the new Form 504

would impose a series of reporting requirements to track and

distinguish between types of hedge exemptions and requires reporting of

all cash market holdings for each day of the spot month that would be

difficult given the portfolio nature of commenter's business and the

fungibility of futures contracts and the underlying cash commodity. The

commenter expressed the view that once a hedge exemption is granted

under the supplemental, the reporting requirements should be similar to

the reporting requirements for existing enumerated bona fide hedging

position exemptions.\1144\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1144\ CL-ADM-60934 at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter expressed the view that it is not necessary to

condition spread exemptions on additional filings to the exchange or

the Commission.\1145\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1145\ CL-ICE-60929 at 25.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Two commenters requested that the Commission clarify that the term

``spread position'' includes all types of spreads and the list of

spreads referenced in proposed Sec. 150.10 is simply illustrative and

not exhaustive.\1146\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1146\ CL-Working Group-60947 at 9-10 and CL-FIA-60937 at 14.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Three commenters requested that the Commission continue to permit

cash and carry exemptions, stating, among other reasons, such

exemptions serve an economic purpose by helping to maintain an

appropriate economic relationship between the nearby and the next

successive delivery month.\1147\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1147\ CL-ICE-60929 at 11-12; CL-NCC-ACSA-60972 at 2; and CL-

CMC-60950 at 11-12.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.10(a)(2), as originally

proposed, and clarifying that the five-day rule does not apply to

spreads. Because the Commission did not propose in the 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal to apply the five-day rule to

``spread positions'', exchanges would have discretion to recognize such

spread positions without regard to the five-day rule. The Commission

cautions exchanges to carefully consider whether

[[Page 96833]]

to recognize a spread position in the last few days of trading in

physical-delivery contracts. For a more detailed discussion please see

Sec. 150.9(a)(1) above.

The Commission reiterates, as proposed and discussed in the 2016

Supplemental Position Limit Proposal, that an exchange would not be

permitted to recognize a spread between a commodity index contract and

one or more referenced contracts. That is, an exchange may not grant a

spread exemption where a bona fide hedging position could not be

recognized for a pass-through swap offset of a commodity index

contract. For a more detailed discussion please see Sec. 150.9(a)(1)

above.

In response to the comment regarding spread exemptions for

electricity contracts, the Commission notes that electricity contracts

are not referenced contracts that will be subject to federal limits at

this time. Thus, exchanges may elect to process spread exemptions for

exchange-set position limits for non-referenced contracts.

In response to the comments regarding the proposed spread exemption

process imposing additional filing requirements on market participants

relying on an exchange-granted spread exemption, the Commission

clarifies that it is in the exchange's discretion to determine whether

there are additional reporting requirements for a spread exemption. For

a more detailed discussion please see Sec. 150.9(a)(1) above.

In response to the comments received requesting clarification that

the list of spreads in Sec. 150.10(a)(2) \1148\ is simply illustrative

and not an exhaustive list of possible spread exemptions that may be

granted by an exchange, the Commission acknowledges that the list of

spreads in Sec. 150.10(a)(2) is not an exhaustive list and that

exchanges may grant other spread exemptions so long as they meet the

requirements in Sec. 150.10(a)(1), (3), and (4)(vi).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1148\ Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(2) included the following list

of spreads that a designated contract market or swap execution

facility may approve under this section include: (i) Calendar

spreads; (ii) Quality differential spreads; (iii) Processing

spreads; and (iv) Product or by-product differential spreads.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to the comments received that requested the Commission

continue to permit ``cash and carry'' spread exemptions, the Commission

has determined to allow exchanges to grant ``cash and carry'' spread

exemptions to exchange and federal limits so long as an exchange has

suitable safeguards in place to require a market participant relying on

such an exemption to reduce their position below the speculative limit

in a timely manner once current market prices no longer permit entry

into a full carry transaction. The Commission notes that the condition

noted above is more stringent than how ICE Futures U.S. has conditioned

market participants relying on a cash-and-carry spread exemption. In

that regard, ICE Futures U.S. has required a market participant to

reduce their positions ``before the price of the nearby contract month

rises to a premium to the second (2nd) contract month.''

c. Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(3)

Proposed Rule

Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(3) set forth a core set of information and

materials that all applicants would be required to submit to enable an

exchange to determine, and the Commission to verify, whether the facts

and circumstances attendant to a spread position furthered the policy

objectives of CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B). In particular, the applicant

would be required to demonstrate, and the exchange to determine, that

exempting the spread position from position limits would, to the

maximum extent practicable, ensure sufficient market liquidity for bona

fide hedgers, but not unduly reduce the effectiveness of position

limits to: Diminish, eliminate or prevent excessive speculation; deter

and prevent market manipulation, squeezes, and corners; and ensure that

the price discovery function of the underlying market is not

disrupted.\1149\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1149\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38479, n. 192, and accompanying text (describing the DCM's

responsibility under its application process to make this

determination in a timely manner).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The proposal pointed out that one DCM, ICE Futures U.S., currently

grants certain types of spread exemptions that the Commission was

concerned may not be consistent with these policy objectives.\1150\ ICE

Futures U.S. allows ``cash-and-carry'' spread exemptions to exchange-

set limits, which permit a market participant to hold a long position

greater than the speculative limit in the spot month and an equivalent

short position in the following month in order to guarantee a return

that, at minimum, covers its carrying charges, such as the cost of

financing, insuring, and storing the physical inventory until the next

expiration.\1151\ Market participants are able to take physical

delivery in the nearby month and redeliver the same product in a

deferred month, often at a profit. The Commission noted that while

market participants are permitted to re-deliver the physical commodity,

they are under no obligation to do so.\1152\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1150\ See ICE Futures U.S. Rule 6.29(e).

\1151\ Carrying charges include insurance, storage fees, and

financing costs, as well as other costs such as aging discounts that

are specific to individual commodities. The ICE Futures U.S. rules

require an applicant to provide: (i) Its cost of carry; (ii) the

minimum spread at which the applicant will enter into a straddle

position and which would result in an profit for the applicant; and

(iii) the quantity of stocks in exchange-licensed warehouses that it

already owns. The applicant's entire long position carried into the

notice period must have been put on as a spread at a differential

that covers the applicant's cost of carry. See Rule Enforcement

Review of ICE Futures U.S., July 22, 2014 (``ICE Futures U.S. Rule

Enforcement Review''), at 44-45, available at http://www.cftc.gov/IndustryOversight/TradingOrganizations/DCMs/dcmruleenf. See also

2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38479, n. 189.

\1152\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38479.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ICE Futures U.S.'s rules condition the cash-and-carry spread

exemption upon the applicant's agreement that ``before the price of the

nearby contract month rises to a premium to the second (2nd) contract

month, it will liquidate all long positions in the nearby contract

month.'' \1153\ The Commission noted that it understood that ICE

Futures U.S. required traders to provide information about their

expected cost of carry, which was used by the exchange to determine the

levels by which the trader has to reduce the position. Those exit

points were then communicated to the applicant when the exchange

responded to the trader's spread exemption request.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1153\ ICE Futures U.S. Rule 6.29(e) (at the time of the target

period of the ICE Futures U.S. Rule Enforcement Review (June 15,

2011 to June 15, 2012), the cash-and-carry provision currently found

in ICE Futures U.S. Rule 6.29(e) was found in ICE Futures U.S. Rule

6.27(e)). Further, under the exchange's rules, additional conditions

may also apply.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal considered whether

to impose on the exchange a requirement to ensure that exit points in

cash-and-carry spread exemptions would facilitate an orderly

liquidation in the expiring futures contract. The Commission stated

that it was concerned that a large demand for delivery on cash and

carry positions might distort the price of the expiring futures

upwards. This would particularly be a concern in those commodity

markets where the cash spot price was discovered in the expiring

futures contract.

As the Commission noted, ICE Futures U.S. opined in a recent rule

enforcement review that such exemptions are ``beneficial for the

market, particularly when there are plentiful warehouse stocks, which

[[Page 96834]]

typically is the only time when the opportunity exists to utilize the

exemption,'' maintaining that the exchange's rules and procedures are

effective in ensuring orderly liquidations.\1154\ The Commission

observed that it remained concerned about these exemptions and their

impact on the spot month price, and noted that it was still reviewing

the effectiveness of the exchange's cash-and-carry spread exemptions

and the procedure by which they were granted.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1154\ ICE Futures U.S. Rule Enforcement Review, at 45.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As an alternative to providing exchanges with discretion to

consider granting cash-and-carry spread exemptions, the Commission

considered, in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal,

prohibiting cash-and-carry spread exemptions to position limits. In

this regard, the Commission pointed out that it does not grant such

exemptions to current federal position limits. As another alternative,

the Commission considered permitting exchanges to grant cash-and-carry

spread exemptions, but would require suitable safeguards be placed on

such exemptions. For example, the Commission considered requiring that

cash-and-carry spread exemptions be conditioned on a market participant

reducing positions below speculative limit levels in a timely manner

once current market prices no longer permit entry into a full carry

transaction, rather than the less stringent condition of ICE Futures

U.S. that a trader reduce positions ``before the price of the nearby

contract month rises to a premium to the second (2nd) contract month.''

\1155\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1155\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38479.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received

One commenter expressed the view that an ``exchange should not be

required to determine whether liquidity will be increased if a

particular Spread Exemption is granted before it is permitted to grant

such Spread Exemption.'' According to the commenter, ``this requirement

effectively would create an entirely new legal standard for spread

exemptions and flip on its head the requirement under CEA section

4a(a)(3)(b)(iii), which states that, to the maximum extent practicable,

in establishing speculative position limits the Commission in its

discretion should ensure sufficient market liquidity for bona fide

hedgers. CEA section 4a(a)(3)(b)(iii) does not require (and should not

require) that, in granting an exemption from speculative position

limits, the exemption must add to liquidity.'' \1156\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1156\ CL-Working Group-60947 at 22. See also CL-ISDA-60931 at 1

(expressing that under the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, the exchange must certify that a spread exemption

increases liquidity in order to grant it. The commenter expressed

the view that the CEA requires limits that do not impair liquidity,

as opposed to limits that specifically increase it. Furthermore, the

commenter recommended that the Commission should remove this

condition because the purpose of a spread exemption ``is not to

increase liquidity but rather to recognize the more limited

speculative opportunity created by such positions.'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Two commenters requested that the proposed application requirements

for market participants be revised to only require ``such information

as the relevant exchange deems necessary to determine if the requested

exemption is consistent with the purposes of hedging.'' Furthermore one

commenter requested that the Commission confirm that the detailed

procedures for exchange-granted exemptions for spread and anticipatory

hedges are not applicable to exemptions granted by exchanges for

positions below the federal level.\1157\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1157\ CL-ICE-60929 at 8. See also CL-Nodal-60948 at 2-3

(expressing the view that ``[t]he Proposed Rule is overly

prescriptive as to the information that must be provided by the

applicant, especially when the exchange may have superior

information regarding intramarket spreads. Unlike intermarket

spreads, the exchange, and not the applicant, is more likely to have

direct information to determine whether an intramarket spread

achieves the goals of CEA 4a(a)(3)(B). For example, [an exchange]

has current deliverable supply analysis, spread and outright trading

activity information, and market data from spot markets for the

underlying physical commodities. In performing its pricing and

surveillance functions, [an exchange] monitors position accumulation

information that is not available to market participants as well as

out-of-market pricing in real time.'' The commenter requested that

it be allowed to determine its application process, and the

information it needs to achieve the policy objectives of CEA

4a(a)(3)(B), ``for which the Commission has the authority to review

the exchange's rules and conclusions.'')

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter expressed the view that ``if proposed Regulations

150.9(a)(3)(iii) and 150.10(a)(3)(iii) indeed are intended to apply to

an applicant's maximum size of all gross positions for each and every

commodity derivative contract the applicant holds (as opposed to the

maximum gross positions in the commodity derivative contract(s) for

which the exemption is sought), such requirements are unnecessary and

unduly burdensome.'' \1158\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1158\ CL-Working Group-60947 at 10. See also CL-ISDA-60931 at

10 (expressing the view that the proposed rule 150.10(a)(3)(iii)

requiring maximum size of all gross positions in derivative

contracts is too broad and practically impossible as no market

participant can predict trading activity for a year).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.10(a)(3), largely as

originally proposed with one clarifying amendment to Sec.

150.10(a)(3)(iii), as discussed further below. The Commission believes

that exchanges should consider the policy objectives of CEA section

4a(a)(3)(B), which is the standard that the Commission would use to

review a petition to exempt a spread position from position limits.

Regarding the comment arguing that CEA section 4a(a)(3)(b)(iii) does

not require that the granting of a spread exemption must increase

liquidity, the Commission interprets the CEA as providing it with the

statutory authority to exempt spreads that are consistent with the

other policy objectives for position limits, such as those in CEA

section 4a(a)(3)(B). CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B) provides that the

Commission shall set limits to the maximum extent practicable, in its

discretion--to diminish, eliminate, or prevent excessive speculation as

described under this section; to deter and prevent market manipulation,

squeezes, and corners; to ensure sufficient market liquidity for bona

fide hedgers; and to ensure that the price discovery function of the

underlying market is not disrupted. The Commission believes that

exchanges who elect to grant spread exemptions to federal position

limits should use the guidance in CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B) as the

Commission would when reviewing de novo a spread exemption application.

Regarding the comment requesting change to the requirements of

Sec. 150.10(a)(3) to only require ``such information as the relevant

exchange deems necessary to determine if the requested exemption is

consistent with the purposes of hedging,'' the Commission believes that

the proposal requires a minimum amount of information, and exchanges

have discretion to require additional information. If (as one commenter

represented) an exchange has market information that would supplement

its analysis of a spread exemption application, nothing in the proposal

would preclude an exchange from using that information in its analysis.

However, the Commission notes that such information must be included in

the records of that spread exemption application as required under

Sec. 150.10(b).

In response to the request for clarification regarding whether

Sec. 150.10 applies to both federal and exchange-set limits, the

Commission clarifies that, as

[[Page 96835]]

explained above in connection with Sec. 150.5, Sec. 150.10 would not

apply if an exchange grants exemptions from speculative position limits

it sets under paragraph Sec. 150.5(a)(1), provided that that any

spread exemptions to exchange-set limits not conforming to Sec. 150.3

and Sec. 150.10 were capped at the level of the applicable federal

limit in Sec. 150.2. Further, Sec. 150.10 would not apply to

exchanges that grant spread exemptions to exchange-set limits, in

commodity derivative contracts not subject to a federal limit.

Regarding the comment about whether the phrase ``maximum size of

all gross positions'' applies to an applicant's entire book of

derivative positions or just those positions pertaining to the

exemption application, the Commission intended that the applicant only

report its maximum size of all gross positions in the commodity related

to the exemption application that it is submitting. In that regard,

Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.10(a)(3)(iii) to clarify as such.

For a more detailed discussion, please see Sec. 150.9(a)(2) above.

d. Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(4)

Proposed Rule

Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(4) set forth certain timing requirements

that an exchange would be required to include in its rules for the

spread application process. Those timing requirements would

substantially mirror those provisions proposed in Sec. 150.9(a)(4)

\1159\ for the non-enumerated bona fide hedging position application

process. While these timing requirements are similar to those under

proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(4), the exchange, under proposed Sec.

150.10(a)(4), must also determine in a timely manner whether the facts

and circumstances attendant to a position further the policy objectives

of CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B).\1160\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1159\ The Commission noted, for example, proposed Sec.

150.9(a)(4) provided that: (i) A person intending to rely on a

exchange's exemption from position limits would be required to

submit an application in advance and to reapply at least on an

annual basis; (ii) the exchange would be required to notify an

applicant in a timely manner whether the position was exempted, and

reasons for any rejection; and (iii) the exchange would be able to

revoke, at any time, any recognition previously issued pursuant to

proposed Sec. 150.9 if the exchange determined the recognition was

no longer in accord with section 4a(c) of the Act. See 2016

Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at 38480, n. 192.

\1160\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38476, n. 171 and accompanying text.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received

The Commission notes that it did not receive comments regarding

Sec. 150.10(a)(4).

Commission Determination

The Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.10(a)(4), as originally

proposed.

e. Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(5)

Proposed Rule

Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(5) clarified that an applicant's spread

position would be deemed to be recognized as a spread position exempt

from federal position limits at the time an exchange recognized it. The

Commission noted that this was substantially similar to proposed Sec.

150.9(a)(5) for non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

exemptions.\1161\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1161\ For example, proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(5) provided that the

position will be deemed to be recognized as a non-enumerated bona

fide hedging position when an exchange recognized it.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received

One commenter expressed the view that it is concerned regarding how

an exchange should coordinate the granting of exemptions with respect

to contracts on the same underlying commodities that trade on different

exchanges, and requests guidance from the Commission on that

matter.\1162\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1162\ CL-ISDA-60931 at 6-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.10(a)(5), as originally

proposed. The Commission notes that the proposal allows each exchange

to use its own expertise to decide what exemptions and limit levels to

employ for their venue with the Commission serving in an oversight role

to monitor exemptions and position limits across exchanges. The

Commission also notes that although the proposal does not address

coordination of granting of exemptions among exchanges, there is

nothing in the proposal that would prohibit exchanges from

coordinating.

f. Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(6)

Proposed Rule

Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(6) required exchanges that elect to

process spread applications to promulgate reporting rules for

applicants who owned, held or controlled positions recognized as

spreads; the Commission noted that this is substantially similar to

proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(6) for non-enumerated bona fide hedge

exemptions.\1163\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1163\ For example, proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(6) provided that an

exchange would promulgate enhanced reporting rules in order to

obtain sufficient information to conduct an adequate surveillance

program to detect and potentially deter excessively large positions

that might disrupt the price discovery process.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received

Several commenters \1164\ recommended, ``that the Commission remove

the proposed requirement that an exchange must adopt enhanced reporting

rules for market participants that rely on non-enumerated hedge

exemptions, spread exemptions, or anticipatory exemptions'' because the

proposal ``would force exchanges to establish rules that require market

participants to report all referenced contract positions that they hold

or control in reliance upon a non-enumerated hedge, spread, or

anticipatory hedge exemption along with the underlying cash market

exposure (e.g., cash positions or components of a spread) hedged by

those positions.'' Many of these commenters expressed the view that

such reporting requirements would be overly burdensome and/or

confusing.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1164\ See, e.g., CL-FIA-60937 at 15; CL-CMC-60950 at 12-13; CL-

CCI-60935 at 7-8; CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 12-13; CL-MGEX-60936 at 6;

CL-ISDA-60931 at 10; CL-NGFA-60941 at 4; CL-Working Group-60947 at

12 (footnotes omitted) and CL-AMG-60946 at 4-5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.10(a)(6) with one

modification to clarify in the regulation text that exchanges are

authorized, but not required, to determine whether to require reporting

by the spread exemption applicant. For a more detailed discussion,

please see the discussion of Sec. 150.9(a)(3) above.

g. Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(7)

Proposed Rule

Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(7) required an exchange to publish on its

Web site, no less frequently than quarterly, a description of each new

type of derivative position that it recognized as a spread; the

Commission noted that this was substantially similar to proposed Sec.

150.9(a)(7) for non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

exemptions.\1165\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1165\ For example, proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(7) provided that an

exchange would publish on its Web site, no less frequently than

quarterly, a description of each new type of derivative position

that it recognized as a non-enumerated bona fide hedge. The

Commission noted that it envisioned that each description would be

an executive summary. The description would be required to include a

summary describing the type of derivative position and an

explanation of why it qualified as a non-enumerated bona fide hedge.

The Commission observed that the exchanges were in the best position

when quickly crafting these descriptions to accommodate an

applicant's desire for trading anonymity while promoting fair and

open access for market participants to information regarding which

positions might be recognized as non-enumerated bona fide hedges.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96836]]

Comments Received

One commenter expressed the view that proposed Sec. 150.10 would

have an anti-competitive effect on markets that rely on intramarket

spread trading to enhance liquidity on less actively traded contracts.

The commenter was concerned that the information that would be

published in a fact pattern summary would provide details that could be

used to identify market participants, especially in thinly traded

specialized markets.\1166\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1166\ CL-Nodal-60948 at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter expressed the view that exchanges should ``not be

required to disclose any conditions of an exemption granted due to the

potential for such information to compromise the exemption recipient's

position.'' \1167\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1167\ CL-CME-60926 at 11.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.10(a)(6), as originally

proposed. The Commission reiterates that the purpose of each summary is

to provide transparency to market participants by providing fair and

open access for market participants to information regarding which

positions might be recognized as spreads. The summary would be an

executive summary that does not provide details of a market participant

who received such an exemption, but rather, a general description of

what the position is and why it qualifies for a spread exemption. The

commenters did not provide any proposed alternatives to provide such

transparency to market participants.

h. Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(8)

Proposed Rule

Proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(8) provided options for an exchange to

elect to request the Commission review a spread application that raised

novel or complex issues, using the process set forth in proposed Sec.

150.10(d), discussed below.\1168\ This was substantially similar to

those proposed under Sec. 150.9(a)(8).\1169\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1168\ If the exchange determined to request under proposed

Sec. 150.10(a)(8) that the Commission consider the application, the

exchange must, under proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(4)(v)(C), notify an

applicant in a timely manner that the exchange had requested that

the Commission review the application. This provision provided the

exchanges with the ability to request Commission review early in the

review process, rather than requiring the exchanges to process the

request, make a determination and only then begin the process of

Commission review provided for under proposed Sec. 150.10(d). The

Commission noted that although most of its reviews would occur after

the exchange makes its determination, the Commission could, as

provided for in proposed Sec. 150.10(d)(1), initiate its review, in

its discretion, at any time.

\1169\ For example, proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(8) provided that if

an exchange makes a request pursuant to proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(8),

the Commission, as would be the case for an exchange, would not be

bound by a time limitation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received

The Commission did not receive comments regarding Sec.

150.10(a)(8).

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.10(a)(8), as originally

proposed.

i. Proposed Sec. 150.10(b)--Recordkeeping Requirements

Proposed Rule

Proposed Sec. 150.10(b) outlined the recordkeeping requirements

for exchanges that elected to process spread exemption applications

submitted pursuant to Sec. 150.10(a). As noted above, the proposed

processes under this rule were substantially similar to the

corresponding provisions in Sec. 150.9(b). Hence, the Commission does

not repeat the discussion here.

Commission Reproposal

The Commission did not receive comments on Sec. 150.10(b), and is

reproposing this rule, as originally proposed, for the same reasons as

discussed in connection with Sec. 150.9(b).

j. Proposed Sec. 150.10(c) (Exchange Reporting) and Reproposal

Proposed Rule

Proposed Sec. 150.10(c)(1) required designated contract markets

and swap execution facilities that elected to process spread exemption

applications to submit to the Commission a report for each week as of

the close of business on Friday showing various information concerning

the derivative positions that had been recognized by the designated

contract market or swap execution facility as an exempt spread

position, and for any revocation, modification or rejection of such

recognition. Moreover, proposed Sec. 150.10(c)(2) required a

designated contract market or swap execution facility that elected to

process applications for exempt spread positions to submit to the

Commission (i) a summary of any exempt spread position newly published

on the designated contract market or swap execution facility's Web

site; and (ii) no less frequently than monthly, any report submitted by

an applicant to such designated contract market or swap execution

facility pursuant to rules required under proposed Sec.

150.10(a)(6).\1170\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1170\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38480; see also discussion of 150.9(c) at 38474-75.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As noted above, the proposed processes under this rule were

substantially similar to the corresponding provisions in Sec.

150.9(c). The Commission did not receive comments on this section that

differed from those received on Sec. 150.9(c).

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing this rule, largely as originally

proposed, for the reasons previously provided in the discussion

regarding Sec. 150.9(c), with the same revision to the regulatory text

included in reproposed Sec. 150.9(c), to clarify that exchanges have

the discretion to determine whether to incorporate additional reporting

requirements for spread exemption applicants. In particular, the

Commission is proposing to amend language in Sec. 150.10(c)(2) to

clarify that, unless otherwise instructed by the Commission, an

exchange that elects to process applications to exempt spread positions

from position limits shall submit to the Commission, no less frequently

than monthly, ``any reports such [DCM or SEF] requires to be submitted

by an applicant to such [DCM or SEF] pursuant to the rules required

under paragraph (a)(6) of this section.''

k. Proposed Sec. 150.10(d) (Review of applications by the Commission)

and Reproposal

Proposed Rule

Proposed Sec. 150.10(d) provided for Commission review of

applications to ensure that the processes administered by the exchange,

as well as the results of such processes, were consistent with the

purposes of section 4a(a)(3)(B) of the Act and the Commission's

regulations thereunder. As noted previously, under the proposal, the

Commission was not diluting its ability to grant or not grant spread

exemptions. The Commission reserved to itself the ability to review any

exchange action, and to review any application by a market participant

to an exchange, whether prior to or after disposition of such

application by an exchange. An exchange could ask the Commission to

consider a spread exemption application (proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(8)).

The Commission could also on its own initiative at any time--before or

after action by an exchange--review any application submitted to an

exchange for recognition of a spread exemption (proposed Sec.

150.10(d)(1)). And, as noted above, market

[[Page 96837]]

participants would still be able to request a staff interpretive letter

under Sec. 140.99 from the Commission or seek exemptive relief under

CEA section 4a(a)(7) from the Commission, as an alternative to the

three proposed exchange-administered processes.

As previously indicated, the processes under the proposed rule was

substantially similar to the corresponding provisions in proposed Sec.

150.9(d). Hence, the Commission does not repeat the discussion here.

Commission Reproposal

The Commission did not receive comments on this section that

differed from those received on Sec. 150.9(d), and is reproposing this

rule, as originally proposed, for the reasons discussed above in

connection with Sec. 150.9(d).

l. Proposed Sec. 150.10(e) (Review of summaries by the Commission) and

Reproposal

Proposed Rule

The Commission proposed to rely on the expertise of the exchanges

to summarize and post executive summaries of spread exemptions to their

respective Web sites under proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(7). The Commission

also proposed, in Sec. 150.10(e), to review such executive summaries

to ensure they provided adequate disclosure to market participants of

the potential availability of relief from speculative position limits.

Commission Reproposal

As noted above, the proposed processes under this rule are

substantially similar to the corresponding provisions in Sec.

150.9(e). The Commission did not receive comments on this section that

differed from those received on Sec. 150.9(e), and so does not repeat

the discussion here. For all the reasons previously provided, the

Commission is reproposing this rule, as originally proposed.

m. Proposed Sec. 150.10(f) (Delegation of Authority) and Reproposal

Proposed Rule

The Commission proposed to delegate certain of its authorities

under proposed Sec. 150.10 to the Director of the Commission's

Division of Market Oversight, or such other employee or employees as

the Director designated from time to time. Proposed Sec.

150.10(f)(1)(i) delegated the Commission's authority to the Division of

Market Oversight to provide instructions regarding the submission of

information required to be reported to the Commission by an exchange,

and to specify the manner and determine the format, coding structure,

and electronic data transmission procedures for submitting such

information. Proposed Sec. 150.10(f)(1)(v) delegated the Commission's

review authority under proposed Sec. 150.10(e) to DMO with respect to

summaries of the types of spread exemptions that were required to be

posted on an exchange's Web site pursuant to proposed Sec.

150.10(a)(7).

Proposed Sec. 150.10(f)(1)(i) delegated the Commission's authority

to the Division of Market Oversight to agree to or reject a request by

an exchange to consider an application for recognition of an

application for a spread exemption. Proposed Sec. 150.10(f)(1)(iii)

delegated the Commission's authority to review any application for a

spread exemption, and all records required to be maintained by an

exchange in connection with such application. Proposed Sec.

150.10(f)(1)(iii) also delegated the Commission's authority to request

such records, and to request additional information in connection with

such application from the exchange or from the applicant.

Proposed Sec. 150.10(f)(1)(iv) delegated the Commission's

authority, under proposed Sec. 150.10(d)(2) to determine when an

application for a spread exemption required additional analysis or

review, and to provide notice to the exchange and the particular

applicant that they had 10 days to supplement such application.

The Commission did not propose to delegate its authority under

proposed Sec. 150.10(d)(3) to make a final determination as to the

exchange's disposition. The Commission stated that if an exchange's

disposition raised concerns regarding consistency with the Act or

presents novel or complex issues, then the Commission should make the

final determination, after taking into consideration any supplemental

information provided by the exchange or the applicant.\1171\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1171\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR

38482, Jun. 13, 2016.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal

As noted above, the proposed processes under this rule are

substantially similar to the corresponding provisions in Sec.

150.9(f); the Commission did not receive comments on this section that

differed from those received on Sec. 150.9(f), and so does not repeat

the discussion here. For all the reasons previously provided, the

Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.9(f), as originally proposed.

I. Sec. 150.11--Process for Recognition of Positions As Bona Fide

Hedging Positions for Unfilled Anticipated Requirements, Unsold

Anticipated Production, Anticipated Royalties, Anticipated Services

Contract Payments or Receipts, or Anticipatory Cross-Commodity Hedge

Positions

1. Overview of the Enumerated Anticipatory Bona Fide Hedging Position

Exemption Proposal

After reviewing comments in response to the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, the Commission proposed another method by which market

participants may have enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedge positions

recognized. As proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

Sec. 150.7 would require market participants to file statements with

the Commission regarding certain anticipatory hedges which would become

effective absent Commission action or inquiry ten days after

submission. As the Commission explained in the 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal, the method in proposed Sec. 150.11 was an

exchange-administered process to determine whether certain enumerated

anticipatory bona fide hedge positions, such as unfilled anticipated

requirements, unsold anticipated production, anticipated royalties,

anticipated service contract payments or receipts, or anticipatory

cross-commodity hedges should be recognized as bona fide hedge

positions.\1172\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1172\ Id. at 38495.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission noted that proposed Sec. 150.11 worked in concert

with the following three proposed rules:

Proposed Sec. 150.3(a)(1)(i), with the effect that

recognized anticipatory enumerated bona fide hedging positions may

exceed federal position limits;

proposed Sec. 150.5(a)(2), with the effect that

recognized anticipatory enumerated bona fide hedging positions may

exceed exchange-set position limits for contracts subject to federal

position limits; and

proposed Sec. 150.5(b)(5), with the effect that

recognized anticipatory enumerated bona fide hedging positions may

exceed exchange-set position limits for contracts not subject to

federal position limits.\1173\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1173\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The proposed Sec. 150.11 process was somewhat analogous to the

application process for recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions under proposed Sec. 150.9. The process for recognition of

enumerated anticipatory

[[Page 96838]]

bona fide hedging positions contained five paragraphs: (a) through (e).

The first three paragraphs--Sec. 150.11(a), (b), and (c)--required

exchanges that elected to have a process for recognizing enumerated

anticipatory bona fide hedging positions, and market participants that

sought position-limit relief for such positions, to carry out certain

duties and obligations. The fourth and fifth paragraphs--Sec.

150.11(d), and (e)--delineated the Commission's role and obligations in

reviewing requests for recognition of enumerated anticipatory bona fide

hedging positions.\1174\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1174\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission noted that there would be significant benefits

related to the adoption of proposed Sec. 150.11. Similar to the

benefits for recognizing positions as non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions under Sec. 150.9, recognizing anticipatory positions as bona

fide hedging posiitons under Sec. 150.11 would provide market

participants with potentially a more expeditious recognition process

than the Commission proposal for a 10-day Commission recognition

process under proposed Sec. 150.7. This could potentially enable

commercial market participants to pursue trading strategies in a more

timely fashion to advance their commercial and hedging needs to reduce

risk. In addition, the Commission pointed out that exchanges would be

able to use existing resources and knowledge in the administration and

assessment of enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging positions. The

Commission and exchanges have evaluated these types of positions for

years (as discussed in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal).\1175\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1175\ Id. at 38496.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also pointed out that proposed Sec. 150.11, similar

to proposed Sec. 150.9 and Sec. 150.10, also would provide the

benefit of enhanced record-retention and reporting of positions

recognized as enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging positions. As

previously discussed, records retained for specified periods would

enable exchanges to develop consistent practices and afford the

Commission accessible information for review, surveillance, and

enforcement efforts. Likewise, weekly reporting under Sec. 150.11

would facilitate the Commission's tracking of such exemptions.\1176\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1176\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. Proposed Sec. 150.11(a)

Proposed Rule

As noted, proposed Sec. 150.11(a) permitted exchanges to recognize

certain enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging positions, such as

unfilled anticipated requirements, unsold anticipated production,

anticipated royalties, anticipated service contract payments or

receipts, or anticipatory cross-commodity hedges. The proposed rule

allowed market participants to work with exchanges to seek the

exemption.

The process under proposed Sec. 150.11(a) was similar to the

process under proposed Sec. 150.9(a), described above. For example, an

exchange with at least one year of experience and expertise

administering position limits could elect to adopt rules to recognize

commodity derivative positions as enumerated anticipatory bona fide

hedges. However, the Sec. 150.11(a) process was different from the

process under proposed Sec. 150.9(a) in that the Commission did not

propose to permit separate processes for applications based on novel

versus non-novel facts and circumstances.\1177\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1177\ Id. at 38481.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As the Commission noted in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, it determined to define certain anticipatory positions as

enumerated bona fide hedging positions when it adopted current Sec.

1.3(z)(2); the Commission did not change this determination in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal.\1178\ Consequently, the

Commission did not anticipate that applications for recognition of

enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging positions would be based on

novel facts and circumstances. For the same reason, proposed Sec.

150.11(a) did not require exchanges to post summaries of any enumerated

anticipatory bona fide hedging positions. As the Commission noted,

other simplifications follow from this difference.\1179\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1178\ Id.

\1179\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received

Several commenters recommended that the Commission specifically

recognize the full scope of anticipatory hedging activities such as

anticipatory merchandising and anticipatory processing hedges, utility

sales and cross-commodity hedges as enumerated bona fide hedging

position exemptions.\1180\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1180\ CL- NCC-ACSA-60972 at 2; CL-AGA-60943 at 3; CL-ICE-60929

at 12; CL-CMC-60950 at 6-9; CL-FIA-60937 at 5, 21; CL-API-60939 at

3; and CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 13.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition, several commenters recommended that the Commission not

adopt the ``active trading'' and ``one year experience'' requirements

as proposed regarding a DCM's qualification to administer exemptions

from federal position limits.\1181\ These commenters stated that such

qualification requirements could have the unintended consequences of:

(i) harming the ability of market participants to effectively manage

their risk by preventing the exchanges from recognizing an otherwise

appropriate exemption from federal speculative position limits; and

(ii) stifling future innovation in the development of new commodity

derivative products created to meet evolving market needs and demands.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1181\ CL-CCI-60935 at 3-4; CL-FIA-60937 at 3; CL-Working Group-

60947 at 10; CL-IECAssn-60949 at 12-13 and CL-CME-60926 at 13.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Certain commenters opposed the Commission delegating hedge

exemption authority to exchanges entirely.\1182\ These commenters

believed that such delegated authority creates an inherent conflict of

interest for exchanges because they are incentivized to increase

trading volume. Among other concerns, these commenters fear that hedge

exemption applicants may develop a preference for those exchanges more

willing to grant exemptions. Further, the exchanges may not have a full

picture of the entire market in which they are being asked to grant the

exemption.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1182\ CL-Public Citizen-60940 at 1-2; CL-RER1-60961 at 1; and

CL-Better Markets-60928 at 3-5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

According to other commenters, the Commission should eliminate the

five-day rule.\1183\ Instead, these commenters stated, the Commission

should specifically authorize exchanges to grant bona fide hedging

position exemptions during the last five days of trading or less and

allow exchanges to permit commercial hedging into the spot period where

the facts and circumstances warrant.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1183\ CL-IECAssn-60949 at 7-9; CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919 at 7; CL-ICE-

60929 at 9; CL-CMC-60950 at 9-11; CL-API-60939 at 3; CL-NCC-ACSA-

60972 at 2; and CL-Working Group-60947 at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Lastly, several commenters advocated for removal of the proposed

requirement that exchanges adopt enhanced reporting requirements for

market participants that rely on exchange-administered hedge

exemptions.\1184\ One argued that such a requirement is not authorized

by the CEA and would have the unintended effect of preventing

[[Page 96839]]

new entrants to the relevant market.\1185\ Another further argues that

these enhanced reporting requirements are unnecessary, impose undue

cost burdens on commercial end-users, and the Commission can always

request the information through its existing authority.\1186\ And two

suggest that the Commission allow exchanges flexibility to request

satisfactory data, but not set a fixed prerequisite time period to

obtaining exemptions.\1187\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1184\ CL-FIA-60937 at 3; and CL-CMC-60950 at 12-13.

\1185\ CL-FIA-60937 at 3.

\1186\ CL-CMC-60950 at 12-13.

\1187\ CL-AMG-60946 at 3-4; and CL-FIA-60937 at 3, 12.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal

After carefully considering the comments received, the Commission

is reproposing the rule, as originally proposed. At this time the

Commission has already proposed several enumerated bona fide hedging

position exemption categories. At this time, the Commission believes

that additional fact patterns for bona fide hedging position exemptions

will require consideration of the facts and circumstances on a case-by-

case basis. The Commission is willing to explore further additions to

the enumerated list at a later date. However, the Commission reiterates

that, as previously discussed, an exchange can petition under Sec.

13.2 for Commission recognition of a generic fact pattern as an

enumerated bona fide hedging position, and that market participants

have the flexibility of two processes for recognition of a position as

an enumerated bona fide hedging position: (i) request an exemptive, no-

action or interpretative letter under Sec. 140.99; and/or (ii)

petition under Sec. 13.2 for changes to Appendix B to part 150.

Separately, as noted in the June 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal and above, the Commission is not persuaded that an exchange

with no active trading and no previous experience with a new product

class would have their interests aligned with the Commission's policy

objectives in CEA section 4a. In addition, as noted above, the

Commission points out that the experience is manifested by the people

carrying out surveillance rather than tied to a particular

exchange.\1188\ Further, the Commission believes that the active

trading requirement can be satisfied by maintaining any referenced

contract listed in the particular commodity at issue. For example, a

DCM may immediately begin accepting hedge exemption requests for a new

commodity contract pursuant to Sec. 150.11(a) if the DCM already

maintains contract(s) in the same underlying commodity class that

satisfy the experience and active trading requirements.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1188\ As the Commission noted above when discussing the

requirement for one year of experience in connection with Sec.

150.9(a), experience manifests in the people carrying out

surveillance in a commodity rather than in an institutional

structure. An exchange's experience could be demonstrated through

the relevant experience of the surveillance staff regarding the

particular commodity. In fact, the Commission has historically

reviewed the experience and qualifications of exchange regulatory

divisions when considering whether to designate a new exchange as a

contract market or to recognize a facility as a SEF; as such

exchanges are new, staff experience has clearly been gained at other

exchanges.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission clarifies, however, that an exchange can petition

the Commission, pursuant to Sec. 140.99, for a waiver of the one-year

experience requirement if such exchange believes that their experience

and interested are aligned with the Commission's interests with respect

to recognizing enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging positions.

The Commission appreciates commenter concerns regarding those

opposed to delegating any hedge exemption authority to exchanges.

However, the Commission reiterates that it retains full oversight

authority over exchanges issuing hedge exemptions. Further, the

Commission believes an exchange's required experience administering

position limits for its actively traded contracts, and the Commission's

de novo review of granted hedge exemptions are adequate to guard

against or remedy any conflicts of interest that may arise. The

Commission also notes that exchanges remain bound by the Commission's

bona fide hedging position definition for all hedge exemption

determinations conducted pursuant to part 150 of Commission

Regulations.

The Commission believes the five-day rule should be applied to

anticipatory bona fide hedging positions. If a market participant

wishes to secure an exemption from the five-day rule, the participant

should submit an exemption request, pursuant to Sec. 150.9, for

recognition of a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position.

Further, the Commission believes that reporting requirements

applicable to market participants seeking an exemption pursuant to

Sec. 150.11 may remain as proposed. The Commission notes that Sec.

150.11(a)(5) clarifies that applicants are bound by the reporting

requirements found in Sec. 150.7(e). As noted in Sec. 150.7,

understanding the recent history of a firm's production data is

necessary to ensure the requested anticipated hedge exemption is

reasonable. However, as discussed above, the Commission notes that it

may permit a reasonable, supported estimate of, for example,

anticipated production for less than three years of annual production

data, in the Commission's discretion, if a market participant does not

have three years of data. Further, the Commission is amending the

applicable form instructions to clarify that Commission staff could

determine that such an estimate is reasonable and would be accepted.

The Commission is also proposing that exchange staff, on behalf of the

Commission, also could permit a reasonable, supported estimate of, for

example, anticipated production for less than three years of annual

production data.

3. Proposed Sec. 150.11(b) (Recordkeeping) and Reproposal

Proposed Rule

Proposed Sec. 150.11(b) required electing designated contract

markets and swap execution facilities to keep full, complete, and

systematic records of all activities relating to the processing and

disposition of enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging exemption

requests submitted pursuant to Sec. 150.11(a). As previously stated,

the Commission believes such recordkeeping requirements are essential

to ensure adequate compliance and oversight.

Commission Reproposal

As noted, the proposed processes under this rule are substantially

similar to the corresponding provisions in Sec. 150.9(b) and Sec.

150.10(b). Hence, the Commission does not repeat the discussion here.

The Commission did not receive comments on Sec. 150.11(b), and is

reproposing this rule, as originally proposed, for the same reasons as

Sec. 150.9(b) and Sec. 150.10(b).

4. Proposed Sec. 150.11(c) (Exchange Reporting) and Reproposal

Proposed Rule

Proposed Sec. 150.11(c) required designated contract markets and

swap execution facilities that elected to process enumerated

anticipatory bona fide hedging position applications to submit to the

Commission a report for each week as of the close of business on Friday

showing various information concerning the derivative positions that

had been recognized by the designated contract market or swap execution

facility as an enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging position, and

for any revocation, modification or rejection of such recognition.

Similar to non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions

[[Page 96840]]

and spreads, this rule implemented a weekly reporting obligation for

exchanges. Unlike the other hedge exemption application types,

exchanges would have no monthly reporting or web-posting obligations

related to accepting or granting enumerated anticipatory bona fide

hedging position exemptions.

Commission Reproposal

In consideration of these reduced reporting requirements and the

previous discussion of this subject regarding proposed Sec. Sec.

150.9(c) and 150.10(c), the Commission is reproposing this rule, as

originally proposed, for the reasons discussed therein.

5. Proposed Sec. 150.11(d) (Review of applications by the Commission)

and Reproposal

Proposed Rule

As set forth in proposed Sec. 150.11(d), an exchange could ask the

Commission to consider an enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging

position application directly. Further, the Commission could also, on

its own initiative, at any time--before or after action by an

exchange--review any application submitted to an exchange for

recognition of an enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging position.

As noted, alternatives also remain available. Market participants would

retain the ability to apply directly to the Commission under Sec.

150.7, to separately request staff interpretive letters pursuant to

Sec. 140.99 or seek exemptive relief under CEA section 4a(a)(7).

The review process set forth in Sec. 150.11(d) was simpler than

other hedge exemption requests because such applications are not

anticipated to be based on novel facts and circumstances. Rather,

Commission review would focus on whether the hedge exemption

application satisfied the filing requirements contained in Sec.

150.11(a). If the filing was not complete, then proposed Sec.

150.11(d) would provide an opportunity to supplement to the applicant

and the exchange.

Commission Reproposal

Aside from this minor difference, the proposed processes under this

rule were substantially similar to the corresponding provisions in

Sec. 150.9(d) and Sec. 150.10(d). Hence, the Commission does not

repeat the discussion here. The Commission believes the proposed de

novo review of exchange-granted anticipatory bona fide hedging position

exemptions is adequate to maintain proper exchange oversight. For all

the reasons previously provided above in the discussion regarding Sec.

150.9(d), the Commission is reproposing this rule, as originally

proposed.

6. Proposed Sec. 150.11(e) (Delegation of Authority) and Reproposal

Proposed Rule

As noted previously, the Commission proposed to delegate certain of

its authorities under Sec. 150.11 to the Director of DMO, or such

other employee or employees as the Director may designate from time to

time. In particular, proposed Sec. 150.11(e)(1)(ii) delegated the

Commission's authority to DMO to provide instructions regarding the

submission of information required by an exchange, and to specify the

manner and determine the format, coding structure, and electronic data

transmission procedures for submitting such information. Proposed Sec.

150.11(e)(1)(i) delegated the Commission's authority to DMO to agree to

or reject a request by an exchange to consider an application for

recognition of an enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedge. Proposed

Sec. 150.11(e)(1)(iii) delegated the Commission's authority to review

any application for recognition of an enumerated anticipatory bona fide

hedging position and delegate the authority to request related records

or supporting information from the exchange or from the applicant.

Lastly, the Commission proposed in Sec. 150.11(e)(iv), to delegate

its authority to determine, under proposed Sec. 150.11(d)(2), that it

was not appropriate to recognize a commodity derivative position as an

enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging position, or that the

disposition by an exchange of an application for such recognition is

inconsistent with the filing requirements of proposed Sec.

150.11(a)(2). The delegation also provided DMO with the authority,

after any such determination was made, to grant the applicant a

reasonable amount of time to liquidate its commodity derivative

position or otherwise come into compliance.

This proposed delegation took into account that applications

processed by an exchange under proposed Sec. 150.11 would be for

positions that should satisfy the requirements for enumerated bona fide

hedging positions set forth in the Commission's rules, and should

therefore be less likely to raise novel issues of interpretation, or

novel issues with respect to consistency with the filing requirements

of proposed Sec. 150.11(a)(2), than applications processed under

proposed Sec. 150.9 or Sec. 150.10. Such delegation is consistent

with the Commission's longstanding delegation to DMO of its authority

to review applications for recognition of enumerated bona fide hedging

positions under current Sec. 1.48, as well as consistent with the more

streamlined approach to Commission review of enumerated anticipatory

bona fide hedging position applications in proposed Sec. 150.7.

Commission Reproposal

As noted above, the proposed processes under this rule are

substantially similar to the corresponding provisions in Sec. 150.9(f)

and Sec. 150.10(f). Hence, the Commission does not repeat the

discussion of related comments here. The Commission is reproposing this

rule, as originally proposed, for the reasons discussed above in

connection with Sec. 150.9(f), with the clarification that the

Commission retains the authority to make the final determination to

grant or deny hedge exemption applications.

J. Miscellaneous Regulatory Amendments

1. Part 150.6--Ongoing Application of the Act and Commission

Regulations

Proposed Rule

The Commission proposed to amend existing Sec. 150.6 to conform

the provision with the general applicability of part 150 to SEFs that

are trading facilities, and concurrently making non-substantive changes

to clarify the provision. The provision, as amended and clarified,

provides this part shall only be construed as having an effect on

position limits and that nothing in part 150 shall affect any provision

promulgated under the Act or Commission regulations including but not

limited to those relating to manipulation, attempted manipulation,

corners, squeezes, fraudulent or deceptive conduct, or prohibited

transactions.\1189\ For example, by requiring DCMs and SEFs that are

trading facilities to impose and enforce exchange-set speculative

position limits, the Commission does not intend for the fulfillment of

such requirements alone to satisfy any other legal obligations under

the Act and Commission regulations of DCMs and SEFs that are trading

facilities to detect and deter market manipulation and corners. In

another example, a market participant's compliance with position limits

or an exemption does not confer any type of safe harbor or good faith

defense to a claim that he had engaged in an

[[Page 96841]]

attempted manipulation, a perfected manipulation or deceptive conduct.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1189\ The Commission notes that amended Sec. 150.6 matches

vacated Sec. 151.11(h).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received

The Commission received no comments on the proposed amendments to

Sec. 150.6.

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing Sec. 150.6, with an amendment to

clarify the application of part 150 to other provisions of the Act or

Commission regulations. Specifically, in order to avoid any confusion

regarding whether Sec. 150.6 applies to position limits regulations

found outside of part 150 of the Commission's regulations (e.g.,

relevant sections of part 19), the amendment clarifies that

recordkeeping and reporting regulations associated with speculative

position limits are affected by part 150. The amendment also clarifies

that regulations incorporated by reference to part 150 are also

affected by the regulations promulgated under part 150. These changes,

while not substantively different from the proposed rule, provide

additional clarity regarding the application of part 150 to other

provisions of the Act or Commission regulations.

The Commission also notes that Sec. 150.6 applies despite the

Commission's amendments to the appendices to parts 37 and 38 of the

Commission's regulations regarding delayed implementation of exchange-

set limits for swaps on exchanges without sufficient swaps position

information.

2. Part 150.8--Severability

Proposed Rule

The Commission proposed to add Sec. 150.8 to address the

severability of individual provisions of part 150. Should any

provision(s) of part 150 be declared invalid, including the application

thereof to any person or circumstance, Sec. 150.8 provides that all

remaining provisions of part 150 shall not be affected to the extent

that such remaining provisions, or the application thereof, can be

given effect without the invalid provisions.\1190\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1190\ The Commission notes that proposed Sec. 150.8 matches

vacated Sec. 151.13.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received

The Commission did not receive any comments regarding proposed

Sec. 150.8.

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing the severability clause in Sec.

150.8. The Commission believes it is prudent to include a severability

clause to avoid any further delay, as practicable, in carrying out

Congress' mandate (underscored by the Commission's own preliminary

finding of necessity) to impose position limits in a timely manner.

3. Part 15--Reports--General Provisions

Proposed Rule

The Commission proposed to amend the definition of the term

``reportable position'' in current Sec. 15.00(p)(2) by clarifying

that: (1) Such positions include swaps; (2) issued and stopped

positions are not included in open interest against a position limit;

and (3) special calls may be made for any day a person exceeds a limit.

Additionally, the proposed amendments to Sec. 15.01(d) added language

to reference swaps positions and updated the list of reporting forms in

current Sec. 15.02 to account for new and updated series '04 reporting

forms, as discussed above.\1191\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1191\ See discussion of new and amended series '04 reports

above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received

The Commission did not receive any comments regarding the proposed

amendments to part 15.

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing amendments to part 15, as originally

proposed, to update and clarify the definition of ``reportable

position,'' add references to swaps positions, and add to the list of

reporting forms.

4. Part 17--Reports by Reporting Markets, Futures Commission Merchants,

Clearing Members, and Foreign Brokers

Proposed Rule

In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed to amend current Sec. 17.00(b) to delete provisions related

to aggregation, since those provisions are duplicative of aggregation

provisions in Sec. 150.4.\1192\ Instead, as proposed, Sec. 17.00(b)

provides that ``[e]xcept as otherwise instructed by the Commission or

its designee and as specifically provided in Sec. 150.4 of this

chapter, if any person holds or has a financial interest in or controls

more than one account, all such accounts shall be considered by the

futures commission merchant, clearing member or foreign broker as a

single account for the purpose of determining special account status

and for reporting purposes.'' In addition, proposed Sec. 17.03(h)

delegates to the Director of the Division of Market Oversight or his

designee the authority to instruct persons pursuant to proposed Sec.

17.03.\1193\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1192\ In a separate final rulemaking, the Commission is

finalizing amendments to Sec. 150.4 regarding the aggregation of

positions. See 2016 Final Aggregation Rule.

\1193\ Previously, in 2013, the Commission adopted amendments to

Sec. 17.03. Ownership and Control Reports, Forms 102/102S, 40/40S,

and 71, 78 FR 69178 (Nov. 18, 2013). The Commission is now proposing

to amend Sec. 17.03 further by adding Sec. 17.03(h).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Comments Received

The Commission did not receive any comments regarding the proposed

changes to part 17.

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing amendments to part 17, as originally

proposed, to delete duplicative aggregation provisions and delegate to

the Division of Market Oversight the authority to instruct persons

pursuant to proposed Sec. 17.03.

4. Removal of Commission Regulations 1.47 and 1.48, and Part 151--

Position Limits for Futures and Swaps

Proposed Rule

As discussed above, the Commission intended, in a 2011 final rule,

to amend several other sections as part of its then adoption on part

151. Among the sections the Commission was then affecting was the

removal and reservation of Sec. Sec. 1.47 and 1.48. Both sections

permitted market participants to seek recognition of positions as bona

fide hedges.\1194\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1194\ Sec. 1.47 pertains to requirements for classification of

purchases or sales of contracts for future delivery as bona fide

hedging under Sec. 1.3(z)(3 of the regulations, while Sec. 1.48

addresses requirements for classification of sales or purchases for

future delivery as bona fide hedging of unsold anticipated

production or unfilled anticipated requirements under Sec.

1.3(z)(2) (i)(B) or (i)(C) of the regulations.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

However, prior to the compliance date for that 2011 rulemaking, as

noted above, a federal court vacated most provisions of that

rulemaking, including the amendments to the definition of a bona fide

hedging position in Sec. 1.3(z), as well as to the removal and

reservation of Sec. Sec. 1.47 and 1.48.\1195\ Because the Commission

did not instruct the Federal Register to roll back the 2011 changes to

the CFR, the current CFR still shows the versions adopted in 2011,

which shows Sec. Sec. 1.47 and 1.48 as ``reserved.'' As the Commission

noted in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, in light of the

proposed amendments to part 150, as well as the District Court vacatur

of part 151, the

[[Page 96842]]

amendments to the definition of a bona fide hedging position in 1.3(z),

and the removal and reservation of Sec. Sec. 1.47 and 1.48, the

Commission again proposed to remove and reserve Sec. Sec. 1.47 and

1.48.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1195\ International Swaps and Derivatives Association v. United

States Commodity Futures Trading Commission, 887 F. Supp. 2d 259

(D.D.C. 2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission Reproposal

The Commission is reproposing to remove and reserve Sec. 1.47 in

light of the Commission's proposal of new provisions in Sec. 150.9

addressing exchange recognitions of positions as non-enumerated bona

fide hedging positions, subject to Commission review. Similarly, in

connection with the reproposal of Sec. Sec. 150.7 and 150.11, the

Commission is proposing to remove and reserve, as originally proposed,

Sec. 1.48. Finally, the Commission is reproposing that part 151 be

removed and reserved in response to the reproposed revisions to part

150 that conform it to the amendments made to the CEA section 4a by the

Dodd-Frank Act.

IV. Related Matters

A. Cost-Benefit Considerations

Section 15(a) of the CEA requires the Commission to consider the

costs and benefits of its actions before promulgating a regulation

under the CEA or issuing certain orders. Section 15(a) further

specifies that the costs and benefits shall be evaluated in light of

five broad areas of market and public concern: (1) Protection of market

participants and the public; (2) efficiency, competitiveness, and

financial integrity of futures markets; (3) price discovery; (4) sound

risk management practices; and (5) other public interest

considerations. The Commission considers the costs and benefits

resulting from its discretionary determinations with respect to the

Section 15(a) factors.

The baseline against which the Commission considers the benefits

and costs of these reproposed rules is the statutory requirements of

the CEA and the Commission regulations now in effect--in particular the

Commission's Part 150 regulations and rules 1.47 and 1.48.\1196\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1196\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, Table 4, at

75712, for a list of existing regulations related to enumerated bona

fide hedges.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

1. Necessity Finding

Out of an abundance of caution in light of the district court

decision in ISDA v. CFTC,\1197\ and without prejudice to any argument

the Commission may advance in any forum, the Commission has

preliminarily found, as a separate and independent basis for the Rule,

that speculative position limits are necessary to achieve the purposes

of the CEA.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1197\ International Swaps and Derivatives Association v. United

States Commodity Futures Trading Commission, 887 F. Supp. 2d 259

(D.D.C. 2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. Benefits of Speculative Position Limits Rules

The Commission expects that the speculative position limits in the

reproposed Rule will promote market integrity. Willingness to

participate in the futures and swaps markets may be reduced by

perceptions that a participant with an unusually large speculative

position could exert unreasonable market power. A lack of participation

in these markets may harm liquidity, and consequently, may negatively

impact price discovery and market efficiency as well.

Position limits may serve as a prophylactic measure that reduces

market volatility due to large trades that impact prices. For example,

a party who is holding large open interest may become unwilling or

unable to meet a call for additional margin or take other steps that

are necessary to maintain the position. In such an instance, the party

may substantially reduce its open interest in a short time interval. In

general, price impacts could arise from large positions as they are

established or liquidated.

Exchanges and the Commission may gain insight into the markets as

market participants seek exemptions from position limits. This may

improve the exchanges' and the Commission's ability to supervise

markets and to deter and prevent market manipulation. Further, the

discipline of seeking exemptions that are tied to particular situations

may improve a market participant's risk management practices, as it

goes through the exercise of justifying the need for an exemption.

There are additional benefits to imposing position limits in the

spot month. Spot month position limits are designed to deter and

prevent corners and squeezes. Spot month position limits may also make

it more difficult to mark the close of a futures contract to possibly

benefit other contracts that settle on the closing futures price.

Marking the close harms markets by spoiling convergence between futures

prices and spot prices at expiration. Convergence is desirable, because

it facilitates hedging of the spot price of a commodity at expiration.

In addition, since many other contracts settle based on the futures

price at expiration, mispricing could affect a larger scope of

contracts.

b. Costs of Speculative Position Limits Rules

The Commission recognizes that position limits impose compliance

costs on market participants. Under position limits, market

participants must monitor their positions and have safeguards in place

to remain under a federal position limit or an exemption level. Some

market participants will have to incur the costs of seeking exemptions

from federal positons limits. In this Reproposal, the Commission has

sought to reduce these costs by setting the federal position limits at

an appropriately high level and by relying on the experience and

expertise of exchanges to administer exemptions.

Market participants who find position limits binding may have to

transact in less effective instruments such as futures contracts that

are similar but not the same as the core referenced futures contract.

These instruments could include forward contracts, trade options, or

futures on a foreign board of trade. Transacting in substitute

instruments may raise transaction costs. Finally, if transactions shift

to other instruments, futures prices might not reflect fully all the

speculative demand to hold the futures contract, because substitute

instruments may not influence prices in the same way that trading

directly in the futures contract does. In these circumstances, futures

market price discovery and efficiency might be harmed.

c. Summary of General Comments Regarding Speculative Position Limits

Rules

i. Comments on General Aspects of the Rule

One commenter asserted that the proposed rules have the potential

to increase systemic risk, impair market function, and increase the

costs and volatility of wholesale energy commodities. Moreover, the

commenter asserted that these adverse impacts are unrelated to any

mandates placed upon the Commission by Congress.\1198\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1198\ CL-IECAssn-59679 at 1-2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter said that position limits that are not necessary

or appropriate increase commercial parties' compliance costs and reduce

market liquidity, which in turn increases the cost of hedging. The

commenter believes the Commission did not adequately consider these

costs and the lack of corresponding benefits.\1199\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1199\ CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 2 and 3, CL-EEI-Sup-60386 at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96843]]

One commenter requested that as the Commission enacts its final

rule it should avoid imposing materially costly and complex rules and

reporting requirements on hedgers unless they are manifestly necessary

to prevent a meaningful threat to market integrity.\1200\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1200\ CL-ASR-60933 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal RFC 37, a

commenter stated that maintaining the status quo in which exchanges

administer an established process for position limits and exemptions

will provide legal certainty and maintain current costs instead of

increasing them.\1201\ In response to 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal RFC 55, this commenter said that the Commission's Division of

Enforcement has numerous tools at its disposal, and that the Exchanges

have position step-down and exemption revocation authorization at their

disposal, to enforce CEA market manipulation regulations.\1202\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1201\ CL-IECAssn-60949 at 19.

\1202\ CL-IECAssn-60949 at 23.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sen. Levin commented that the benefits of the proposed rules, while

difficult to quantify, create a net benefit to the public and the

markets by helping to ensure the markets' continued stability,

fairness, and profitability.\1203\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1203\ CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 9-10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Response to Comments on General Aspects of the Rule

The Commission has interpreted the Dodd-Frank Act to mandate that

the Commission impose federal position limits on physical-delivery

futures contracts. In addition, the Commission is making a preliminary

alternative finding that position limits are necessary to accomplish

statutory objectives. The Commission believes that it has calibrated

the levels of those limits so as to avoid harmful effects on the

markets and, accordingly, does not believe the imposition of federal

position limits at the reproposed levels will have the effects that

concerned commenters. These commenter concerns are counterpoised by the

desirable effects on markets that Sen. Levin ascribed to position

limits.

iii. Comments on Cost Estimates

A commenter expressed concern that the CFTC has underestimated the

costs of compliance with the position limits rules, and the number of

affected parties, so that the potential unintended consequences of the

rules will outweigh their benefits. The commenter believes this would

result because the compliance costs associated with position limits are

high and particularly burdensome for market participants who are

unlikely ever to come close to reaching the limits.\1204\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1204\ CL-MFA-60385 at 12-13. See also CL-COPE-59622 at 5 and

CL-CMC-59634 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter believes that the cost-benefit analysis in the

2016 supplemental proposal features unrealistically low estimates of

the time and costs that will be required to implement and maintain

compliance programs.\1205\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1205\ CL-ISDA-60931 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter asserted that the Commission did not adequately

quantify the harm from position limits on liquidity for bona fide

hedgers and the price discovery function, or the implementation and on-

going reporting and monitoring costs for market participants. The

commenter believes that costs will arise from altering speculative

trading strategies in response to a limited definition of bona fide

hedging; reassessing and modifying existing trading strategies to

comply with limits; amending DCMs' current aggregation and bona fide

hedging policies; and creating compliant application regimes for

SEFs.\1206\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1206\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 24-25.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal RFC 56,

another commenter asserted that unduly low position limits would reduce

liquidity and discourage market participation, thereby not advancing

regulatory goals that are already appropriately protected under the

status quo. In response to 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal

RFC 66, this commenter said the Commission should consider public

interest considerations relating to the particular interests of

commercial end-users, which rely on mitigating price risk in order to

remain in business. This commenter believes that commercial end-users

are at risk of being squeezed out of the market, and potentially

squeezed out of business, as a result of the difficulty of hedging

commercial risks. The commenter urged the Commission to apply graduated

regulatory requirements for bona fide hedging determinations that would

account for differences between market participants.\1207\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1207\ CL-IECAssn-60949 at 23, 25-26.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iv. Response to Comments on Cost Estimates

As shown in the impact analysis, the Commission seeks to reduce

market participants' compliance costs by setting the federal position

limits at a level sufficiently high to only affect market participants

with very large open interest. Thus, the Commission expects minimal

compliance costs for those with positions below these high levels.

Small traders would be required only to monitor their open interest and

have safeguards in place to remain below position limits. The

Commission finds the exemption process valuable because it requires

participants with very large open interest to provide the information

required by the exemption application to the relevant exchange(s) and

to the Commission. Having this information helps exchanges and the

Commission to better understand the markets they regulate.

As for the high costs that some commenters claimed to be required

to implement and maintain compliance programs, the Commission presented

and requested comment on its estimates of the costs associated with

compliance programs. Commenters did not provide any specific cost

estimates to support their assertions of the potential for high costs.

v. Comments on Cross-Border Aspects of the Rule

In response to 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal RFC 67, a

commenter noted that swaps and futures markets have become more global

and suggested that restrictive position limit regulations and added

reporting requirements would drive global companies to jurisdictions

that have more friendly regulatory treatment.\1208\ Another commenter

urged the Commission to consider and assess the costs and benefits of

applying the rules on an extraterritorial basis.\1209\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1208\ CL-IECAssn-60949 at 26.

\1209\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 23.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

vi. Response to Comments on Cross-Border Aspects of the Rule

The Commission considers that market participants might use other

means to engage in derivative activity besides domestic futures and

swaps if federal position limits are set too low. For instance, price

discovery for a futures contract might move to a foreign board of trade

that lists a substitute contract. Further, foreign parties might elect

to engage in foreign swaps instead of transacting in U.S. futures and

swaps. To mitigate these risks, the Commission endeavors not to set the

position limits at levels that are unduly low.

vii. Comments on Quantification of Costs of the Rule

A commenter criticized the Commission's consideration of the costs

and benefits of the proposed rules for

[[Page 96844]]

failing to consider both direct and indirect costs on commodities

markets, market participants, and the economy generally.\1210\ The

Commenter believes that legal precedents require that in order to adopt

a position limit rule, the Commission must find a reasonable likelihood

that excessive speculation will pose a problem in a particular market,

and that position limits are likely to curtail the excessive

speculation without imposing undue costs.\1211\ To the contrary, this

commenter said it had not observed excessive speculation in the years

since the financial crisis and, thus, position limits would only

increase regulatory burdens with no corresponding benefit.\1212\

Moreover, the commenter thinks the Commission did not adequately

quantify the harm that market experts predict position limits will

impose on liquidity for bona fide hedgers, the disruption to the price

discovery function, or the shifting of price discovery offshore. The

commenter also pointed to a lack of quantification of implementation

costs, initial compliance and monitoring costs, and on-going reporting

and monitoring costs for market participants, and the lack of

quantified costs of a limited definition of bona fide hedging which

would require alterations to speculative trading strategies to meet the

definition; the amendments to DCMs' current aggregation and bona fide

hedging policies; or the creation of compliant application regimes for

SEFs.\1213\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1210\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 3-4 and 22. See also CL-ISDA-60370

at 2.

\1211\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 2, 3, citing ISDA, 887 F. Supp. 2d

at 273. The commenter said the Commission should identify marginal

benefits of the rule and evaluate the costs and benefits

appropriately (given limitations on available data). See also CL-

ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 22, n. 83, citing Inv. Co. Inst. v. CFTC, 720

F.3d 370, 378-79 (D.C. Cir. 2013). Another commenter believed that

the Commission must find there is a problem in market pricing as a

result of positions exceeding non-spot month position limits, or a

benefit from prohibiting such excess positions, before adopting

position limits. CL-Working Group-59693 at 61. The commenter is

concerned that, as a result of non-spot month position limits,

parties carrying positions above the limit will lose the market

opportunity experienced in holding the positions, there could be an

immediate reduction in liquidity if those parties must liquidate

those positions, and a reduction in the positions of the market

participants would reduce open interest, reducing subsequent non-

spot month limits and beginning a continuous downward cycle that

eventually would draw liquidity from markets and impact hedgers. Id.

\1212\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 30

\1213\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 24-25

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The commenter cited papers by Craig Pirrong and Philip Verleger as

proper evaluations of the costs and benefits of position limits for

derivatives,\1214\ and asserted that if quantitative information is

lacking the Commission must make guesses, even if imprecise, and

conduct an economic analysis of the likely impact of the proposed

rules.\1215\ In the paper cited by the commenter, Craig Pirrong

suggested that the Commission could provide ``valuable evidence'' about

costs and benefits by documenting for each commodity subject to limits,

using a long period of historical data, how often limits would have

been binding and how much large speculators would have had to reduce

their positions in order to comply with limits.\1216\ He believes it

would be useful to see how often sudden and unreasonable price changes

occurred during the period the limits would have been binding, in

comparison to costs during periods when limits have been binding and

not associated with sudden and unreasonable price changes.\1217\ He

said that a proper cost-benefit analysis should quantify net benefits

relative to the status quo and identify which categories of market

participants benefit, the sources of those benefits, and their

magnitude, and also identify which types of participants are more

likely to incur the costs associated with the limits, identify the

sources of those costs, and quantify them, while providing the data and

information necessary for replication of the analysis.\1218\ Last, Mr.

Pirrong believes the Commission should address potential costs raised

by commenters on the position limit rules proposed in 2011.\1219\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1214\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 22 fn 83

\1215\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 23-24.

\1216\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at Annex B at 5.

\1217\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at Annex B at 5.

\1218\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at Annex B at 5-6.

\1219\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at Annex B at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter also thought that the Commission should perform a

cost-benefit analysis to determine whether non-spot month position

limits are justified. The commenter said that the Commission's

statements that ``few'' participants would exceed the limits is not a

sufficient analysis and that the Commission is obligated to do a more

rigorous analysis before declaring 5, 7, or 11 persons as ``few.''

Further, the commenter pointed out that the Commission has not

specifically stated how often those market participants would have

exceeded those levels, how much over the limit they were, how the

position exceedances were distributed along the price curve, or whether

the positions were calendar spreads, and claimed that the lack of this

information means there is no way to know whether the removal of those

positions would have led to a significant reduction in liquidity and

therefore market participants must assume that such a reduction in

liquidity would have been significant.\1220\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1220\ CL-Working Group-59693 at 61. The commenter also believes

that non-spot month position limits would create a restraint on non-

spot month liquidity due to strip positions along the curve, and

this would create an unnecessary impact on hedgers. Id. at 61-62.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sen. Levin commented that the Commission correctly identified the

prevention and reduction of artificial price disruptions to commodity

markets as a positive benefit that would protect both market

participants and the public, and that would outweigh the cost imposed

on certain speculative traders. Sen. Levin commented that the

Commission correctly observed that the sound risk management practices

required by the proposed rules would benefit speculators, end users,

and consumers.\1221\ Sen. Levin believes these benefits would include:

The promotion of prudent risk management (with Amaranth illustrating

the dangers of poor risk management), and broader economic efficiency,

public welfare, and political security attributable to the availability

and price stability of commodities such as wheat.\1222\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1221\ CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 9.

\1222\ CL-OSEC-59972 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

viii. Response to Comments on Quantification of Costs of the Rule

The Commission does not believe that the consideration of costs and

benefits under CEA section 15(a) requires a quantification of all costs

and benefits. Nor does the statute require the Commission to hazard a

guess when the available information is imprecise. The statute requires

the Commission to consider the costs and benefits of its rulemaking,

which contemplates a qualitative discussion when quantification is

difficult.

The Commission addresses most of the commenter's cost and benefit

concerns later in this consideration of costs and benefits. As for the

identification and quantification of costs and benefits suggested by

Mr. Pirrong, the Commission believes it would be of limited usefulness.

For instance, the quantification would be highly uncertain and require

many subjective interpretations and judgements on the part of

investigators. Further, due to statutory restrictions on its release of

confidential data, the Commission would be unable to provide data and

other information necessary for the public to conduct an independent

replication of the Commission's analysis.

The Commission considered proceeding in stages by first imposing

[[Page 96845]]

position limits in the spot month before imposing then in the single

month and all months combined. The Commission is preliminarily

rejecting this alternative based on the impact analysis, because the

single month and all months combined positon limits are set

sufficiently high to impact only very few market participants. Further,

the Commission believes that most of these participants would qualify

for various exemptions to positions limits.

Another commenter asserted that the CEA directs the Commission to

balance the four factors listed in CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B) and, thus,

the Commission should present rigorous analysis to meet this

requirement.\1223\ In particular, the commenter pointed out that the

Commission has not published an analysis of how the proposed position

limits promote sound risk management and ensure that trading on foreign

boards of trade in the same commodity will be subject to comparable

limits so that position limits do not cause price discovery to shift to

the foreign boards of trade.\1224\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1223\ CL-CMC-59634 at 2.

\1224\ See,CL-CMC-59634 at 3. Cf.CEA section 15(a)(2)(D) (titled

``Costs and Benefits''): ``The costs and benefits of the proposed

Commission action shall be evaluated in light of . . .

considerations of sound risk management practices;'' CEA section

4a(a)(2)(C) (titled ``Goal''): ``In establishing the limits required

under [CEA section 4a(a)(2)(A)], the Commission shall strive to

ensure that trading on foreign boards of trade in the same commodity

will be subject to comparable limits and that any limits to be

imposed by the Commission will note cause price discovery in the

commodity to shift to trading on the foreign boards of trade.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to this commenter, the Commission interprets CEA

section 4a(a)(3)(B) as a direction to the Commission to set limits ``to

the maximum extent practicable'' to further the four policy objectives

in that section. The Commission believes this is a Congressional

recognition of the impossibility of achieving an actual ``maximum'' for

each of the four policy objectives. In any case, as part of this

consideration of costs and benefits, the Commission considers the

promotion of sound risk management practices and whether price

discovery in a commodity will shift to a foreign board of trade.\1225\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1225\ See the discussion of factors 3 (risk management) and 4

(price discovery) under section 15(a), below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ix. Comments on Liquidity Effects

Commenters addressed the effects of position limits on liquidity.

One expressed concern that the proposed position limits may constrain

effective risk transfer by unduly restricting hedging or limiting the

risk-bearing capacity of large speculators, thereby causing reduced

liquidity, wider bid-offer spreads and higher transaction costs.\1226\

Another thought the Commission did not consider that liquidity and

price discovery may be diminished if speculative traders' activities

are restricted.\1227\ In response to 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal RFC 62, another commenter said that price discovery will

improve if market participants are allowed to innovate and grow without

excessive governmental interference and regulatory reporting

costs.\1228\ And in response to 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal RFC 59, this commenter suggested that position limits should

be imposed in a manner that will foster innovation and growth for the

betterment of the markets.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1226\ CL-MFA-60385 at 4.

\1227\ See CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 25. Another commenter asserted

that the Commission determined in 1993 that all-months-combined

position limits are unnecessary and that the benefits of such limits

did not outweigh the likely costs of eroding speculative volume and

liquidity and the disruption in the efficient functioning of the

non-storable commodity futures markets. CL-Working Group-59693 at 61

or CL-CMC. The commenter provided no citations to Commission actions

in 1993. Commission staff believes that the commenter may be

referring to a proposal from CME to eliminate the all-months-

combined limits in the live cattle, live hogs, and feeder cattle

futures and options markets in a March 4, 1993, submission. The

Commission approved the proposal in an August 2, 1993, letter to the

CME.

\1228\ See CL-IECAssn-60949 at 24. Another commenter suggested

that non-spot month position limits operate as a barrier to market

entry for longer dated activities in the name of preventing ``a

shallow threat'' of excessive speculation, and that costs resulting

from position limits would be ultimately passed to the consumer,

harming the American economy. CL-EDF-60398 at 4-5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

x. Response to Comments on Liquidity Effects

Liquidity is not a factor that the Commission is required to

consider under section 15(a) of the CEA; nevertheless, the Commission

did consider how liquidity concerns implicate the 15(a) factors. For

instance, the Commission's regulatory goals generally include

protecting market liquidity, and enhancing market efficiency and

improving price discovery through increased liquidity. The Commission

has sought to reduce market participant burdens with the understanding

that regulatory compliance costs increase transaction costs, which

might reduce liquidity, all else being equal. The Commission has

considered that liquidity, including the risk-bearing capacity of

markets, and price discovery may be harmed if position limits are set

too low and so has sought to avoid these adverse effects.

The Commission preliminarily declines to treat general goals such

as fostering innovation and growth for the betterment of markets as a

specific public interest consideration under CEA section 15(a). While

these are of course laudable objectives, the Commission believes they

are difficult to accomplish through position limits. The Commission has

not cited these general benefits as a reason for position limits. Last,

the Commission notes that exchanges have proper incentives and a

variety of tools with which to increase liquidity on their exchanges

and, as a general matter, make their exchanges useful to the

market.\1229\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1229\ CL-Working Group-59693 at 61-62.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

xi. Comments Referring to Position Accountability

A commenter requested that the Commission compare the costs and

benefits of the proposed position limits regime with those of a

position accountability regime, because the commenter believed that

position accountability levels would serve as a less costly and

disruptive alternative to position limits.\1230\ Another commenter

compared a position accountability process to position limits, and

argued that if the Commission imposes position limits for non-spot

month contracts, the commenter would need to expend significant

resources to ensure that its information technology systems could

identify, gather and report bona fide hedging positions. But under

position accountability, the commenter would be able to reply to a

specific request for additional information using its own internal

reports that have been designed to meet its specific commercial and

risk-management needs. The position accountability approach would

substantially reduce, if not eliminate, the burden of having to conform

information technology systems to the Commission's reporting

requirements.\1231\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1230\ CL-MFA-60385 at 13.

\1231\ CL-Calpine-59663 at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A third commenter also suggested that while administering position

accountability levels, the Commission could conduct a comprehensive

cost-benefit analysis of the impact of spot month position limits on

market liquidity for commercial hedgers and price discovery before

determining whether to extend position limits outside of the spot

months, and use the information collected to understand the trading

activity of market participants with large speculative positions and

determine if non-spot month

[[Page 96846]]

speculative position limits are necessary.\1232\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1232\ CL-FIA-60303 at 3-4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

xii. Response to Comments Referring to Position Accountability

The Commission considered administering position accountability

levels in the non-spot month, but has preliminarily determined that the

adoption of position limits with an exemption process is the better

approach, because it benefits the supervisory functions of the

exchanges and the Commission by providing better insight into the

markets. In addition, the Commission notes it has a lack of statutory

authority for the Commission itself to administer position

accountability levels. Rather, the CEA authorizes exchanges to

administer position accountability levels. In contrast, the

Commission's emergency authority under the CEA is limited. Further, the

Commission notes it interprets CEA section 4a(a)(3) as a direction to

impose, at an appropriate level, position limits on the spot month,

each other month (i.e., single month), and the aggregate of all months.

2. DCM Core Principle 5(B) and SEF Core Principle 6(B), and new

Appendix E to Part 150

a. Summary of Changes

The Commission is reproposing to amend its guidance regarding DCM

core principle 5(B) and SEF core principle 6(B), and adopting a new

Appendix E to Part 150. The amendments have the effect of delaying the

implementation of exchanges' obligation to adopt swap position limits

until there is sufficient access to swap position information regarding

market participants' swap positions.

b. Baseline

The baselines for these changes are the Commission's current

guidance on DCM Core Principle 5, SEF Core Principle 6, and the current

Part 150.

c. Benefits and Costs

Section 15(a) of the CEA requires the Commission to consider the

costs and benefits of its discretionary actions with respect to rules

and orders. The Commission believes it is also appropriate to consider

the costs and benefits of changes to the appendices to parts 37, 38,

and 150 of the Commission's regulations, even though these appendices

constitute guidance. The Commission appreciates that the changes to

this guidance will delay the point in time when exchanges will become

obligated to monitor and enforce federal position limits for swaps

(although exchanges could take voluntary steps in this regard at any

appropriate time). As a result, this change in guidance will likely

confer benefits and reduce costs, although it is difficult to identify

the benefits and costs that result directly from the change in guidance

because the exact time at which exchanges will become obligated to

monitor and enforce federal position limits for swaps is not currently

specified but will instead depend on the future availability of

information. Also, given the interrelationship between the exchanges'

enforcement of federal position limits for swaps with the exchanges'

other actions with respect to position limits and the Commission's

enforcement of federal position limits, it is difficult to identify the

incremental effect that will occur when exchanges become obligated to

enforce federal position limits for swaps.

However, the Commission believes that because of the change in the

Commission's guidance, exchanges and market participants will benefit

because the delay will result in a lower requirement to invest in

technology and personnel to assess federal position limits. In terms of

costs, the Commission believes that there might be a cost to the market

associated with this change in guidance because the delay may result in

exchanges' reducing their monitoring of excessive positions in real-

time.\1233\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1233\ As stated in Section IIA, the Commission foresees various

possibilities in remediating this current inability to monitor

position limits in real-time in the future.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

d. Summary of Comments

The Commission requested comment on its consideration of the

benefits and costs associated with the proposed amendments to guidance,

and asked if there are additional alternatives that the Commission has

not identified. Two commenters requested that the Commission formulate

a plan to address the lack of data access by DCMs and SEFs.\1234\ These

commenters did not provide a detailed alternative, however. On the

other hand, one commenter asserted that there should be no delay in

implementing position limits for swaps because, according to the

commenter, the Commission has access to sufficient swap data it needs

to implement position limits.\1235\ The Commission is considering

various alternatives, but has not made a determination on which

direction to take.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1234\ CL-AFR-60953 at 2; CL-RER2-60962 at 1.

\1235\ CL-Better Markets-60928 at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. Section 150.1--Definitions

The Commission is reproposing new definitions of, or amendments to

the definitions of, several terms: Basis contract, bona fide hedge,

calendar spread contract, commodity derivative contract, commodity

index contract, core referenced futures contract, eligible affiliate,

entity, excluded commodity, futures-equivalent, intercommodity spread,

long position, short position, spot month, intermarket spread, physical

commodity, pre-enactment swap, pre-existing position, referenced

contract, spread contract, speculative position limit, swap, swap

dealer, and transition period. These new definitions and amendments are

discussed above.

a. Benefits and Costs

A general benefit of including definitions in the regulation is

greater clarity. In particular, having specific definitions of terms

set out as a separate part of the regulations helps users of the

regulation to understand how the position limit rulemaking relates, in

general, to the concepts and terminology of CEA as amended by the Dodd-

Frank Act. Although market participants and other users of the

regulations must take time and effort to understand and adapt to new

definitions in the context of the rulemaking, the Commission believes

these costs are reduced by setting out the definitions as a separate

part of the regulations rather than incorporating the definitions in

the substantive provisions of the rules.

Specific benefits and costs of definitions are discussed within the

context of specific rules where the definitions are directly

applicable. In addition, the Commission believes that several

definitions merit a specific consideration of costs and benefits,

because the adoption of these definitions would represent the exercise

of substantive discretion on the part of the Commission.

b. Bona Fide Hedging Position

i. Summary of Changes

The Commission is reproposing a definition of bona fide hedging

position in Sec. 150.1. The Commission believes this definition of

bona fide hedging position is consistent with CEA section 4a(c)

regarding physical commodities and otherwise closely conforms to the

status quo. Commercial cash market activities are covered by the part

of the definition that sets out an economically appropriate test. The

Commission also notes that since CEA 4c(a)(5) separately states that

intentional or reckless

[[Page 96847]]

disregard for orderly trading execution is unlawful and because it is

unclear how a market participant would comply with an orderly trading

requirement in the context of OTC transactions, the Commission is

proposing to delete the orderly trading requirement in the definition

of bona fide hedging position. The Commission's addition of sub-

paragraph (2)(iii)(C) to the definition of bona fide hedging position

in Sec. 150.1 reiterates the Commission's authority to permit

exchanges to recognize bona fide hedging positions in accordance with

Sec. 150.9(a). Those positions are subject to CEA section 4a(c)

standards as well as Commission review.

ii. Baseline

The baseline for this amendment to the rule is the definition for

``bona fide hedging transactions and positions,'' set forth in current

Sec. 1.3(z).\1236\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1236\ 17 CFR 1.3(z) (2010). As discussed above, a district

court generally vacated the Commission's part 151 rulemaking, that

would have amended Sec. 1.3(z) to apply only to excluded

commodities. However, the Commission has not instructed the Federal

Register to roll back those vacated amendments. Thus, the current

version of Sec. 1.3(z) is found in the 2010 or earlier version of

the CFR.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iii. Benefits and Costs

Futures contracts function to hedge price risk because they allow a

party to fix a price for a specified quantity of a particular commodity

at a designated point in time. Futures contracts, thereby, can be used

by market participants to create price certainty for physically-settled

transactions. Thus, the Commission believes that to qualify as a bona

fide hedging position for a physical commodity, the position must

ultimately result in hedging against some form of price risk in the

physical marketing channel.

The Commission is amending the five day/spot month rule so that it

will allow exchanges to grant spread exemptions that are valid in the

five day/spot month period. The Commission anticipates that allowing

spread exemptions to be recognized in the spot month might improve

liquidity and, thereby, lower costs for market participants.

Also, the rule amendments will allow bona fide hedge exemptions to

cover a period of more than one year of cash market exposure. The

current definition limits to one year the hedging of anticipated

production of, or requirements for, an agricultural commodity. Removing

this current restriction is desirable because many commercial

enterprises may prefer to hedge cash market exposure for more than one

year.

The Commission understands that some activity that may have been

recognized by exchanges as bona fide hedging in the past may not

satisfy the definition in the reproposed rule. The Commission has

sought to mitigate costs arising from this transition by setting

position limits at levels that are appropriately high (so as to limit

the extent of positions that may require an exemption) and by not

including any requirement that exchanges use the reproposed rule's

definition of bona fide hedging position other than with respect to the

federal position limits in the referenced contracts listed in 150.2(d).

The Commission notes that an exchange is permitted to recognize

exemptions for non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions, certain

spread positions, and anticipatory bona fide hedging positions, under

the processes of Sec. 150.9, 150.10 and 150.11, respectively, subject

to assessment of the particular facts and circumstances, where price

risk arises as a result of other fact patterns than those of the

enumerated positions. The Commission expects to review with an open

mind any hedging activity that exchanges choose to exempt as bona fide

hedging positions with respect to federal position limits. The

Commission believes, however, that it would be inappropriate to allow

the exchanges to act with unbounded discretion in interpreting the

meaning of the term ``economically appropriate'' when the exchanges

determine whether to recognize an exemption for bona fide hedging. Such

a broad delegation is not authorized by the CEA and, in the

Commission's view, would be contrary to the reasonably certain

statutory standards in CEA section 4a(c), such as the ``economically

appropriate'' test. That is, if the statutory standards are reasonable

certain, then the Commission may delegate authority to exchanges. If

the statutory standards were not reasonably certain, then the

Commission would be precluded from delegating authority to the

exchanges. Further, as explained in the discussion of Sec. 150.9,

150.10 and 150.11, exchange determinations in this regard will be

subject to the Commission's de novo review.

iv. Summary of Comments

Several commenters said that the rule's definition of bona fide

hedging position should be expanded in various ways that would extend

the scope of the definition to include the hedging of a wider variety

of risks, in addition to price risk. For example, one commenter claimed

that hedging some of the risks and costs associated with building

energy infrastructure may not satisfy the bona fide hedging position

definition, and that as a result some of these costs would likely be

passed onto consumers.\1237\ A commenter representing asset managers

said that the final rule should include a risk management exemption,

including for commodity index contract positions, because the

availability of such an exemption would reduce compliance costs and

reduce negative consequences for liquidity and price discovery, while

providing the same benefit in terms of preventing excessive

speculation.\1238\ A third commenter asserted that the ``specifically

enumerated'' criterion in the proposed definition would constrain risk

management activities by effectively reclassifying large risk reducing

positions as excessive speculation.\1239\ On the other hand, a fourth

commenter believed that the definition of bona fide hedging position in

the supplemental proposal will benefit consumers through lower prices

enabled by an efficient hedging mechanism as existing strategies remain

readily available.\1240\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1237\ CL-Working Group-59693at 23-26.

\1238\ CL-AMG-60946 at 2-3.

\1239\ CL-CME-59718 at 47.

\1240\ CL-NGFA-60941 at 2-3

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter asserted that the correlation standards in the

proposed rule would make the bona fide hedging position exemption

unavailable for hedges related to illiquid delivery locations and

result in higher risks for market participants and higher costs for

consumers.\1241\ Along similar lines, another commenter said the

Commission had not sufficiently considered the commonly accepted

accounting practice of entering into economic hedges or sufficiently

analyzed the costs and burdens to companies that engage in economic

hedging of applying the 0.80 correlation for cross-commodity hedging

required in the final rule.\1242\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1241\ See, e.g., CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 14. The commenter

believes that the Commission evaluated only correlation during the

spot month, but not the closer correlation that typically exists in

the non-spot months. Id.

\1242\ CL-NRG at 5

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission believes that the definition of bona fide hedging

position and the related exemption process in the reproposed rule will

accommodate many existing hedging strategies that market participants

use. As it would be impossible to enumerate every acceptable bona fide

hedging activity, the Commission has preliminarily determined that it

is appropriate to rely on the experience and expertise of exchanges to

process these exemptions. The Commission believes that the exchanges

will be better placed to

[[Page 96848]]

determine which activities qualify for bona fide hedging position

exemptions based on the applicable facts and circumstances. The

Commission anticipates that the exchanges' role in administering bona

fide hedging position exemptions will help to mitigate the potential

adverse effects that commenters attributed to an overly narrow

application of such exemptions.\1243\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1243\ For example, the Commission believes that the exchanges'

involvement in this process is more flexible and far superior to

setting out regulatory safe harbors for factors such as a linear

correlation in the spot month that may demonstrate a position

qualifies for the exemption.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Regarding commenters' suggestions that the definition of bona fide

hedging position be expanded to encompass hedges of risks other than

risks related to prices in physical marketing channels, the Commission

notes that many risks come into play outside the physical marketing

channel to which referenced contracts relate. The Commission has

preliminarily determined that hedging of these other risks should not

be covered by the bona fide hedging position definition, because the

Commission views the statutory standards in CEA section 4a(c)(2),

largely mirroring those of the general definition of a bona fide

hedging position in Sec. 1.3(z)(1), to be reasonably certain as

limited to hedges of price risks. Further, as explained above, the

statutory standard of CEA section 4a(c) requires bona fide hedging

positions to be a substitute for a transaction taken or to be taken in

the cash market. Generally, this precludes application of the bona fide

hedging exemption to hedging of purely financial risks that are not

price risks related to the physical marketing channel. For example,

commodity index contracts are not eligible for recognition as the basis

of a bona fide hedging position exemption because these contracts are

not used to hedge price risks in physical marketing channels, as

required in CEA section 4a(c)(2)(A)(i), and, as well, would not meet

the requirements for a bona fide hedging position as a pass-through

swap offset under CEA section 4a(c)(2)(B).

Commenters also addressed the element of the bona fide hedging

position definition that generally requires that hedges be considered

on a net basis in determining whether the definition is satisfied. One

commenter argued that hedging on a net basis would be unworkable and

require costly new technology systems to be built around more rigid,

commercially impractical hedging protocols that prevent dynamic risk

management in response to rapidly changing market conditions.\1244\

Another commenter asserted that hedging on a gross basis is

economically appropriate in a variety of circumstances and the

Commission's proposal would limit market participants' ability to hedge

the risks associated with their commercial activities, potentially

resulting in increased costs and volatility that could detrimentally

impact the market participants and lead to higher prices for

consumers.\1245\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1244\ See, e.g., CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 15, CL-EEI-Sup-60386 at

7. See also CL-Calpine-59663 at 7.

\1245\ CL-Olam-59946 at 1.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission believes that it is fundamental to the definition of

bona fide hedging position to require that such hedging reduce the

overall risk of the commercial enterprise. Consistent with that focus

on overall risk, it should be noted that the Commission does recognize

certain gross hedges, e.g., the use of a calendar month spread position

to hedge the price risk of a soybean crush processor, because those

gross hedges reduce overall risk. That is, in applying the definition

one must consider whether a hedge reduces the overall risk of the

commercial enterprise, and overall risks must be determined on a net

basis.\1246\ In this aspect, too, the Commission believes that the

involvement of exchanges in the bona fide hedge exemption process will

be valuable, and the Commission would expect to consider the

determinations of exchanges in this regard with an open mind.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1246\ See the Commission determination regarding comments on

specific, identifiable risks, above, for an explanation of why it

would be inappropriate to apply the bona fide hedging definition on

an item by item basis.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Four commenters expressed opposition to an aspect of the proposal

in the supplemental notice that would not allow hedge exemptions for

spread transactions to be applied during the last five days of trading

of a futures contract, saying that spread exemptions should be allowed

into the spot month to avoid negative effects on liquidity and

potential disruptions of convergence, potentially resulting in

additional risk for market participants which ultimately gets passed to

consumers.\1247\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1247\ See CL-NCGA-ASA-60917 at 7; CL-IECAssn-60949 at 25; and

CL-FIA-60937 at 18-19.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission agrees with commenters that allowing spread

exemptions to be applied in the spot month might improve liquidity and

lower risks for market participants. Thus, the Reproposal would permit

exchanges to grant Sec. 150.10 spread exemptions into the five day/

spot period. The costs and benefits of the forms are considered in the

discussion of Part 19 and rule 150.7.

c. Core Referenced Futures Contract and Referenced Contract

i. Summary of Changes

The Commission proposes to define the term ``core referenced

futures contract'' and amend the list of contracts in Sec. 150.2. The

effect of this is that the federal positon limits in Sec. 150.2(d)

will apply to the following additional contracts: Rough Rice, Live

Cattle, Cocoa, Coffee, Frozen Orange Juice, U.S. Sugar No. 11, U.S.

Sugar No. 16, Light Sweet Crude Oil, NY Harbor ULSD, RBOB Gasoline,

Henry Hub Natural Gas, Gold, Silver, Copper, Palladium, and Platinum.

ii. Baseline

The baseline for the definition of the term ``core referenced

futures contract'' is that the term encompasses the legacy agricultural

futures contracts that are subject to existing federal position limits,

namely: Corn (and Mini-Corn), Oats, Soybeans (and Mini-Soybeans), Wheat

(Mini-Wheat), Soybean Oil, Hard Winter Wheat, Hard Red Spring Wheat,

and Cotton No. 2. The baseline for the definition of the term

``referenced contract'' is the same as that of the term ``core

referenced futures contract.''

iii. Benefits and Costs

The definitions of the terms ``core referenced futures contract''

and ``referenced contract'' set the scope of contracts to which federal

position limits apply. As noted above, the Commission has preliminarily

decided to proceed in stages when imposing federal position limits.

Among other things, this will allow the Commission to observe how

futures markets respond to an initial set of position limits before

applying position limits more widely, including to contracts with less

liquidity. All other things being equal, markets for contracts that are

more illiquid tend to be more concentrated, so that a position limit on

such contracts might significantly reduce trading interest on one side

of the market, because a large trader would face the potential of being

capped out by a position limit. For this reason, among others, the

contracts to which the position limits in Sec. 150.2(d) apply include

some of the most liquid physical-delivery futures contracts. Following

the application of position limits to these contracts, the Commission

would be able to study the effects of position limits more readily and,

it is anticipated, consider how to apply position limits more broadly

in a

[[Page 96849]]

way that would not unduly restrain liquidity in less liquid markets.

The Commission has also preliminarily determined not to apply

position limits to cash-settled core referenced futures contracts (that

are not linked to physical-delivery futures contracts) at this time.

For these contracts, the possibility of corners and squeezes is

reduced, because there is no link to a physical-delivery futures

contract that may be distorted, and therefore there is less of a need

for position limits. Of course, there may be other concerns about

manipulation of cash-settled futures contracts that are not linked to

physical-delivery futures contracts, however. For instance, there may

be an incentive to manipulate a commodity price index in a manner that

would benefit particular cash-settled futures or swap positions. Such

manipulative conduct includes cornering or squeezing the underlying

cash market on which a cash-settlement index is based. The Commission

notes that these manipulation concerns may be addressed, in part,

through the Commission's authority to regulate futures and swaps

(including the terms of these contracts set by exchanges) and take

enforcement actions, until such time as the Commission adopts position

limits on cash-settled core referenced futures contracts. Further,

exchanges in their SRO function may also constrain and discipline

traders who are trading in a disruptive fashion. Indeed, it is

reasonable to expect that, given the exchanges' deep familiarity with

their own markets and their ability to tailor a response to a

particular market disruption, such exchange action is likely to be more

effective than a position limit in such circumstances. However, the

Commission notes the exchanges do not have authority over those persons

who only transact in OTC swaps.

The Commission has preliminarily determined to exclude trade

options from the rule's definition of ``referenced contract,'' for

several reasons. The Commission believes that many trade options would

qualify for bona fide hedging position exemptions, since trade options

are generally used to hedge risks. The Commission also believes that

not including trade options in the scope of position limits will

relieve many market participants of significant compliance costs that

would be required to apply position limits to trade options. Last, this

approach will allow the market to continue to innovate in the use of

trade options to hedge a variety of risks.

The rule's definition of the term ``referenced contract'' includes

a swap or futures contract that is ``indirectly linked'' to a physical-

delivery futures contract. The ``indirectly linked'' contract could be

a cash-settled swap or cash-settled futures contract that settles to

the price of another cash-settled derivative that, in turn settles to

the price of a physical-delivery futures contract. A contract that

settles based on the level of a commodity price index, comprised of

commodities that are not the same or substantially the same, would not

be an ``indirectly linked'' contract, even if the index uses futures

prices as components. A contract based on such a commodity price index

is excluded because the index represents a blend of the prices of

various commodities.

The Reproposal's definition of the term ``referenced contract''

does not include a swap or futures contract that fixes its closing

price on the prices of the same commodity at different delivery

locations than specified in the core referenced futures contract, or on

the prices of commodities with different commodity specifications than

those of the core referenced futures contract. This approach is also in

accord with market practice, in that a core referenced futures contract

specifies location(s) and grade(s) of a commodity in the relevant

contract specification. Thus, a contract on one grade of commodity is

treated by the market as different from a contract on a different grade

of the same commodity.

A location basis contract--a contract which reflects the difference

between two delivery locations of the same commodity--is also excluded

from the definition of referenced contract.\1248\ A location basis

contract may be used to hedge price risks relating to delivery at a

location other than that of the core referenced futures contract. For

instance, a location basis contract can be used in combination with a

referenced contract to create a synthetic derivative contract on a

commodity at a different delivery location, with a resulting zero net

position in the referenced contract. However, a location basis contract

that had a relatively small difference in location with that of the

core referenced futures contract likely would not expose a speculator

to significant price risk. Absent the exclusion of location basis

contracts from the definition of referenced contract, such a speculator

could increase exposure to a referenced contract by netting down, using

such a location basis contract, the position that would otherwise be

restricted by a position limit on the referenced contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1248\ The defined term ``location basis contract'' generally

means a derivative that is cash-settled based on the difference in

price, directly or indirectly, of (1) a core referenced future

contract; and (2) the same commodity underlying a particular core

referenced futures contract at a different delivery location than

that of the core referenced futures contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iv. Summary of Comments

Commenters said that trade options should not be included in the

definition of ``referenced contract.'' One commenter said there is

significant uncertainty about the distinction between forward contracts

and trade options, so costs associated with imposing position limits on

trade options would greatly exceed any benefits.\1249\ Another argued

that because trade options have never been subject to position limits,

commercial parties do not have any systems in place to: Distinguish

between trade options that are referenced contracts and those that are

not; monitor the number and quantity of referenced-contract trade

option positions across delivery points and trading venues; and

integrate them with other position tracking systems.\1250\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1249\ CL-FIA-59595 at 20.

\1250\ See, e.g., CL-NGSA-59674 at 33; CL-NGSA-59900 at 9.

Another commenter made a more general assertion that the costs of

monitoring positions subject to a limit, including reporting costs,

would drive commercial market participants to the spot markets and

cause them to restrict the variability provided to customers, if

trade options or forward contracts with optionality were subject to

position limits. CL-Calpine-59663 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission took the difficulties explained by commenters in

complying with position limits on trade options into account when

preliminarily determining not to include trade options in the

definition of referenced contract. To provide flexibility, the

reproposed rule permits trade options to be taken into consideration as

a cash position, on a futures-equivalent basis, as the basis of a bona

fide hedging position.

Another commenter discussed the exclusion of commodity index swaps

from the definition of swaps that are economically equivalent to core

referenced futures contracts. This commenter said this disparate

treatment will shift trading activity to index swaps, drain liquidity

from exchange-listed products, harm pre-trade transparency and the

price discovery process, and further depress open interest (as volumes

shift to index swap positions that do not count toward open interest

calculations).\1251\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1251\ CL-Citadel-59933 at 1-3. The commenter also made two

recommendations relevant to the definition of core referenced

futures contract: That position limits for cash-settled contracts

are not warranted and that commodity index swaps should not be

treated differently than other cash-settled contracts: Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96850]]

The Commission acknowledges uncertainty about whether there will be

a loss in liquidity due to the imposition of federal position limits.

The Commission will monitor this issue going forward.

Another commenter suggested that the definition of bona fide

hedging position should include the hedging of a binding and

irrevocable bid, because a failure to do so could increase the costs

incurred by utilities and special entities to provide power or gas by

forcing bidders to incorporate into their bids or offers the cost

associated with the risk that no exemption for such a hedge would be

permitted.\1252\ In response, the Commission points out that, under

reproposed Sec. 150.9, a bidder may seek recognition of a non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position, under which an exchange may

consider the facts and circumstances on a case-by-case basis.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1252\ See, e.g., CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 18.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

d. Futures Equivalent

i. Summary of Changes

The Commission is reproposing two further revisions to the

definition of ``futures-equivalent'' in the rule. The first revision

clarifies that the term ``futures-equivalent'' includes a futures

contract which has been converted to an economically equivalent amount

of an open position in a core referenced futures contract. Second, the

Commission clarifies that, for purposes of calculating futures

equivalents, the size of an open position represented by an option

contract must be determined as the economically-equivalent amount of an

open position in a core referenced futures contract.

ii. Baseline

The baseline for this change to the rule's definition of ``futures

equivalent'' is the current Sec. 150.1(f) definition of ``futures-

equivalent''.

iii. Benefits and Costs

The Commission has preliminarily determined that the definition of

``futures-equivalent'' in current Sec. 150.1(f) is too narrow in light

of the Dodd-Frank Act amendments to CEA section 4a. To conform to the

statutory changes and to make the definition more amenable to

application within the broader position limits regime, the Commission

is reproposing a more descriptive definition of the term ``futures-

equivalent'' by adding more explanatory text. The Commission continues

to believe that, as it stated in the proposal, there are no cost or

benefit implications to these further clarifications.

iv. Summary of Comments

The Commission requested comment on the revisions to the definition

of the term ``futures equivalent,'' but did not receive any substantive

comments. Consequently, the Commission is reproposing the definition in

the Supplemental 2016 position limit proposal.

e. Intermarket Spread Position and Intramarket Spread Position

i. Summary of Changes

Current part 150 does not contain definitions for the terms

``intermarket spread position'' or ``intramarket spread position.'' In

the Supplemental 2016 Position Limits Proposal the Commission proposed

to expand the scope of definitions of these terms that had been

included in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal. The expanded

definitions of ``intermarket spread position'' or ``intramarket spread

position'' include positions in multiple commodity derivative

contracts. This expansion would allow market participants to establish

an intermarket spread position or an intramarket spread position that

would be taken into account under the position limits regime and

exemption processes. The expanded definitions also cover spread

positions established by taking positions in derivative contracts in

the same commodity, in similar commodities, or in the products or by-

products of the same or similar commodities.

ii. Baseline

Current Sec. 150.1 does not include definitions for the terms

``intermarket spread position'' and ``intramarket spread position.''

Therefore, the baseline is a market where ``intermarket'' and

``intramarket'' spread positions are not explicitly included in the

definition of contracts that are exempt from federal position limits.

iii. Benefits and Costs

The changes to the definitions of the terms ``intermarket spread

position'' and ``intermarket spread positions'' broaden the scope of

the two terms in comparison to the definitions proposed in the December

2013 Position Limits Proposal. In the Commission's view, the changes

are only operative in the application of Sec. Sec. 150.3, 150.5 and

150.10, which address exemptions from position limits for certain

spread positions. The two definitions operate in conjunction with Sec.

150.10, which sets forth a process for exchanges to administer spread

exemptions. The definitions and Sec. 150.10, together, will enable

market participants to obtain relief from position limits for these

types of spreads, among others.

iv. Summary of Comments

Citadel recommended that cross-commodity netting should be

permitted.\1253\ The Commission preliminarily declines to permit cross-

commodity netting within a particular referenced contract. However, the

Commission addresses cross-commodity netting in the context of

authorizing exchanges to recognize spread exemptions under reproposed

Sec. 150.10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1253\ CL-Citadel-59933 at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

4. Section 150.2--Speculative Position Limits

a. Rule Summary

As previously discussed, the Commission interprets CEA section

4a(a)(2) to mandate that it establish speculative position limits for

all agricultural and exempt physical commodity derivative contracts

and, as a separate and independent basis for this rulemaking, has made

a preliminary finding that position limits are necessary as a

prophylactic measure to carry out the purposes of section 4a(a).\1254\

The Commission currently sets and enforces speculative position limits

for futures and futures-equivalent options contracts on nine

agricultural products. Specifically, current Sec. 150.2 provides

``[n]o person may hold or control positions, separately or in

combination, net long or net short, for the purchase or sale of a

commodity for future delivery or, on a futures-equivalent basis,

options thereon, in excess of [enumerated spot, single-month, and all-

month levels for nine specified contracts].'' \1255\ The Commission

proposed to amend Sec. 150.2 to expand the scope of federal position

limits regulation in three chief ways: (1) Specify limits on 16

contracts in addition to the nine existing legacy contracts (i.e., a

total of 25); (2) extend the application of these limits beyond futures

and futures-equivalent options to all commodity derivative interests,

including swaps; and (3) extend the application of these limits across

trading venues to all economically equivalent contracts that are based

on the same

[[Page 96851]]

underlying commodity. In addition, the Commission's proposed rule

included methods and procedures for implementing and applying the

expanded limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1254\ See supra discussion of the Commission's interpretation

of this mandate and the alternative necessity finding.

\1255\ These contracts are Chicago Board of Trade corn and mini-

corn, oats, soybeans and mini-soybeans, wheat and mini-wheat,

soybean oil, and soybean meal; Minneapolis Grain Exchange hard red

spring wheat; ICE Futures U.S. cotton No. 2; and Kansas City Board

of Trade hard winter wheat.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is reproposing amendments to Sec. 150.2 to impose

speculative position limits as mandated by Congress in accordance with

the statutory bounds that define the Commission's discretion in doing

so and, as a separate and independent basis for the Reproposal, because

the speculative position limits are necessary to achieve their

statutory purposes.\1256\ First, pursuant to CEA section 4a(a)(5) the

Commission must concurrently impose position limits on swaps that are

economically equivalent to the agricultural and exempt commodity

derivatives for which position limits are mandated in CEA section

4a(a)(2), and for which the Commission separately finds position limits

are necessary. Second, CEA section 4a(a)(3) requires that the

Commission appropriately set limit levels mandated and/or found

necessary under section 4a(a)(2) that ``to the maximum extent

practicable, in its discretion,'' accomplish four specific

objectives.\1257\ Third, CEA section 4a(a)(2)(C) requires that in

setting limits mandated (or adopted as necessary) under section

4a(a)(2)(A), the ``Commission shall strive to ensure that trading on

foreign boards of trade in the same commodity will be subject to

comparable limits and that any limits. . . imposed. . .will not cause

price discovery in the commodity to shift to trading on the foreign

boards of trade.'' Key elements of the reproposed rule are summarized

below.\1258\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1256\ See supra discussion of the Commission's necessity

finding.

\1257\ These objectives are to: (1) ``diminish, eliminate, or

prevent excessive speculation;'' (2) ``deter and prevent market

manipulation, squeezes, and corners;'' (3) ``ensure sufficient

market liquidity for bona fide hedgers;'' and (4) ``ensure that the

price discovery function of the underlying market is not

disrupted.'' 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(3).

\1258\ For a more detailed description, see discussion above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Generally, Sec. 150.2 will limit the size of speculative

positions,\1259\ i.e., prohibit any person from holding or controlling

net long/short positions above certain specified spot month, single

month, and all-months-combined position limits. These position limits

will reach: (1) 25 ``core referenced futures contracts,'' \1260\

representing an expansion of 16 contracts beyond the 9 legacy

agricultural contracts identified currently in Sec. 150.2; \1261\ (2)

a newly defined category of ``referenced contracts'' (as defined in

Sec. 150.1); \1262\ and (3) across all trading venues to all

economically equivalent contracts that are based on the same underlying

commodity.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1259\ Sec. 150.1 includes a definition of the term

``speculative position limits.''

\1260\ Sec. 150.1 defines the term ``core referenced futures

contract'' by reference to ``a futures contract that is listed in

Sec. 150.2(d).''

\1261\ Specifically, in addition to the existing 9 legacy

agricultural contracts now within Sec. 150.2--i.e., Chicago Board

of Trade corn (C), oats (O), soybeans (S), soybean oil (SO), soybean

meal (SM), and wheat (W); Minneapolis Grain Exchange hard red spring

wheat (MWE); ICE Futures U.S. cotton No. 2 (CT); and Kansas City

Board of Trade hard winter wheat (KW)--proposed Sec. 150.2 would

expand the list of core referenced futures contracts to capture the

following additional agricultural, energy, and metal contracts:

Chicago Board of Trade Rough Rice (RR); ICE Futures U.S. Cocoa (CC),

Coffee C (KC), FCOJ-A (OJ), Sugar No. 11 (SB) and Sugar No. 16 (SF);

Chicago Mercantile Exchange Live Cattle (LC); Commodity Exchange,

Inc., Gold (GC), Silver (SI) and Copper (HG); and New York

Mercantile Exchange Palladium (PA), Platinum (PL), Light Sweet Crude

Oil (CL), NY Harbor ULSD (HO), RBOB Gasoline (RB) and Henry Hub

Natural Gas (NG). The Commission originally proposed in its 2013 to

set position limits on 28 core referenced contracts, including the

25 contracts noted above plus CME Feeder Cattle, Lean Hog and Class

III Milk. Those three contracts will not be included in the

Reproposal for the reasons discussed above.

\1262\ This would result in the application of prescribed

position limits to a number of contract types with prices that are

or should be closely correlated to the prices of the 25 core

referenced futures contracts--i.e., economically equivalent

contracts--including: (1) ``look-alike'' contracts (i.e., those that

settle off of the core referenced futures contract and contracts

that are based on the same commodity for the same delivery location

as the core referenced futures contract); (2) contracts based on an

index comprised of one or more prices for the same delivery location

and in the same or substantially the same commodity underlying a

core referenced futures contract; and (3) inter-commodity spreads

with two components, one or both of which are referenced contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Sec. 150.2(a) Spot-Month Speculative Position Limits

i. Summary of Changes

In order to implement CEA section 4a(a)(3)(A), reproposed rule

Sec. 150.2(a) prohibits any person from holding or controlling

positions in referenced contracts in the spot month in excess of the

level specified by the Commission for referenced contracts.\1263\

Additionally, Sec. 150.2(a) requires that a trader's positions, net

long or net short, in the physical-delivery referenced contract and

linked cash-settled referenced contract be calculated separately under

the spot month position limits fixed by the Commission for each. As a

result, a trader could hold positions up to the applicable spot month

limit in the physical-delivery contracts, as well as positions up to

the applicable spot month limit in linked cash-settled contracts (i.e.,

cash-settled futures and swaps), but would not be able to net across

physical-delivery and cash-settled contracts in the spot month.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1263\ As discussed supra, the Commission is reproposing to

adopt a streamlined, amended definition of ``spot month'' in Sec.

150.1. The term is defined as the trading period immediately

preceding the delivery period for a physical-delivery futures

contract and cash-settled swaps and futures contracts that are

linked to the physical-delivery contract. The definition provides

that the spot month for cash-settled contracts is that same period

as that of the core referenced futures contract. For more details,

see discussion above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Baseline

To the extent the Commission has correctly interpreted that CEA

section 4a(a)(2) mandates position limits, the costs and benefits of

whether to require position limits have been balanced by Congress and

the Commission is not tasked with revisiting those costs and benefits

on that specific question.\1264\ To the extent the Reproposal rests on

the preliminary alternative necessity finding, the baseline is the

current Sec. 150.2 of the Commission's regulations.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1264\ See Nat'l Ass'n of Mfrs. v. SEC, 748 F.3d 359, 369-70

(D.C. Cir. 2014).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iii. Benefits and Costs

As discussed above, CEA section 4a(a)(3)(A) directs the Commission,

each time it establishes limits, to set limits on speculative positions

during the spot-month.\1265\ It is during the spot-month period that

concerns regarding certain manipulative behaviors, such as corners and

squeezes, become most urgent.\1266\ The Commission has for decades

applied guidance that spot-month position limits for physical-delivery

futures contracts should be equal to no more than one-quarter of the

estimated deliverable supply for that commodity. Spot-month position

limits provide benefits to the market by restricting speculators'

ability to amass market power, regardless of whether there is intent to

manipulate or distort the market. In so doing, spot-month position

limits restrict the ability of speculators to engage in corners and

squeezes and other forms of manipulation. They also prevent the

potential adverse impacts of unduly large positions even in the absence

of manipulation, thereby promoting a more orderly liquidation process

for each contract and fostering convergence between the expiring core

referenced futures contract and its underlying cash market. This makes

the core referenced futures contract more useful for hedging cash

market positions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1265\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(3)(A).

\1266\ See discussion above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For example, as discussed above, the absence of manipulative intent

behind excessive speculation does not preclude the risk that

accumulation of very large positions will cause the negative

[[Page 96852]]

consequences of the types observed in the Hunt and Amaranth incidents.

Moreover, it is often difficult to discern manipulative intent. That is

one reason position limits are valuable as a prophylactic measure for,

in the language of Section 4a(a)(1), ``preventing'' burdens on

interstate commerce. The Hunt brothers and Amaranth examples illustrate

the burdens on interstate commerce of excessive speculation that

occurred in the absence of position limits, and position limits would

have restricted those traders' ability to cause unwarranted price

movement and market volatility. This would be so even had their

motivations been innocent. Both episodes involved extraordinarily large

speculative positions, which the Commission has historically associated

with excessive speculation.\1267\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1267\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR 75685 n.

60.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Exchanges and market participants also benefit from spot-month

position limits because market participants who seek exemptions to the

spot-month limit will have to justify why their positions qualify for

the exemption, which fosters visibility into the market for the

exchanges and fosters better risk management practices for the market

participant seeking the exemption.

In its determination of the appropriate spot month levels for the

core referenced futures contracts, the Commission took into account

exchange estimates of deliverable supply, which were verified by the

Commission staff, and exchange spot-month limit level recommendations.

A more detailed discussion of the costs and benefits for the actual

limits can be found below in the discussion of 150.2(d). However, more

generally, the Commission recognizes federal spot month position limits

do impose costs to exchanges and market participants. Federal spot

month limits will require hedgers to apply for exemptions if they hold

positions in excess of the federal limits. These costs are considered

in the discussion of 150.3. In addition, speculators who want exposure

beyond the federal limit for a referenced contract will incur costs to

trade in instruments that are not subject to federal limits, such as

trade options and bespoke swaps, which typically incur more expensive

transactions costs than exchange traded futures and swaps.

Furthermore, as discussed above, exchanges may choose to adopt

spot-month limits below the federal limit. Market participants who are

hedging their cash market positions would incur costs of having to

apply for an exemption from the exchange if their hedging positons are

above the lower limit set by the exchange. Otherwise, a market

participant who wants speculative exposure above the lower limit, but

who does not qualify for an exemption, would have to take speculative

positions in other instruments not subject to exchange or Federal

position limits, which as noted above may involve higher transaction

costs.

The Commission also recognizes that there are costs to setting

federal spot-month limits too high or too low. If the Federal spot-

month limit is too high, the exchanges and the Commission lose

visibility into market activity because the number of exemption

applications from market participants will be reduced because of the

higher limit. In addition, if limits are too high, market participants

could obtain positions that would impact the price of the commodity,

possibly manipulating or distorting the futures price, thus impairing

the price discovery process of the core referenced futures contract.

Furthermore, if a market participant establishes a very large position

and then has to unwind its position, there could be an adverse impact

on the price of the core referenced futures contract (e.g., as occurred

with Amaranth).

Conversely, if the Federal spot-month limit is too low, market

participants and exchanges would incur larger costs to apply for and

process, respectively, more exemption applications. In addition, as

noted above, transactions costs for market participants who are near or

above the limit would rise as they transact in other instruments with

higher transaction costs to obtain their desired level of speculative

positions. Additionally, limits that are too low could incentivize

speculators to leave the market and not be available to provide

liquidity for hedgers, resulting in ``choppy'' prices and reduced

market efficiency.\1268\ Further, option premiums would likely increase

to account for the more volatile prices of the underlying core

referenced futures contract. Moreover, if confidence in the price of

the core referenced futures contract erodes, market participants may

move to another DCM or FBOT.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1268\ ``Choppy'' prices often refers to illiquidity in a market

where transacted prices bounce between the bid and the ask prices.

Market efficiency may be harmed in the sense that transacted prices

might need to be adjusted for bid-ask bounce to determine the

fundamental value of the underlying contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission proposes to use its discretion in the manner in

which it implements the statutorily-required spot-month position limits

so as to achieve Congress's objectives in CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B)(ii);

that is, to prevent or deter market manipulation, including corners and

squeezes. For example, the Commission proposes to use its discretion

under CEA section 4a(a)(1) to set limits that are equal in the spot-

month for physical-delivery and linked cash-settled referenced

contracts respectively. By setting separate limits for physical-

delivery and cash-settled referenced contracts, the Reproposal

restricts the size of the position a trader may hold or control in

cash-settled referenced contracts, thus reducing the incentive of a

trader to manipulate the settlement of the physical-delivery contract

in order to benefit positions in the cash-settled referenced contract.

Thus, the separate limits further enhance the prevention of market

manipulation provided by spot-month position limits by reducing the

potential for incentives to engage in manipulative action.

iv. Summary of Comments

One commenter urged the Commission to ensure that a final rule does

not compromise predictable convergence in the market, or risk

threatening the utility of contracts for risk management purposes,

noting the importance of risk management to the general health of the

economy.\1269\ Another commenter noted the requirement that the

Commission consider alternatives and said that the Commission should

consider not adopting non-spot-month limits, limits that are set

arbitrarily, or limits on financially settled contracts; consider

recognizing cross-commodity netting; consider a plan for cross-border

application of position limits; and consider new data sources,

including SDRs (although such data's reliability is still in

development).\1270\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1269\ CL-ADM-60300 at 3.

\1270\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at 26.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission agrees that the federal position limit regime should

not unnecessarily impede convergence between the futures and cash

markets, which would impede the price discovery process of the core

referenced contract. As discussed below, the Commission endeavors to

take into account how the position limit levels would impact the number

of market participants in all of the referenced contracts to reduce

undesirable impact on those markets.

The Commission has preliminarily exercised its discretion in

determining how to adopt position limits and has chosen to start with

the 25 core referenced futures contracts which were selected on the

basis that such contracts:

[[Page 96853]]

(1) Have high levels of open interest and significant notional value;

or (2) serve as a reference price for a significant number of cash

market transactions. The specific levels are not set arbitrarily.

Rather, as discussed more below, the Commission takes into account the

expertise of the exchanges that list the core referenced futures

contracts. In that regard, the Commission received and verified

estimates of deliverable supplies for core referenced futures contracts

and considered spot-month limit levels those exchanges suggested.

Regarding the data considered in setting the levels of non-spot month

limits, Commission staff has worked with industry to improve the

reliability of swap data collected pursuant to part 20 of Commission

regulations. As discussed below in more detail, the Commission's

confidence in the data has improved such that it relied on part 20 swap

position data, to propose initial levels of federal non-spot month

limits on futures and swaps in the Reproposal. The Commission addresses

cross-commodity netting in the spread exemptions covered in reproposed

Sec. 150.10.

A commenter was concerned that the proposed position limits will

cause market participants to transact in less-transparent and non-

cleared markets due to a lack of liquidity on futures markets, and

undermine efforts to encourage market transparency and reduce systemic

risks through centralized clearing.\1271\ Another commenter pointed out

that constraining speculation would constrain hedging, and that more

financial involvement in commodity markets has lowered risk premia and

made hedging cheaper, making it economical to hold larger inventories

that help reduce the frequency and severity of large price

increases.\1272\ A third commenter questioned whether the Supplemental

Proposal's cost-benefit analysis includes the costs of processing bona

fide hedging and spread exemptions for contracts subject only to

exchange-set speculative position limits and not federal speculative

position limits.\1273\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1271\ See CL-MFA-60385 at 4. Citing testimony of Erik Haas

(Director of Market Regulation, ICE Futures U.S.) at the EEMAC

public meeting on February 26, 2105, the commenter asserted that the

volume of over-the-counter transactions is already increasing

because futures contracts have become too costly the further out the

curve one goes. Id.

\1272\ See CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at Annex B at 5. This commenter

referenced, but did not include, two papers as follows. James

Hamilton and Jing Wu, Risk Premia in Crude Oil Futures Prices, NBER

Working Paper (2013). Peter Christoffersen, Kris Jacobs, and Bingxin

Li, Dynamic Jump Intensities and Risk Premiums in Crude Oil Futures

and Options Markets, working paper (2013).

\1273\ CL-Working Group-60947 at 14.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission has preliminarily considered how the limits would

impact traders. In that regard the Commission sought not to impede the

liquidity of the markets for both hedgers and speculators by setting

the spot month position limit at a level that would not deter hedgers

or speculators from participating in the market. The Commission is

mindful of the beneficial effects that speculators have on the

commodity markets. As a consequence, the Commission takes into

consideration the risk of deterring appropriate speculation when

setting the federal limits. The Commission also preliminarily

considered the exchange-suggested spot-month limits when setting the

federal spot-month limit. As discussed below, in most cases the

exchange-suggested limit levels reproposed by the Commission are the

federal spot-month limit. Therefore, the Commission preliminarily

believes that the federal limits are in line with the exchanges'

expectations and therefore the exchanges would be unlikely, at least

initially, to adopt a smaller exchange-set spot-month limit for the

core referenced futures contracts. The Commission will also review the

federal limits in the future to determine if they are effective and not

unduly restrictive.

c. Sec. 150.2(b) Single-Month and All-Months-Combined Speculative

Position Limits

i. Summary of Changes

Reproposed Sec. 150.2(b) provides that no person may hold or

control positions, net long or net short, in referenced contracts in a

single-month or in all-months-combined in excess of the levels

specified by the Commission. In that regard, Sec. 150.2(b) would

require netting all positions in referenced contracts (regardless of

whether such referenced contracts are physical-delivery or cash-

settled) when calculating a person's positions for purposes of the

proposed single-month or all-months-combined position limits

(collectively ``non-spot-month'' position limits).\1274\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1274\ The Commission is reproposing to adopt the same level for

single-month and all-months-combined limits, and refers to those

limits as the ``non-spot-month limits.'' The spot month and any

single month refer to those periods of the core referenced futures

contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Baseline

The baseline is the current Sec. 150.2 of the Commission's

regulations.

iii. Benefits and Costs

CEA section 4a(a)(3)(A) directs the Commission, each time it

establishes limits, to set limits on speculative positions for months

other than the spot-month.\1275\ While market disruptions arising from

the concentration of positions remain a possibility outside the spot

month, the above-mentioned concerns about corners and squeezes and

other forms of manipulation are reduced outside the spot-month.

Accordingly, the Reproposal requires netting of physical-delivery and

cash-settled referenced contracts for purposes of determining

compliance with non-spot-month limits. The Commission has preliminarily

determined it is appropriate to permit the additional flexibility in

complying with the non-spot-months limits that netting allows, given

the decreased risk of corners and squeezes outside the spot-month.

Because this additional flexibility means market participants are able

to retain offsetting positions outside of the spot-month, liquidity

should not be significantly impaired and disruptions to price discovery

should be reduced.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1275\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(3)(A).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

However, more generally, the Commission recognizes that federal

non-spot month position limits do impose costs to exchanges and market

participants. These costs are generally the same as discussed above

with respect to Sec. 150.2(a). The consideration of the costs to

exchanges and market participants of Sec. 150.2(a) is also applicable

to Sec. 150.2(b).

iv. Summary of Comments

Comments on this section are addressed in the discussion of

150.2(e) below.

d. Sec. 150.2(c) Purpose of This Part

i. Summary of Changes

Reproposed Sec. 150.2(c)(1) and (2) specify that for purposes of

part 150, the spot month and any single month shall be those of the

core referenced futures contract and that an eligible affiliate is not

required to comply separately with speculative position limits.

ii. Baseline

The baseline is the current Sec. 150.2 of the Commission's

regulations.

iii. Benefits and Costs

The Commission believes these are conforming amendments to

effectuate the rule and do not have cost or benefit implications.

[[Page 96854]]

iv. Summary of Comments

No commenter addressed any cost or benefit considerations relating

to proposed rules Sec. 150.2(c)(1) or (2).

e. Sec. 150.2(d) Core Referenced Futures Contracts

i. Summary of Changes

As defined in proposed Sec. 150.1, referenced contracts are

futures, options, or swaps contracts that are directly or indirectly

linked to a core referenced futures contract or the commodity

underlying a core referenced futures contract.\1276\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1276\ As discussed above, the definition of referenced contract

excludes any guarantee of a swap, location basis contracts,

commodity index contracts and trade option that meets the

requirements of Sec. 32.3 of this chapter.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

New rule Sec. 150.2(d) lists the 25 core referenced futures

contracts on which the Commission has preliminarily determined to

establish federal speculative position limits. The list reflects a

significant expansion of federal speculative position limits from the

list of nine agricultural contracts under current part 150.\1277\ The

Commission has selected these important food, energy, and metals

contracts on the basis that such contracts (i) have high levels of open

interest and significant notional value and/or (ii) serve as a

reference price for a significant number of cash market transactions.

Thus, the Commission is reproposing position limits on these contracts

in order to commence the expansion of its federal position limit regime

with those commodity derivative contracts that it believes have the

greatest impact on interstate commerce. The Commission will be

reviewing other contracts going forward.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1277\ 17 CFR 150.2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As discussed in the 2013 Position Limit Proposal,\1278\ the

Commission calculated the notional value of open interest (delta-

adjusted) and open interest (delta-adjusted) for all futures, futures

options, and significant price discovery contracts as of December 31,

2012 in all agricultural and exempt commodities as part of its

selection of the 25 core referenced futures contracts in Sec.

150.2(d). The Commission selected commodities in which the derivative

contracts had largest notional value of open interest and open interest

for three categories: Agricultural, energy, and metals. The Commission

then designated the benchmark futures contracts for each commodity as

the core referenced futures contract for which position limits would be

established. Reproposed Sec. 150.2(d) lists 16 core referenced futures

contracts for agricultural commodities, four core referenced futures

contracts for energy commodities, and five core referenced futures

contracts for metals commodities.\1279\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1278\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR 75725.

\1279\ The Commission originally proposed in its 2013 to set

position limits on 28 core referenced contracts, including the 25

contracts noted above plus CME Feeder Cattle, Lean Hog and Class III

Milk. Those three contracts will not be included in the Reproposal

for the reasons discussed above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Baseline

The baseline is the current Sec. 150.2 of the Commission's

regulations.

iii. Benefits and Costs

The benefits and costs are considered in the discussion of the

definition of core referenced futures contract and referenced contract

in Sec. 150.1.

iv. Summary of Comments

Comments on this section are considered in the discussion of the

definition of core referenced futures contract and referenced contract

in Sec. 150.1.

f. Sec. 150.2(e) Levels of Speculative Position Limits

i. Summary of Changes

The list of initial spot month, single month and all-months

combined position limit levels adopted by the Commission for referenced

contracts can be found in Appendix D to this part. Under reproposed

Sec. 150.2(e)(3), the Commission will recalibrate spot month position

limit levels no less frequently than every two calendar years, with any

such recalibration to result in limits no greater than one-quarter (25

percent) of the estimated spot-month deliverable supply \1280\ in the

relevant core referenced futures contract. This formula is consistent

with the acceptable practices in current Sec. 150.5, as well as the

Commission's longstanding practice of using this measure of deliverable

supply to evaluate whether DCM-set spot-month limits are in compliance

with DCM core principles 3 and 5. The Reproposal separately restricts

the size of positions in cash-settled referenced contracts that would

potentially benefit from a trader's potential distortion of the price

of the underlying core referenced futures contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1280\ The guidance for meeting DCM core principle 3 (as listed

in 17 CFR part 38 app. C) specifies that, ``[t]he specified terms

and conditions [of a futures contract], considered as a whole,

should result in a `deliverable supply' that is sufficient to ensure

that the contract is not susceptible to price manipulation or

distortion. In general, the term `deliverable supply' means the

quantity of the commodity meeting the contract's delivery

specifications that reasonably can be expected to be readily

available to short traders and salable by long traders at its market

value in normal cash marketing channels . . .'' See Core Principles

and Other Requirements for Designated Contract Markets, 77 FR 36612,

36722 (Jun. 19, 2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Accordingly, each DCM is required to supply the Commission with an

estimated spot-month deliverable supply figure that the Commission will

use to recalibrate spot-month position limits unless the Commission

decides to rely on its own estimate of deliverable supply

instead.\1281\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1281\ Sec. 150.2(e)(3)(ii)(A) would require DCMs to submit

estimates of deliverable supply. DCM estimates of deliverable

supplies (and the supporting data and analysis) would continue to be

subject to Commission review. Sec. 150.2(e)(3)(ii)(A) would allow a

DCM to petition the Commission no less than two calendar months

before the due date for submission of an estimate of deliverable

supply to recommend that the Commission not change the spot-month

limit.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In contrast to spot-month limits, which will be set as a function

of deliverable supply, the formula for the non-spot-month position

limits is based on total open interest for all referenced contracts

that are aggregated with a particular core referenced futures contract.

In that regard, Sec. 150.2(e)(4) explains that the Commission will

calculate non-spot-month position limit levels based on the following

formula: 10 percent of the largest annual average open interest for the

first 25,000 contracts and 2.5 percent of the open interest

thereafter.\1282\ As is the case with spot month limits, the Commission

will adjust single month and all-months-combined limits no less

frequently than every two calendar years.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1282\ Since 1999, the same 10 percent/2.5 percent methodology,

now incorporated in current Sec. 150.5(c)(2), has been used to

determine futures all-months position limits for referenced

contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission's average open interest calculation will be computed

for each of the past two calendar years, using either month-end open

contracts or open contracts for each business day in the time period,

as practical and in the Commission's discretion. Initially, the

Commission is reproposing initial non-spot-month limits using the

larger open interest level from two 12-month periods (July 1, 2104 to

June 30, 2015; and July 1, 2015 to June 30, 2016), for futures

contracts and options thereon reported under part 16, and for swaps

reported under part 20.

In the future, the Commission expects to use the data reported

pursuant to parts 16, 20, and/or 45 of the Commission's regulations to

estimate average open interest in referenced contracts.\1283\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1283\ Options listed on DCMs would be adjusted using an option

delta reported to the Commission pursuant to 17 CFR part 16; swaps

would be counted on a futures equivalent basis, equal to the

economically equivalent amount of core referenced futures contracts

reported pursuant to 17 CFR part 20 or as calculated by the

Commission using swap data collected pursuant to 17 CFR part 45.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96855]]

ii. Baseline

The baseline is the current Sec. 150.2 of the Commission's

regulations.

iii. Benefits and Costs

Method for Setting Spot-Month Position Limit Levels

The method for determining the levels at which the limits are set

is consistent with the Commission's longstanding acceptable practices

for DCM-set speculative position limits. In the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, the Commission proposed to set the initial spot month

speculative position limit levels for referenced contracts at the

existing DCM-set levels for the core referenced futures

contracts.\1284\ As an alternative, the Commission stated that it was

considering using 25 percent of an exchange's estimate of deliverable

supply if the Commission verified the estimate as reasonable.\1285\ As

a further alternative, the Commission stated that it was considering

setting initial spot month position limit levels at a recommended

level, if any, submitted by a DCM (if lower than 25 percent of

estimated deliverable supply).\1286\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1284\ December 2013 Position Limit Proposal, 78 FR 75727. One

commenter urged the Commission to retain the legacy speculative

limits for enumerated agricultural products. The ``enumerated''

agricultural products refer to the list of commodities contained in

the definition of ``commodity'' in CEA section 1a; 7 U.S.C. 1a. This

list of agricultural contracts includes nine currently traded

contracts: Corn (and Mini-Corn), Oats, Soybeans (and Mini-Soybeans),

Wheat (and Mini-wheat), Soybean Oil, Soybean Meal, Hard Red Spring

Wheat, Hard Winter Wheat, and Cotton No. 2. See 17 CFR 150.2. The

position limits on these agricultural contracts are referred to as

``legacy'' limits because these contracts on agricultural

commodities have been subject to federal positions limits for

decades. This commenter stated, ``There is no appreciable support

within our industry or, as far as we know, from the relevant

exchanges to move beyond current levels. . . . Changing current

limits, as proposed in the rule, will have a negative impact on

futures-cash market convergence and will compromise contract

performance.'' CL-American Farm Bureau Federation-59730 at 3).

Contra CL-ISDA and SIFMA-59611 at 32 (setting initial spot-month

limits at the existing exchange-set levels would be arbitrary

because the exchange-set levels have not been calibrated to apply as

``a ceiling on the spot-month positions that a trader can hold

across all exchanges for futures, options and swaps''); CL-ICE-59966

at 6 (``the Proposed Rule . . . effectively halves the present

position limit in the spot month by aggregating across trading

venues and uncleared OTC swaps''). See also CL-ISDA and SIFMA-59611

at 3 (the spot month limit methodology is ``both arbitrary and

unjustified'').

\1285\ December 2013 Position Limit Proposal, 78 FR 75727. The

Commission also stated that if the Commission could not verify an

exchange's estimate of deliverable supply for any commodity as

reasonable, the Commission might adopt the existing DCM-set level or

a higher level based on the Commission's own estimate, but not

greater than would result from the exchange's estimated deliverable

supply for a commodity.

One commenter was unconvinced that estimated deliverable supply

is ``the appropriate metric for determining spot month position

limits'' and opined that the ``real test'' should be whether limits

``allow convergence of cash and futures so that futures markets can

still perform their price discovery and risk management functions.''

CL-NGFA-60941 at 2. Another commenter stated, ``While 25% may be a

reasonable threshold, it is based on historical practice rather than

contemporary analysis, and it should only be used as a guideline,

rather than formally adopted as a hard rule. Deliverable supply is

subject to numerous environmental and economic factors, and is

inherently not susceptible to formulaic calculation on a yearly

basis.'' CL-MGEX-60301 at 1. Another commenter expressed the view

that the 25 percent formula is not ``appropriately calibrated to

achieve the statutory objective'' set forth in section

4a(a)(3)(B)(i) of the CEA, 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(3)(B)(i). CL-CME-60926 at

3. Another commenter opined that because the Commission ``has not

established a relationship between `estimated deliverable supply'

and spot-month potential for manipulation or excessive

speculation,'' the 25 percent formula is arbitrary. CL-ISDA and

SIFMA-59611 at 31.

Several commenters opined that a limit at 25 percent of

deliverable supply is too high. E.g., CL-Americans for Financial

Reform-59685 at 2; CL-Tri-State Coalition for Responsible

Investment-59682 at 1; CL-CMOC-59720 at 3; CL-WEED-59628 (``Only a

lower limit would ensure market stability and prevent market

manipulation.''); CL-Public Citizen-60313 at 1 (``There is no good

reason for a single firm to take 25% of a market.''); CL-IECA-59964

at 3 (25 percent of deliverable supply ``is a lot of market power in

the hands of speculators''). One commenter stated that ``position

limits should be set low enough to restore a commercial hedger

majority in open interest in each core referenced contract,'' CL-

Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy (``IATP'')-60323 at 5,

suggesting in a later submission that position limits at 5-10

percent of estimated deliverable supply in each covered contract

applied on an aggregated basis might ``enable commercial hedgers to

regain for all covered contracts their pre-2000 average share of 70

percent of agricultural contracts,'' CL-IATP-60394 at 2. One

commenter supported expanding position limits ``to ensure rough or

approximate convergence of futures and underlying cash at

expiration.'' CL-Pamela D. Thornton (``Thornton'')-59702 at 1.

Several commenters supported setting limits based on updated

estimates of deliverable supply which reflect current market

conditions. E.g., CL-ICE-59966 at 5; CL-FIA-59595 at 8; CL-EEI-EPSA-

59602 at 9; CL-MFA-59606 at 5; CL-CMC-59634 at 14; CL-Olam-59658 at

3; CL-CCMC-59684 at 6-7.

\1286\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75728.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In preliminarily determining the levels at which to set the initial

speculative position limits, the Commission considered, among other

things, the recommendations of the exchanges as well as data to which

the exchanges do not have access. In considering these and other

factors, a significant concern of the Commission became the effect of

alternative limit levels on traders in the cash-settled referenced

contracts. A DCM has reasonable discretion in establishing the manner

in which it complies with core principle 5 regarding position

limits.\1287\ As the Commission observed in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, ``there may be a range of spot month limits, including

limits set below 25 percent of deliverable supply, which may serve as

practicable to maximize . . . [the] policy objectives [set forth in

section 4a(a)(3)(B) of the CEA].'' \1288\ The Commission must also

consider the competitiveness of futures markets.\1289\ Thus, the

Commission preliminarily determined to accept the recommendations of

the exchanges to set federal limits below 25 percent of deliverable

supply, where setting a limit level at less than 25 percent of

deliverable supply did not appear to restrict unduly positions in the

cash-settled referenced contracts. The exchanges retain the ability to

adopt lower exchange-set limit levels than the initial speculative

position limit levels set by the Commission in this rulemaking.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1287\ CEA section 5(d)(1)(B), 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(1)(B).

\1288\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

\1289\ CEA section 15(a)(2)(B), 7 U.S.C. 19(a)(2)(B).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As discussed in more detail above, the process of determining

appropriate spot-month limit levels included the Commission receiving

updated estimates of deliverable supply from the DCMs listing the 25

core referenced contracts, which Commission staff verified as

reasonable after conducting its own independent review of estimated

deliverable supply for the subject core referenced contracts.

Furthermore, the DCMs provided recommended spot-month limit levels for

some of the 25 core referenced contracts which the Commission

considered while determining the appropriate level of spot-month limits

for the 25 core referenced futures contracts.\1290\ In addition, the

Commission then conducted an impact analysis of different spot-month

limit levels to discern how many market participants would be affected

by the different limit levels.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1290\ The Commission notes that the CME did not provide a

recommended spot month limit for its Live Cattle Contract. The

Commission ultimately kept the current spot month limit of 450

contracts in place for the Live Cattle contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As part of reproposing Sec. 150.2(e)(3)(i), the Commission has

considered scenarios where exchanges may or may not update deliverable

supply. This may result in the Commission reviewing and re-establishing

position limits in the spot month. Exchanges may elect not to undertake

this expense of re-estimating the deliverable supply of the underlying

[[Page 96856]]

commodity. Among many reasons, this might be because the deliverable

supply has not changed much during the time that the last estimate was

made. In these cases, the Commission has the option to maintain the

current spot month position limit level or use the formula based on the

outdated deliverable supply estimate if different, or use the

exchange's recommendation for the level of the spot month position

limit. Sparing the exchanges of the cost of re-estimating the

deliverable supply may be beneficial if the estimation costs are high

or if the anticipated difference in the estimates is small. The

Commission must also be mindful that exchanges might want the federal

position limit to be set lower, because a lower limit might prevent

liquidity in the exchange's core reference contract from developing on

another exchange. Exchanges may elect to re-estimate deliverable

supply. This would allow the Commission to maintain the current spot

month level, replace it with the formula based on 25% of updated

deliverable supply, or accept the exchange's recommendation for a

different level. It is prudent to revise the spot month position limit

if the deliverable supply has changed appreciably, because setting the

limit too low might harm liquidity or setting it too high might make it

easier for someone to engage in market manipulation such as perfecting

a corner and squeeze.

iv. Summary of Comments

One commenter cautioned the Commission not to rely on inaccurate or

unreliable data or apply a one-size-fits-all approach in setting the

levels of position limits, in order to avoid potential harms to market

liquidity and increased costs.\1291\ Another commenter suggested that,

in light of the complexities and costs of implementing federal and

exchange-set limits, the Commission should not implement final rules

until at least nine months after the final rule is issued.\1292\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1291\ CL-Chamber-59684 at 4 and 5-6.

\1292\ CL-FIA at 6 and 44.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission has preliminarily determined to ease the transition

to the initial speculative position limits by setting a compliance date

of January 3, 2018 in Sec. 150.3(e)(1). As for the process of

determining appropriate spot-month position limit levels, the

Commission endeavored to use accurate and reliable data. For example,

the Commission looked to updated estimates of deliverable supply from

the DCMs listing the 25 core referenced contracts, which Commission

staff verified as reasonable after conducting its own independent

review of estimated deliverable supply for the subject core referenced

futures contracts.\1293\ In addition, the Commission then conducted an

impact analysis of different spot-month limit levels to discern how

many market participants would be affected by the different limit

levels. To determine the non-spot month position limits, the Commission

used futures daily open interest data. In addition, it worked with

market participants to improve the swap data collected pursuant to part

20 of the Commission's regulations, so that data could be used in

determining open interest levels in the swap markets for referenced

contracts. The Commission deems both the estimated deliverable supply

data and exchange recommended spot-month limits along with the open

interest data to be current and reliable for basing federal spot month

and non-spot month limits, respectively.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1293\ The Commission notes that the CME did not provide a

recommended spot month limit for its Live Cattle Contract. The

Commission ultimately kept the current spot month limit of 450

contracts in place for the Live Cattle contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

g. Initial Speculative Spot Month Position Limit Levels

i. CME and MGEX Agricultural Contracts

For the CME and MGEX Agricultural (Legacy) contracts, which were

previously subject to federal position limits, the Commission has

preliminarily determined to set the initial speculative spot month

position limit levels for C, O, RR, S, SM, SO, W and KW at the

recommended levels submitted by CME,\1294\ all of which are lower than

25 percent of estimated deliverable supply.\1295\ As is evident from

the table set forth in the discussion above, this also means that the

Commission is reproposing the initial speculative position limit levels

for these eight contracts as proposed. These initial levels track the

existing DCM-set levels for the core referenced futures contracts;

\1296\ therefore, as noted in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal, many market participants are already used to these levels and

conform their practices accordingly.\1297\ The Commission continues to

believe this approach is consistent with the regulatory objectives of

the Dodd-Frank Act amendments to the CEA.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1294\ CL-CME-61007 at 5.

\1295\ The Commission noted in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal ``that DCMs historically have set or maintained exchange

spot month limits at levels below 25 percent of deliverable

supply.'' December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR 75729.

\1296\ See CL-CME-61007 (specifying lower exchange-set limit

levels for W and RR in certain circumstances).

\1297\ December 2013 Position Limit Proposal, 78 FR 75727.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission has also preliminarily determined to set the initial

speculative spot month position limit level for MWE at 1,000 contracts,

which is the level requested by MGEX \1298\ and approximately equal to

25 percent of estimated deliverable supply. This is an increase from

the proposed level of 600 contracts and is greater than the initial

speculative spot month position limit levels for W and KW.\1299\ As

stated in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the 25 percent

formula is consistent with the longstanding acceptable practices for

DCM core principle 5.\1300\ The Commission continues to believe, based

on its experience and expertise, that the 25 percent formula is a

reasonable ``prophylactic tool to reduce the threat of corners and

squeezes, and promote convergence without compromising market

liquidity.'' \1301\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1298\ CL-MGEX-60938 at 2.

\1299\ Most commenters who supported establishing the same level

of speculative limits for each of the three wheat core referenced

futures contracts focused on parity in the non-spot months. However,

some commenters did support wheat party in the spot month, e.g., CL-

CMC-59634 at 15; CL-NCFC-59942 at 6.

\1300\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR 75729.

\1301\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission's impact analysis reveals no traders in cash settled

contracts in any of C, O, S, SM, SO, W, MWE, KW, or RR, and no traders

in physical delivery contracts for O and RR, above the initial

speculative limit levels for those contracts. The Commission found

varying numbers of traders in the C, S, SM, SO, W, MWE, KW physical

delivery contracts over the initial levels, but the numbers were very

small for MWE and KW. Because the levels that the Commission is

adopting for C, O, S, SM, SO, W, KW, and RR maintain the status quo for

those contracts, the Commission assumes that some or possibly all of

such traders over the initial levels are hedgers. Hedgers may have to

file for an applicable exemption, but hedgers with bona fide hedging

positions should not have to reduce their positions as a result of

speculative position limits per se. Thus, the number of traders in the

C, S, SM, SO, W and KW physical delivery contracts who would need to

reduce speculative positions below the initial limit levels should be

lower than the numbers indicated by the impact

[[Page 96857]]

analysis. And, while setting initial speculative levels at 25 percent

of deliverable supply would, based upon logic and the Commission's

impact analysis, affect fewer traders in the C, S, SM, SO, W and KW

physical delivery contracts, consistent with its statement in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission believes that

setting these lower levels of initial spot month limits will serve the

objectives of preventing excessive speculation, manipulation, squeezes

and corners,\1302\ while ensuring sufficient (in the view of the

listing DCM) market liquidity for bona fide hedgers and ensuring that

the price discovery function of the market is not disrupted.\1303\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1302\ Contra CL-ISDA and SIFMA-59611 at 55 (proposed spot month

limits ``are almost certainly far smaller than necessary to prevent

corners or squeezes'').

\1303\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR 75729, Dec.

12, 2013.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Summary of Comments

MGEX contended that the proposed wheat position limit disparity

(particularly in non-spot months) may inject significant instability

into the market, as market participants will be unable to utilize time-

tested risk management practices equally across the three contracts and

have unintended negative market consequences resulting from hedgers and

speculators limiting their activity (particularly spread trading) in

markets with the lowest limits--or ceasing to trade in the lower-limit

markets altogether.\1304\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1304\ CL-MGEX-59932 at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

MGEX was concerned that the proposed method inhibits growth in

rapidly changing and expanding derivatives markets and will limit

growth in the HRSW contract at a time when participation is

increasing.\1305\ MGEX asserted that the Proposed Rule has a

disproportionate impact on HRSW market participants, given that MGEX

HRSW has more large traders approaching the single month and all months

combined limits than CBOT Wheat and KCBT Hard Winter Wheat despite the

fact that the number of large traders approaching the Proposed Rule

single month and all months combined limit levels stayed relatively

constant among the three U.S. wheat contracts; MGEX also contended that

price volatility or concentration in one contract may unduly affect the

price of the others.\1306\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1305\ CL-MGEX-60380 at 5.

\1306\ CL-MGEX-59932 at 2. MGEX asserted that ``[w]ithout wheat

contract parity--proven historically effective and efficient--

inequities would be introduced into the marketplace that could well

result in artificial market disruption through a lack of

convergence, distorting the market and bringing no value to the

price discovery process.'' Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission took concerns about wheat contract parity into

account when preliminarily setting the spot month and non-spot month

levels for the CBOT Wheat, KCBT Hard Winter Wheat and MGEX Hard Red

Spring Wheat contracts. In that regard, as discussed below, the

Commission is reproposing to maintaining the status quo for the non-

spot month position limit levels for the KW and MWE core referenced

futures contracts so that there will be partial wheat parity.\1307\ The

Commission has preliminarily determined not to raise the limit levels

for KW and MWE to the limit level for W, as 32,800 contracts appears to

be extraordinarily large in comparison to open interest in the KW and

MWE markets, and the limit level for KW and MWE is already larger than

a limit level based on the ``10, 2.5 percent'' formula. Even when

relying on a single criterion, such as percentage of open interest, the

Commission has historically recognized that there can ``result . . . a

range of acceptable position limit levels.'' \1308\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1307\ Several commenters supported adopting equivalent non-spot

month position limits for the three existing wheat referenced

contracts traders. E.g., CL-FIA-59595 at 4, 15; CL-CMC-60391 at 8;

CL-CMC-60950 at 11; CL-CME-59718 at 44; CL-American Farm Bureau-

59730 at 4; CL-MGEX-59932 at 2; CL-MGEX-60301 at 1; CL-MGEX-59610 at

2-3; CL-MGEX-60936 at 2-3; CL-NCFC-59942 at 6; CL-NGFA-59956 at 3.

\1308\ Revision of Speculative Position Limits, 57 FR 12766,

12770 (Apr. 13, 1992). See also Revision of Speculative Position

Limits and Associated Rules, 63 FR 38525, 38527 (July 17, 1998). Cf.

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR 75729, Dec. 12, 2013

(there may be range of spot month limits that maximize policy

objectives).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Softs

For the ``Softs''--agricultural contracts on cocoa, coffee, cotton,

orange juice, sugar and live cattle--the Commission has preliminarily

determined to set the initial speculative spot month position limit

levels for the CC, KC, CT, OJ, SB, and SF \1309\ core referenced

futures contracts, based on the estimates of deliverable supply

submitted by ICE,\1310\ at 25 percent of estimated deliverable

supply.\1311\ As is evident from the table set forth in the discussion

above, this also means that the Commission is reproposing initial

speculative position limit levels that are significantly higher than

the levels for these six contracts as proposed. As stated in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the 25 percent formula is

consistent with the longstanding acceptable practices for DCM core

principle 5.\1312\ The Commission continues to believe, based on its

experience and expertise, that the 25 percent formula is a reasonable

``prophylactic tool to reduce the threat of corners and squeezes, and

promote convergence without compromising market liquidity.'' \1313\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1309\ One commenter supported considering ``tropicals (sugar/

coffee/cocoa) . . . separately from those agricultural crops

produced in the US domestic market.'' CL-Thornton-59702 at 1; see

also CL-Armajaro Asset Management-59729 at 1.

\1310\ CL-CME-61007 at 5.

\1311\ The Commission noted in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal ``that DCMs historically have set or maintained exchange

spot month limits at levels below 25 percent of deliverable

supply.'' December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR 75729, Dec.

12, 2013.

\1312\ Id.

\1313\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission did not receive any estimate of deliverable supply

for the CME (LC) core referenced futures contract from CME, nor did CME

recommend any change in the limit level for LC. In the absence of any

such update, the Commission is reproposing the initial speculative

position limit level of 450 contracts as proposed. Of 616 reportable

persons, the Commission's impact analysis did not reveal any unique

person trading cash settled or physical delivery spot month contracts

who would have held positions above this level for LC.

With respect to the IFUS CC, KC, CT, OJ, SB, and SF core referenced

futures contracts, the Commission's impact analysis did not reveal any

unique person trading cash settled spot month contracts who would have

held positions above the initial levels that the Commission is

adopting; as illustrated above. Rather, adopting lower levels would

mostly have affected small numbers of traders in physical delivery

contracts. Therefore, the Commission has preliminarily determined to

accept ICE's recommendations.

iii. Metals

For the metals contracts, the Commission has preliminarily

determined to set the initial speculative spot month position limit

levels for GC, SI, and HG at the recommended levels submitted by

CME,\1314\ all of which are lower than 25 percent of estimated

deliverable supply.\1315\ In the case of GC and SI, this is a doubling

of the current exchange-set limit levels.\1316\ In the case

[[Page 96858]]

of HG, the initial level is the same as the existing DCM-set level for

the core referenced futures contract, and lower than the level

proposed. The Commission has also preliminarily determined to set the

initial speculative spot month position limit level for PL at 100

contracts and PA at 500 contracts, which are the levels recommended by

CME. In the case of PL and PA, the initial level is the same as the

existing DCM-set level for the core referenced futures contract, and a

decrease from the proposed levels of 500 and 650 contracts,

respectively.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1314\ CL-CME-61007 at 5.

\1315\ The Commission noted in the December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal ``that DCMs historically have set or maintained exchange

spot month limits at levels below 25 percent of deliverable

supply.'' December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR 75729, Dec.

12, 2013.

\1316\ One commenter cautioned against raising limit levels for

GC to 25 percent of deliverable supply, and expressed concern that

higher federal limits would incentivize exchanges to raise their own

limits. CL-WGC-59558 at 2-4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission found varying numbers of traders in the GC, SI, PL,

PA, and HG physical delivery contracts over the initial levels, but the

numbers were very small except for PA. Because the levels that the

Commission is adopting for PL, PA, and HG maintain the status quo for

those contracts, the Commission assumes that some or possibly all of

such traders over the initial levels are hedgers. The Commission

reiterates the discussion above regarding agricultural contracts:

hedgers may have to file for an applicable exemption, but hedgers with

bona fide hedging positions should not have to reduce their positions

as a result of speculative position limits per se. Thus, the number of

traders in the metals physical delivery contracts who would need to

reduce speculative positions below the initial limit levels should be

lower than the numbers indicated by the impact analysis. And, while

setting initial speculative levels at 25 percent of deliverable supply

would, based upon logic and the Commission's impact analysis, affect

fewer traders in the metals physical delivery contracts, consistent

with its statement in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission believes that setting these lower levels of initial spot

month limits will serve the objectives of preventing excessive

speculation, manipulation, squeezes and corners,\1317\ while ensuring

sufficient market liquidity for bona fide hedgers in the view of the

listing DCM and ensuring that the price discovery function of the

market is not disrupted.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1317\ Contra CL-ISDA and SIFMA-59611 at 55 (proposed spot month

limits ``are almost certainly far smaller than necessary to prevent

corners or squeezes'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission's impact analysis reveals no unique persons in the

SI and HG cash settled referenced contracts, and very few unique

persons in the cash settled GC referenced contract, whose positions

would have exceeded the initial limit levels for those contracts. Based

on the Commission's impact analysis, preliminarily setting the initial

federal spot month limit levels for PL and PA at the lower levels

recommended by CME impact a few traders in PL and PA cash settled

contracts.

The Commission has considered the numbers of unique persons that

would have been impacted by each of the cash-settled and physical-

delivery spot month limits in the PL and PA referenced contracts. The

Commission notes those limits would have impacted more traders in the

physical-delivery PA contract than in the cash-settled PA contract,

while fewer traders would have been impacted in the physical-delivery

PL contract than in the cash-settled PL contract, albeit in any event

few traders would have been impacted.\1318\ The Commission also

considered the distribution of those cash-settled traders over time; as

reflected in the open interest table discussed above regarding setting

non-spot month limits, it can be readily observed that open interest in

each of the cash-settled PL and PA referenced contracts was markedly

lower in the second 12-month period (year 2) than in the prior 12-month

period (year 1). Accordingly, the Commission preliminarily concludes

that the CME recommended levels in PL and PA referenced contracts are

acceptable.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1318\ In this regard, the Commission notes that CME did not

have access to the Commission's impact analysis when CME recommended

levels for its physical-delivery core referenced futures contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iv. Energy

For the energy contracts, the Commission has preliminarily

determined to set the initial speculative spot month position limit

levels for the NG, CL, HO, and RB core referenced futures contracts at

25 percent of estimated deliverable supply which, in the case of CL,

HO, and RB is higher than the levels recommended by CME.\1319\ As is

evident from the table set forth above, this also means that the

Commission is adopting initial speculative position limit levels that

are significantly higher than the proposed levels for these four

contracts. As stated in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

25 percent formula is consistent with the longstanding acceptable

practices for DCM core principle 5.\1320\ The Commission continues to

believe, based on its experience and expertise, that the 25 percent

formula is a reasonable ``prophylactic tool to reduce the threat of

corners and squeezes, and promote convergence without compromising

market liquidity.'' \1321\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1319\ CL-CME-61007 at 5. One commenter opined that 25 percent

of deliverable supply would result in a limit level that is too high

for natural gas, and suggest 5 percent as an alternative that

``would provide ample liquidity and significantly reduce the

potential for excessive speculation.'' CL-IECA-59964 at 3.

\1320\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75729.

\1321\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The levels that CME recommended for NG, CL, HO, and RB are twice

the existing exchange-set spot month limit levels. Nevertheless, the

Commission is proposing to set the initial speculative spot month limit

levels at 25 percent of deliverable supply for CL, HO, and RB because

the higher levels will lessen the impact on a number of traders in both

cash settled and physical delivery contracts. For NG, the Commission is

proposing to set the physical delivery limit at 25 percent of

deliverable supply, as recommended by CME; the Commission is also

proposing to set a conditional spot month limit exemption of 10,000 for

NG only.\1322\ This exemption would to some degree maintain the status

quo in natural gas because each of the NYMEX and ICE cash settled

natural gas contracts, which settle to the final settlement price of

the physical delivery contract, include a conditional spot month limit

exemption of 5,000 contracts (for a total of 10,000 contracts).\1323\

However, neither

[[Page 96859]]

NYMEX and ICE penultimate contracts, which settle to the daily

settlement price on the next to last trading day of the physical

delivery contract, nor OTC swaps, are currently subject to any spot

month position limit. In addition, the Commission's impact analysis

suggests that a conditional spot month limit exemption greater than 25

percent of deliverable supply for cash settled contracts in CL, HO, and

RB would potentially benefit only a few traders, while a conditional

spot month limit exemption for cash settled contracts in NG would

potentially benefit many traders.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1322\ This exemption for up to 10,000 contracts would be five

times the spot month limit of 2,000 contracts, consistent with the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal. See December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75736-8. Under vacated Sec. 151.4, the

Commission would have applied a spot-month position limit for cash-

settled contracts in natural gas at a level of five times the level

of the limit for the physical delivery core referenced futures

contract. See Position Limits for Futures and Swaps, 76 FR 71626,

71687 (Nov. 18, 2011).

\1323\ Some commenters supported retaining a conditional spot

month limit in natural gas. E.g., CL-ICE-60929 at 12 (``Any changes

to the current terms of the Conditional Limit would disrupt present

market practice for no apparent reason. Furthermore, changing the

limits for cash-settled contracts would be a significant departure

from current rules, which have wide support from the broader market

as evidenced by multiple public comments supporting no or higher

cash-settled limits.''). Contra CL-Levin-59637 at 7 (``The proposed

higher limit for cash settled contracts is ill-advised. It would not

only raise the affected position limits to levels where they would

be effectively meaningless, it would also introduce market

distortions favoring certain contracts and certain exchanges over

others, and potentially disrupt important markets, including the

U.S. natural gas market that is key to U.S. manufacturing.''); CL-

Public Citizen-59648 at 5 (``Congress, in allowing an exemption for

bona fide hedgers but not pure speculators, could not possibly have

intended for the Commission to implement position limits that allow

market speculators to hold 125 percent of the estimated deliverable

supply. Once again, while this exception for cash-settled contracts

would avoid market manipulations such as corners and squeezes (since

cash-settled contracts give no direct control over a commodity), it

does not address the problem of undue speculative influence on

futures prices.''). One commenter urged the Commission ``to

eliminate the requirement that traders hold no physical-delivery

position in order to qualify for the conditional spot-month limit

exemption'' in order to maintain liquidity in the NYMEX natural gas

futures contract. CL-BG-59656 at 6-7. See also CL-APGA at 8 (the

Commission should condition the spot month limit exemption for cash

settled natural gas contracts by precluding a trader from holding

more than one quarter of the deliverable supply in physical

inventory). Cf. CL-CME-59971 at 3 (eliminate the five times natural

gas limit because it ``encourages participants to depart from, or

refrain from establishing positions in, the primary physical

delivery contract market and instead opt for the cash-settled

derivative contract market, especially during the last three trading

days when the five times limit applies. By encouraging departure

from the primary contract market, the five times limit encourages a

process of de-liquefying the benchmark physically delivered futures

market and directly affects the determination of the final

settlement price for the NYMEX NG contract- the very same price that

a position representing five times the physical limit will settle

against.'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Summary of Comments

One economist estimated, using various stated assumptions but not

an empirical model, that position limits at the proposed level would

cost American consumers roughly $100 billion, based on an increase of

$15 per barrel of oil in 2013.\1324\ This economist also asserted that

position limits (or the mere possibility that such limits may be

tightened) would discourage passive investors from the commodity

derivative sector and, thus, would adversely affect investment in the

oil and gas industry by raising the cost of hedging for exploration

firms.\1325\ This economist believes that position limits would

increase costs whether or not the position limits actually restrict a

market participant's trading, because compliance costs such as

recordkeeping and reporting would modestly increase the costs of

drilling associated with the regulations and discourage market

entry.\1326\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1324\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611 at Annex A at 3. The economist noted

that he used a ``methodology for predicting changes in crude oil

prices linked to global inventory levels.'' Id.

\1325\ Id. at 9.

\1326\ Id. at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission believes that positon limits are unlikely to deter

passive investors because they have the opportunity to invest in

commodities through collective investment vehicles such as exchange

traded funds (ETFs) or commodity pools. For example, if a position

limit would become binding on a particular ETF, market demand would be

expected to encourage another party to create a new ETF that could

replicate a similar strategy to the previous one, which would allow the

passive investment to continue.

Regarding the forms and application process to obtain a Sec.

150.11 exemption, the Commission believes that the requirements are not

as onerous as the commenter fears. In this regard, an oil exploration

firm would likely be able to qualify for an anticipatory hedge

exemption. The Commission believes the costs of this process will have

a negligible impact on the oil exploration firm's costs of hedging.

Another commenter was concerned that position limits set so low as

to diminish speculative capacity in U.S. energy markets will distort

prices, increase volatility, increase option premiums and increase the

cost of hedging.\1327\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1327\ CL-Vectra-60369 at 1-2. The commenter was particularly

concerned that given the ``dearth of speculative capacity'' in many

energy contracts, hedging costs would increase and be passed on to

consumers. Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission agrees with the commenter that setting position

limits too low could distort prices, increase volatility, increase

option premiums and increase the cost of hedging. The Commission

believes it has preliminarily set the limit levels sufficiently high so

that they will not have a significant adverse impact on the efficiency

and price discovery functions of the core referenced futures contracts.

In response to 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal RFC 55, a

commenter pointed out that the Commission's Division of Enforcement has

numerous tools at its disposal, and the exchanges have position step-

down and exemption revocation authorization at their disposal, to

enforce market manipulation prohibitions.\1328\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1328\ CL-IECAssn-60949 at 23.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission agrees with the commenter, but notes that the

Division of Enforcement's tools can be used only after market

manipulation or other adverse consequences have already occurred. As

for the tools at the disposal of the exchanges to reduce a market

participant's position or deter it from attempting to manipulate the

market, the Commission considered these points when preliminarily

setting the federal position limits at levels that may be higher than

the Commission would otherwise consider, and in some cases higher than

the levels suggested by the exchanges.

h. Method for Setting Single-Month and All-Months Combined Position

Limit Levels

As discussed in more detail above, the Commission has preliminarily

determined to use the futures position limits formula, 10 percent of

the open interest for the first 25,000 contracts and 2.5 percent of the

open interest thereafter (i.e., the ``10, 2.5 percent'' formula), to

set non-spot month speculative position limits for referenced

contracts. This was the method proposed in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal. The Commission used a combination of data on open

interest in physical commodity futures and options from the relevant

exchanges and adjusted part 20 swaps data covering a total of 24

months, rather than two calendar years of data in setting the initial

non-spot month position limit levels.\1329\ The Commission continues to

believe that ``the non-spot month position limits would restrict the

market power of a speculator that could otherwise be used to cause

unwarranted price movements.'' \1330\ In preliminarily determining the

appropriate non-spot month limit levels the Commission considered the

results of its impact analysis of different non-spot month limit levels

to discern how many market participants would be affected by different

limit levels.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1329\ Commission staff analyzed and evaluated the quality of

part 20 data for the period from July 1, 2014 through June 30, 2015

(``Year 1''), and the period from July 1, 2015 through June 30, 2016

(``Year 2'').

\1330\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR 75730, Dec.

12, 2013.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition, the Commission believes that it is beneficial to

update the non-spot month position limits based on recent position

data, such as Part 20 data. The Commission also proposes to retain the

option to maintain the existing position limit levels if it believes

there is good reason to deviate from the formulas. This could be the

case if, for example, the Commission has experience at a level higher

the amount given in the formula and believes that the higher level is

appropriate, because the Commission has not observed any problems at

the higher level. Furthermore, the

[[Page 96860]]

Commission has preliminarily determined that it will fix subsequent

levels no less frequently than every two calendar years. This

conclusion is reproposed in Sec. 150.2(e)(2).

i. CME and MGEX Agricultural Contracts

The Commission is reproposing non-spot month speculative position

limit levels for the Corn (C), Oats (O), Rough Rice (RR), Soybeans (S),

Soybean Meal (SM), Soybean Oil (SO), and Wheat (W) core referenced

futures contracts based on the 10, 2.5 percent open interest

formula.\1331\ Based on the Commission's experience since 2011 with

non-spot month speculative position limit levels for the Hard Red

Winter Wheat (KW) and Hard Red Spring Wheat (MWE) core referenced

futures contracts, the Commission is proposing to maintain the limit

levels for those two commodities at the current level of 12,000

contracts rather than reducing them to the lower levels that would

result from applying the 10, 2.5 percent formula.\1332\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1331\ One commenter expressed concern ``that proposed all-

months-combined speculative position limits based on open interest

levels is not necessarily the appropriate methodology and could lead

to contract performance problems.'' This commenter urged ``that all-

months-combined limits be structured to `telescope' smoothly down to

legacy spot-month limits in order to ensure continued convergence.''

CL-National Grain and Feed Association-60312 at 4.

\1332\ One commenter supported a higher limit for KW than

proposed to promote growth and to enable liquidity for Kansas City

hedgers who often use the Chicago market. CL-Citadel-59717 at 8.

Another commenter supported setting ``a non-spot month and combined

position limit of no less than 12,000 for all three wheat

contracts.'' CL-MGEX-60301 at 1. Contra CL-Occupy the SEC-59972 at

7-8 (commending ``the somewhat more restrictive limitations . . . on

wheat trading'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Maintaining the status quo for the non-spot month limit levels for

the KW and MWE core referenced futures contracts means there will be

partial wheat parity.\1333\ The Commission has preliminarily determined

not to raise the limit levels for KW and MWE to the limit level for W,

as 32,800 contracts appears to be extraordinarily large in comparison

to open interest in the KW and MWE markets, and the limit level for KW

and MWE is already larger than a limit level based on the 10, 2.5

percent formula. Even when relying on a single criterion, such as

percentage of open interest, the Commission has historically recognized

that there can ``result . . . a range of acceptable position limit

levels.'' \1334\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1333\ Several commenters supported adopting equivalent non-spot

month position limits for the three existing wheat referenced

contracts traders. See, e.g., CL-FIA-59595 at 4, 15; CL-CMC-60391 at

8; CL-CMC-60950 at 11; CL-CME-59718 at 44; CL-American Farm Bureau-

59730 at 4; CL-MGEX-59932 at 2; CL-MGEX-60301 at 1; CL-MGEX-59610 at

2-3; CL-MGEX-60936 at 2-3; CL-NCFC-59942 at 6; CL-NGFA-59956 at 3.

\1334\ Revision of Speculative Position Limits, 57 FR 12770,

12766, Apr. 13, 1992. See also Revision of Speculative Position

Limits and Associated Rules, 63 FR 38525, 38527, Jul. 17, 1998. Cf.

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal (there may be range of spot

month limits that maximize policy objectives), 78 FR 75729, Dec. 12,

2013.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Softs

The Commission is reproposing non-spot month speculative position

limit levels for the CC, KC, CT, OJ, SB, SF and LC \1335\ core

referenced futures contracts based on the 10, 2.5 percent open interest

formula.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1335\ One commenter expressed concern that too high non-spot

month limit levels could lead to a repeat of convergence problems

experienced by certain contracts and that ``the imposition of all

months combined limits in continuously produced non-storable

commodities such as livestock . . . will reduce the liquidity needed

by hedgers in deferred months who often manage their risk using

strips comprised of multiple contract months.'' CL-American Farm

Bureau Federation-59730 at 3-4. One commenter requested that the

Commission withdraw its proposal regarding non-spot month limits,

citing, among other things, the Commission's previous approval of

exchange rules lifting all-months-combined limits for live cattle

contracts ``to ensure necessary deferred month liquidity.'' CL-CME-

59718 at 4. Another commenter expressed concern that non-spot month

limits would have a negative impact on live cattle market liquidity.

CL- ``CMC'')-59634 at 12-13. See also CL-CME-59718 at 41.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iii. Metals

The Commission is reproposing non-spot month speculative position

limit levels for the GC, SI, PL, PA, and HG core referenced futures

contracts based on the 10, 2.5 percent open interest formula.\1336\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1336\ One commenter was concerned that applying the 10, 2.5

percent formula to open interest for gold would result in a lower

non-spot month limit level than the spot month limit level, and

urged the Commission to ``apply a consistent methodology to both

spot and non-spot months.'' CL-WGC-59558 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iv. Energy

The Commission is reproposing non-spot month speculative position

limit levels for the NG, CL, HO, and RB core referenced futures

contracts based on the 10, 2.5 percent open interest formula.\1337\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1337\ One commenter suggested deriving non-spot month limit

levels for the CL, HO, and RB referenced contracts from the usage

ratios for US crude oil and oil products rather than open interest

and expressed concern that ``unnecessarily low limits will hamper

legitimate hedging activity.'' CL-Citadel-59717 at 7-8. Another

commenter suggested setting limit levels based on customary position

size. CL-APGA-59722 at 6. This commenter also supported setting the

single month limit at two-thirds of the all months combined limit in

order to relieve market congestion as traders exit or roll out of

the next to expire month into the spot month. CL-APGA-59722 at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Summary of Comments

A commenter claimed that the proposed rule did not address the

price impact of speculative money flows into commodities, and that if

the Commission is concerned with the types of manipulative activities

shown by the Hunt Brothers and Amaranth cases, there are ``targeted and

less burdensome and complex ways to prevent such a manipulative harm''

and the inclusion of position limits on swaps is invalid because swaps

cannot be used to cause this detrimental impact.\1338\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1338\ CL-COPE-59662 at 5. The commenter asserted that the

Commission's position limits proposal was based solely on concerns

about attempts to manipulate the price discovery contract or hoard

physical inventory because the Commission highlighted only the

Amaranth and Hunt Brothers cases. Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission disagrees, and notes that swaps can be used to cause

detrimental impact, as occurred in the Amaranth case. Amaranth entered

into swaps on an exempt commercial market that were directly linked to

a core reference futures contract. So to ignore swaps would not

adequately address the issue that position limits are intended to

address.

i. Sec. 150.2(f)-(g) Pre-Existing Positions and Positions on Foreign

Boards of Trade

i. Summary of Changes

The Commission is reproposing new Sec. 150.2(f)(2) to exempt from

federal non-spot-month speculative position limits any referenced

contract position acquired by a person in good faith prior to the

effective date of such limit, provided that the pre-existing position

is attributed to the person if such person's position is increased

after the effective date of such limit.\1339\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1339\ See also the definition of the term ``Pre-existing

position'' adopted in Sec. 150.1. Such pre-existing positions that

are in excess of the position limits will not cause the trader to be

in violation based solely on those positions. To the extent a

trader's pre-existing positions would cause the trader to exceed the

non-spot-month limit, the trader could not increase the directional

position that caused the positions to exceed the limit until the

trader reduces the positions to below the position limit. As such,

persons who established a net position below the speculative limit

prior to the enactment of a regulation would be permitted to acquire

new positions, but the total size of the pre-existing and new

positions may not exceed the applicable limit.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Finally, reproposed Sec. 150.2(g) will apply position limits to

positions on FBOTs provided that positions are held in referenced

contracts that settle to a referenced contract and the FBOT allows

direct access to its trading system for participants located in the

United States.

[[Page 96861]]

ii. Baseline

The baseline is the current Sec. 150.2 of the Commission's

regulations.

iii. Benefits and Costs

The Commission exempted certain pre-existing positions from

position limits under new Sec. 150.2(f) as part of its grandfathering

provisions.\1340\ Essentially, this means only futures contracts

initially will be subject to non-spot month position limits, as well as

swaps entered after the compliance date. The Commission notes that a

pre-existing position in a futures contract also would not be a

violation of a non-spot month limit, but, rather, would be

grandfathered, as discussed under Sec. 150.2(f)(2). Therefore, market

participants can more easily adjust their existing positions to the new

federal position limit regime. Market participants will however incur

costs for newly established positions in the relevant swaps after the

compliance date, such as those discussed above such as the costs of

monitoring their positions with respect to any applicable federal

position limit and applying for exemptions should they need to exceed

those limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1340\ The Commission excluded from position limits ``pre-

enactment swaps'' and ``transition period swaps,'' in its

grandfathering provisions, as discussed above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

New Sec. 150.2(g), extends the federal position limits to a person

who holds positions in referenced contracts on an FBOT that settle

against any price of one or more contracts listed for trading on a DCM

or SEF that is a trading facility, if the FBOT makes available such

referenced contracts to its members or other participants located in

the United States through direct access to its electronic trading and

ordering matching system. In that regard, Sec. 150.2(g) is consistent

with CEA section 4a(a)(6)(B), which directs the Commission to apply

aggregate position limits to FBOT linked, direct-access

contracts.\1341\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1341\ See supra discussion of CEA section 4a(a)(6) concerning

aggregate position limits and the treatment of FBOT contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Regulations 150.2(f) and (g) implement statutory directives in CEA

section 4a(b)(2) and CEA section 4a(a)(6)(B), respectively, and are not

acts of the Commission's discretion. Thus, a consideration of costs and

benefits of these provisions is not required under CEA section 15(a).

iv. Summary of Comments

No commenter addressed the costs or benefits of Sec. 150.2(f) and

(g).

5. Section 150.3--Exemptions From Federal Position Limits

As discussed above, the Commission has provided a general

discussion of reproposed Sec. 150.3 and highlighted the rule-text

changes that it has made after several rounds of proposed rulemakings

and responsive comments. In this release, the Commission has reproposed

paragraphs (a), (b), (d), (e), (g) and (h) as proposed in December

2013.\1342\ The Commission has amended the text in proposed Sec.

150.3(c) and (f). In the December 2013 proposal, the Commission also

discussed the costs and benefits of these two paragraphs, as well as,

paragraphs (a), (b), (d), (e), (g) and (h).\1343\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1342\ December 2013 Proposal, 78 FR 75828, Dec. 12, 2013.

\1343\ Reproposed Sec. 150.3 has ten paragraphs: (a) through

(j). Reproposed Sec. 150.3(i) (aggregation of accounts) and (j)

(delegation of authority to DMO Director) do not have cost-benefit

implications, and are not discussed in this section.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the June 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission changed proposed paragraph (a). The Commission also

explained in the 2016 cost-benefit section that the changes it was

making to proposed Sec. 150.3(a)(1) should be read in conjunction with

proposed Sec. Sec. 150.9, 150.10, and 150.11.\1344\ Between the June

2016 changes to Sec. Sec. 150.9, 150.10, and 150.11 and now, the

Commission has not made additional changes to Sec. 150.3(a)(1). In

general, the proposed changes made in the June 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal detailed processes that exchanges could offer

to market participants who seek exemptions for positions to exchange-

set and federal position limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1344\ For a fuller discussion of all the changes to reproposed

Sec. 150.3, see Section III.C., above.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In this section, the Commission summarizes reproposed Sec. 150.3,

and, thereafter, discusses the related benefits and costs of the final

rules.

a. Section 150.3 Rule Summaries

i. Section 150.3(a)--Bona Fide Hedging Exemption

Among other things, reproposed Sec. 150.3(a)(1)(i) codifies the

statutory requirement that bona fide hedging positions be exempt from

federal position limits. Reproposed Sec. 150.3(a)(2) authorizes other

exemptions from position limits for financial-distress positions,

conditional spot-month limit positions, spread positions, and other

risk-reduction practices.

ii. Section 150.3(b)--Financial Distress Exemption

Reproposed Sec. 150.3(b) provides the means for market

participants to request relief from applicable position limits during

certain financial distress circumstances, including the default of a

customer, affiliate, or acquisition target of the requesting entity,

that may require an entity to assume in short order the positions of

another entity.

iii. Section 150.3(c)--Conditional Spot-Month Position Limit Exemption

Reproposed Sec. 150.3(c) provides a conditional spot-month limit

exemption that permits traders to acquire positions for natural gas up

to 10,000 contracts if such positions are exclusively in cash-settled

contracts. The natural-gas conditional exemption would not be available

to traders who hold or control positions in the spot-month physical-

delivery referenced contract in order to reduce the risk that traders

with large positions in cash-settled contracts would attempt to distort

the physical-delivery price to benefit such positions.

iv. Section 150.3(d)--Pre-Enactment and Transition Period Swaps

Exemption

Reproposed Sec. 150.3(d) provides an exemption from federal

position limits for swaps entered into before July 21, 2010 (the date

of the enactment of the Dodd-Frank Act), the terms of which have not

expired as of that date, and for swaps entered into during the period

commencing July 22, 2010, the terms of which have not expired as of

that date, and ending 60 days after the publication of final rule Sec.

150.3--that is, its effective date.

v. Section 150.3(e)--Other Exemptions

Reproposed Sec. 150.3(e) explains that a market participant

engaged in risk-reducing practices that are not enumerated in the

revised definition of bona fide hedging in reproposed Sec. 150.1 may

use two different methods to apply to the Commission for relief from

federal position limits. The market participant may request an

interpretative letter from Commission staff pursuant to Sec. 140.9

concerning the applicability of the bona fide hedging position

exemption, or may seek exemptive relief from the Commission under CEA

section 4a(a)(7) of the Act.

vi. Section 150.3(f)--Previously Granted Exemptions

After reviewing comments, the Commission has preliminarily

determined it is best to change the Sec. 150.3(f) text proposed in

December 2013. The amended text broadens exemption relief to pre-

existing financial instruments that are within current Sec. 1.47's

scope, and to exchange-granted non-enumerated exemptions in non-legacy

commodity derivatives

[[Page 96862]]

outside of the spot month with other conditions.

vii. Section 150.3(g) and (h)--Recordkeeping

Reproposed Sec. 150.3(g)(1) specifies recordkeeping requirements

for market participants who claim any exemption in final Sec. 150.3.

Market participants claiming exemptions under reproposed Sec. 150.3

would need to maintain complete books and records concerning all

details of their related cash, forward, futures, options and swap

positions and transactions. Reproposed Sec. 150.3(g)(2) requires

market participants seeking to rely upon the pass-through swap offset

exemption to obtain a representation from its counterparty and keep

that representation on file. Similarly, reproposed Sec. 150.3(g)(3)

requires a market participant who makes such a representation to

maintain records supporting the representation. Under reproposed Sec.

150.3(h), all market participants would need to make such books and

records available to the Commission upon request, which would preserve

the ``call for information'' rule set forth in current Sec. 150.3(b).

b. Baseline

The baseline is the current Sec. 150.3 of the Commission's

regulations.

c. Benefits and Discussion of Comments

i. Section 150.3(a)--Positions Which May Exceed Limits

As explained in the December 2013 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal, Sec. 150.3 works with Sec. Sec. 150.9, 150.10, and Sec.

150.11. All of these rules operate together within the broader

position-limits regulatory regime and provide significant benefits,

such as regulatory certainty, consistency, and transparency. As such,

the benefits of reproposed Sec. 150.3 are discussed in the cost-

benefit sections related to reproposed Sec. Sec. 150.9, 150.10, and

150.11.

ii. Section 150.3(b)--Financial Distress Exemption

The Commission continues to believe that by codifying historical

practices of temporarily lifting position limit restrictions several

benefits will ensue. Reproposed Sec. 150.3 ensures the orderly

transfers of positions from financially distressed firms to financially

secure firms or facilitating other necessary remediation measures

during times of market stress. Because of this Reproposal, the

Commission believes it is less likely that positions will be

prematurely or unnecessarily liquidated, and it is less likely that the

price-discovery function of markets will be harmed.

iii. Section 150.3(c)--Conditional Spot Month Limit Exemption

In the December 2013 proposal, the Commission proposed Sec.

150.3(c) that provided speculators with an opportunity to maintain

relatively large positions in cash-settled contracts up to but no

greater than 125 percent of the spot-month limit. The Commission

explained that by prohibiting speculators using the exemption in the

cash-settled contract from trading in the spot-month of the physical-

delivery contract, the final rules should further protect the delivery

and settlement process, and reduce the ability for a trader with a

large cash settled contract position to attempt to manipulate the

physical-delivery contract price in order to benefit his position. The

Commission invited comment on this general exemption. Upon review of

the comment letters, the Commission has preliminarily determined to

restrict the conditional-spot-month-limit exemption to natural gas

cash-settled referenced contracts. The reasons for this change are

explained above.

iv. Section 150.3(d)--Pre-Enactment and Transition Period Swaps

Exemption

The pre-existing swaps exemption in reproposedSec. 150.3(d) is

consistent with CEA section 4a(b)(2). The exemption promotes the smooth

transition for previously unregulated swaps markets to swaps markets

that will be subjected to position limits compliance. In addition,

allowing netting with pre-enactment and transition swaps provides

flexibility where possible in order to lessen the impact of the regime

on entities with swap positions.

v. Section 150.3(e)--Other Exemptions

Reproposed Sec. 150.3(e) is essentially clarifying and

organizational in nature. For the most part, the Reproposal provides

the benefit of regulatory certainty for those granted exemptions.

vi. Section 150.3(f)--Other Exemptions and Previously Granted

Exemptions

As explained above, the Commission has expanded the scope of

reproposed Sec. 150.3(f) exemptive relief. In December 2013, the

Commission discussed the benefits of proposed Sec. 150.3(f), and

believed that the benefits centered on regulatory certainty. Now that

the Commission has increased the types of financial instruments that

may be exempted from position limits under this rule, the Commission

believes that it has reduced the likelihood of market disruption

because of forced and unexpected liquidations. In other words, the

Commission believes that reproposed Sec. 150.3(f) will support market

stability.

vii. Section 150.3(g) and (h)--Recordkeeping and Special Calls

The Commission believes that the reproposed Sec. 150.3(g)'s

recordkeeping requirements are critical to the Commission's ability to

effectively monitor compliance with exemption eligibility standards.

Because the Commission will have access to records under Sec.

150.3(h), it will be able to assess whether exemptions are susceptible

to abuse and to support the position-limits regime, which, among other

things, aims to prevent excessive speculation and/or market

manipulation.

d. Costs and Discussion of Comments

As the Commission expressed in the December 2013 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal, the exemptions under reproposed Sec. 150.3

do not increase the costs of complying with position limits. The

Commission continues to believe that many costs will likely decrease by

the Commission providing for relief from position limits in certain

situations. The reproposed Sec. 150.3 exemptions are elective, so no

entity is required to assert an exemption if it determines the costs of

doing so do not justify the potential benefit resulting from the

exemption. While the Commission appreciates that there will be

compliance duties connected to the reproposed Sec. 150.3, the

Commission does not anticipate the costs of obtaining any of the

exemptions to be overly burdensome.\1345\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1345\ See, e.g., the discussion of costs related to non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position determinations, anticipatory

bona fide hedge filings, and spread exemptions below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

i. Section 150.3(a)--Positions Which May Exceed Limits

Because of the proposed changes in the June 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal, reproposed Sec. 150.3(a) must be read with

reproposed Sec. Sec. 150.9, 150.10, and Sec. 150.11. Moreover, the

costs of reproposed Sec. 150.3 are linked to reproposed Sec. Sec.

150.9, 150.10, and Sec. 150.11, and are discussed more fully below.

ii. Section 150.3(b)--Financial Distress Exemption

The Commission's view on the costs related to the financial

distress exemption under reproposed Sec. 150.3(b) remains unchanged.

The costs are likely to be minimal. Market participants who voluntarily

employ these exemptions will incur filing and recordkeeping

[[Page 96863]]

costs. As explained in the 2013 proposal, the Commission cannot

accurately estimate how often this exemption may be invoked because

emergency or distressed market situations are unpredictable and

dependent on a variety of firm- and market-specific factors as well as

general macroeconomic indicators. The Commission, nevertheless,

believes that emergency or distressed market situations that might

trigger the need for this exemption will be infrequent. The Commission

continues to assume that reproposed Sec. 150.3(b) will add

transparency to the process. Finally, the Commission believes that in

the case that one firm is assuming the positions of a financially

distressed firm, the costs of claiming the exemption would be

incidental to the costs of assuming the position.

iii. Section 150.3(c)--Conditional Spot Month Limit Exemption

A natural gas market participant that elects to exercise this

exemption will incur certain direct costs to do so. The natural gas

market participant must file Form 504 in accordance with requirements

listed in reproposed Sec. 19.01. The Commission does not believe that

there will be additional costs, or at least not significant costs,

because exchanges already have the exemption. Given that there has been

experience with this type of exemption for natural gas market

participants,\1346\ the Commission does not believe that liquidity, in

the aggregate (across the core referenced futures contract and

referenced contracts) will be adversely impacted.\1347\ By retaining

the exemption for natural gas contracts, the Commission has heeded

commenters concerns about disrupting market practices and harming

liquidity in the cash market, thus increasing the cost of hedging and

possibly preventing convergence between the physical-delivery futures

and cash markets.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1346\ CL-ICE-59962 at 6-7 (commenter argued that the

conditional limit for natural gas ``has had no adverse consequences

with supply constraints and underlying physical delivery

contracts.'')

\1347\ CL-ICE-59966 at 4-5, CL-ICE-59962 at 5, and CL-IECAssn-

59679 at 30.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iv. Section 150.3(d)--Pre-Enactment and Transition Period Swaps

Exemption

The exemption offered in reproposed Sec. 150.3(d) is self-

executing and will not require a market participant to file for relief.

Nevertheless, as explained in the December 2013 proposal, a market

participant may incur costs to identify positions eligible for the

exemption and to determine if that position is to be netted with post-

enactment swaps for purposes of complying with a non-spot-month

position limit. The Commission believes these costs will not be overly

burdensome, and notes that market participants who assume such costs do

so voluntarily.

v. Section 150.3(e)--Other Exemptions and Previously Granted Exemptions

Under the reproposed Sec. 150.3(e), market participants electing

to seek an exemption other than those specifically enumerated, will

incur certain direct costs to do so. The Commission discussed the

expected costs in the December 2013 proposal and continues to believe

that the same costs will arise should market participants elect

exemptive relief under reproposed Sec. 150.3(e). As explained in the

December 2013 proposal, market participants will incur costs related to

petitioning the Commission under Sec. 140.99 of the Commission's

regulations or under CEA section 4a(a)(7). There also will be

recordkeeping costs for those market participants who elect to pursue a

Sec. 150.3(e) exemption. The Commission believes that these costs will

be minimal, as participants already maintain books and records under a

variety of other Commission regulations and as the information required

in these sections is likely already being maintained. The Commission

has estimated the costs entities might incur and discussed those costs

in the PRA section of this release.

vi. Section 150.3(f)--Previously Granted Exemptions

Market participants who had previously relied upon the exemptions

granted under current Sec. 1.47 will be able to continue to rely on

such exemptions for existing positions under reproposed Sec. 150.3(f).

Between the December 2013 proposal and now, the Commission has

determined to expand the relief in reproposed Sec. 150.3(f). As more

fully discussed above, the Commission amended the regulatory text so

that previously-granted exemptions may apply to pre-existing financial

instruments, rather than only to pre-existing swaps, and to exchange-

granted, non-enumerated exemptions in non-legacy commodity derivatives

outside of the spot month, with other conditions. The Commission

believes that there will be recordkeeping costs but there also will be

cost-savings in the form of market stability because market

participants will not be required to liquidate positions prematurely,

and the relief covers financial instruments not just swaps.

vii. Section 150.3(g) and (h)--Recordkeeping and Special Calls

Under reproposed Sec. 150.3(g) and (h), the costs related to

maintaining and producing records will be minimal because, under most

circumstances, market participants already maintain books and records

in compliance with Commission regulations and as part of prudent

accounting and risk management policies and procedures. The Commission

has estimated the costs entities might incur and discussed those costs

in the PRA section of this release.

6. Section 150.5--Exemptions From Exchange-Set Position Limits

The Dodd-Frank Act scaled back the discretion afforded DCMs for

establishing position limits under the earlier CFMA amendments.

Specifically, among other things, the Dodd-Frank Act: (1) Amended DCM

core principle 5 to require that, with respect to contracts subject to

a position limit set by the Commission under CEA section 4a, a DCM must

set limits no higher than those prescribed by the Commission; \1348\

and (2) added parallel core principle obligations on newly-authorized

SEFs, including SEF core principle 6 regarding the establishment of

position limits.\1349\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1348\ Dodd-Frank Act section 735(b). CEA section 4a(e),

effective prior to, and not amended by, the Dodd-Frank Act, likewise

provides that position limits fixed by a board of trade not exceed

federal limits. 7 U.S.C. 6a(e).

\1349\ Dodd-Frank Act section 733 (adding CEA section 5h; 7

U.S.C. 7b-3).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. Rule Summary

In light of these Dodd-Frank Act statutory amendments, the

Commission has adopted Sec. 150.5 to specify certain requirements and

guidance for DCMs and SEFs establishing exchange-set limits.

Specifically, Sec. 150.5(a)(1) requires that DCMs and SEFs set

position limits for commodity derivative contracts, subject to federal

position limits, at a level not higher than the Commission's levels

specified in Sec. 150.2. In addition, exchanges with cash-settled

contracts price-linked to contracts subject to federal limits must also

adopt limit levels not higher than federal position limits.

Further, Sec. 150.5(a)(5) requires for all contracts subject to

federal speculative limits, and Sec. Sec. 150.5(b)(8) and 150.5(c)(8)

suggest for other contracts not subject to federal speculative limits,

that designated contract markets and swap execution facilities adopt

aggregation rules that conform to Sec. 150.4. Regulation Sec.

150.5(a)(2)(i) requires for all contracts subject to federal

speculative limits, and

[[Page 96864]]

regulations Sec. Sec. 150.5(b)(5)(i)(A) and (c)(5)(1) suggest for

other contracts not subject to federal speculative limits, that

exchanges conform their bona fide hedging exemption rules to the Sec.

150.1 definition of bona fide hedging position.

Regulation Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(ii) requires, and Sec. Sec.

150.5(b)(5)(iii) and (c)(5)(iii) suggest that exchanges condition any

exemptive relief from federal or exchange-set position limits on an

application from the trader. And, if granted an exemption, such trader

must reapply for such exemption at least on an annual basis. As noted

supra, the Commission understands that requiring traders to apply for

exemptive relief comports with existing DCM practice; thus, the

Commission anticipates that the codification of this requirement will

have the practical effect of incrementally increasing, rather than

creating, the burden of applying for such exemptive relief.

Finally, under Sec. 150.5(b) and Sec. 150.5(c) for commodity

derivative contracts not subject to federal position limits, the

Commission provides guidance for exchanges to use their reasonable

discretion to set exchange position limits and exempt market

participants from exchange-set limits. This includes, under Sec.

150.5(b), commodity derivative contracts in a physical commodity as

defined in Sec. 150.1, and, under Sec. 150.5(c), excluded commodity

derivative contracts as defined in section 1a(19) of the Act.

b. Baseline

The baseline is the current reasonable discretion afforded to

exchanges to exempt market participant from their exchange-set position

limits.

c. Benefits and Costs

Functioning as an integrated component within the broader position

limits regulatory regime, the Commission expects the proposed changes

to Sec. 150.5 will further the four objectives outlined in CEA section

4a(a)(3).\1350\ The Commission has endeavored to preserve the status

quo baseline within the framework of establishing new federal position

limits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1350\ CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B) applies for purposes of setting

federal limit levels. 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(3)(B). The Commission considers

the four factors set out in the section relevant for purposes of

considering the benefits and costs of these amendments addressed to

exchange-set position limits as well.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The reproposed regulations require that exchange-set limits employ

aggregation policies that conform to the Commission's aggregation

policy for contracts that are subject to federal limits under Sec.

150.2, thus harmonizing aggregation rules for all federal and exchange-

set speculative position limits. For contracts subject to federal

speculative position limits under Sec. 150.2, the Commission

anticipates that a harmonized approach to aggregation will prevent

confusion that otherwise might result from allowing divergent standards

between federal and exchange-set limits on the same contracts. Further,

the harmonized approach to aggregation policies for limits on all

levels eliminates the potential for exchanges to use permissiveness in

aggregation policies as a competitive advantage, which would impair the

effectiveness of the Commission's aggregation policy. In addition, DCMs

and SEFs are required to set position limits at a level not higher than

that set by the Commission. Differing aggregation standards may have

the practical effect of increasing a DCM- or SEF-set limit to a level

that is higher than that set by the Commission. Accordingly,

harmonizing aggregation standards reinforces the efficacy and intended

purpose of Sec. Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(ii), (b)(5)(iii) and (c)(5)(iii) by

foreclosing an avenue to circumvent applicable limits. Moreover, by

extending this harmonized approach to contracts not included in Sec.

150.2, the Commission encourages a common standard for all federal and

exchange-set limits. The adopted rule provides uniformity, consistency,

and certainty for traders who are active on multiple trading venues,

and thus should reduce the administrative burden on traders as well as

the burden on the Commission in monitoring the markets under its

jurisdiction.

With respect to exchange-set limits, DCM and SEF core principles

already address the costs associated with the requirement that

exchanges set position limits no higher than federal limits. Further,

for commodity derivatives contracts subject to federal position limits,

exchanges are provided the discretion to decide whether or not to set

position-limits that are lower than the federal position limit.

Finally, when an exchange grants an exemption from a lower exchange-set

limit, it is not required to use the Commission's bona fide hedging

position definition so long as the exempted position does not exceed

the federal position limit.

To the extent that a DCM or SEF grants exemptions, the Commission

anticipates that exchanges and market participants will incur minimal

costs to administer the application process for exemption relief in

accordance with standards set forth in the proposed rule. The

Commission understands that requiring traders to apply for exemptive

relief comports with existing DCM practice. Accordingly, by

incorporating an application requirement that the Commission has reason

to understand most if not all active DCMs already follow, the impact of

the potential costs has been reduced because the nature of the

exemption process is similar to what DCMs already have in place. For

SEFs, the rules necessitate a compliant application regime, which will

require an initial investment similar to that which DCMs have likely

already made and need not duplicate. As noted above, the Commission

considers it highly likely that, in accordance with industry best

practices, to comply with core principles and due to the utility of

application information in demonstrating compliance with core

principles, SEFs may incur such costs with or without the adopted

rules. Again, due to the new existence of these entities, the

Commission is unable to estimate what costs may be associated with the

requirement to impose an application regime for exemptive relief on the

exchange level.

Also, with respect to phasing, exchanges are not required to use

the Commission's definition of bona fide hedging position when setting

positon limits on commodity derivative contracts in a physical

commodity that are not subject to federal position limits (and when

exchanges grant an exemption from exchange-set limits if such exemption

does not exceed the federal limit) or excluded commodity derivative

contracts. Nevertheless, exchanges are free to use the Commission's

bona fide hedging position definition if they so choose.

Relative to the status quo baseline, this rulemaking imposes a

ceiling on exchange-set position limits for referenced contracts in 25

commodities. The core principals already require such ceiling, and such

costs are addressed in the part 37 and 38 rulemakings. As mandated and

necessary, this rule adopts limits for 16 additional commodities. In

addition, market participants may be facing hard position limits on

some contract that previously only had accountability levels. As such,

this rulemaking will confer any benefits that hard position limits have

over accountability levels. This may include information gleaned from

exemption applications that will better inform the supervisory

functions of DCMs or SEFs as well as to protect markets from any

adverse effects from market participants that hold positions in excess

of an exchange set position limit. In addition, exchanges retain the

ability to set accountability levels lower than the levels of the

position limits; if an exchanges chooses to adopt such accountability

levels, they would

[[Page 96865]]

provide exchanges with additional information regarding positions of

various market participants.

Exchanges and market participants will have to adapt to new federal

position limits. Position limits will alter the way that swap and

futures trading is conducted. For many contracts that did not have

federal limits, participants will be facing new exchange set position

limits in the spot, single month, and all months combined. Such limits

may impose new compliance costs on exchanges and market participants.

These compliance costs may consists of adapting the method of

aggregating contracts and filing for exchange exemptions to position

limits. The Commission anticipates that these costs will be higher for

contracts that have only had accountability levels and not hard

exchange-set position limits. Exchange-set position limits may also

deter some speculators from fully participating and affecting the price

of some futures contracts. The Commission expects that for the most

part, exchange-set position limits will not have much effect except for

rare circumstances when exemptions to exchange set limits do not apply

or other derivative contracts such as swap contracts (below the federal

limit), forwards, or trade options are not adequate to meet a market

participant's needs.

d. Response to Commenter

A commenter asked whether the Supplemental Proposal's cost-benefit

analysis assesses the appropriateness of such requirement on exchange-

set speculative position limits or includes the costs of processing

non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions and Spread Exemptions for

contracts subject only to exchange-set speculative position limits and

not federal speculative position limits.\1351\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1351\ CL-Working Group-60947 at 14.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that if an exchange elects to set a position

limit lower than a federal limit, the costs resulting from such choices

are not imposed by Sec. 150.5, because the exchange has made the

choice not the Commission. The costs on market participants to apply

for exchange set limits below the federal level are also discussed in

Sec. 150.2. The Commission is unable to forecast these costs, because

it does not know when an exchange will set its limits lower than the

federal limit; nor does it know how low any such exchange-set position

limit level may be.

This rulemaking maintains the status quo for exchange-set

speculative limits for contracts not subject to federal limits.

Therefore, there are no costs and benefits resulting from this

rulemaking on the processing of such exemptions.

7. Section 150.7--Reporting Requirements for Anticipatory Hedging

Positions

a. Rule Summary

The revised definition of bona fide hedging position reproposed in

Sec. 150.1 of this rule incorporates hedges of five specific types of

anticipated transactions: Unfilled anticipated requirements, unsold

anticipated production, anticipated royalties, anticipated service

contract payments or receipts, and anticipatory cross-hedges.\1352\ The

Commission is reproposing new requirements in Sec. 150.7 for traders

seeking an exemption from position limits for any of these five

enumerated anticipated hedging transactions that were designed to build

on, and replace, the special reporting requirements for hedging of

unsold anticipated production and unfilled anticipated requirements in

current Sec. 1.48.\1353\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1352\ See paragraphs 3(iii), 4(i), 4(iii), 4(iv) and (5),

respectively, of the Commission's definition of bona fide hedging

position in Sec. 150.1 as discussed supra.

\1353\ See 17 CFR 1.48. See also definition of bona fide hedging

transactions in current 17 CFR 1.3(z)(2)(i)(B) and (ii)(C),

respectively.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission proposed to add a new series '04 reporting form,

Form 704, to effectuate these additional and updated reporting

requirements for anticipatory hedges. Persons wishing to avail

themselves of an exemption for any of the anticipatory hedging

transactions enumerated in the updated definition of bona fide hedging

position in Sec. 150.1 would be required to file an initial statement

on Form 704 with the Commission at least ten days in advance of the

date that such positions would be in excess of limits established in

Sec. 150.2.

Reproposed Sec. 150.7(f) adds a requirement for any person who

files an initial statement on Form 704 to provide annual updates that

detail the person's actual cash market activities related to the

anticipated exemption. Reproposed Sec. 150.7(g) enables the Commission

to review and compare the actual cash activities and the remaining

unused anticipated hedge transactions by requiring monthly reporting on

Form 204.

As is the case under current Sec. 1.48, reproposed Sec. 150.7(h)

required that a trader's maximum sales and purchases must not exceed

the lesser of the approved exemption amount or the trader's current

actual anticipated transaction.

b. Baseline

The baseline is current Sec. 1.48.

c. Benefits and Costs

The Commission remains concerned that distinguishing whether an

over-the-limit position is entered into in order to reduce risk arising

from anticipatory needs, or whether it is excess speculation, may be

exceedingly difficult if anticipatory transactions are not well

defined. The Commission is, therefore, reproposing the collection of

Form 704 to collect information that is vital in performing this

distinction. While there will be costs associated with fulfilling

obligations related to anticipatory hedging, the Commission believes

that advance notice of a trader's intended maximum position in

commodity derivative contracts to offset anticipatory risks would

identify--in advance--a position as a bona fide hedging position,

avoiding unnecessary contact during the trading day with surveillance

staff to verify whether a hedge exemption application is in process,

the appropriate level for the exemption and whether the exemption is

being used in a manner that is consistent with the requirements. Market

participants can anticipate hedging needs well in advance of assuming

positions in derivatives markets and in many cases need to supply the

same information after the fact; in such cases, providing the

information in advance allows the Commission to better direct its

efforts towards deterring and detecting manipulation. The annual

updates in Sec. 150.7(d) similarly allow the Commission to verify on

an ongoing basis that the person's anticipated cash market

transactions, estimated in good faith, closely track that person's real

cash market activities. Absent monthly filing pursuant to Sec.

150.7(e), the Commission would need to issue a special call to

determine why a person's commodity derivative contract position is, for

example, larger than the pro rata balance of her annually reported

anticipated production. The Commission believes it is reproposing a low

cost method of obtaining the necessary information to ensure that

anticipatory hedges are valid.\1354\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1354\ The Commission understands that there will be costs

associated with the filing of Form 704. Costs of filing that form

are discussed in the context of the part 19 requirements as well as

in the Paperwork Reduction Act section of this release.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

d. Summary of Comments

One commenter asserted that the reporting requirements for

anticipatory hedges of an operational or commercial

[[Page 96866]]

risk comprising an initial, supplementary and annual report are unduly

burdensome. The commenter recommended that the Commission require

either an initial and annual report or an initial and supplementary

report.\1355\ Another commenter agreed that the proposed requirements

to file Forms 204, 704 and/or 604 ``are unduly burdensome and

commercially impracticable,'' and stated that the Commission should

``scale back both the frequency and the content of the filings required

to maintain bona fide hedge positions.'' \1356\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1355\ CL-IECAssn-59679 at 11.

\1356\ CL-BG Group-59656 at 11.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter suggested deleting Form 704 because it believes

that no matter how extensive the Commission makes reporting

requirements, the Commission will still need to request additional

information on a case-by-case basis to ensure hedge transactions are

legitimate.\1357\ The commenter suggested that the Commission should be

able to achieve its goal of obtaining enough information to determine

whether to request additional information using Form 204 along with

currently collected data sources and so the additional burden of the

new series '04 reports outweighs the benefit to the Commission.\1358\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1357\ CL-NGFA-60941 at 7-8.

\1358\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters remarked on the cost associated with Form 704.

One commenter stated that the additional reporting requirements,

including new Form 704 to replace the reporting requirements under

current rule 1.48, and annual and monthly reporting requirements under

rules 150.7(f) and 150.7(g) ``will impose significant additional

regulatory and compliance burdens on commercials;'' the commenter

believes that the Commission should consider alternatives, including

targeted special calls when appropriate.\1359\ Another commenter stated

the reporting requirements for the series 04 forms is overly burdensome

and would impose a substantial cost to market participants because

while the proposal would require the Commission to respond fairly

quickly, it does not provide an indication of whether the Commission

will deem the requirement accepted if the Commission does not respond

within a stated time frame. The commenter is concerned that a market

participant may have to refuse business if it does not receive an

approved exemption in advance of a transaction.\1360\ A third commenter

stated that Form 704 is ``commercially impracticable and unduly

burdensome'' because it would require filers to ``analyze each

transaction to see if it fits into an enumerated hedge category.'' The

commenter is concerned that such ``piecemeal review'' would require a

legal memorandum and the development of new software to track positions

and, since the Commission proposed that Form 704 to be used in proposed

Sec. 150.11, the burden associated with the form has increased.\1361\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1359\ CL-APGA-59722 at 10.

\1360\ CL-EDF-59961 at 6.

\1361\ CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Finally, a commenter stated that the Commission significantly

underestimated costs associated with reporting, and provided revised

estimates of start-up and ongoing compliance costs for filing Form

704.\1362\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1362\ CL-FIA at 35-36.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As discussed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission remains concerned about distinguishing between anticipatory

reduction of risk and speculation.\1363\ Therefore, the Commission is

retaining the requirement to file Form 704 for anticipatory hedges. The

Commission notes that most of the information required on Form 704 is

currently required under Sec. 1.48, and that such information is not

found in any other Commission data source, including Form 204.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1363\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75746.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is adopting the commenters' suggestions, however, to

reduce the frequency of filings by maintaining the requirement for the

initial statement and annual update but eliminating the supplemental

filing as proposed in Sec. 150.7(e). After considering the commenter's

concerns, the Commission believes the monthly reporting on Form 204 and

annual updates on Form 704 will provide sufficient updates to the

initial statement and is deleting the supplemental filing provision in

proposed Sec. 150.7(e) to reduce the burden on filers. The Commission

has made several burden-reducing changes to Form 704 and Sec.

150.7(d), including merging the initial statement and annual update

sections of Form 704, clarifying and amending the instructions to Form

704, and eliminating redundant information.\1364\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1364\ See, supra, discussion of changes to Form 704 and Sec.

150.7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to the commenter who suggested the Commission consider

targeted special calls and other alternatives to the annual and monthly

filings, the Commission believes these filings are critical to the

Commission's Surveillance program. Anticipatory hedges, because they

are by definition forward-looking, require additional detail regarding

the firm's commercial practices in order to ensure that a firm is not

using the provisions in proposed Sec. 150.7 to evade position limits.

In contrast, special calls are backward-looking and would not provide

the Commission's Surveillance program with the information needed to

prevent markets from being susceptible to excessive speculation.

However, the Commission expects the new filing requirements to be an

improvement over current practice under Sec. 1.48 because as facts and

circumstances change, the Commission's Surveillance program will have a

more timely understanding of the market participant's hedging needs.

The Commission notes in response to the commenter that there is no

requirement to analyze individual transactions or submit a memorandum.

Finally, while costs of filing Form 704 are discussed below in the

context of part 19, the Commission notes that changes made to the

frequency of the forms should help alleviate some of the cost burdens

associated with filing Form 704.

8. Part 19--Reports

CEA Section 4i authorizes the Commission to require the filing of

reports, as described in CEA section 4g, when positions equal or exceed

position limits. Current part 19 of the Commission's regulations sets

forth these reporting requirements for persons holding or controlling

reportable futures and option positions that constitute bona fide

hedging positions as defined in Sec. 1.3(z) and in markets with

federal speculative position limits--namely those for grains, the soy

complex, and cotton. Since having a bona fide hedging position

exemption affords a commercial market participant the opportunity to

hold positions that exceed a position limit level, it is important for

the Commission to be able to verify that, when an exemption is invoked,

that it is done so for legitimate purposes. As such, commercial

entities that hold positions in excess of those limits must file

information on a monthly basis pertaining to owned stocks and purchase

and sales commitments for entities that claim a bona fide hedging

position exemption.

In order to help ensure that the additional exemptions described in

Sec. 150.3 are used in accordance with the requirements of the

exemption

[[Page 96867]]

employed, as well as obtain information necessary to verify that any

futures, options and swaps positions established in referenced

contracts are justified, the Commission is making conforming and

substantive amendments to part 19. First, the Commission is amending

part 19 by adding new and modified cross-references to proposed part

150, including the new definition of bona fide hedging position in

reproposed Sec. 150.1.\1365\ Second, the Commission is amending Sec.

19.00(a) by extending reporting requirements to any person claiming any

exemption from federal position limits pursuant to reproposed Sec.

150.3. The Commission is adding three new series '04 reporting forms to

effectuate these additional reporting requirements. Third, the

Commission is updating the manner of part 19 reporting. Lastly, the

Commission is updating both the type of data that would be required in

series '04 reports, as well as the time allotted for filing such

reports.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1365\ These amendments are non-substantive conforming

amendments and do not have implications for the Commission's

consideration of costs and benefits.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Below, the Commission describes each of the proposed changes;

responds to commenters; and considers the costs and benefits of such

changes.\1366\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1366\ The Commission notes that comments related to costs and

benefits are described in this section, and other comments regarding

these provisions are discussed in the section supra that describes

the reproposed rules for part 19. For a complete picture of the

comments received, the Commission's response to comments, and the

reproposed rules, all sections of this preamble should be read

together.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. Amendments to Part 19

In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

proposed to amend part 19 so that it would conform to the Commission's

proposed changes to part 150.\1367\ The proposed conforming amendments

included: Amending part 19 by adding new and modified cross-references

to proposed part 150, including the new definition of bona fide hedging

position in proposed Sec. 150.1; updating Sec. 19.00(a) by extending

reporting requirements to any person claiming any exemption from

federal position limits pursuant to proposed Sec. 150.3; adding new

series '04 reporting forms to effectuate these additional reporting

requirements; updating the manner of part 19 reporting; and updating

both the type of data that would be required in series '04 reports as

well as the timeframe for filing such reports.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1367\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75741-46.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Baseline

The baseline is current part 19.

c. Summary of Comments

The Commission received several comments regarding the general

nature of series '04 reports and/or the manner in which such reports

are required to be filed. One commenter stated that the various forms

required by the regime, while not lengthy, represent significant data

collection and categorization that will require a non-trivial amount of

work to accurately prepare and file. The commenter claimed that a

comprehensive position limits regime could be implemented with a ``far

less burdensome'' set of filings and requested that the Commission

review the proposed forms and ensure they are ``as clear, limited, and

workable'' as possible to reduce burden. The commenter stated that it

is not aware of any software vendors that currently provide solutions

that can support a commercial firm's ability to file the proposed

forms.\1368\ Another commenter supports the Commission's decision to

require applications for risk management exemptions but requests the

Commission to reevaluate the cost the forms will impose such as new

compliance programs, training of staff, and purchasing or modifying

data management systems in order to meet and maintain the compliance

requirements.\1369\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1368\ CL-COPE-59662 at 24, CL-COPE-60932 at 10. See also CL-

EEI-EPSA-60925 at 9.

\1369\ CL-EDF-59961 at 6-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters requested that the Commission create user-

friendly guidebooks for the forms so that all entities can clearly

understand any required forms and build the appropriate systems to file

such forms, including providing workshops and/or hot lines to improve

the forms.\1370\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1370\ See CL-COPE-59662 at 24, CL-COPE-60932 at 10; CL-ASR-

60933 at 4; CL-Working Group-60947 at 17-18; CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Finally, two commenters recommended modifying or removing the

requirement to certify series '04 reports as ``true and correct.'' One

commenter suggested that the requirement be removed due to the

difficulty of making such a certification and the fact that CEA section

6(c)(2) already prohibits the submission of false or misleading

information.\1371\ Another noted that the requirement to report very

specific information relating to hedges and cash market activity

involves data that may change over time. The commenter suggested the

Commission adopt a good-faith standard regarding ``best effort''

estimates of the data when verifying the accuracy of Form 204

submissions.\1372\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1371\ See, CL-CMC-59634 at 17.

\1372\ CL-Working Group-59693 at 65.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is reproposing the amendments to part 19. The

Commission agrees with the commenters that the forms should be clear

and workable, and offers several clarifications and amendments in other

sections of this release in response to comments about particular

aspects of the series '04 reports.\1373\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1373\ See, supra, discussion of reproposed rules regarding

series '04 reports and part 19.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that the information required on the series

'04 reports represents a trader's most basic position data, including

the number of units of the cash commodity that the firm has purchased

or sold, or the size of a swap position that is being offset in the

futures market. The Commission believes this information is readily

available to traders, who routinely make trading decisions based on the

same data that is required on the series '04 reports. The Commission is

moving to an entirely electronic filing system, allowing for

efficiencies in populating and submitting forms that require the same

information every month. Most traders who are required to file the

series '04 reports must do so for only one day out of the month,

further lowering the burden for filers. In short, the Commission

believes potential burdens have been reduced while still providing

adequate information for the Commission's Surveillance program. For

market participants who may require assistance in monitoring for

speculative position limits and gathering the information required for

the series '04 reports, the Commission is aware of several software

companies who, prior to the vacation of the Part 151 Rulemaking,

produced tools that could be useful to market participants in

fulfilling their compliance obligations under the new position limits

regime.

In response to the commenters that requested guidebooks for the

series '04 reporting forms, the Commission has revised the series '04

forms and the instructions to such forms as discussed supra in this

release. The Commission believes that it is less confusing to ensure

that form instructions are clear and detailed than it is to provide

generalized guidebooks that may not respond to specific issues. The

Commission's longstanding experience with collecting and reviewing Form

204 and Form 304 has shown that many questions about the series '04

reports are specific to the circumstances and trading strategies of an

individual

[[Page 96868]]

market participant, and do not lend themselves to generalization that

would be helpful to many market participants. The Commission notes

that, should a market participant have questions regarding how to file

a particular form, they are encouraged to contact Commission staff

directly to get answers tailored to their particular circumstances.

Finally, the Commission is amending the certification language

found at the end of each form to clarify that the certification

requires nothing more than is already required of market participants

in CEA section 6(c)(2). The Commission believes the certification

language is an important reminder to reporting traders of their

responsibilities to file accurate information under several sections of

the Act, including but not limited to CEA section 6(c)(2).

d. Information Required on Series '04 Reports

i. Bona Fide Hedgers Reporting on Form 204--Sec. 19.01(a)(3)

Current Sec. 19.01(a) sets forth the data that must be provided by

bona fide hedgers (on Form 204) and by merchants and dealers in cotton

(on Form 304). The Commission proposed to continue using Forms 204 and

304, which will feature only minor changes to the types of data to be

reported under Sec. 19.01(a)(3).\1374\ These changes include removing

the modifier ``fixed price'' from ``fixed price cash position;''

requiring cash market position information to be submitted in both the

cash market unit of measurement (e.g., barrels or bushels) and futures

equivalents; and adding a specific request for data concerning open

price contracts to accommodate open price pairs. In addition, the

monthly reporting requirements for cotton, including the granularity of

equity, certificated and non-certificated cotton stocks, would be moved

to Form 204, while weekly reporting for cotton would be retained as a

separate report made on Form 304 in order to maintain the collection of

data required by the Commission to publish its weekly public cotton

``on call'' report.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1374\ The list of data required for persons filing on Forms 204

and 304 has been relocated from current Sec. 19.01(a) to reproposed

Sec. 19.01(a)(3).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter suggested that the costs to industry participants in

collecting and submitting Form 204 data and to the Commission in

reviewing it ``greatly outweigh'' the regulatory benefit. The commenter

recommended that the Commission undertake a cost-benefit analysis to

reconsider what information is required to be provided under part 19

and on Form 204 and limit that information only to what will assist

Commission staff in assessing the validity of claimed hedge

exemptions.\1375\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1375\ CL-Working Group-60396 at 17-18.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter stated that CFTC should reduce the complexity and

compliance burden of bona fide hedging record keeping and reporting by

using a model similar to the current exchange-based exemption

process.\1376\ The commenter also stated that the requirement to keep

records and file reports, in futures equivalents, regarding the

commercial entity's cash market contracts and derivative market

positions on a real-time basis globally, will be complex and impose a

significant compliance burden. The commenter noted such records are not

needed for commercial purposes.\1377\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1376\ CL-ASR-59668 at 3.

\1377\ Id. at 7. See also CL-ASR-60933 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another commenter recommended that the Commission should require a

market participant with a position in excess of a spot-month position

limit to report on Form 204 only the cash-market activity related to

that particular spot-month derivative position, and not to require it

to report cash-market activity related to non-spot-month positions

where it did not exceed a non-spot-month position limit; the commenter

stated that the burden associated with such a reporting obligation

would increase significantly.\1378\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1378\ CL-FIA-59595 at 38.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter recommended that reporting rules require traders to

identify the specific risk being hedged at the time a trade is

initiated, to maintain records of termination or unwinding of a hedge

when the underlying risk has been sold or otherwise resolved, and to

create a practical audit trail for individual trades, to discourage

traders from attempting to mask speculative trades under the guise of

hedges.\1379\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1379\ CL-Sen. Levin-59637 at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission recognizes that market participants will incur costs

to file Form 204; these costs are described in detail below. However,

the Commission believes that the costs of filing Form 204 are not

overly burdensome for market participants, most of whom currently file

similar information with either the Commission or the exchanges in

order to obtain and maintain exemptions from speculative position

limits. The Commission believes it is reproposing requirements for Form

204 that provide the Commission with the most basic information

possible to ascertain the veracity of claimed bona fide hedging

positions. The Commission has in some cases accepted commenter

suggestions to reduce or amend the information required in order to

reduce confusion and alleviate burden on filers.\1380\ Where the

Commission has retained required information fields, the Commission

believes, based on its longstanding experience conducting surveillance

in the markets it oversees, that such fields are necessary to determine

the legitimacy of claimed bona fide hedging position exemptions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1380\ See supra the Commission's determinations regarding part

19

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that, while the exchange referred to by the

commenter does not have a reporting process analogous to Form 204, it

does require an application prior to the establishment of a position

that exceeds a position limit. In contrast, advance notice is not

required for most federal enumerated bona fide hedging positions.\1381\

In the Commission's experience, the series '04 reports have been useful

and beneficial to the Commission's Surveillance program and the

Commission finds no compelling reason to change the forms to conform to

the exchange's process. Further, the Commission notes that Form 204 is

filed once a month as of the close of business of the last Friday of

the month; it is not and has never been required to be filed on a real-

time basis globally. A market participant only has to file Form 204 if

it is over the limit at any point during the month, and the form

requires only cash market activity (not derivatives market positions).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1381\ The Commission notes that advance notice is required for

recognition of anticipatory hedging positions by the Commission. See

supra for more discussion of anticipatory hedging reporting

requirements.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission has never distinguished between spot-month limits

and non-spot-month limits with respect to the filing of Form 204. The

Commission notes that, as discussed in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal, Form 204 is used to review positions that exceed

speculative limits in general, not just in the spot-month.\1382\

Because of this, the Commission is proposing not to adopt the

commenter's recommendation to

[[Page 96869]]

only require Form 204 when a market participant exceeds a spot-month

limit.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1382\ The Commission stated that the Form 204 ``must show the

trader's positions in the cash market and are used by the Commission

to determine whether a trader has sufficient cash positions that

justify futures and option positions above the speculative limits''

because the Commission is seeking to ``ensure that any person who

claims any exemption from federal speculative position limits can

demonstrate a legitimate purpose for doing so.'' See December 2013

Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75741-42.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to the commenter who suggested the Commission require a

``practical audit trail'' for bona fide hedgers, the Commission notes

that other sections of the Commission's regulations provide rules

regarding detailed individual transaction recordkeeping as suggested by

the commenter.

ii. Conditional Spot-Month Limit Exemption Reporting on Form 504--Sec.

19.01(a)(1)

As proposed, Sec. 19.01(a)(1) would require persons availing

themselves of the conditional spot-month limit exemption (pursuant to

proposed Sec. 150.3(c)) to report certain detailed information

concerning their cash market activities for any commodity specially

designated by the Commission for reporting under Sec. 19.03 of this

part. In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the Commission

noted its concern about the cash market trading of those availing

themselves of the conditional spot-month limit exemption and so

proposed to require that persons claiming a conditional spot-month

limit exemption must report on new Form 504 daily, by 9 a.m. Eastern

Time on the next business day, for each day that a person is over the

spot-month limit in certain special commodity contracts specified by

the Commission.

The Commission proposed to require reporting on new Form 504 for

conditional spot-month limit exemptions in the natural gas commodity

derivative contracts only, until the Commission gains additional

experience with the limits in proposed Sec. 150.2 in other commodities

as well.

Benefits and Costs

The reporting requirements allow the Commission to obtain the

information necessary to verify whether the relevant exemption

requirements are fulfilled in a timely manner. This is needed for the

Commission to help ensure that any person who claims any exemption from

federal speculative position limits can demonstrate a legitimate

purpose for doing so. In the absence of the reporting requirements

detailed in part 19, the Commission would lack critical tools to

identify abuses related to the exemptions afforded in Sec. 150.3 in a

timely manner. As such, the reporting requirements are necessary for

the Commission to be able to perform its essential surveillance

functions. These reporting requirements therefore promote the

Commission's ability to achieve, to the maximum extent practicable, the

statutory factors outlined by Congress in CEA section 4a(a)(3).

The Commission recognizes there will be costs associated with the

changes and additions to the report filing requirements under part 19.

Though the Commission anticipates that market participants should have

ready access to much of the required information, the Commission

expects that, at least initially, market participants will require

additional time and effort to become familiar with new and amended

series '04 forms, to gather the necessary information in the required

format, and to file reports in the proposed timeframes. As described

above, the Commission has attempted to mitigate the cost impacts of

these reports.

Actual costs incurred by market participants will vary depending on

the diversity of their cash market positions and the experience that

the participants currently have regarding filing Form 204 and Form 304

as well as a variety of other organizational factors. However, the

Commission has estimated average incremental burdens associated with

the proposed rules in order to fulfill its obligations under the

Paperwork Reduction Act (``PRA'').\1383\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1383\ See supra for discussion of the Commission's Paperwork

Reduction Act estimates and explanation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For Form 204, the Commission estimates that approximately 425

market participants will file an average of 12 reports annually at an

estimated labor burden of 3 hours per response for a total per-entity

hour burden of approximately 36 hours, which computes to a total annual

burden of 15,300 hours for all affected entities. Using an estimated

hourly wage of $122 per hour,\1384\ the Commission estimates an annual

per-entity cost of approximately $4,392 and a total annual cost of

$1,866,600 for all affected entities. These estimates are summarized

below in Table IV-A-1.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1384\ The Commission's estimates concerning the wage rates are

based on 2011 salary information for the securities industry

compiled by the Securities Industry and Financial Markets

Association (``SIFMA''). The Commission is using $122 per hour,

which is derived from a weighted average of salaries across

different professions from the SIFMA Report on Management &

Professional Earnings in the Securities Industry 2013, modified to

account for an 1800-hour work-year, adjusted to account for the

average rate of inflation since 2013, and multiplied by 1.33 to

account for benefits and 1.5 to account for overhead and

administrative expenses. The Commission anticipates that compliance

with the provisions would require the work of an information

technology professional; a compliance manager; an accounting

professional; and an associate general counsel. Thus, the wage rate

is a weighted national average of salary for professionals with the

following titles (and their relative weight); ``programmer

(senior)'' and ``programmer (non-senior)'' (15% weight), ``senior

accountant'' (15%) ``compliance manager'' (30%), and ``assistant/

associate general counsel'' (40%). All monetary estimates have been

rounded to the nearest hundred dollars.

Table IV-A-1--Burden Estimates for Form 204

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours of responses Hourly wage Per-entity

respondents per response per respondent estimate labor cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Form 204........................................................... 425 3 12 $122.00 $4,392

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

For Form 304, the Commission estimates that approximately 200

market participants will file an average of 52 reports annually at an

estimated labor burden of 1 hour per response for a total per-entity

hour burden of approximately 52hours, which computes to a total annual

burden of 10,400 hours for all affected entities. Using an estimated

hourly wage of $122 per hour, the Commission estimates an annual per-

entity cost of approximately $6,344 and a total annual cost of

$1,268,800 for all affected entities. These estimates are summarized

below in Table IV-A-2.

[[Page 96870]]

Table IV-A-2--Burden Estimates for Form 304

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours of responses Hourly wage Per-entity

respondents per response per respondent estimate labor cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Form 304........................................................... 200 1 52 $122.00 $6,344

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

For Form 504, the Commission estimates that approximately 40 market

participants will file an average of 12 reports annually at an

estimated labor burden of 15 hours per response for a total per-entity

hour burden of approximately 180 hours, which computes to a total

annual burden of 7,200 hours for all affected entities. Using an

estimated hourly wage of $122 per hour, the Commission estimates an

annual per-entity cost of approximately $21,960 and a total annual cost

of $878,400 for all affected entities. These estimates are summarized

below in Table IV-A-3.

Table IV-A-3--Burden Estimates for Form 504

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours of responses Hourly wage Per-entity

respondents per response per respondent estimate labor cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Form 504........................................................... 40 15 12 $122.00 $21,960

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

For Form 604 filed outside of the spot month, the Commission

estimates that approximately 250 market participants will file an

average of 10 reports annually at an estimated labor burden of 30 hours

per response for a total per-entity hour burden of approximately 300

hours, which computes to a total annual burden of 75,000 hours for all

affected entities. Using an estimated hourly wage of $122 per hour, the

Commission estimates an annual per-entity cost of approximately $36,600

and a total annual cost of $9,150,000 for all affected entities. For

Form 604 filed during of the spot month, the Commission estimates that

approximately 100 market participants will file an average of 10

reports annually at an estimated labor burden of 20 hours per response

for a total per-entity hour burden of approximately 200 hours, which

computes to a total annual burden of 20,000 hours for all affected

entities. Using an estimated hourly wage of $122 per hour, the

Commission estimates an annual per-entity cost of approximately $24,400

and a total annual cost of $2,440,000 for all affected entities. These

estimates are summarized below in Table IV-A-4.

Table IV-A-4--Burden Estimates for Form 604

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number

Required record or report Total number Burden hours of responses Hourly wage Per-entity

of respondents per response per respondent estimate labor cost

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Form 604, Non-Spot-Month........ 250 30 10 $122.00 $36,600

Form 604, Spot-Month............ 100 20 10 122.00 24,400

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

For initial statements filed on Form 704, the Commission estimates

that approximately 250 market participants will file an average of 1

report annually at an estimated labor burden of 15 hours per response

for a total per-entity hour burden of approximately 15 hours, which

computes to a total annual burden of 3,750 hours for all affected

entities. Using an estimated hourly wage of $122 per hour, the

Commission estimates an annual per-entity cost of approximately $1,830

and a total annual cost of $457,500 for all affected entities. For

annual updates filed on Form 704, the Commission estimates that

approximately 250 market participants will file an average of 1 report

annually at an estimated labor burden of 8 hours per response for a

total per-entity hour burden of approximately 8 hours, which computes

to a total annual burden of 2,000 hours for all affected entities.

Using an estimated hourly wage of $122 per hour, the Commission

estimates an annual per-entity cost of approximately $976 and a total

annual cost of $244,000 for all affected entities. These estimates are

summarized below in Table IV-A-5.

Table IV-A-5--Burden Estimates for Form 704

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number

Required record or report Total number Burden hours of responses Hourly wage Per-entity

of respondents per response per respondent estimate labor cost

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Form 704, Initial Statement..... 250 15 1 $122 $1,830

Form 704, Annual Update......... 250 8 1 122 976

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96871]]

(2) Summary of Comments

Several commenters seemed not to understand which market

participants will be required to file Form 504, as many made comments

regarding the burden on bona fide hedgers (who are not required to file

Form 504). One commenter stated its belief that the information

required on Form 504 is redundant of information required on Form 204

and would overly burden hedgers.\1385\ Another commenter stated that

Form 504 creates a burden for hedgers to track their cash business and

affected contracts and to create systems to file multiple forms. The

commenter noted its belief that end-users/hedgers should never be

subjected to the daily filing of reports.\1386\ Another commenter

requested that the Commission change the Proposed Rule to permit market

participants that rely on the conditional limit to file monthly bona

fide hedging reports rather than a daily filing of all cash market

positions because Form 504 would impose significant burdens on

commercial market participants with cash market positions, particularly

when compared to purely speculative traders who do not hold cash market

positions.\1387\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1385\ CL-Working Group-59693 at 65-66

\1386\ CL-COPE-59662 at 24

\1387\ See, CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A commenter suggested that the Commission should modify the data

requirements for Form 504 in a manner similar to the approach used by

ICE Futures U.S. for natural gas contracts, that is, requiring a

description of a market participant's cash-market positions as of a

specified date filed in advance of the spot-month.\1388\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1388\ CL-FIA-59595 at 37

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that there is a key distinction between Form

504 and Form 204. Form 504 is required of speculators that are relying

upon the conditional spot-month limit exemption. Form 204 is required

for hedgers that exceed position limits. To the extent a firm is

hedging, there is no requirement to file Form 504.

In the unlikely event that a firm is both hedging and relying upon

the conditional spot-month limit exemption, the firm would be required

to file both forms at most one day a month, given the timing of the

spot-month in natural gas markets (the only market for which Form 504

will be required). In that event, however, the Commission believes that

requiring similar information on both forms should encourage filing

efficiencies rather than duplicating the burden. For example, both

forms require the filer to identify fixed price purchase commitments;

the Commission believes it is not overly burdensome for the same firm

to report such similar information on Form 204 and Form 504, should a

market participant ever be required to file both forms.

The Commission does not believe that a description of a cash market

position is sufficient to allow Commission staff to administer its

Surveillance program. Descriptions are not as exact as reported

information, and the Commission believes the information gathered in

daily Form 504 reports would be more complete--and thus more

beneficial--in determining compliance and detecting and deterring

manipulation. The Commission reiterates that Form 504 will only be

required from participants in natural gas markets who seek to avail

themselves of the conditional spot-month limit exemption, limiting the

burden to only those participants.\1389\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1389\ As stated in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

the Commission will closely monitor the reporting requirements

associated with conditional spot-month limit exemptions in natural

gas to determine whether reporting on Form 504 would be appropriate

in the future for other commodity derivative contracts in response

to market developments or in order to facilitate surveillance

efforts. See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75744.

However, the Commission is not proposing a conditional spot-month

limit exemption in any other commodity at this time.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iii. Time and Place of Filing Reports--Sec. 19.01(b)

As proposed, Sec. 19.01(b)(1) would require all reports, except

those submitted in response to special calls or on Form 504, Form 604

during the spot-month, or Form 704, to be filed monthly as of the close

of business on the last Friday of the month and not later than 9 a.m.

Eastern Time on the third business day following the last Friday of the

month.\1390\ For reports submitted on Form 504 and Form 604 during the

spot-month, proposed Sec. 19.01(b)(2) would require filings to be

submitted as of the close of business for each day the person exceeds

the limit during the spot period and not later than 9 a.m. Eastern Time

on the next business day following the date of the report.\1391\

Finally, proposed Sec. 19.01(b)(3) would require series '04 reports to

be transmitted using the format, coding structure, and electronic data

transmission procedures approved in writing by the Commission or its

designee.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1390\ The timeframe for filing Form 704 is included as part of

proposed Sec. 150.7. See supra for discussion regarding the filing

of Form 704.

\1391\ In proposed Sec. 19.01(b)(2), the Commission

inadvertently failed to include reports filed under Sec.

19.00(a)(1)(ii)(B) (i.e. Form 604 during the spot month) in the same

filing timeframe as reports filed under Sec. 19.00(a)(1)(i) (i.e.

Form 504). The correct filing timeframe was described in multiple

places on the forms published in the Federal Register as part of the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter recommended an annual Form 204 filing requirement,

rather than a monthly filing requirement. The commenter noted that

because the general size and nature of its business is relatively

constant, the differences between each monthly report would be

insignificant. The commenter recommended the CFTC ``not impose

additional costs of monthly reporting without a demonstration of

significant additional regulatory benefits.'' The commenter noted its

futures position typically exceeds the proposed position limits, but

such positions are bona fide hedging positions.\1392\ Similarly,

another commenter suggested that if the Commission does not eliminate

the forms in favor of the requirements in the 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal the Commission should require only an annual

notice that details its maximum cash market exposure that justifies an

exemption, to be filed with the exchange.\1393\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1392\ CL-DFA-59621 at 2.

\1393\ CL-FIA-60937 at 17.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter suggested that the reporting date for Form 204 should

be the close of business on the day prior to the beginning of the spot

period and that it should be required to filed no later than the 15th

day of the month following a month in which a filer exceeded a federal

limit to allow the market participant sufficient time to collect and

report its information.\1394\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1394\ CL-Working Group-60947 at 17-18

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With regards to proposed Sec. 19.01(b)(2), one commenter

recommended that the Commission change the proposed next-day reporting

of Form 504 for the conditional spot-month limit exemption and Form 604

for the pass-through swap offsets during the spot-month, to a monthly

basis, noting market participants need time to generate and collect

data and verify the accuracy of the reported data. The commenter

further stated that the Commission did not explain why it needs the

data on Form 504 or Form 604 on a next-day basis.\1395\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1395\ CL-FIA-59595 at 35.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another asserted that the daily filing requirement of Form 504 for

participants who rely on the conditional spot-month limit exemption

``imposes significant burdens and substantial costs on market

participants.'' The commenter urged a monthly rather than a daily

filing of all cash market positions, which the commenter claimed is

consistent with current

[[Page 96872]]

exchange practices.\1396\ Another commenter agreed, claiming that by

making the reporting requirement monthly rather than daily, the

Commission would balance the costs and benefits associated with Form

504 requirements on market participants relying on the conditional spot

month limit.\1397\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1396\ CL-ICE-59669 at 7.

\1397\ See CL-EEI-EPSA-59602 at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to the commenters' suggestions that Form 204 be filed

annually, the Commission notes that throughout the course of a year,

most commodities subject to federal position limits under proposed

Sec. 150.2 are subject to seasonality of prices as well as less

predictable imbalances in supply and demand such that an annual filing

would not provide the Commission's Surveillance program insight into

cash market trends underlying changes in the derivative markets. This

insight is necessary for the Surveillance program to determine whether

price changes in derivative markets are caused by fundamental factors

or manipulative behavior. Further, the Commission believes that an

annual filing could actually be more burdensome for firms, as an annual

filing could lead to special calls or requests between filings for

additional information in order for the Commission's Surveillance

program to fulfill its responsibility to detect and deter market

manipulation. In addition, the Commission notes that while one

participant's positions may remain constant throughout a year, the same

is not true for many other market participants. The Commission believes

that varying the filing arrangement depending on a particular market or

market participant is impractical and would lead to increased burdens

for market participants due to uncertainty regarding when each firm

with a position in a particular commodity derivative would be required

to file.

The Commission is retaining the last Friday of the month as the

required reporting date in order to avoid confusion and uncertainty,

particularly for those participants who already file Form 204 and thus

are accustomed to that reporting date.

The Commission is reproposing Sec. 19.01(b)(2) to require next-

day, daily filing of Forms 504 and 604 in the spot-month. In response

to the commenter, the Commission notes that it described its rationale

for requiring Forms 504 and 604 daily during the spot-month in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal.\1398\ In order to detect and

deter manipulation during the spot-month, concurrent information

regarding the cash positions of a speculator holding a conditional

spot-month limit exemption (Form 504) or the swap contract underlying a

large offsetting position in the physical-delivery contract (Form 604)

is necessary during the spot-month. Receiving Forms 504 or 604 before

or after the spot-month period would not help the Surveillance program

to protect the price discovery process of physical-delivery contracts

and to ensure that market participants have a qualifying pass-through

swap contract position underlying offsetting futures positions held

during the spot-month.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1398\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at 75744-

45. The Commission noted that its experience overseeing the

``dramatic instances of disruptive trading practices in the natural

gas markets'' warranted enhanced reporting for that commodity during

the spot month on Form 504. The Commission noted its intent to wait

until it gained additional experience with limits in other

commodities before imposing enhanced reporting requirements for

those commodities. The Commission further noted that it was

concerned that a trader could hold an extraordinarily large position

early in the spot month in the physical-delivery contract along with

an offsetting short position in a cash-settled contract (such as a

swap), and that such a large position could disrupt the price

discovery function of the core referenced futures contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that Form 504 is required only for the Natural

Gas commodity, which has a 3-day spot period. Daily reporting on Form

504 during the spot-month allows the Surveillance program to monitor a

market participant's cash market activity that could impact or benefit

their derivatives position. Given the short filing period for natural

gas and the importance of accurate information during the spot-month,

the Commission believes that requiring Form 504 to be filed daily

provides an important benefit that outweighs the potential burdens for

filers.\1399\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1399\ Should the Commission determine in the future to require

Form 504 for other commodities, particularly those with longer spot

month periods, the Commission will evaluate the daily filing

requirement as it applies to such other commodities.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As a practical matter, the Commission notes that Form 604 is

collected during the spot-month only under particular circumstances,

i.e., for an offset of a cash-settled swap position with a physical-

delivery referenced contract during the spot-month. Because the ``five-

day rule'' applies to such positions, the spot-month filing of Form 604

would only occur in contracts whose spot-month period is longer than 5

days (excluding, for example, energy contracts, but including many

agricultural commodities).

9. Sections 150.9, 150.10, and 150.11--Processes for Recognizing

Positions Exempt From Position Limits

The Commission is reproposing the process for recognizing certain

market-participant positions as bona fide hedges (Sec. 150.9), spreads

(Sec. 150.10), and anticipatory bona fide hedges (Sec. 150.11), so

that the positions may be deemed exempt from federal and exchange-set

position limits. The Commission invited the public to comment on the

Commission's consideration of the costs and benefits of the processes

in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, identify and assess

any costs and benefits not discussed therein, and provide possible

alternative proposals. The Commission received comment letters in 2013

that helped the Commission re-design the exemption-recognition

processes and then reproposrepropose them in the 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal. The Commission received more comment letters

on the June 2016 proposed exemption-recognition processes and a number

of commenters remarked on the costs and benefits.

The general theme of the costs-related comments is that the three,

exemption-recognition processes have overly burdensome reporting

requirements. And the majority of benefits-related comments expressed

that the exchanges are the best positioned entities to assess whether

market positions fall within one of the categories of positions exempt

from position limits. There also were a few comments asserting that the

Commission underestimated the quantified costs, such as staff hours

needed to review exemption applications. The Commission is addressing

the qualitative and quantitative comments in the discussion that

follows. Furthermore, the Commission will explain why it believes,

after careful consideration of the comments, that the reproposed

exemption-recognition processes will, among other things, improve

transparency via exchange- and Commission-reporting, and improve

regulatory certainty by having applicants submit materials for review

to exchanges, and by having exchanges assess whether positions should

be deemed exempt from position limits.

The baseline against which the Commission considers the benefits

and costs of the exemption-recognition rules is a combination of CEA

requirements and Commission regulations that are now in effect. That

is, the general baseline is the Commission's part 150 regulations and

current Sec. Sec. 1.47 and

[[Page 96873]]

1.48.\1400\ For greater specificity, the Commission has identified the

specific, associated baseline from which costs and benefits are

determined under each discussion of the reproposed exemption rules

below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1400\ See chart listing current regulations, December 2013

Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR 75712, Dec. 12, 2013.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. Section 150.9--Exchange Recognition of Non-Enumerated Bona Fide

Hedging Positions

Under Section III.G., above, the Commission summarizes the changes

it reproposed in rule Sec. 150.9, which outlines the process that

exchanges may employ to recognize certain commodity derivative

positions as non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions. The reproposed

version of Sec. 150.9 closely follows the regulatory text proposed in

the June 2016 Supplemental Proposal. Most of the changes are

clarifications. There are, however, substantive changes between the

regulatory text proposed in June 2016 and the reproposed regulatory

text in this Release; they are to the following subsections:

The exchange-application requirements under Sec.

150.9(a)(1)(v) and Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(ii), (iii), and (iv);

the applicant-to-exchange, reporting requirement under

Sec. 150.9(a)(6); and

the exchange-to-Commission, reporting requirement under

Sec. 150.9(c)(2).

i. Section 150.9(a)--Exchange-Administered Non-Enumerated Bona Fide

Hedging Position Application Process

In paragraph (a) of reproposed Sec. 150.9, the Commission

identifies the process and information required for an exchange to

assess whether it should grant a market participant's request that its

derivative position(s) be recognized as an non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position. In the reproposed version of Sec. 150.9(a), the

Commission clarified a condition in Sec. 150.9(a)(1)(v).\1401\ The

clarification is that an exchange offering non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position exemptions must have at least one year of experience

and expertise to administer position limits for a referenced contract

rather than experience and expertise in the derivative contract. In

reproposed Sec. 150.9(a)(2), the Commission offers guidelines for

exchanges to establish adaptable application processes by permitting

different processes for ``novel'' versus ``substantially similar''

applications for non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

recognitions. Reproposed Sec. 150.9(a)(3) describes in general terms

the type of information that exchanges should collect from applicants.

The Commission made a material change in reproposed Sec.

150.9(a)(3)(iv) by reducing the amount of cash-market data an applicant

must submit to an exchange from three years to one year.\1402\ In

addition, 150.9(a)(3)(ii) and (iv) were both changed to provide that

the exchange need require the ``information'' rather than ``detailed

information.'' Reproposed Sec. 150.9(a)(4) obliges applicants and

exchanges to act timely in their submissions and notifications,

respectively, and that exchanges retain revocation authority.

Reproposed Sec. 150.9(a)(5) provides that the position will be deemed

recognized as an non-enumerated bona fide hedging position when an

exchange recognizes it. Reproposed Sec. 150.9(a)(6) instructs

exchanges to determine whether there should be a reporting requirement

for non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions. The Commission changed

Sec. 150.9(a)(6) to relieve market participants from an additional

filing, and to give exchanges discretion on non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position reporting. Reproposed Sec. 150.9(a)(7) requires an

exchange to publish on their Web site descriptions of unique types of

derivative positions recognized as non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions based on novel facts and circumstances.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1401\ For a fuller discussion of the change, see Section

III.G.3.a.(i)-(iii).

\1402\ For a fuller discussion of the change, see Section

III.G.3.b.(iii)

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Section 150.9(b)--Non-Enumerated Bona Fide Hedging Position

Recordkeeping Requirements

The Commission made no changes to the rule text in Sec. 150.9(b)

between the 2016 supplemental proposal and this Reproposal. Under

reproposed Sec. 150.9(b), exchanges will be required to maintain

complete books and records of all activities relating to the processing

and disposition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

applications. As explained in reproposed Sec. 150.9(b)(1) through

(b)(2), the Commission instructs exchanges to retain applicant-

submission materials, exchange notes, and determination documents.

Moreover, consistent with current Sec. 1.31, the Commission expects

that these records will be readily accessible until the termination,

maturity, or expiration date of the bona fide hedge recognition and

during the first two years of the subsequent, five-year retention

period.

iii. Section 150.9(c)--Non-Enumerated Bona Fide Hedging Positions

Reporting Requirements

The Commission made a change to reporting to the rule text in Sec.

150.9(c) between the 2016 supplemental proposal and this Reproposal.

While the Commission is reproposing rules requiring weekly reporting

obligations by exchanges for positions recognized as non-enumerated

bona fide hedging positions, the Commission changed Sec.

150.9(c)(1)(i) and Sec. 150.9(c)(2) for purposes of clarification. In

regards to Sec. 150.9(c)(1)(i), the Commission is clarifying that the

reports required under (c)(1)(i) are those for each commodity

derivatives position that had been recognized that week and for any

revocation or modification of a previously granted recognition. The

change to Sec. 150.9(c)(2) explains that exchanges must file monthly

Commission reports only if the exchange has determined, in its

discretion, that applicants should file exchange reports. The

Commission also reproposes Sec. 150.9(c)(1)(ii), which provides that

exchanges post non-enumerated bona fide hedging position summaries on

their Web sites.

iv. Section 150.9(d) and (e)--Commission Review

The Commission made no changes to the rule text in Sec. Sec. 150.9

(d) or (e) between the 2016 supplemental proposal and this Reproposal.

The Commission reproposes rules that states that market participants

and exchanges must respond to Commission requests, as well as

liquidated positions within a commercially reasonable amount of time if

required under Sec. 150.9(d).

v. Section 150.9(f)--Delegation to Director of the Division of Market

Oversight

The Commission made no changes to the rule text in Sec. 150.9(f)

between the 2016 supplemental proposal and this Reproposal. In the

reproposed version of Sec. 150.9(f), the Commission delegates certain

review authority for the non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

recognition-process to the Director of the Division of Market

Oversight.

vi. Baseline

For the non-enumerated bona fide hedging position process, the

baseline for non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions subject to

federal position limits is current Sec. 1.47. For non-enumerated bona

fide hedging position exemptions to exchange-set position limits, the

baseline is the current exchange regulations and practices as well as

the Commission's guidance to

[[Page 96874]]

exchanges in current Sec. 150.5(d). The current rule provides,

generally, that an exchange may recognize bona fide hedging positions

in accordance with the general definition of bona fide hedging position

in current Sec. 1.3(z)(1).

vii. Benefits and Discussion of Comments

The Commission continues to believe that the non-enumerated bona

fide hedging position exemption-recognition process outlined in Sec.

150.9 will produce significant benefits. As explained in the 2016

supplemental proposal, the Commission recognizes that there are

positions that reduce price risks incidental to commercial operations.

For that reason, among others, such positions that are shown to be bona

fide hedging positions under CEA Section 4a(c) are not subject to

position limits. And, therefore, it is beneficial for market

participants to have several options regarding bona fide hedging

positions. With this Reproposal, market participants will have three

ways in which they may determine that positions are bona fide hedging

positions. First, market participants could conclude that a commodity

derivative position comports with the definition of bona fide hedging

position under Sec. 150.1. Second, market participants may request a

staff interpretive letter under Sec. 140.99 or seek exemptive relief

under CEA section 4(a)(7). Third, they may file an application with an

exchange for recognition of an non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position under reproposed Sec. 150.9.

While all of the aforementioned options are viable, the Commission

continues to believe that reproposed Sec. 150.9 outlines a framework

similar to existing exchange practices that recognize non-enumerated

bona fide hedge exemptions to exchange-set limits. These practices are

familiar to many market participants. Moreover, a number of commenters

agreed that exchanges should oversee the exemption-recognition

process.\1403\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1403\ See, e.g., CL-CME-60926; CL-Nodal-60948.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission believes that under reproposed Sec. 150.9, the

Commission will be able to leverage exchanges' existing practices and

expertise in administering exemptions. Thus, reproposed Sec. 150.9

should reduce the need to invent new procedures to recognize non-

enumerated bona fide hedging positions. As explained in the 2016

supplemental proposal, exchanges also may be familiar with the

applicant-market participant's needs and practices so there will be an

advanced understanding for why certain trading strategies are pursued.

The Commission received comments that were consistent with this view.

For example, in response to proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(iv)--the

rule requiring applicants to submit detailed information regarding the

applicant's activity in the cash market during the past three years--

there were a few comments. One commenter noted that exchanges should

have the discretion to determine the requisite number of years of data

that should be collected.\1404\ Another commenter proposed that

exchanges have the discretion to collect up to one year of data.\1405\

A different commenter remarked that proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(iii)

(requiring an applicant to identify ``the maximum size of all gross

positions in derivative contracts to be acquired by the applicant

during the year after the application is submitted'') is unnecessary

and unduly burdensome.'' \1406\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1404\ CL-AGA-60943 at 6.

\1405\ CL-NCGA/NGSA-60919 at 10.

\1406\ CL-Commercial Energy Working Group-60932 at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

These comments support the Commission's determination to reduce

filing burdens. In reproposed Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(ii) and (iv), the

Commission changed the requirement that the application process require

an applicant submit ``detailed information'' in regards to certain

information to ``information.'' The change provides the exchanges with

the discretion to determine what level of detail is needed to make

their determination. The Commission has also reduced the minimum cash

market data requirement to one-year from three-years in proposed Sec.

150.9(a)(3)(iv), which will reduce market participants burden in

comparison to the proposed rule.\1407\ Furthermore, the Commission

continues to believe, even with this change to Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(iv),

that given the availability of the exchange's analysis and the

Commission's macro-view of the markets, the Commission will be well-

informed should it become necessary for the Commission to review a

determination under reproposed Sec. 150.9(d), and determine whether a

commodity derivative position should be recognized as an non-enumerated

bona fide hedging position. The Commission also has clarified in

reproposed Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(iii) that the filing must include the

maximum size of all gross positions for which the application is

submitted, which may be a longer time period than the proposed one-year

period. In administering requests for recognition of non-enumerated

bona fide hedging position exemptions under Sec. 1.47, the Commission

has found a maximum size statement, as required under Sec. 1.47(b)(4),

to be useful both at the time of review of the filing (in determining

whether the requested maximum size is reasonable in relation to past

cash market activity) and at the time of review of a filer's position

that exceeds the level of the position limit (reducing the need for

special calls to inquire as to the reason a position exceeds a position

limit level).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1407\ It should be noted that this one-year cash-market history

is less than the three-year cash-market history required under

reproposed Sec. 150.7(d)(1)(iv) for initial statements regarding

enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging positions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In general, the non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

recognition process under reproposed Sec. 150.9 should reduce

duplicative efforts because applicants will be saved the expense of

applying to both an exchange for relief from exchange-set position

limits and to the Commission for relief from federal limits. The

Commission also seeks to collect relevant information. Thus, because

commenters reasonably complained about the application requirement for

three years of cash-market position information, the Commission changed

the requirement to one year.\1408\ Once commenter stated that the

three-year data provided ``little practical benefit'' for assessing

whether an non-enumerated bona fide hedging position is

appropriate.\1409\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1408\ For a fuller discussion, see Section III.G.1.b. See also

the following comment letters: CL-AGA-60943 at p. 6 (requirement is

vague and restrictive); CL-CCI-60935 at p. 7 (one year of data

suggested); CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at p. 10 (requirement is ``unduly

burdensome and unnecessary''); CL-NCGA/NGSA-60919 at p. 10 (same);

CL-COPE-60932 at p. 9 (criticized the three-year data requirement);

CL-Commercial Energy Working Group-60932 at p. 11 (the requirement

is unnecessary).

\1409\ CL-Commercial Energy Working Group-60932 at 11.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another section where commenters observed redundancy was in

proposed Sec. 150.9(a)(6) regarding requirements for exchanges to

require applicants to file reports.\1410\ One commenter stated that the

proposal to require reports ``is particularly problematic due to its

vagueness in terms of the frequency that a cash market report must be

provided.'' \1411\ Another commenter explained further that proposed

Sec. 150.9(a)(6) had no ``incremental market surveillance or other

regulatory benefit'' because other rules provide for applicants to

reapply for exemptions

[[Page 96875]]

annually, real-time market surveillance, the exchanges' abilities to

make one-off requests for information, and the Commission's special

call authority.\1412\ There also was a commenter who stated that

``neither exchanges nor the Commission are likely to have resources

available to meaningfully review such reports'' as those under Sec.

150.9(a)(6), as well as those reports under Sec. 105.10(a)(6).\1413\

As explained above, the Commission changed the regulatory text so that

exchanges may decide whether non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

applicants should provide additional reports to exchanges. As a result

of this change, market participants may have less reporting

requirements but that assessment will depend on whether the exchanges--

based on their experiences and expertise in position limits in general

and in non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions specifically--decide

to grant a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position exemption without

establishing a reporting requirement.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1410\ See also CL-Commercial Energy Working Group-60932 at 12

(the same conclusion applies to proposed 105.10(a)(6), and Sec.

150.11(a)(5)).

\1411\ CL-AGA-60943 at 6.

\1412\ CL-CCI-60935 at 7-8 (the same argument applies to

proposed Sec. Sec. 150.10(a)(6) and 150.11(a)(5)). See also CL-

Commercial Energy Working Group-60932 at 12 (the same argument

applies to proposed Sec. 105.10(a)(6), and Sec. 150.11(a)(5). See

also CL-FIA-60937 at 16 (criticism of requirement to produce

enhanced information regarding cash market activity and size of cash

market exposure.

\1413\ CL-ISDA-60931 at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As expressed in the 2016 supplemental proposal, the creation and

retention of records under Sec. 150.9 may be used as reference

material in the future for similar bona fide hedge recognition requests

either by relevant exchanges or the Commission. This will be beneficial

because retained records will help the Commission to ensure that an

exchange's determinations are internally consistent and consistent with

the Act and the Commission's regulations thereunder. There is also the

additional benefit that records will be accessible if they are needed

for a potential enforcement action.

The Commission continues to believe that the exchange-to-Commission

reporting under Sec. 150.9(c) will have surveillance benefits. The

reports will provide the Commission with notice that an applicant may

take a commodity derivative position that the exchange has recognized

as an non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, and also will show the

applicant's underlying cash commodity and expected maximum size in the

cash markets. Reports will facilitate the tracking of non-enumerated

bona fide hedging positions recognized by the exchanges, and will

assist the Commission in ensuring that a market participant's

activities conform to the exchange's terms of recognition and to the

Act. While there are great benefits, in reproposed Sec. 150.9(c)(1)(i)

and Sec. 150.9(c)(2), the Commission made clarifications that, as

noted above, eased the burden on exchanges and applicants.

Asreproposed, Sec. 150.9(c)(1)(i) clarifies that the reports required

are only for those for each commodity derivatives position that had

been recognized that week and for any revocation or modification of a

previously granted recognition. In addition, reproposed Sec.

150.9(c)(2) defers to the exchanges by clarifying that they have the

discretion to determine whether a market participant must report under

reproposed Sec. 150.9(a)(6); however, if an exchange requires reports

of a market participant, that exchange must forward any such report to

the Commission under reproposed Sec. 150.9(c)(2). This gives the

exchanges flexibility and defers to their expertise. The web-posting of

summaries also will benefit market participants in general by providing

transparency and open access to the non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position recognition process. In addition, reporting and posting gives

market participants seeking recognition of a non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position an understanding of the types of commodity derivative

positions an exchange may recognize as an non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position, thereby providing greater administrative and legal

certainty.

viii. Costs and Discussion of Comments

In the June 2016 Supplemental Proposal, the Commission explained

that to a large extent, exchanges and market participants have incurred

already many of the compliance costs associated with the proposed

exemptions. The Commission, however, detailed a number of the readily-

quantifiable costs for exchanges and market participants associated

with processing non-enumerated bona fide hedging position recognitions,

as well as spreads and anticipatory bona fide hedges. The Commission

invited public comment on the estimated financial numbers, which were

detailed in tables. Several commenters remarked on the costs the

Commission quantitatively estimated in the June 2016 Supplemental

Proposal. One group commenter stated that the Commission underestimated

costs to market participants.\1414\ The same commenter explained that

the Commission failed to ``break out the costs for submitting an

initial application and filing subsequent updates every time

information in the application changes.'' \1415\ Another commenter

stated that the 2016 Supplemental Proposal has ``highly unrealistic

estimates of the time and cost that will be required to implement and

maintain compliance programs.'' \1416\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1414\ CL-Commercial Energy Working Group-60932 at 13.

\1415\ Id.

\1416\ CL-ISDA-60931 at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One exchange commenter declared that the Commission ``significantly

underestimates the number of exemptions that the Exchange will be

required to review,'' and offered different numbers.\1417\ For example,

the exchange commenter stated that it reviewed as many as 500 exemption

requests annually as opposed to the 285 exemption requests that the

Commission estimated.\1418\ In addition, the exchange commenter stated

that the Commission underestimated the number of staff-review hours,

and that the number should be two additional hours for a total of seven

hours per exemption review.\1419\ The exchange commenter also provided

different hours for different exercises: (a) Seven hours for preparing

quarterly Web site postings; (b) six hours for preparation for weekly

reports; and (c) six hours for preparing monthly reports.\1420\ The

exchange commenter also explained that it believed it would need to

hire a seasoned, senior level employee to help comply with the proposed

rules and three regulatory analysts.\1421\ Finally, the exchange

commenter noted that the Commission failed to consider start-up costs

associated with complying with reporting requirements.\1422\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1417\ CL-ICE-60929 at p 17.

\1418\ Id.

\1419\ Id.

\1420\ Id.

\1421\ Id.

\1422\ CL-ICE-60929 at 17.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response, the Commission is persuaded by commenters, and is

adjusting its estimated staff-review hours and costs that it believes

exchanges and market participants will incur to comply with exemption-

recognition processes in this Reproposal. These estimates are reflected

in the tables below.

Even though the Commission has outlined three different exemption-

application processes in this release, the Commission believes that

aspects of the processes will become standardized and the data

collected for one exemption will be the same as data collected for

another exemption. As a result, it is likely that over time some costs

will

[[Page 96876]]

decrease. Some commenters, however, expressed different views. One

commenter stressed that the Commission's proposed exemption processes

triggered greater oversight, increased scope of monitoring, and need

for additional staff; whereas a standardized application might reduce

market-entry barriers.\1423\ The same commenter remarked that increased

compliance costs and capital investments might lead to decreased market

participation and liquidity.\1424\ The commenter then suggested the

development of a standardized hedge exemption application to minimize

monitoring and compliance costs.\1425\ Finally, the same commenter

asserted that a standardized application might drive efficiency and

minimize regulatory risk exposure via innovation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1423\ CL-EDF-60944 at 2.

\1424\ Id.

\1425\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission continues to believe that there are costs that are

not easily quantified. These are qualitative costs that are related to

the specific attributes and needs of individual market participants

that are hedging. Given that qualitative costs are highly specific, the

Commission continues to believe that market participants will choose to

incur Sec. 150.9-related costs only if doing so is less costly than

complying with position limits and not executing the desired hedge

position. Thus, by providing market participants with an option to

apply for relief from speculative position limits under reproposed

Sec. 150.9, the Commission continues to believe it is offering market

participants a way to ease overall compliance costs because it is

reasonable to assume that entities will seek recognition of non-

enumerated bona fide hedging positions only if the outcome of doing so

justifies the costs. This is because the Commission appreciates that

the costs of not trading might be substantially higher. The Commission

also believes that market participants will consider how the costs of

applying for recognition of an non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position under reproposed Sec. 150.9 will compare to the costs of

requesting a staff interpretive letter under Sec. 140.99, or seeking

exemptive relief under CEA section 4a(a)(7). Likewise, exchanges must

consider qualitative costs in their decision to create an non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position application process or revise an

existing program.

The Commission acknowledges that there may also be other costs to

market participants if the Commission disagrees with an exchange's

decision to recognize an non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

under reproposed Sec. 150.9 or under an independent Commission request

or review under reproposed Sec. 150.9(d) or (e). These costs will

include time and effort spent by market participants associated with a

Commission review, which the Commission addresses in the tables below.

There also is the possibility that market participants will lose

amounts that the Commission can neither predict nor quantify if it

became necessary to unwind trades or reduce positions were the

Commission to conclude that an exchange's disposition of an non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position application is inconsistent with

section 4a(c) of the Act and the general definition of bona fide

hedging position in Sec. 150.1.

A few commenters remarked on this concern and pointed to the term

that the Commission would provide applicants a ``commercially

reasonable amount of time'' to unwind positions that the Commission

determined did not fall within the categories of exempted positions

under Sec. 150.9(d)(4), 150.10(d)(4), and 150.11(d)(3).\1426\ One

commenter explained that if a market participant is required to unwind

a position in the middle of its green-lit hedging activity, the unwind

could cause ``significant harm to the participant,'' and the ``rapid

unanticipated liquidation of positions could result in market

disruption''.\1427\ The commenter also highlighted that the less-than-

24-hours, commercially-reasonable period compels market participants to

seek pre-approval of positions by the Commission or not engage in risk

mitigation.\1428\ The commenter also added that market participants

might restrict trading to some exchanges and concentrate market risk on

a single exchange.\1429\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1426\ CL-MGEX-90936 at 8; CL-EEI-EPSA-60925 at 10 (one business

to unwind is ``unreasonable'' in energy products); CL-NCGA/NGSA-

60919 at 13 (concerned about Commission's suggestion that positions

can be unwound in less than one business day); CL-NGFA-60941 at 3;

CL-NCFC-60930 at 5 (dislikes the one-day unwind period for dairy

market).

\1427\ CL-MGEX-90936 at 8. See also CL-NCGA/NGSA-60919 at 13

(``Unwinding a position quickly in an illiquid market, such as in

many non-spot month contracts, could create a significant market

disruption.''); CL-NGFA-60941 at 3 (commented that a one-day

liquidation ``in thinly traded contracts without broad liquidity''

could be extremely disruptive); CL-NCFC-60930 at 5 (``Requiring the

same time period and the same process to unwind the dairy

transactions could lead to a market disruption, disorderly trading

and regulatory-influence and unnecessary price volatility.'').

\1428\ CL-MGEX-90936 at 8.

\1429\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission recognizes that costs may result if the Commission

disagrees with an exchange's disposition of a non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position application under reproposed Sec. 150.9 (or other

exempt position under Sec. Sec. 150.10 or 150.11). The Commission,

however, believes such situations will be limited based on the history

of exchanges approving similar applications for exemptions to exchange-

set limits. Moreover, as explained in the 2016 supplemental proposal,

exchanges have incentives to protect market participants from the harms

that position limits are intended to prevent, such as manipulation,

corners, and squeezes. In addition, an exchange that recognizes a

market participant's non-enumerated bona fide hedging position (or

other exempt position) that enables the participant to exceed position

limits must then deter the same market participant from trading in a

manner that causes adverse price impacts on the market; such adverse

price impacts may cause financial harm to market participants, or even

reputational risk or economic disadvantage to the exchange.\1430\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1430\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38488-89.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ix. Costs To Create or Amend Exchange Rules for Non-Enumerated Bona

Fide Hedging Position Application Programs

The Commission believes that exchanges electing to process non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position applications under reproposed

Sec. 150.9(a) are likely to already administer similar processes and

will need to file with the Commission amendments to existing exchange

rules rather than create new rules. The exchanges will only have to

file amendments once. As discussed in the Paperwork Reduction Act

discussion below, the Commission forecasts an average annual filing

cost of $1,220 per exchange that files new rules or modifications per

final process that an exchange adopts. Under the Paperwork Reduction

Act, these costs are reported as an average annual cost over a five-

year period.

[[Page 96877]]

Table IV-A-6--Burden Estimates for Filing New or Amended Rules

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

New or amended rule filings under part 40 per Sec. 6 5 2 $122.00 $1,220

150.9(a)(1), (a)(6).....................................

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

x. Costs To Review Applications Under Reproposed Processes

An exchange that elects to process applications also will incur

costs related to the review and disposition of such applications

pursuant to reproposed Sec. 150.9(a). For example, exchanges will need

to expend resources on reviewing and analyzing the facts and

circumstances of each application to determine whether the application

meets the standards established by the Commission. Exchanges also will

need to expend effort in notifying applicants of the exchanges'

disposition of recognition or exemption requests. The Commission

believes that exchanges electing to process non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position applications under reproposed Sec. 150.9(a) are

likely to have processes for the review and disposition of such

applications currently in place. The Commission has adjusted the costs

in Table IV-A-7 based on information submitted by commenters. Thus, the

Commission has forecast that the average annual cost for each exchange

to process applications for non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

recognitions is $277,500.

Table IV-A-7--Burden Estimates for Reviewing Applications

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Collection, review, and disposition of application per 6 7 325 $122.00 $277,550

Sec. 150.9(a).........................................

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

xi. Costs To Post Summaries for Non-Enumerated Bona Fide Hedging

Position Recognitions

Exchanges that elect to process the applications under reproposed

Sec. 150.9 will incur costs to publish on their Web sites summaries of

the unique types of non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

positions. The Commission has estimated an average annual cost of

$25,620 for the web-posting of non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position summaries.

Table IV-A-8--Burden Estimates for Posting Summaries

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Summaries Posted Online per Sec. 150.9(a).............. 6 7 30 $122.00 $25,620

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

xii. Costs To Market Participants Who Will Seek Non-Enumerated Bona

Fide Hedging Position Relief From Position Limits

Under reproposed Sec. 150.9(a)(3), market participants must submit

applications that provide sufficient information to allow the exchanges

to determine, and the Commission to verify, whether it is appropriate

to recognize such position as an non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position. These applications will be updated annually. Reproposed Sec.

150.9(a)(6) will require applicants to file a report with the exchanges

when an applicant owns, holds, or controls a derivative position that

has been recognized as an non-enumerated bona fide hedging position.

The Commission estimates that each market participant seeking relief

from position limits under reproposed Sec. 150.9 will likely incur

approximately $976 annually in application costs.\1431\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1431\ Assuming that exchanges administer exemptions to

exchange-set limits, these costs are incrementally higher.

Table IV-A-9--Burden Estimates for Market Participants To Apply

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sec. 150.9(a)(3) Application........................... 325 4 2 $122.00 $976

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96878]]

xiii. Costs for Non-Enumerated Bona Fide Hedging Position Recordkeeping

The Commission believes that exchanges that currently process

applications for spread exemptions and bona fide hedging positions

maintain records of such applications as required pursuant to other

Commission regulations, including Sec. 1.31. The Commission, however,

also believes that the reproposed rules may confer additional

recordkeeping obligations on exchanges that elect to process

applications for non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions. The

Commission estimates that each exchange electing to administer the

reproposed non-enumerated bona fide hedging position process will

likely incur approximately $3,660 annually to retain records for each

process.

Table IV-A-10--Burden Estimates for Recordkeeping

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sec. 150.9(b) Recordkeeping............................ 6 30 1 $122.00 $3,660

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

xiv. Costs for Weekly and Monthly Non-Enumerated Bona Fide Hedging

Position Reporting to the Commission

The Commission anticipates that exchanges that elect to process

non-enumerated bona fide hedging position applications will be required

to file two types of reports. The Commission is aware that five

exchanges currently submit reports each month, on a voluntary basis,

which provide information regarding exchange-processed exemptions of

all types. The Commission believes that the content of such reports is

similar to the information required of the reports in proposed rule

Sec. 150.9(c), but the frequency of such required reports will

increase under the reproposed rule. The Commission estimates an average

cost of approximately $38,064 per exchange for weekly reports under

reproposed Sec. 150.9(c).

Table IV-A-11--Burden Estimates for Submitting Weekly Reports

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sec. 150.9(c)(1) Weekly Report......................... 6 6 52 $122.00 $38,064

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

For the monthly report, the Commission anticipates a minor cost for

exchanges because the reproposed rules will require exchanges

essentially to forward to the Commission notices received from

applicants who own, hold, or control the positions that have been

recognized or exempted. The Commission estimates an average cost of

approximately $8,784 per exchange for monthly reports under reproposed

Sec. 150.9(c).

Table IV-A-12--Burden Estimates for Submitting Monthly Reports

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sec. 150.9(c)(2) Monthly Report........................ 6 6 12 $122.00 $8,784

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

xv. Costs Related to Subsequent Monitoring

Exchanges will have additional surveillance costs and duties with

respect to non-enumerated bona fide hedging position that the

Commission believes will be integrated with their existing self-

regulatory organization surveillance activities as an exchange.

b. Section 150.10--Spread Exemptions

Since the Commission issued the June 2016 Supplemental Proposal,

the Commission made very few changes to the provisions authorizing

exchanges to exempt spread positions from federal position limits under

reproposed Sec. 150.10. In addition to non-substantive changes for

purposes of clarification, substantive changes were made in subsections

s of paragraphs (a) and (c) of Sec. 150.10: Sec. Sec.

150.10(a)(1)(ii); 150.10(a)(3)(ii) and (iii); 150.10(a)(6);

150.10(c)(2); The Commission did not make changes to paragraphs (b),

(d), (e), or (f) of reproposed Sec. 150.10.

i. Section 150.10(a)--Exchange-Administered Spread Exemption

In paragraph (a) of reproposed Sec. 150.10, the Commission

identifies the process and information required for an exchange to

grant a market participant's request that its derivative position(s) be

recognized as an exempt spread position.

As an initial step under reproposed Sec. 150.10(a)(1), exchanges

that voluntarily elect to process spread exemption applications are

required to notify the Commission of their intention to do so by filing

new rules or rule amendments with the Commission under part 40 of the

Commission's regulations. The Commission clarified reproposed Sec.

150.10(a)(1)(ii) to explain that an exchange may offer spread

exemptions if the contract, which is either a component of the spread

or a referenced contract that is related to the spread, in a particular

commodity is actively traded. The Commission reduced the burden of

proposed Sec. 150.10(a)(1)(ii) (that would require an

[[Page 96879]]

exchange to have applied position limits for at least one year), by

providing in reproposed Sec. 150.10(a)(1) that an exchange must have

at least one year of experience and expertise administering position

limits for such referenced contract. As explained above, the exchange

may gain such experience and expertise, for example, through employing

experienced staff.

In reproposed Sec. 150.10(a)(2), the Commission identifies four

types of spreads that an exchange may approve. Reproposed Sec.

150.10(a)(3) describes in general terms the type of information that

exchanges should collect from applicants. In reproposed Sec.

150.10(a)(3)(ii), similar to the change made in Sec. 150.9(a)(3), the

Commission changed the requirement that the application process require

an applicant submit ``detailed information'' in regards to certain

information to ``information.'' The change provides the exchanges with

the discretion to determine what level of detail is needed to make

their determination. The Commission clarified the reproposed

requirements to explain that applicant must report its maximum size of

all gross positions in the commodity related to the spread-exemption

application. Reproposed Sec. 150.10(a)(4) obliges applicants and

exchanges to act timely in their submissions and notifications,

respectively, and require exchanges to retain revocation authority.

Reproposed Sec. 150.10(a)(6) was modified and authorizes exchanges to

determine whether enhanced reporting is necessary. Reproposed Sec.

150.10(a)(7) requires exchanges to publish on its Web site a summary

describing the type of spread position and explaining why it was

exempted.

ii. Section 150.10(b)--Spread Exemption Recordkeeping Requirements

The Commission made no changes to the regulatory text in Sec.

150.10(b) that was proposed in June 2016. Under the reproposed rule,

exchanges must maintain complete books and records of all activities

relating to the processing and disposition of spread exemption

applications under reproposed Sec. 150.10(b). This is similar to the

record retention obligations of exchanges for positions recognized as

non-enumerated bona fide hedging positionss.

iii. Section 150.10(c)--Spread Exemption Reporting Requirements

The Commission amended Sec. 150.10(c)(2) and kept the rest of

regulatory text in Sec. 150.10(c) the same as the text proposed in the

2016 supplemental proposal. Under the reproposed rule exchanges will

have weekly reporting obligations for spread exemptions. The change in

subsection (c)(2) clarifies that exchanges have the discretion to

determine whether applicants should have monthly reports that must

ultimately be sent to the Commission. These reporting obligations are

similar to the reporting obligations of exchanges for positions

recognized as non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions.

iv. Baseline

For the reproposed spread exemption process for positions subject

to federal limits, the baseline is CEA section 4a(a)(1). In that

statutory section, the Commission is authorized to recognize certain

spread positions. That statutory provision is currently implemented in

a limited calendar-month spread exemption in Sec. 150.3(a)(3). For

exchange-set position limits, the baseline for spreads is the guidance

in current Sec. 150.5(a), which provides generally that exchanges may

recognize exemptions for positions that are normally known to the trade

as spreads.

v. Benefits

CEA section 4a(a)(1) authorizes the Commission to exempt certain

spreads from speculative position limits. In exercising this authority,

the Commission recognizes that spreads can have considerable benefits

for market participants and markets. The Commission now proposes a

spread exemption framework that utilizes existing exchanges--resources

and exchanges--expertise so that fair access and liquidity are promoted

at the same time market manipulations, squeezes, corners, and any other

conduct that will disrupt markets are deterred and prevented. Building

on existing exchange processes preserves the ability of the Commission

and exchanges to monitor markets and trading strategies while reducing

burdens on exchanges that will administer the process, and market

participants, who will utilize the process.

In addition to these benefits, there are other benefits related to

reproposed Sec. 150.10 that will inure to markets and market

participant. Yet, there is difficulty in quantifying these benefits

because benefits are dependent on the characteristics, such as

operational size and needs, of the market participants that will seek

spread exemptions, and the markets in which the participants trade.

Accordingly, the Commission considers the qualitative benefits of

reproposed Sec. 150.10.

For both exchanges and market participants, reproposed Sec. 150.10

will likely alleviate compliance burdens to the status quo. Exchanges

will be able to build on established procedures and infrastructure. As

stated earlier, many exchanges already have rules in place to process

and grant applications for spread exemptions from exchange-set position

limits pursuant to part 38 of the Commission's regulations (in

particular, current Sec. 38.300 and Sec. 38.301) and current Sec.

150.5. In addition, exchanges may be able to use the same staff and

electronic resources that will be used for reproposed Sec. 150.9 and

Sec. 150.11. Market participants also may benefit from spread-

exemption reviews by exchanges that are familiar with the commercial

needs and practices of market participants seeking exemptions. Market

participants also might gain legal and regulatory clarity and

consistency that will help in developing trading strategies. Moreover,

the Commission has reduced burdens by making changes to proposed

Sec. Sec. 150.10(a)(1) and (3). In the reproposed Sec. 150.10(a)(1),

the Commission changed the rule so that exchanges may employ

experienced staff to satisfy the requirement that an exchange have at

least one year of experience and expertise in administering position

limits for referenced contracts related to spread exemptions. In

reproposed Sec. 150.10(a)(3)(ii), the Commission gave exchanges

greater discretion in determining the level of detail needed from

spread-exemption applicants.

Reproposed Sec. 150.10 will authorize exchanges to approve spread

exemptions that permit market participants to continue to enhance

liquidity, rather than being restricted by a position limit. For

example, by allowing speculators to execute intermarket and intramarket

spreads in accordance with reproposed Sec. 150.3(a)(1)(iv) and Sec.

150.10, speculators will be able to hold a greater amount of open

interest in underlying contract(s), and, therefore, bona fide hedgers

may benefit from any increase in market liquidity. Spread exemptions

might lead to better price continuity and price discovery if market

participants who seek to provide liquidity (for example, through entry

of resting orders for spread trades between different contracts)

receive a spread exemption and, thus, will not otherwise be constrained

by a position limit.

Here are two examples of positions that could benefit from the

spread exemption in reproposed Sec. 150.10:

Reverse crush spread in soybeans on the CBOT subject to an

intermarket spread exemption. In the case where soybeans are processed

into two different products, soybean meal and

[[Page 96880]]

soybean oil, the crush spread is the difference between the combined

value of the products and the value of soybeans. There are two actors

in this scenario: The speculator and the soybean processor. The

spread's value approximates the profit margin from actually crushing

(or mashing) soybeans into meal and oil. The soybean processor may want

to lock in the spread value as part of its hedging strategy,

establishing a long position in soybean futures and short positions in

soybean oil futures and soybean meal futures, as substitutes for the

processor's expected cash market transactions (purchase of the

anticipated inputs for processing and sale of the anticipated

products). On the other side of the processor's crush spread, a

speculator takes a short position in soybean futures against long

positions in soybean meal futures and soybean oil futures. The soybean

processor may be able to lock in a higher crush spread, because of

liquidity provided by such a speculator who may need to rely upon a

spread exemption. It is important to understand that the speculator is

accepting basis risk represented by the crush spread, and the

speculator is providing liquidity to the soybean processor. The crush

spread positions may result in greater correlation between the futures

prices of soybeans and those of soybean oil and soybean meal, which

means that prices for all three products may move up or down together

in a closer manner.

Wheat spread subject to intermarket spread exemptions.

There are two actors in this scenario: The speculator and the wheat

farmer. In this example, a farmer growing hard wheat will like to

reduce the price risk of her crop by shorting MGEX wheat futures.

There, however, may be no hedger, such as a mill, that is immediately

available to trade at a desirable price for the farmer. There may be a

speculator willing to offer liquidity to the hedger; the speculator may

wish to reduce the risk of an outright long position in MGEX wheat

futures through establishing a short position in CBOT wheat futures

(soft wheat). Such a speculator, who otherwise will have been

constrained by a position limit at MGEX or CBOT, may seek exemptions

from MGEX and CBOT for an intermarket spread, that is, for a long

position in MGEX wheat futures and a short position in CBOT wheat

futures of the same maturity. As a result of the exchanges granting an

intermarket spread exemption to such a speculator, who otherwise may be

constrained by limits, the farmer might be able to transact at a higher

price for hard wheat than might have existed absent the intermarket

spread exemptions. Under this example, the speculator is accepting

basis risk between hard wheat and soft wheat, reducing the risk of a

position on one exchange by establishing a position on another

exchange, and potentially providing liquidity to a hedger. Further,

spread transactions may aid in price discovery regarding the relative

protein content for each of the hard and soft wheat contracts.

Finally, the Commission is allowing exchanges to recognize and

exempt spreads during the five-day spot month. There may be

considerable benefits that evolve from spreads exempted during the spot

month, in particular. Besides enhancing the opportunity for market

participants to use strategies involving spread trades into the spot

month, this relief may improve price discovery in the spot month for

market participants. And, as in the intermarket wheat example above,

the spread relief in the spot month may better link prices between two

markets, e.g., the price of MGEX wheat futures and the price of CBOT

wheat futures. Put another way, the prices in two different but related

markets for substitute goods may be more highly correlated, which

benefits market participants with a price exposure to the underlying

protein content in wheat generally, rather than that of a particular

commodity.

vi. Costs and Discussion of Comments

As discussed in the 2016 supplemental proposal, the Commission has

been able to quantify some costs, but other costs related to reproposed

Sec. 150.10 are not easily quantifiable. The Commission continues to

believe that some costs are more dependent on individual markets and

market participants seeking a spread exemption, and, thus, are more

readily considered qualitatively. In general, the Commission believes

that reproposed Sec. 150.10 should provide exchanges and market

participants greater regulatory and administrative certainty and that

costs will be small relative to the benefits of having an additional

trading tool under reproposed Sec. 150.10.

The Commission comes to this conclusion even though the most common

complaint about the spread-exemption process is that it requires

excessive reporting. One exchange commenter focused specifically on the

spread-exemption-recognition process, and stated that it is ``overly

prescriptive as to the information that must be provided by the

applicant, especially when the exchange may have superior information

regarding intramarket spreads.'' \1432\ The exchange commenter

criticized the proposed intramarket spread exemption application as

possibly being ``inefficient and time consuming thereby hindering the

exchange from effectively supporting its bona fide hedgers.'' \1433\

And the exchange commenter suggested that the Commission grant the

exchanges the ``flexibility and discretion to establish'' application

processes.\1434\ The exchange commenter further explained that

exchanges are best positioned to assess liquidity for bona fide hedgers

and perform the price discovery function for granting exemptions,

which, in turn protects market participants and the public.\1435\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1432\ CL-Nodal-60948 at 2.

\1433\ Id.

\1434\ Id. at 3.

\1435\ Id. at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission recognizes that spread-exemption application

requirements and reporting requirements are detailed. Moreover, these

costs will be borne by exchanges and market participants. But, the

Commission continues to believe that the qualitative costs will be

reasonable in view of the benefits to exchanges and market participants

of being able to use spread exemptions. Furthermore, the benefits of

having an application process and reporting regime will create cost-

savings to the public in the form of enhanced regulatory oversight.

The Commission, however, did respond to comments about proposed

Sec. 150.10(a)(3)(iii), which requires an applicant to identify ``the

maximum size of all gross positions in derivative contracts to be

acquired by the applicant during the year after the application is

submitted.'' The comment was that the requirement was too broad and

almost impossible because of the inability to predict trading activity

over the next year.\1436\ Another commenter described the proposed rule

as ``unnecessary and unduly burdensome.'' \1437\ The Commission, as

discussed above regrading reproposed Sec. 150.9(a)(3)(iii), has

clarified in reproposed Sec. 150.10(a)(3)(iii) that the filing must

include the maximum size of all gross positions for which the

application is submitted, which may be a longer time period that the

proposed one-year period. As noted above, in administering requests for

recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging position exemptions

under Sec. 1.47, the Commission has found a maximum size statement, as

required under Sec. 1.47(b)(4), to be useful both at the time

[[Page 96881]]

of review of the filing and at the time of review of a filer's position

that exceeds the level of the position limit.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1436\ CL-ISDA-60931 at 10.

\1437\ CL-Working Group-60947 at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Finally, like the discussion about quantified costs related to

reproposed Sec. 150.9, exchanges and market participants may have

already many of the financial outlays for administering the application

process and applying for spread exemptions, respectively. Yet, as

commenters have asserted, the Commission might have underestimated the

costs. In deference to the comments, the Commission has adjusted its

estimates of quantified costs that will arise from reproposed Sec.

150.10 in Tables IV-A-13 through IV-A-19, below. The Commission's new

estimates are based on commenters noting that the Commission estimated

staff hours, as well as the number of exemption requests, were low.

Note: The activities priced in Tables A2 to G2 are similar to the

activities discussed in the section affiliated with Tables A1 through

G1, above.

Table IV-A-13--Burden Estimates Filing New or Amended Rules

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

New or amended rule filings under part 40 per Sec. 6 5 2 $122.00 $1,220

150.10(a)(1), (a)(6)....................................

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table IV-A-14--Burden Estimates for Reviewing Applications

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Collection, review, and disposition of application per 6 7 85 $122.00 $72,590

Sec. 150.10(a)........................................

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table IV-A-15--Burden Estimates for Posting Summaries

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Summaries Posted Online per Sec. 150.10(a)............. 6 7 10 $122.00 $8,540

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Regarding the following Table D2, note that reports are also

required to be sent to the Commission in the case of exempt spread

positions under Sec. 150.10(a)(5).

Table IV-A-16--Burden Estimates for Market Participants to Apply

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sec. 150.10(a)(3) Spread Exemption Application......... 85 3 2 $122.00 $732

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table IV-A-17--Burden Estimates for Recordkeeping

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sec. 150.10(b) Recordkeeping........................... 6 30 1 $122.00 $3,660

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table IV-A-18--Burden Estimates for Submitting Weekly Reports

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sec. 150.10(c)(1) Weekly Report........................ 6 6 52 $122.00 $38,064

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96882]]

Table IV-A-19--Burden Estimates for Submitting Monthly Reports

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number of

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours per responses per Hourly wage Per-entity labor

respondents response respondent estimate cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sec. 150.10(c)(2) Monthly Report....................... 6 6 12 $122.00 $8,784

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Other costs to exchanges will include those related to

surveillance. For example, exchanges that elect to grant spread

exemptions will have to adapt and develop procedures to determine

whether a particular spread exemption furthers the goals of CEA section

4a(a)(3)(B) as well as monitor whether applicant speculators are, in

fact, providing liquidity to other market participants. There will

likely also be costs related to disagreements between the Commission

and exchanges over exchanges' disposition of a spread applications, or

costs from a Commission request or review under reproposed Sec.

150.11(d) or (e). As expressed in the 2016 supplemental proposal, these

costs are not easily quantified because they depend on the specifics of

the Commission's request or review.

c. Section 150.11--Enumerated Anticipatory Bona Fide Hedges

Between the 2016 Supplemental Proposal and now, the Commission is

making two changes in the following regulatory text: Sec.

150.11(a)(1)(v) and Sec. 150.11(a)(6).

i. Section 150.11(a)--Exchange-Administered Enumerated Anticipatory

Bona Fide Hedge Process

Under reproposed Sec. 150.11(a)(1), exchanges that voluntarily

elect to process enumerated anticipatory bona-fide hedge applications

are required to notify the Commission of their intention to do so by

filing new rules or rule amendments with the Commission under part 40

of the Commission's regulations. In reproposed Sec. 150.11(a)(1)(v),

the Commission clarified that exchanges that elect to offer a Sec.

150.11 exemption, must have at least one year of experience and

expertise in the referenced contract, rather than the derivative

contract. In reproposed Sec. 150.11(a)(2), the Commission identifies

certain types of information necessary for the application, including

information required under reproposed Sec. 150.7(d). In reproposed

Sec. 150.11(a)(3), the Commission states that applications must be

updated annually and that the exchanges have ten days in which to

recognize an enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedge. In addition,

exchanges must retain authority to revoke recognitions. reproposed

Sec. 150.11(a)(4) states that once an enumerated anticipatory bona

fide hedging position has been recognized by an exchange, the position

will be deemed to be recognized by the Commission. Reproposed Sec.

150.11(a)(5) discusses reports that must be filed by an applicant

holding an enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging position, as

required under reproposed Sec. 150.7(e). The Commission clarified

those reporting requirements, which were also proposed in Sec.

150.11(a)(3)(i), and eliminated language that was confusing to

commenters regarding updating and maintaining the accuracy of such

reports. Reproposed 150.11(a)(6) explains that exchanges may choose to

seek Commission review of an application and the Commission has ten

days in which to respond.

ii. Section 150.11(b)--Enumerated Anticipatory Bona Fide Hedge

Recordkeeping Requirements

The Commission did not make any changes to Sec. 150.11(b) as

proposed in the 2016 supplemental proposal. Exchanges must maintain

complete books and records of all activities relating to the processing

and disposition of anticipatory hedging applications under reproposed

Sec. 150.11(b).

iii. Section 150.11(c)--Enumerated Anticipatory Bona Fide Hedge

Reporting Requirements

The Commission did not make any changes to Sec. 150.11(c) as

proposed in the 2016 supplemental proposal. Exchanges will have weekly

reporting obligations under reproposed Sec. 150.11(c).

iv. Baseline

The baseline is the same as it was in the December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal: The current filing process detailed in current Sec.

1.48.

v. Benefits

There are significant benefits that will likely accrue should Sec.

150.11 be finalized. Recognizing anticipatory positions as bona fide

hedging positions under Sec. 150.11 will provide market participants

with potentially a more expeditious recognition process than the

Commission proposal for a 10-day Commission recognition process under

reproposed Sec. 150.7. The benefit of prompter recognitions, though,

is not readily quantifiable, and, in most circumstances, is subject to

the characteristics and needs of markets as well as market

participants. So it is challenging to quantify the benefits that will

likely be associated with reproposed Sec. 150.11.

For example, exchanges will be able to use existing resources and

knowledge in the administration and assessment of enumerated

anticipatory bona fide hedging positions. The Commission and exchanges

have evaluated these types of positions for years (as discussed in the

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal). Utilizing this experience and

familiarity will likely produce such benefits as prompt but reasoned

decision making and streamlined procedures. In addition, reproposed

Sec. 150.11 permits exchanges to act in less than ten days--a

timeframe that will be less than the Commission's process under current

Sec. 1.48, or under reproposed Sec. 150.7.\1438\ This could

potentially enable commercial market participants to pursue trading

strategies in a more timely fashion to advance their commercial and

hedging needs to reduce risk.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1438\ See discussion in December 2013 Position Limits Proposal,

78 FR 75745-46, Dec. 12, 2013.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Reproposed Sec. 150.11, similar to reproposed Sec. 150.9 and

Sec. 150.10, also will provide the benefit of enhanced record-

retention and reporting of positions recognized as enumerated

anticipatory bona fide hedging positions. As previously discussed,

records retained for specified periods will enable exchanges to develop

consistent practices and afford the Commission accessible information

for review, surveillance, and enforcement efforts. Likewise, weekly

reporting under Sec. 150.11 will facilitate the tracking of positions

by the Commission.

vi. Costs and Discussion of Comments

The Sec. 150.11-related comments in response to the 2016

supplement proposal's request for comments

[[Page 96883]]

centered on the claim that the exemption process and reporting

requirements are burdensome. Nevertheless, as explained above, the

Commission made a few changes to clarify application and reporting

requirements.

The costs for reproposed Sec. 150.11 are similar to the costs for

reproposed Sec. Sec. 150.9 and 150.10, and have been quantified are in

Tables A3 through G3. As mentioned earlier, the Commission has

increased the number of staff hours and exemption requests based on

commenters stating that the Commission underestimated costs. Other

costs associated with reproposed Sec. 150.11, like those for

reproposed Sec. Sec. 150.9 and 150.10, are more qualitative in nature

and hinge on specific market and participant attributes. Other costs

could arise from reproposed Sec. 150.11 if the Commission disagrees

with an exchange's disposition of an enumerated anticipatory bona fide

hedging position application, or costs from a Commission request or

review under reproposed Sec. 150.11(d). These costs will include time

and effort spent by market participants associated with a Commission

review. In addition, market participants will lose amounts that the

Commission can neither predict nor quantify if it became necessary to

unwind trades or reduce positions were the Commission to conclude that

an exchange's disposition of an enumerated anticipatory bona fide

hedging position application is not appropriate or is inconsistent with

the Act. This concern was raised by commenters as discussed above. The

Commission believes that such disagreements will be rare based on the

Commission's past experience and review of exchanges' efforts.

Nevertheless, the Commission notes that assessing whether a position is

for the reduction of risk arising from anticipatory needs or excessive

speculation is complicated.

Note: For a general description of reproposed rules identified

in the following Tables IV-A-20 to IV-A-24, see discussion above.

Table IV-A-20--Burden Estimates for Filing New or Amended Rules

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours of responses Hourly wage Per-entity

respondents per response per respondent estimate labor cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

New or amended rule filings under part 40 per Sec. 150.11(a)(1), 6 5 2 $122.00 $1,220

(a)(5)............................................................

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table IV-A-21--Burden Estimates for Reviewing Applications

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours of responses Hourly wage Per-entity

respondents per response per respondent estimate labor cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Collection, review, and disposition of application per Sec. 6 7 90 $122.00 $76,860

150.11(a).........................................................

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table IV-A-22--Burden Estimates for Market Participants to Apply

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours of responses Hourly wage Per-entity

respondents per response per respondent estimate labor cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sec. 150.11(a)(2) Application on Form 704........................ 90 3 2 $122.00 $732

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table IV-A-23--Burden Estimates for Recordkeeping

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours of responses Hourly wage Per-entity

respondents per response per respondent estimate labor cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sec. 150.11(b) Recordkeeping..................................... 6 30 1 $122.00 $3,660

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table IV-A-24--Burden Estimates for Submitting Weekly Reports

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Annual number

Required record or report Total number of Burden hours of responses Hourly wage Per-entity

respondents per response per respondent estimate labor cost

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sec. 150.11(c) Weekly Report..................................... 6 6 52 $122.00 $38,064

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Exchanges will have additional surveillance costs and duties that

the Commission believes will be integrated with their existing self-

regulatory organization surveillance activities as an exchange.

[[Page 96884]]

10. Summary of CEA Section 15(a) Factors

CEA section 15(a) requires the Commission to consider the costs and

benefits of its actions in light of five factors.

a. Protection of Market Participants and the Public

The imposition of position limits is intended to protect the

markets and market participants from manipulation and excessive

speculation. Position limits may serve as a prophylactic measure that

reduces market volatility due to a participant otherwise engaging in

large trades that induce price impacts. Such price impacts may occur

when a party who is holding large open interest is not willing or is

unable to meet a call for additional margin. In such an instance, a

substantial amount of open interest may have to be liquidated in a

short time interval. In addition, price impacts could also occur from a

large trader establishing or liquidating large positions.

There are additional benefits to imposing position limits in the

spot month. Spot month position limits are designed to deter and

prevent corners and squeezes as well as promote a more orderly

liquidation process at expiration.\1439\ Spot month position limits may

also make it more difficult to mark the close of a futures contract to

possibly benefit other contracts that settle on the closing futures

price. Marking the close harms markets by spoiling convergence between

futures prices and spot prices at expiration. Convergence is desirable,

because many market participants want to hedge the spot price of a

commodity at expiration. In addition, since many other contracts,

including cash market contracts, settle based on the futures price at

expiration, the mispricing might affect a larger amount of the

commodity than the deliverable supply of the futures contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1439\ Most futures contracts do not ultimately result in

physical delivery. Instead, most positions are eliminated by a

trader taking an offsetting position in the contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The CEA provides that position limits do not apply to positions

shown to be bona fide hedging positions, as defined by the Commission,

or spread positions, as recognized by the Commission. Exemptions from

federal position limits for bona fide hedging positions of qualified

market participants help ensure the hedging utility of the futures

markets while protecting market participants from excess speculation.

The Commission believes that the reproposed rules will preserve the

important protections of the federal position limit regime while

maintaining the hedging function of the futures or swaps markets.

The Commission believes the exemption provisions of these

reproposed rules will have a negligible effect on the protection

afforded market participants and the public, as compared to the level

of protection that is provided by the exemptions policy reflected

currently in Sec. 150.3. Moreover, by expanding current Sec. 150.3 to

allow exchanges to review applications for exemptions from federal

limits, the Commission will be able to rely on the exchanges'

experience and expertise in monitoring their own contract markets, with

Commission supervision, to help ensure that any exemptions do not

detract from the protection of market participants and the public.

Because exchanges have experience and expertise, including as part of

their SRO functions, the Commission believes they will be able to

carefully design exemptions under which position limits will continue

to protect market participants while meeting needs for bona fide

hedging. Moreover, exchanges have strong incentives--such as

maintaining credibility of their markets through protecting against the

harms of excessive speculation and manipulation--to appropriately

administer exemptions.

b. Efficiency, Competitiveness, and Financial Integrity of Futures

Markets

There is a potential market integrity issue with excess

speculation. People may not be willing to participate in a futures

market if they perceive that there is a participant with an unusually

large speculative position exerting what they believe is unreasonable

market power. A lack of participation may harm liquidity, and

consequently, may harm market efficiency.

On the other hand, traders who find position limits binding may

have to trade in substitute instruments--such as futures contracts that

are similar but not the same as the core referenced futures contract,

forward contracts, trade options, or futures on a foreign board of

trade--in order to meet their demand for speculative instruments. These

traders may also decide to not trade beyond the federal speculative

position limit. Trading in substitute instruments may be less effective

that trading in referenced contracts and, thus, may raise the

transaction costs for such traders. In these circumstances, futures

prices might not fully reflect all the speculative demand to hold the

futures contract, because substitute instruments may not fully

influence prices the same way that trading directly in the futures

contract does. Thus, market efficiency might be harmed.

c. Price Discovery

Reduced liquidity may have a negative impact on price discovery. In

the absence of position limits, market participants might elect to

trade less as a result of a perception that the market pricing is

unfair as a consequence of what they perceive is the exercise of too

much market power by a larger speculator. On the other hand, liquidity

may also be harmed by a speculator being restricted from additional

trading by a position limit. The Commission has set the levels of

position limits at high levels, to avoid harming liquidity that may be

provided by speculators that would establish large positions, while

restricting speculators from establishing extraordinarily large

positions. The Commission believes that the recognition and exemption

processes will foster liquidity and potentially improve price discovery

by making it easier for market participants to have their bona fide

hedging exemptions and spread exemptions recognized, however.

Position limits may serve as a prophylactic measure that reduces

market volatility due to a participant otherwise engaging in large

trades that induce price impacts which interrupt price discovery. Spot

month position limits make it more difficult to mark the close of a

futures contract to possibly benefit other contracts that settle on the

closing futures price. Marking the close harms markets by spoiling

convergence between futures prices and spot prices at expiration and

damaging price discovery.

d. Sound Risk Management Practices

The Commission believes that traders knowing their positions and

ensuring that they do not exceed a position limit or exempted level is

a sound risk management practice. Under the exemption processes, market

participants must explain and document the methods behind their hedging

or spreading strategies to exchanges, and the Commission or exchanges

would have to evaluate them. As a result, the Commission believes that

the evaluation processes should help market participants, exchanges,

the Commission, and the public to understand better the risk management

techniques and objectives of various market participants.

e. Other Public Interest Considerations

The Commission has not identified any other public interest

considerations.

[[Page 96885]]

The Commission declined to treat the goal of fostering innovation and

growth for the betterment of markets as an additional public interest

consideration, because these objectives are amorphous and likely

difficult to accomplish with a position limit. Instead, exchanges have

proper incentives and a variety of tools, including financial

innovation, with which to increase liquidity on their exchanges.

9. CEA Section 15(b) Considerations

Section 15(b) of the CEA requires the Commission to consider the

public interest to be protected by the antitrust laws and to endeavor

to take the least anticompetitive means of achieving the objectives,

policies and purposes of the CEA, before promulgating a regulation

under the CEA or issuing certain orders. The Commission believes that

the rules and guidance in this notice are consistent with the public

interest protected by the antitrust laws.

The Commission acknowledges that, with respect to exchange

qualifications to recognize or grant non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions, spread exemptions, and anticipatory bona fide hedging

position exemptions for federal position limit purposes, the threshold

experience requirements that it is reproposing will advantage certain

more-established incumbent DCMs (``incumbent DCMs'') over smaller DCMs

seeking to expand or future entrant DCMs (collectively ``entrant

DCMs'') or SEFs.\1440\ Specifically, incumbent DCMs--based on their

past track records of: (1) Listing actively traded referenced contracts

or actively traded components of spreads; and (2) setting and

administering exchange-set position limits applicable to those

contracts for at least a year, or having otherwise hired staff with

such position limit experience gained elsewhere--will be immediately

eligible to submit rules to the Commission under part 40 of the

Commission's regulations to process trader applications for recognition

of non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions, spread exemptions,\1441\

and anticipatory bona fide hedges; in contrast, entrant DCMs and SEFs

will be foreclosed from doing so until such time as they have met the

eligibility criteria, although the Commission has clarified in the

reproposed rule that any exchange may meet the experience requirement,

but not the actively traded contract requirement, by hiring staff with

appropriate experience. However, in the absence of any comments

supporting a contrary view, the Commission does not perceive that an

ability to process applications for non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions, spread exemptions and/or anticipatory bona fide hedging

positions is a necessary function for a DCM or SEF to compete

effectively as a trading facility. In the event an incumbent DCM

declines to process a trader's request for hedging recognition or a

spread exemption,\1442\ the trader may seek the recognition or

exemption directly from the Commission in order to trade on an entrant

DCM or SEF. Accordingly, the Commission does not view the reproposed

threshold experience requirements as establishing a barrier to entry or

competitive restraint likely to facilitate anticompetitive effects in

any relevant antitrust market for contract trading.\1443\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1440\ See reproposed Sec. Sec. 150.9(a)(1), 150.10(a)(1), and

150.11(a)(1).

\1441\ In the case of qualifications to exempt certain spread

positions, the contract may be either a referenced contract that is

a component of the spread or another contract that is a component of

the spread. See reproposed Sec. 150.10(a)(1)(i).

\1442\ The Commission recognizes that in certain circumstances

it might be in an exchange's economic interest to deny processing a

particular trader's application for hedge recognition or a spread

exemption. For example, this might occur in a circumstance in which

a trader has reached the exchange-set limit and the exchange

determines that liquidity is insufficient to maintain a fair and

orderly contract market if the trader's position increases.

\1443\ See, e.g., Brown Shoe Co. v. U.S., 370 U.S. 294, 324-25

(1962) (``The outer boundaries of a product market are determined by

the reasonable interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of

demand between the product itself and the substitutes for it'');

U.S. v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 353 U.S. 586, 593

(1957)(``Determination of the relevant market is a necessary

predicate to finding a violation''); Rebel Oil v. Atl. Richfield

Co., 51 F. 3d 1421, 1434 (9th Cir. 1995) (``A `market' is any

grouping of sales whose sellers, if unified by a monopolist or a

hypothetical cartel will have market power in dealing with any group

of buyers,'' quoting Phillip Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust

Law ]518.1b, at 534 (Supp. 1993)).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission invited comment on any considerations related to the

public interest to be protected by the antitrust laws and potential

anticompetitive effects of the proposal, as well as data or other

information to support such considerations. One exchange commenter

responded that it was concerned that the overly prescriptive

intramarket spread exemption application process might diminish spread

trading on all exchanges.\1444\ More specifically, the exchange

commenter stated that it believed it would be adversely affected by the

proposed spread exemption rule because it is an exchange that offers a

certain type of spread trading.\1445\ Moreover, the exchange commenter

relies on intramarket spread trading to enhance liquidity on less

actively traded contracts and believes the publication requirement

under Sec. 150.10(a)(7) would have an anti-competitive effect.\1446\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1444\ CL-Nodal-60948 at 4.

\1445\ Id. at 4.

\1446\ Id. at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response, the Commission notes that it has the responsibility to

review the record of the exchange in granting spread exemptions. For

example, a spread trader, who is a speculator, may amass a large

position in a referenced contract and a corresponding large position in

a non-referenced contract. Such a speculator has an incentive to mark

the close of the core referenced futures contract to benefit their

large position in a referenced contract. The Commission is concerned

that it has an adequate record to review timely a grant of a spread

exemption, which would allow a speculator to build a large position in

a referenced contract, exempt from position limits. Regarding the

publication requirement, the Commission reiterates that the publication

requirement is only for a summary describing the type of spread

position and why it was exempted and, thus, does not require details of

all components of spread trading within low liquidity non-referenced

contract markets to be revealed; the Commission notes it would not

expect such a summary would reveal identifying information for any

trader, but, rather, would reveal, at a minimum, the referenced

contract and a generic description of the type of non-referenced

contract that is a component of the spread. In addition, the Commission

notes that spread trades may qualify as bona fide hedging positions,

obviating the need for a spread exemption. Finally, the Commission

notes an exchange may petition the Commission for an exemption under

CEA section 4a(a)(7) or the Commission staff for a no-action letter

under Sec. 140.99.

B. Paperwork Reduction Act

1. Overview

The Paperwork Reduction Act (``PRA''), 44 U.S.C. 3501 et seq.,

imposes certain requirements on Federal agencies, including the

Commission, in connection with their conducting or sponsoring any

collection of information as defined by the PRA. An agency may not

conduct or sponsor, and a person is not required to respond to, a

collection of information unless it displays a currently valid control

number issued by the Office of Management and Budget (``OMB''). This

reproposed rulemaking would result in the collection of information

within the meaning of the PRA, as discussed

[[Page 96886]]

below. Specifically, if adopted, it would amend previously-approved

collection of information requirements. Therefore, the Commission is

submitting this reproposal to OMB for review in accordance with 44

U.S.C. 3507(d) and 5 CFR 1320.11. The information collection

requirements reproposed herein will be an amendment to the previously-

approved collection associated with OMB control number 3038-0013.\1447\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1447\ Part 19--Reports by persons holding bona fide hedge

positions--currently covered by OMB control number 3038-0009, is

being proposed for inclusion in OMB control number 3038-0013.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

If the reproposed changes to regulations are adopted, responses to

this collection of information would be mandatory. Several of the

reporting requirements would be mandatory in order to obtain exemptive

relief, and, therefore, would be mandatory under the PRA to the extent

a market participant elects to seek such relief. The Commission will

protect any proprietary information received in accordance with the

Freedom of Information Act and 17 CFR part 145, titled ``Commission

Records and Information.'' In addition, the Commission emphasizes that

section 8(a)(1) of the Act strictly prohibits the Commission, unless

specifically authorized by the Act, from making public ``data and

information that would separately disclose the business transactions or

market positions of any person and trade secrets or names of

customers.'' \1448\ The Commission also is required to protect certain

information contained in a government system of records pursuant to the

Privacy Act of 1974.\1449\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1448\ 7 U.S.C. 12(a)(1).

\1449\ 5 U.S.C. 552a.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In December 2013, the Commission proposed a number of modifications

to its speculative position limits regime. Under that proposal, market

participants with positions in a ``referenced contract,'' as defined in

Sec. 150.1, would be subject to the position limit framework

established in parts 19 and 150 of the Commission's regulations.

Proposed changes to part 19 would prescribe new forms and reporting

requirements for persons claiming exemptions to speculative position

limits and update reporting obligations and required information on

existing forms. In proposed part 150, the Commission changed reporting

requirements for DCMs listing a core referenced futures contract as

well as for traders who wish to apply for an exemption from exchange-

set position limits. The Commission also proposed to update and change

recordkeeping requirements for market participants and exchanges.

In June 2016, the Commission published in the Federal Register a

supplemental notice of proposed rulemaking to update and revise the

regulations proposed in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal. The

Commission proposed to allow a participant to exceed speculative

position limits to the extent that the participant's position is

recognized as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, an exempt

spread position, or an enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedge, by a

DCM or SEF. The Commission proposed to require new or amended rule

filings under part 40 of its regulations that comply with certain

conditions set forth in the revisions to part 150. Further, the

proposed changes stated that in order to seek exemptive relief market

participants would need to file applications with a DCM or SEF that met

criteria established under the proposal.

In this Reproposal, the Commission is reproposing its changes to

parts 1, 15, 17, 19, 37, 38, 140, 150, and 151 of the Commission's

regulations. Specifically, with regard to the PRA, the Commission is

reproposing the following: New and amended series '04 forms under part

19 and Sec. 150.7; submission of deliverable supply estimates under

Sec. 150.2(a)(3); recordkeeping obligations under Sec. 150.3(g);

revised special call authority under Sec. 150.3(h); exchange set limit

exemption application requirements under Sec. 150.5(a)(2); and

requirements for recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions, certain spread positions, and enumerated anticipatory bona

fide hedging positions under Sec. 150.9, Sec. 150.10, and Sec.

150.11, respectively.

The Commission proposes reorganizing the information found in the

OMB Collection Numbers associated with this rule. In particular, the

Commission proposes that the burdens related to series '04 forms be

moved from OMB Collection #3038-0009 to OMB Collection #3038-0013. This

change is non-substantive but allows for all information collections

related to exemptions from speculative position limits to be housed in

one collection, making it simpler for market participants to know where

to find the relevant PRA burdens. If adopted, OMB Collection #3038-0009

would hold collections of information related to parts 15, 17, and 21

while OMB Collection #3038-0013 would hold collections of information

related to parts 19 and 150.

2. Methodology and Assumptions

It is not possible at this time to accurately determine the number

of respondents that will be affected by the these rules. Many of the

regulations that impose PRA burdens are exemptions that a market

participant may elect to take advantage of, meaning that without

intimate knowledge of the day-to-day business decisions of all its

market participants, the Commission could not know which participants,

or how many, may elect to obtain such an exemption. Further, the

Commission is unsure of how many participants not currently in the

market may be required to or may elect to incur the estimated burdens

in the future.

The provisions under Sec. 150.9-11 permits designated contract

markets and swap execution facilities to elect to process applications

for recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions, exempt

spread positions, or enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedges;

accordingly the Commission does not know which, or how many, designated

contract markets and swap execution facilities may elect to offer such

recognition processes, or which, or how many market participants may

submit applications. The Commission is unsure of how many designated

contract markets, swap execution facilities, and market participants

not currently active in the market may elect to incur the estimated

burdens in the future.

Finally, many of the regulations proposed herein are applying to

participants in swaps markets for the first time, and the Commission's

lack of experience enforcing speculative position limits for such

markets and for many of the participants therein hinders its ability to

determine with precision the number of affected entities. These

limitations notwithstanding, the Commission has made best-effort

estimations regarding the likely number of affected entities for the

purposes of calculating burdens under the PRA.

3. Information Provided by Reporting Entities/Persons

To determine the number of entities who may file series '04 forms

with the Commission and/or exemption applications with DCMs that elect

to process such applications, the Commission used its proprietary data

collected from market participants as well as information provided by

DCMs regarding the number of exemptions processed by exchange

surveillance programs each year.\1450\ As discussed

[[Page 96887]]

supra,\1451\ the Commission analyzed data covering a two-year period of

July 1, 2014-June 30, 2016 to determine how many participants would

have been over 60, 80, 100, 125, 150, 175, 200, and 500 percent of the

limit levels in each of the 25 commodities subject to limits under

Sec. 150.2 had such levels been in effect during the covered

period.\1452\ The Commission determined that in that period, 409 unique

entities would have exceeded any of the limits in any commodities; the

Commission is using a figure of 425 entities to account for any

additional entities which may be required to comply with limits. The

Commission assumes that only entities over such levels--or close to

being over such levels--will file the necessary forms and applications.

The Commission's analysis does not account for persons holding hedging

or other exemptions from position limits, and the figures provided by

DCMs account for exemptions filed for all commodities, not just the 25

subject to limits under Sec. 150.2. Accordingly, the Commission

believes the estimates of the number of 425 respondents used herein are

highly conservative.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1450\ The Commission also described this information in the

2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal. See 2016 Supplemental

Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR 38500.

\1451\ See supra discussion of number of traders over the limit

levels.

\1452\ The Commission also used this analysis to determine the

number of entities subject to the Commission's recordkeeping and

special call rules in Sec. 150.3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

To determine the number of exchanges who would be affected by the

reproposal, the Commission analyzed how many exchanges currently list

actively traded contracts in the commodities for which federal position

limits will be set, as the proposed rules in Sec. 150.5 as well as in

Sec. Sec. 150.9, 150.10, and 150.11 will all apply to exchanges that

list commodity derivative contracts that may be subject federal limits

under Sec. 150.2(d).

The Commission's estimates concerning wage rates are based on 2013

salary information for the securities industry compiled by the

Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association (``SIFMA''). The

Commission is using a figure of $122 per hour, which is derived from a

weighted average of salaries across different professions from the

SIFMA Report on Management & Professional Earnings in the Securities

Industry 2013, modified to account for an 1800-hour work-year, adjusted

to account for the cumulative rate of inflation since 2013. This figure

was then multiplied by 1.33 to account for benefits, and further by 1.5

to account for overhead and administrative expenses. The Commission

anticipates that compliance with the provisions would require the work

of an information technology professional; a compliance manager; an

accounting professional; and an associate general counsel. Thus, the

wage rate is a weighted national average of salary for professionals

with the following titles (and their relative weight); ``programmer

(average of senior and non-senior)'' (15% weight), ``senior

accountant'' (15%) ``compliance manager'' (30%), and ``assistant/

associate general counsel'' (40%). All monetary estimates below have

been rounded to the dollar.

A commenter estimated that for an exchange to promulgate the

regulations required of them under this part such an exchange would

need a senior level regulation employee and three regulatory

analysts.\1453\ When the Commission estimated a per-hour wage rate

using these professions, however, the average hourly wage rate was

lower than the $122 estimated above.\1454\ In this reproposal, the

Commission is therefore estimating all burdens with the higher wage

rate. The Commission notes that the wage rate used for PRA calculations

is an average rate, and that some entities may face a higher or lower

wage rate based on individual circumstances.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1453\ CL-ICE-60929 at 17.

\1454\ The Commission computed the alternative wage rate as a

weighted national average of salary for professionals with the

following titles (and their relative weight); ``compliance manager''

(25 percent weight), 3 ``compliance examiner, intermediate'' (15

percent each) and ``assistant/associate general counsel'' (30

percent). After adjusting for inflation, overhead, and benefits, the

wage rate was $107. These titles appeared to best represent the

commenter's suggestion but without additional input from the

commenter it is impossible to ascertain the commenter's original

intent regarding titles of necessary staffing.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

4. Collections of Information

(a) Recordkeeping and Reporting Obligations for Market Participants

(i) Forms 204 and 304

Previously, the Commission estimated the combined annual labor

hours for both Form 204 and Form 304 to be 1,350 hours, which amounted

to a total labor cost to industry of $68,850 per annum.\1455\ Below,

the Commission has estimated the costs for each form separately.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1455\ This estimate was based upon an average wage rate of $51

per hour. Adjusted to the hourly wage rate used for purposes of this

PRA estimate, the previous total labor cost would have been

$202,500.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As proposed, Form 204 would be required to be filed when a trader

accumulates a net long or short commodity derivative position that

exceeds a federal limit in a referenced contract. Form 204 would inform

the Commission of the trader's cash positions underlying those

commodity derivative contracts for purposes of claiming bona fide

hedging exemptions.

The Commission estimates that approximately 425 traders would be

required to file Form 204 once a month (12 times per year) each. At an

estimated 3 labor hours to complete and file each Form 204 report for a

total annual burden to industry of 15,300 labor hours, the Form 204

reporting requirement would cost industry $1,866,600 in labor costs.

As proposed, Form 304 would be required to be filed by merchants

and dealers in cotton and contains information on the quantity of call

cotton bought or sold on a weekly basis. Form 304 would be required in

order for the Commission to produce its weekly cotton ``on call''

report.\1456\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1456\ The Commission's Weekly Cotton On-Call Report can be

found here: http://www.cftc.gov/MarketReports/CottonOnCall/index.htm.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission estimates that approximately 200 traders would be

required to make a Form 304 submission for call cotton 52 times per

year each. At 1 hour to complete each submission for a total annual

burden to industry of 10,400 labor hours, the Form 304 reporting

requirement would impose upon industry $1,268,800 in labor costs.

(ii) Form 504

As proposed, Sec. 19.01(a)(1) would require persons claiming a

conditional spot month limit exemption pursuant to Sec. 150.3(c) to

file Form 504. Unlike other series '04 forms, Form 504 would apply only

to commodity derivative contracts in natural gas markets.\1457\ A Form

504 filing would show the composition of the natural gas cash position

underlying a referenced contract that is held or controlled for which

the exemption is claimed. The Commission notes that this form should be

submitted daily for each day of the 3-day spot period for the core

referenced futures contract in natural gas. The Commission estimates

that approximately 40 traders would claim a conditional spot month

limit 12 times per year, and each corresponding submission would take

15 labor hours to complete and file. Therefore, the Commission

estimates that the proposed Form 504 reporting requirement would result

in approximately 7,200 total annual labor hours for an additional

industry-wide labor cost of $878,400.

[[Page 96888]]

The Commission requests comment on its estimates regarding new Form

504.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1457\ See supra, discussion of conditional spot month limit

exemption (Sec. 150.3(c)).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

(iii) Form 604

Persons claiming a pass-through swap exemption pursuant to Sec.

150.3(a) would be required to file proposed Form 604 showing various

data (depending on whether the offset is for non-referenced contract

swaps or spot-month swaps) including, at a minimum, the underlying

commodity or commodity reference price, the applicable clearing

identifiers, the notional quantity, the gross long or short position in

terms of futures-equivalents in the core referenced futures contracts,

and the gross long or short positions in the referenced contract for

the offsetting risk position. For proposed Form 604 reports filed for

positions held outside of the spot month, the Commission estimates that

approximately 250 traders would claim a pass-through swap exemption an

average of 10 times per year each. At approximately 30 labor hours to

complete each corresponding submission for a total burden to traders of

75,000 annual labor hours, compliance with the proposed Form 604 filing

requirements industry-wide would impose an additional $9,150,000 in

labor costs.

(iv) Form 704

Traders claiming anticipatory bona fide hedging exemptions would be

required to file proposed Form 704 for the initial statement/

application pursuant to Sec. 150.7(d), along with an annual update on

the same form. Because annual update requires mostly the same

information as the initial statement, allowing market participants to

update only fields that have changed since the initial statement was

filed rather than having to update the entire form, the Commission

anticipates the annual update requiring about half the time to

complete. The Commission estimates that approximately 250 traders would

claim anticipatory exemptions by filing an initial statement

approximately once per year. At an estimated 15 labor hours to complete

and file an initial statement on Form 704 for a total annual burden to

traders of 3,750 labor hours, the anticipatory exemption filing

requirement would cost industry an additional $457,500 in labor costs.

The annual update to proposed Form 704 is estimated to be required of

the same 250 traders once a year, at an estimated 8 hours to complete

and file, for an industry-wide burden of 2,000 hours and $244,000 in

labor costs.

(v) Recordkeeping and Other Provisions

Any person claiming an exemption from federal position limits under

part 150 would be required to keep and maintain books and records

concerning all details of their related cash, forward, futures, options

and swap positions and transactions to serve as a reasonable basis to

demonstrate reduction of risk on each day that the exemption was

claimed. These records would be required to be comprehensive, in that

they must cover anticipated requirements, production and royalties,

contracts for services, cash commodity products and by-products, pass-

through swaps, cross-commodity hedges, and more.

The Commission estimates that approximately 425 traders would claim

an average of 50 exemptions each per year that fall within the scope of

the recordkeeping requirements of proposed Sec. 150.3(g). At

approximately one hour per exemption claimed to keep and maintain the

required books and records, the Commission estimates that industry

would incur a total of 20,000 annual labor hours amounting to

$2,592,500 in additional labor costs.

In addition, proposed Sec. 150.3(h) would provide that upon call

from the Commission any person claiming an exemption from speculative

position limits under proposed Sec. 150.3 must provide to the

Commission any information as specified in the call. It is difficult to

determine in advance of any such call who may be required to submit

information under proposed Sec. 150.3(h), how that information may be

submitted, or how many labor hours it may take to prepare and submit

such information. However, for the purposes of the PRA, the Commission

has made estimates regarding the potential burden.

The Commission estimates that approximately 425 traders would be

eligible to be called upon for additional information under proposed

Sec. 150.3(h) each year. At approximately two hours per exemption

claimed to keep and maintain the required books and records, the

Commission estimates that industry would incur a total of 850 annual

labor hours amounting to $103,700 in additional labor costs.

(vi) Exchange-Set Limits and Exchange-Recognized Exemptions

Traders who wish to avail themselves of any exemption from a DCM or

SEF's speculative position limit rules would need to submit an

application to the DCM or SEF explaining how the exemption would be in

accord with sound commercial practices and would allow for a position

that could be liquidated in an orderly fashion. As noted supra, the

Commission understands that requiring traders to apply for exemptive

relief comports with existing DCM practice; thus, the Commission

anticipates that the proposed codification of this requirement would

have the practical effect of incrementally increasing, rather than

creating, the burden of applying for such exemptive relief. The

Commission estimates that approximately 425 traders would claim

exemptions from DCM or SEF-established speculative position limits each

year, with each trader on average making 1 application to the DCM or

SEF each year. Each submission is estimated to take 2 hours to complete

and file, meaning that these traders collectively would incur a total

burden of 850 labor hours per year for an industry-wide additional

labor cost of $39,976.

Under proposed Sec. Sec. 150.9(a)(3), 150.10(a)(3), and

150.11(a)(2), designated contract markets and swap execution facilities

that elect to process applications to establish an application process

that elicits sufficient information to allow the designated contract

market or swap execution facility to determine, and the Commission to

verify, whether it is appropriate to recognize a commodity derivative

position as an non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, exempt spread

position or enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedge, respectively.

Pursuant to proposed Sec. Sec. 150.9(a)(4)(i), 150.10(a)(4), and

150.11(a)(3), an applicant would be required to update an application

at least on an annual basis. Further, DCMs and SEFs have authority

under Sec. Sec. 150.9(a)(6), 150.10(a)(6), and 150.11(a)(5) to require

that any such applicant file a report with the designated contract

market or swap execution facility pertaining to the use of any

exemption that has been granted.

The Commission anticipates that market participants would be mostly

familiar with the non-enumerated bona fide hedging position application

provided by exchanges that currently process such applications, and

thus believes that the burden for applying to an exchange would be

minimal. Information included in the application would be required to

be sufficient to allow the exchange to determine, and the Commission to

verify, whether the position meets the requirements of CEA section

4a(c), but specific data fields are left to the exchanges to determine.

The Commission notes that there would be a slight additional burden for

market participants to submit the notice

[[Page 96889]]

regarding the use of any exemption granted, should the DCM or SEF

require such a report.

The Commission estimates that 325 entities would file an average of

2 applications each year to obtain recognition of certain positions as

non-enumerated bona fide hedges and that each application, including

any usage report that may be required by the DCM or SEF, would require

approximately 4 burden hours to complete and file. Thus, the Commission

estimates an average per entity burden of 8 labor hours and an

industry-wide burden of 2,600 labor hours annually. The Commission

estimates an average cost of approximately $976 per entity or $317,200

for the industry as a whole for applications under Sec. 150.9(a)(3).

The Commission anticipates that market participants would be mostly

familiar with the spread exemption application provided by exchanges

that currently process such applications, and thus believes that the

burden for applying to an exchange would be minimal. Information

included in the application is required to be sufficient to allow the

exchange to determine, and the Commission to verify, whether the

position fulfills the objectives of CEA section 4a(a)(3)(B), but

specific data fields are left to the exchanges to determine. The

Commission notes that there would be a slight additional burden for

market participants to submit the notice regarding the use of any

exemption granted should the DCM or SEF require such a report.

The Commission estimates that 85 entities would file an average of

2 applications each year to obtain an exemption for certain spread

positions and that each application, including any usage report

required by the DCM or SEF, would require approximately 3 burden hours

to complete and file. Thus, the Commission approximates an average per

entity burden of 6 labor hours and an industry-wide burden of 510 labor

hours annually. The Commission estimates an average cost of

approximately $732 per entity or $62,220 for the industry as a whole

for applications under Sec. 150.10(a)(2).

The Commission anticipates that market participants would be mostly

familiar with the enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedge application

provided by exchanges that currently process such applications, and

thus believes that the burden for applying to an exchange would be

minimal. The application is required to include, at a minimum, the

information required under Sec. 150.7(d). The Commission estimates

that 90 entities would file an average of 2 applications each year to

obtain recognition that certain positions are enumerated anticipatory

bona fide hedges and that each application would require approximately

3 burden hours to complete and file. Thus, the Commission estimates an

average per entity burden of 6 labor hours and an industry-wide burden

of 510 labor hours annually. The Commission estimates an average cost

of approximately $732 per entity or $65,880 for the industry as a whole

for applications under proposed Sec. 150.11(a)(2). The Commission

invites comments on any these proposed estimates.

(b) Recordkeeping and Reporting Obligations for DCMs and SEFs

(i) Submission of Estimates of Deliverable Supply

For purposes of assisting the Commission in resetting spot-month

limits, proposed Sec. 150.2(e)(3)(ii) would require DCMs to supply the

Commission with an estimated spot-month deliverable supply for each

core referenced futures contract listed. The estimate must include

documentation as to the methodology used in deriving the estimate,

including a description and any statistical data employed. The

Commission estimates that the submission would require a labor burden

of approximately 20 hours per estimate. Thus, a DCM that submits one

estimate may incur a burden of 20 hours for a cost of approximately

$2,440. DCMs that submit more than one estimate may multiply this per-

estimate burden by the number of estimates submitted to obtain an

approximate total burden for all submissions, subject to any

efficiencies and economies of scale that may result from submitting

multiple estimates.

The Commission notes that, in response to comments, the Commission

proposes to allow a DCM that does not wish a spot-month limit level to

be changed to petition the Commission to not change the limit level

and, if the petition is approved, the DCM would not need to submit

deliverable supply estimates for such a commodity. A DCM that submits

one petition may incur a burden of one hour, resulting in an estimated

per-petition cost of approximately $488. Again, DCMs that submit more

than one petition may multiply this per-petition burden by the number

of petitions submitted.

(ii) Filing New or Amended Rules Pursuant to Part 40

Designated contract markets and swap execution facilities that

elect to process the recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions, exempt spread positions, or enumerated anticipatory bona

fide hedging positions would be required to file new rules or rule

amendments pursuant to Part 40 of this chapter, establishing or

amending its application process for recognition of the above-

referenced positions, consistent with the requirements of proposed

Sec. Sec. 150.9, 150.10, and 150.11.

The Commission estimates that, at most, 6 entities would file new

rules or rule amendments pursuant to Part 40 to elect to process non-

enumerated bona fide hedging, spread, or enumerated anticipatory

hedging applications. The Commission determined this estimate by

analyzing how many exchanges currently list actively traded contracts

for the 28 commodities for which federal position limits would be set,

because proposed Sec. Sec. 150.9(a), 150.10(a), and 150.11(a) would

require a referenced contract to be listed by and actively traded on

any exchange that elects to process applications for recognition of

positions in such referenced contract. The Commission anticipates that

the exchanges that would elect to process applications under these

sections are likely to have processes for recognizing such exemptions

currently, and so would need to file amendments to existing exchange

rules rather than adopt new rules. Thus, the Commission approximates an

average per entity burden of 10 labor hours.\1458\ The Commission

estimates an average cost of approximately $1,220 per entity for filing

revised rules under part 40 of the Commission's regulations.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1458\ Table IV-B-1 at the end of this section provides a more

detailed breakdown of costs.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

(iii) Review and Disposition of Applications

An exchange that elects to process applications may incur a burden

related to the review and disposition of such applications pursuant to

proposed Sec. Sec. 150.9(a), 150.10(a), and 150.11(a). The review of

an application would be required to include analysis of the facts and

circumstances of such application to determine whether the application

meets the standards established by the Commission. Exchanges would be

required to notify the applicant regarding the disposition of the

application, including whether the application was approved, denied,

referred to the Commission, or requires additional information.

In the 2016 Supplemental Proposal, the Commission noted that the

exchanges that would elect to process non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position, exempt spread position, and

[[Page 96890]]

enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging position applications are

likely to have processes for the review and disposition of such

applications currently in place. The Commission noted its preliminary

belief that in such cases, complying with the rules would be less

burdensome because the exchange would already have staff, policies, and

procedures established to accomplish its duties under the rules.

One exchange submitted a comment requesting the Commission alter

its estimates of the burdens to exchanges for reviewing such

submissions, noting that the proposed rules ``provide[d] for the

collection of considerably more documents than are currently required

for Exchange exemption requests.'' The commenter continued that the

``review and consideration of these documents will result in additional

time spent on each exemption request'' and suggested the Commission

increase its estimate from five hours to seven hours per review.\1459\

The commenter also suggested the Commission increase the number of

applications that exchanges are estimated to process, stating that the

Commission's estimate of 285 exemption requests (for all three types of

applications) paled in comparison to the exchange's estimate of 500

applications.\1460\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1459\ See CL-ICE-60929 at 17.

\1460\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that it is unclear whether the exchange's

estimate of 500 applications includes applications in commodities

outside of the commodities subject to the proposed rules. If so, the

exchange may have overestimated the number of new applications the

exchange may process per year. Further, the estimates of one exchange

may not be representative of the number of applications received by the

other five exchanges. However, in an abundance of caution, the

Commission proposes to use the exchange's estimate for the number of

applications. Since the commenter did not suggest the proportion of

applications was improperly distributed amongst the sections regarding

non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions, exempt spread positions,

and enumerated anticipatory hedging positions, the Commission has

estimated the costs resulting from each type of application using

roughly the same proportion as originally proposed.

Thus, the Commission estimates that each exchange would process

approximately 325 non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

applications per year and that each application would require 7 hours

to process, for an average per entity burden of 2,275 labor hours

annually. The Commission estimates an average cost of approximately

$277,500 per entity under Sec. 150.9(a).

The Commission estimates that each exchange would process about 85

spread exemption applications per year and that each application would

require 7 hours to process, for an average per entity burden of 595

labor hours annually. The Commission estimates an average cost of

approximately $72,590 per entity under proposed Sec. 150.10(a). The

Commission invites comments on these estimates.

The Commission estimates that each entity would process about 90

anticipatory hedging applications per year and that each application

would require 7 hours to process, for an average per entity burden of

630 labor hours annually. The Commission estimates an average cost of

approximately $76,860 per entity under proposed Sec. 150.11(a).

(iv) Publication of Summaries

Exchanges that would elect to process the applications under

proposed Sec. Sec. 150.9 and 150.10 may incur burdens to publish on

their Web sites summaries of the unique types of non-enumerated bona

fide hedging position positions and spread positions, respectively.

This requirement would be new even for exchanges that already have a

similar process under exchange-set limits.

The Commission estimated in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits

Proposal that a single summary would require 5 hours to write, approve,

and post. An exchange also commented that these summaries would likely

require seven hours per summary to prepare.\1461\ Thus, the Commission

now estimates that each exchange would post approximately 40 summaries

per year, with an average per summary burden of 7 labor hours.\1462\

The Commission estimates an average cost of approximately $34,160 per

entity, representing the combined burdens of Sec. 150.9(a)(7) and

Sec. 150.10(a)(7). The Commission invites comments on these estimates.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1461\ See CL-ICE-60929 at 17.

\1462\ The Commission has combined the burdens for summaries

published in accordance with Sec. 150.9(a)(7) and Sec.

150.10(a)(7) in order to make the text clearer. Table IV-B-1 at the

end of this section provides a more detailed breakdown of costs by

regulation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

(v) Recordkeeping

Designated contract markets and swap execution facilities that

elect to process applications are required under proposed Sec. Sec.

150.9(b), 150.10(b), and 150.11(b) to keep full, complete, and

systematic records, which include all pertinent data and memoranda, of

all activities relating to the processing and disposition of

applications for recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions, exempt spread positions, and enumerated anticipatory bona

fide hedges. The Commission believes that exchanges currently process

applications for recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions, exempt spread positions, and enumerated anticipatory bona

fide hedges maintain records of such applications as required pursuant

to other Commission regulations, including Sec. 1.31. However, the

Commission also believes that the rules may confer additional

recordkeeping obligations on exchanges that elect to process

applications for recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions, exempt spread positions, and enumerated anticipatory bona

fide hedges.

The Commission estimates that 6 entities would have recordkeeping

obligations pursuant to proposed Sec. Sec. 150.9(b), 150.10(b), and

150.11(b). Thus, the Commission approximates an average per entity

burden of 90 labor hours annually for all three sections. The

Commission estimates an average cost of approximately $10,980 per

entity for records and filings under Sec. Sec. 150.9(b), 150.10(b),

and 150.11(b).\1463\ The Commission invites comments on its estimates.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1463\ The Commission has combined the burdens for recordkeeping

under Sec. Sec. 150.9(b), 150.10(b), and 150.11(b). Table IV-B-1 at

the end of this section provides a more detailed breakdown of costs

by regulation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

(vi) Reporting

The Commission anticipates that exchanges that elect to process

applications for recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions, spread exemptions, and enumerated anticipatory bona fide

hedges would be required to file two types of reports. In particular,

proposed Sec. Sec. 150.9(c) and 150.10(c) would require a designated

contract market or swap execution facility that elects to process

applications for non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions and exempt

spread positions to submit to the Commission (i) a summary of any non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position and exempt spread position newly

published on the designated contract market or swap execution

facility's Web site; and (ii) no less frequently than monthly, any

report submitted by an applicant to such designated contract market or

swap execution facility pursuant to rules authorized under

[[Page 96891]]

proposed Sec. Sec. 150.9(a)(6)and 150.10(a)(6), respectively. Further,

proposed Sec. Sec. 150.9(c), 150.10(c), and 150.11(c) would require

designated contract markets and swap execution facilities that elect to

process relevant applications to submit to the Commission a report for

each week as of the close of business on Friday showing various

information concerning the derivative positions that have been

recognized by the designated contract market or swap execution facility

as an non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, exempt spread

position, or enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedge position, and for

any revocation, modification or rejection of such recognition.

The Commission understands that 5 exchanges currently submit

reports, on a voluntary basis each month, which provide information

regarding exchange-recognized exemptions of all types. The Commission

stated in the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal its

preliminary belief that the content of such reports is similar to the

information required of the reports in Sec. Sec. 150.9(c), 150.10(c),

and 150.11(c), but the frequency of such reports would increase under

the proposed rules. The Commission estimated that the weekly report

would require approximately 3 hours to complete and submit and that the

monthly report would require 2 hours to complete and submit.

An exchange commented that the Commission ``significantly

understated'' the time required to prepare, review, and submit the

weekly and monthly reports based on the amount of time the exchange

currently spends to prepare and submit the reports it already submits.

The commenter suggested the Commission revise its estimates to reflect

the exchange's estimates of six hours to prepare the weekly report and

six hours to prepare the monthly report.\1464\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1464\ See CL-ICE-60929 at 17.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission estimates that 6 entities would have weekly

reporting obligations pursuant to reproposed Sec. Sec. 150.9(c)(1),

150.10(c)(1), and 150.11(c).\1465\ The Commission is revising its

estimate to reflect the commenter's assertion that the weekly report

will require a burden of approximately 6 hours to complete and submit.

Thus, the Commission estimates an average per entity burden of 936

labor hours annually. The Commission estimates an average cost of

approximately $114,192 per entity for weekly reports pursuant to all

three related sections. The Commission invites comments on its

estimates.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1465\ The Commission has combined the burdens for recordkeeping

under Sec. Sec. 150.9(c), 150.10(c), and 150.11(c). Table IV-B-1 at

the end of this section provides a more detailed breakdown of costs

by regulation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also estimates that 6 entities would have monthly

reporting obligations pursuant to reproposed Sec. Sec. 150.9(c)(2) and

150.10(c)(2).\1466\ The Commission also estimates that the monthly

report would require a burden of approximately 6 hours to complete and

submit. Thus, the Commission approximates an average per entity burden

of 144 labor hours annually. The Commission estimates an average cost

of approximately $17,568 per entity for monthly reports under both

sections.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1466\ The Commission has combined the burdens for recordkeeping

under Sec. Sec. 150.9(c)(2) and 150.10(c)(2). Table IV-B-1 at the

end of this section provides a more detailed breakdown of costs by

regulation.

Table IV-B-1--Breakdown of Burden Estimates by Regulation and Type of Respondent

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Estimated

Total number Annual number Total annual number of

Type of respondent Required record or report of respondents of responses responses burden hours Annual burden

per respondent per response

A B................................ C D E \1467\ F G \1468\

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Exchange............................. New or amended rule filings under 6 2 12 5 60

part 40 per Sec. 150.9(a)(1),

(a)(6).

Exchange............................. New or amended rule filings under 6 2 12 5 60

part 40 per Sec. 150.10(a)(1),

(a)(6).

Exchange............................. New or amended rule filings under 6 2 12 5 60

part 40 per Sec. 150.11(a)(1),

(a)(5).

Exchange............................. Collection, review, and 6 325 1,950 7 13,650

disposition of application per

Sec. 150.9(a).

Exchange............................. Collection, review, and 6 85 510 7 3,570

disposition of application per

Sec. 150.10(a).

Exchange............................. Collection, review, and 6 90 540 7 3,780

disposition of application per

Sec. 150.11(a).

Exchange............................. Summaries Posted Online per Sec. 6 30 180 7 1,260

150.9(a).

Exchange............................. Summaries Posted Online per Sec. 6 10 60 7 420

150.10(a).

Exchange............................. Sec. 150.9(b) Recordkeeping.... 6 1 6 30 180

Exchange............................. Sec. 150.10(b) Recordkeeping... 6 1 6 30 180

Exchange............................. Sec. 150.11(b) Recordkeeping... 6 1 6 30 180

Exchange............................. Sec. 150.9(c)(1) Weekly Report. 6 52 312 6 1,872

Exchange............................. Sec. 150.10(c)(1) Weekly Report 6 52 312 6 1,872

Exchange............................. Sec. 150.11(c) Weekly Report... 6 52 312 6 1,872

Exchange............................. Sec. 150.9(c)(2) Monthly Report 6 12 72 6 432

Exchange............................. Sec. 150.10(c)(2) Monthly 6 12 72 6 432

Report.

Exchange............................. Sec. 150.2(a)(3)(ii) DS 6 4 24 1 24

Estimate Submission Petition.

Exchange............................. Sec. 150.2(a)(3)(ii) DS 6 4 24 20 480

Estimate Submission.

Exchange............................. Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(ii) Exchange- 6 425 2,550 2 5,100

Set Limit Exemption Application.

Market Participant................... Sec. 150.5(a)(2)(ii) Exchange- 425 1 425 2 850

Set Limit Exemption Application.

Market Participant................... Sec. 150.9(a)(3) NEBFH 325 2 650 4 2,600

Application.

[[Page 96892]]

Market Participant................... Sec. 150.10(a)(3) Spread 85 2 170 3 510

Exemption Application.

Market Participant................... Sec. 150.11(a)(2) Application 90 2 180 3 540

On Form 704.

Market Participant................... Sec. 150.3(g) Recordkeeping.... 425 50 21,250 1 21,250

Market Participant................... Sec. 19.01(a)(1) Form 504...... 40 12 480 15 7,200

Market Participant................... Sec. 19.01(a)(2)(i) Form 604 250 10 2,500 30 75,000

Non Spot Month.

Market Participant................... Sec. 19.01(a)(2)(ii) Form 604 100 10 1,000 20 20,000

Spot Month.

Market Participant................... Sec. 19.02 Form 304............ 200 52 10,400 1 10,400

Market Participant................... Sec. 19.01(a)(3) Form 204...... 425 12 5,100 3 15,300

Market Participant................... Sec. 150.3(h) Special Call..... 425 1 425 2 850

Market Participant................... Sec. 150.7(a) Form 704 Initial 250 1 250 15 3,750

Statement.

Market Participant................... Sec. 150.7(a) Form 704 Annual 250 1 250 8 2,000

Update.

------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Totals........................... ................................. 431 116.13 50,052 3.91 195,734

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1467\ Column C times column D.

\1468\ Column E times column F.

4. Initial Set-Up and Ongoing Maintenance Costs

In documents submitted to OMB in accordance with the requirements

of the Paperwork Reduction Act, the Commission estimated that the total

annualized capital, operational, and maintenance costs associated with

complying with the proposed rules amending part 150 would be

approximately $11.6 million across approximately 400 firms. Of this

$11.6 million, the Commission estimated that $5 million would be from

annualized capital and start-up costs and $6.6 million would be from

operating and maintenance costs. These cost estimates were based on

Commission staff's estimated costs to develop the reports and

recordkeeping required in the proposed part 150.

The Commission explained that the proposed expansion of the number

of contract markets with Commission-set position limits, and the

Congressional determination that such limits be applied on an aggregate

basis across all trading venues and all economically-equivalent

contracts, might increase operational costs for traders to monitor

position size to remain in compliance with federal position limits. The

Commission further explained that as such limits have been in place in

the futures markets for over 70 years, the Commission believed that

traders in those markets would have already developed means of

compliance and thus would not require additional capital or start-up

costs. The Commission stated its expectation that, while affected

futures entities would be able to significantly leverage existing

systems and faculties to comply with the extended regime, entities

trading only or primarily in swaps contracts may not have developed

such means.

One commenter provided specific estimates of the start-up costs to

develop new systems to track and report positions, stating that per-

entity costs will range from $750,000 to $1,500,000. The commenter also

stated that ongoing annual costs would range from $100,000 to $550,000

per entity.\1469\ The Commission notes that the commenter did not

provide data underlying its cost estimates from which the Commission

could duplicate the commenter's estimates.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1469\ See CL-FIA-59595 at 35-36.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission maintains its belief that market participants will

be able to leverage existing systems and strategies for tracking and

reporting positions. As noted above, the Commission recognizes that

expanding the federal speculative position limits regime into

additional commodities beyond the legacy agricultural commodities will

increase monitoring costs for firms. However, the Commission continues

to expect that firms trading in the commodities subject to federal

limits under Sec. 150.2 do currently monitor for exchange-set and/or

federal limits, and submit reports to claim exemptions in contracts for

future delivery in such commodities. The Commission therefore continues

to believe that costs for futures market participants resulting from

the rules adopted herein are marginal increases upon existing costs,

rather than entirely new burdens. Further, the Commission notes that it

is difficult to ascertain an estimate of the average cost to market

participants, as, depending on its size and complexity, a market

participant could comply with position limits using anything from an

Excel spreadsheet to multiple transaction capture systems.

The Commission is increasing its estimates to respond to the

commenter. For swaps market participants unused to speculative position

limits on swaps contracts, the Commission continues to estimate a

greater cost to start and continue monitoring for and complying with

speculative position limits.

Specifically, the Commission estimates that 441 entities would

incur annualized start-up costs across all affected entities of

$47,800,000. The

[[Page 96893]]

Commission also estimates that 441 entities would incur ongoing

operating and maintenance costs of $12,075,000 across all affected

entities. The Commission invites comments on its estimates. Table IV-B-

2 breaks down the start-up and annual operating and maintenance costs

by affected entities.

Table IV-B-2--Breakdown of Start-Up and Annual Operating and Maintenance Costs

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Average

Total Average Total annual annual Total

Total number annualized annualized operating & (operating & annualized

of respondents capital/start- capital/start- maintenance maintenance cost requested

up costs up costs costs costs)

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sec. Sec. 19 and 150--Futures & Swaps Participants... 425 42,500,000 100,000 10,625,000 25,000 53,125,000

Sec. Sec. 19 and 150--Swaps Only Participants........ 10 5,000,000 500,000 1,000,000 100,000 6,000,000

Sec. 150--Exchanges................................... 6 300,000 50,000 450,000 75,000 750,000

-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Total............................................... .............. 47,800,000 .............. 12,075,000 .............. 59,875,000

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

5. Request for Comment

The Commission invites the public and other Federal agencies to

comment on any aspect of the reproposed information collection

requirements discussed above. The Commission will consider public

comments on this reproposed collection of information in:

(1) Evaluating whether the reproposed collection of information is

necessary for the proper performance of the functions of the

Commission, including whether the information will have a practical

use;

(2) evaluating the accuracy of the estimated burden of the

reproposed collection of information, including the degree to which the

methodology and the assumptions that the Commission employed were

valid;

(3) enhancing the quality, utility, and clarity of the information

proposed to be collected; and

(4) minimizing the burden of the reproposed information collection

requirements on registered entities, including through the use of

appropriate automated, electronic, mechanical, or other technological

information collection techniques, e.g., permitting electronic

submission of responses.

Copies of the submission from the Commission to OMB are available

from the CFTC Clearance Officer, 1155 21st Street NW., Washington, DC

20581, (202) 418-5160 or from http://RegInfo.gov. Organizations and

individuals desiring to submit comments on the reproposed information

collection requirements should send those comments to:

The Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs, Office

of Management and Budget, Room 10235, New Executive Office Building,

Washington, DC 20503, Attn: Desk Officer of the Commodity Futures

Trading Commission;

(202) 395-6566 (fax); or

[email protected] (email).

Please provide the Commission with a copy of submitted comments so

that all comments can be summarized and addressed in the final

rulemaking, and please refer to the ADDRESSES section of this

rulemaking for instructions on submitting comments to the Commission.

OMB is required to make a decision concerning the proposed information

collection requirements between 30 and 60 days after publication of

this Release in the Federal Register. Therefore, a comment to OMB is

best assured of receiving full consideration if OMB receives it within

30 calendar days of publication of this Release. Nothing in the

foregoing affects the deadline enumerated above for public comment to

the Commission on the Reproposal.

C. Regulatory Flexibility Act

The Regulatory Flexibility Act (``RFA'') requires that agencies

consider whether the rules they propose will have a significant

economic impact on a substantial number of small entities and, if so,

provide a regulatory flexibility analysis respecting the impact.\1470\

A regulatory flexibility analysis or certification typically is

required for ``any rule for which the agency publishes a general notice

of proposed rulemaking pursuant to'' the notice-and-comment provisions

of the Administrative Procedure Act, 5 U.S.C. 553(b).\1471\ The

requirements related to the proposed amendments fall mainly on

registered entities, exchanges, FCMs, swap dealers, clearing members,

foreign brokers, and large traders. The Commission has previously

determined that registered DCMs, FCMs, swap dealers, major swap

participants, eligible contract participants, SEFs, clearing members,

foreign brokers and large traders are not small entities for purposes

of the RFA.\1472\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1470\ 44 U.S.C. 601 et seq.

\1471\ 5 U.S.C. 601(2), 603-05.

\1472\ See Policy Statement and Establishment of Definitions of

``Small Entities'' for Purposes of the Regulatory Flexibility Act,

47 FR 18618-19, Apr. 30, 1982 (DCMs, FCMs, and large traders) (``RFA

Small Entities Definitions''); Opting Out of Segregation, 66 FR

20740-43, Apr. 25, 2001 (eligible contract participants); Position

Limits for Futures and Swaps; Final Rule and Interim Final Rule, 76

FR 71626, 71680, Nov. 18, 2011 (clearing members); Core Principles

and Other Requirements for Swap Execution Facilities, 78 FR 33476,

33548, Jun. 4, 2013 (SEFs); A New Regulatory Framework for Clearing

Organizations, 66 FR 45604, 45609, Aug. 29, 2001 (DCOs);

Registration of Swap Dealers and Major Swap Participants, 77 FR

2613, Jan. 19, 2012, (swap dealers and major swap participants); and

Special Calls, 72 FR 50209, Aug. 31, 2007 (foreign brokers).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One commenter, the NFP Electric Entities,\1473\ stated that the

Commission ``ignore[d] its responsibilities under the RFA'' because it

did not account for the impact on the members of the trade

associations. The commenter states that the rules impose costs on

``small entities'' that ``should not be swept up in the Commission's

new speculative position limits.'' \1474\ The Commission notes,

however, that under the Between NFP Electrics Exemptive Order certain

delineated non-financial energy transactions between certain

specifically defined entities were exempted, pursuant to CEA sections

4(c)(1) and 4(c)(6), from all requirements of the CEA and Commission

regulations issued thereunder, subject to certain anti-fraud, anti-

manipulation, and record inspection conditions.\1475\ All entities

[[Page 96894]]

that meet the requirements for the exemption provided by the Federal

Power Act 201(f) Order are, therefore, already exempt from position

limits compliance for all transactions that meet the Order's

conditions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1473\ The NFP Electric Entities is a group of trade

associations related to electricity entities comprised of the

National Rural Electric Cooperative Association, the American Public

Power Association, and the Large Public Power Council, with the

support of ACES and The Energy Authority.

\1474\ See CL-NFP-59690 at 26-27.

\1475\ See the Between NFP Electrics Exemptive Order (Order

Exempting, Pursuant to Authority of the Commodity Exchange Act,

Certain Transactions Between Entities Described in the Federal Power

Act, and Other Electric Cooperatives, 78 FR 19670 (Apr. 2, 2013)

(``Federal Power Act 201(f) Order''). See also CL-NFP-59690 at 14-

15. The Federal Power Act 201(f) Order exempted all ``Exempt Non-

Financial Energy Transactions'' (as defined in the Federal Power Act

201(f) Order) that are entered into solely between ``Exempt

Entities'' (also as defined in the Federal Power Act 201(f) Order,

namely ``any electric facility or utility that is wholly owned by a

government entity as described in the Federal Power Act (`FPA')

section 201(f) . . .; (ii) any electric facility or utility that is

wholly owned by an Indian tribe recognized by the U.S. government

pursuant to section 104 of the Act of November 2, 1994 . . .; (iii)

any electric facility or utility that is wholly owned by a

cooperative, regardless of such cooperative's status pursuant to FPA

section 201(f), so long as the cooperative is treated as such under

Internal Revenue Code section 501(c)(12) or 1381(a)(2)(C), . . . and

exists for the primary purpose of providing electric energy service

to its member/owner customers at cost; or (iv) any other entity that

is wholly owned, directly or indirectly, by any one or more of the

foregoing.''). See Federal Power Act 201(f) Order at 19688.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Further, while the requirements under this rulemaking may impact

non-financial end users, the Commission notes that position limits

levels apply only to large traders. Accordingly, the Chairman, on

behalf of the Commission, hereby certifies, on behalf of the

Commission, pursuant to 5 U.S.C. 605(b), that the actions proposed to

be taken herein would not have a significant economic impact on a

substantial number of small entities. The Chairman made the same

certification in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal \1476\ and

the 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal.\1477\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1476\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, 78 FR at

75784.

\1477\ See 2016 Supplemental Position Limits Proposal, 81 FR at

38499.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

V. Appendices

A. Appendix A--Review of Economic Studies \1478\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1478\ Earlier this year, a draft literature review written by

staff was released prematurely. Although there are similarities

between the analysis in that document and the analysis herein, that

document did not represent the final views of the Commission or the

Office of the Chief Economist.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Introduction

There are various statistical techniques for testing various

hypotheses about position limits and related matter. Many of these

techniques are deployed to determine whether speculative positions

influence price, price changes, or volatility. The Commission has

engaged in a comprehensive review and analysis of the various economic

studies and papers in the administrative record.

These economic studies bearing on the proposed rule arrived in the

administrative record in various ways. They include studies cited in

the Commission's notice of proposed rulemaking; studies substantially

relied upon in comment letters; and studies mentioned in a list

submitted by commenter Markus Henn (``Henn Letter'').\1479\ Those

studies that were submitted formally for the record receive focused

discussion in Section IV below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1479\ February 10, 2014, comment letter by Markus Henn of World

Economic, Ecology & Development, including an attachment, a November

26, 2013 list entitled ``Evidence on the Negative Impact of

Commodity Speculation by Academics, Analysis and Public

Institutions.'' See http://comments.cftc.gov/PublicComments/ViewComment.aspx?id=59628&SearchText=henn. As noted, of the various

economic studies and papers in the administrative record, some were

cited in the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal. Others were

substantially relied upon in comment letters or mentioned in a list

submitted by commenter Markus Henn (CL-WEED-59628); these studies

are available in the comment letter file through the Commission's

Web site at http://comments.cftc.gov/PublicComments/CommentList.aspx?id=1708.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As a group, these studies do not show a consensus in favor of or

against position limits. Many studies limited themselves to subsidiary

questions and did not direct address the desirability or utility of

position limits themselves. The quality of the studies varies. Some

studies are written by esteemed economists and published in academic,

peer-reviewed journals. For other studies, that is not the case. Those

studies that did at least touch on position limits had disparate

conclusions on the ability economists to use market fundamentals to

explain commodity prices; the existence of ``excessive speculation'' in

various futures markets; and the utility of position limits. Section

4a(a)(1) of the CEA provides for position limits as a means to address

certain specified burdens on interstate commerce. Studies that dispute

the utility of position limits for the purposes Congress identified are

less helpful than studies addressing other questions.

Preliminary Matters

1. Defining ``Speculation'' and Use of Proxies To Measure Speculation

It can be difficult to distinguish between ordinary speculation

that is permitted and desirable, because it facilitates the transfer of

risk and provides liquidity for hedgers, and harmful or ``excessive''

speculation. Ideally, speculation may better align prices with market

fundamentals.\1480\ Speculators in the commodity futures market can

generally enhance liquidity and reduce a hedger's cost associated with

searching for a counterparty who wants to take an opposition position.

Speculators facilitate the needs of hedgers to transfer price risk and

increase overall trading volume, all of which can generally contribute

to the well-being of a marketplace.\1481\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1480\ Speculation is a natural market phenomenon in a market

with differing investor expectations. Harrison and Kreps,

Speculative Investor Behavior in a Stock Market with Heterogeneous

Expectations, Quarterly Journal of Economics (Oxford University

Press 1978).

\1481\ Bahattin B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Jeffrey H.

Harris, The Role of Speculators in the Crude Oil Futures Market

(working paper 2009).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Congress has found ``excessive speculation'' in futures contracts

to be ``an undue and unnecessary burden on interstate commerce.''

\1482\ In accordance with that finding, Congress has provided for

position limits in order to ``diminish, eliminate, or prevent such

burden.'' This paper evaluates economic studies concerning how position

limits can diminish unreasonable price fluctuations and changes.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1482\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(1).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a.''Excess Speculation'' and Volatility

Although volatility may be an indicator of excess speculation, as

Congress has determined, price volatility, in itself, does not

establish ``excess speculation.'' \1483\ Changes in fundamentals of

supply and demand can create substantial volatility, and some

commodities are, based on their nature, more prone to price volatility.

Changes in these fundamentals may induce disagreement between market

participants on the appropriate price, causing some measure of price

volatility, but this does not necessarily imply the existence of excess

speculation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1483\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One of the main functions of the swaps and futures markets is to

permit parties with structural exposure to price risk (hedgers such as

buyers or sellers of commodity-related products) to manage price

changes or price volatility by transferring price risk to others.

Speculators in these markets often, in effect, shield hedgers from some

forms of price volatility by accepting this price risk. The nation's

futures and swaps markets helps producers and suppliers of these

commodities, and the customers they serve, hedge price risk to avoid

price uncertainty when desired. In this way, volatility and speculation

are not per se unwelcome phenomena in these markets. They are natural

events in these markets. It is the nature of markets to

fluctuate.\1484\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1484\ What may be ``natural'' volatility in one commodity

futures market may be unexpected in another. Some critics of the

proposed rule emphasize that different commodity markets behave

differently, and that not all of the commodity markets referenced in

the rule are likely to behave as the crude oil markets did in the

2006-2009 time period. On the other hand, some economic studies

suggest there can be ``spillovers'' or transmission of volatility

from one commodity market to the next. See, e.g., Du, Yu, and Hayes,

Speculation and Volatility Spillover in the Crude Oil and

Agricultural Commodity Markets: A Bayesian Analysis, Energy

Economics (2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96895]]

Just as volatility is not a per se harmful or unexpected event in

the commodity futures markets, speculation in those markets is welcome

and will often actually reduce volatility. A well-reasoned 2009

economic study (by economists who were then CFTC employees) concluded

that speculative trading in the futures market is not, in and of

itself, destabilizing.\1485\ This frequently cited study concludes that

normal speculative trading activity actually reduces volatility levels,

as a general rule, while acknowledging that there are limited empirical

studies on the subject. ``The limited nature of the previous literature

on the market impact of speculators can be attributed to the difficulty

of obtaining data on their trading activities.'' \1486\ There is,

however, substantial theoretical literature that predicts that

profitable speculation has a stabilizing effect, ``since speculators

buy when the price is low, therefore, increasing depressed prices, and

sell when the price is high, therefore, decreasing inflated prices.''

\1487\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1485\ Brunetti and B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Is Speculation

Destabilizing? (working paper 2009). The Commission cited this study

in particular in its December 2013 Position Limits Proposal. In

addition, a copy of this economic study was formally submitted by

the CME Group, Inc., as part of the administrative record in a March

28, 2011 comment.

\1486\ Id. at 3.

\1487\ Id. at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some economic studies attempt to distinguish between normal and

helpful speculative activity and excessive speculation: between normal

volatility and, in the words of the Commodity Exchange Act,

``unreasonable fluctuations'' in price.\1488\ Part of the research task

before any economist studying markets for excessive speculation is to

model and interpret excessive speculation and unwanted volatility so as

to distinguish between unwanted phenomena and the proper workings of a

well-functioning market.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1488\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(1).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Working's Speculative T Index

While there is no well-established economic definition of ``excess

speculation,'' many economists studying commodity futures marketplace

have used a proxy for speculation in commodity futures marketplace

known in the economic literature as the Working's speculative T index.

Economist Holbrook Working devised in 1960 a ratio to measure the

adequacy or excessiveness of speculation. As applied to commodity

futures positions, the speculative T index is used to assess the amount

of speculative positions in the marketplace beyond the amount of

speculative positions necessary to provide liquidity for hedgers in the

marketplace.\1489\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1489\ See Bahattin B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Jeffrey H.

Harris, The Role of Speculators in the Crude Oil Futures Market, at

9 n.7, 10-11 & 24 (working paper 2009) (employing this technique).

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.000

It is calculated by computing the ratio of long and short positions for

all trades in the commodity market, including those of hedgers and

those of speculators.\1490\ A high ratio indicates many speculators are

holding commodity futures positions. When this speculative T-index is

included as an economic variable in economist's models to explain

prices, economists may interpret the T index to be a proxy for the

relative amount of speculation in the marketplace.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1490\ The Working speculative index is ``predicated on the fact

that long and short hedgers do not always trade simultaneously or in

the same quantity, so that speculators fill the role of satisfying

unmet hedging demand in the marketplace. Id. at 1.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A high Working T index is one way to quantify excess speculation in

technical terms, but even then that may not translate into excessive

speculation in ``economic terms.''\1491\ Additional economic analysis

or historical comparisons are useful to understand the meaning and

impact of a relatively high number of speculators in a market

place.\1492\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1491\ Id. at 10.

\1492\ See id. at 9-10 (a speculative index of 1.41 for crude

oil futures contracts in 2008 meant that share of speculation beyond

what was minimally necessary to meeting short and long hedging

needs, was 41 percent: while such a percentage may seem on its face

``potentially alarming,'' it is comparable historically with

agricultural commodity markets).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

c. Absence of Consensus on ``Price Bubbles''

There are several published studies on the effect of speculation on

prices and price volatility, as well as studies on speculation

generally. These studies employ various statistical methodologies. Some

of these find the existence of ``price bubbles,'' meaning somehow

artificially high prices that last longer than they should. These

studies are analyzed below, but there is no academic consensus on what

a ``price bubble'' is and how it can be detected. Thus many of the

interpretations set forth in the ``price bubble'' studies are not the

only plausible explanation for their statistical findings.

As further detailed below, there is no broad academic consensus on

the economic definition of ``excess speculation'' or ``price bubble''

in commodity futures markets. There is also no broad academic consensus

on the best statistical model to test for the existence of excess

speculation. There is open skepticism in many economic quarters that

there can even exist a significant ``price bubble'' in commodity

futures markets.\1493\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1493\ Dwight R. Sanders & Scott H. Irwin, A speculative bubble

in commodity futures prices? Cross-sectional evidence, 41

Agricultural Economics 25-32 (2010) (arguing that while ``bubble''

explanations ``are deceptively appealing, they do not generally

withstand close examination''). Because commodity index fund buying

is very predictable, it seems highly unlikely that in ordinary

market environment traders would fail to trade against an index fund

if the fund were driving prices away from fundamental values.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A large measure of the difficulty stems from the difficulties of

second-guessing the market's determination of the price of a commodity

contract:

Experts may express opinions about what the fundamental price

should be, given current supply and demand conditions, but

[[Page 96896]]

a basic axiom of classical economics is that free markets do a

better job of weighing information and determining prices that any

group of experts.\1494\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1494\ D. Andrew Austin & Mark Jickling, Hedge Fund Speculation

and Oil Prices (1 ed. 2011).

Nonetheless, there are statistical techniques, and theoretical models,

that economists have employed to attempt to discern whether recent

behavior in the nation's commodity futures markets has deviated from

what can be reasonably ascribed to the fundamentals of supply and

demand.

d. The Project: Studying Whether Speculative Positions Causing

Unwarranted Price Moves

In order to test for the presence of ``excessive'' speculation,

many of these economic studies look to whether the existence of

substantial positions by speculative traders causes price volatility or

a semi-permanent change in price. The idea underlying these studies is

that if the presence of sufficiently large positions can induce such

price behavior, it is ``excessive.'' Economists use various statistical

tools, including correlation analysis, to determine whether there is

price behavior caused by speculative positions that is ``unwarranted.''

``Unwarranted'' price movements are those not associated with

fundamentals of supply and demand, the inherent volatility of market

prices, or other factors independent of position.

In these studies, economists discuss whether positions have caused

movements in price. Technically, economists will study ``price

returns'' for a class of commodity, rather than just ``price'' (the

nominal price level). Price return gives one the change in price over

time, divided by price.\1495\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1495\ P is price and t is a particular time, with t+1 being the

point in time that is one fixed increment away over which the return

is being computed.

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.040

Price return measures price changes over the scale of the underlying

price. That is, different commodities may have entirely different

scales for prices; by dividing by the underlying price, price returns

put different commodity classes on the same percentage scale for

comparison purposes.

The conclusions of these various economic analyses, discussed in

detail in Section III below, have achieved a reasonable measure of

academic consensus on some subsidiary matters bearing on the ultimate

question of whether excessive speculation has had an impact on the

commodity futures markets. However, there is no academic consensus on

the ultimate question of the extent and breadth of the impact, and

there is no singular economic study of compelling persuasiveness.

2. Dearth of Compelling Empirical Studies on the Effect of Position

Limits on Prices or Price Volatility

There are not many compelling, peer-reviewed economic studies

engaging in quantitative, empirical analysis of the impact of position

limits on prices or price volatility, and thus on whether position

limits are useful in curbing excessive speculation.\1496\ The

limitations that inhere in empirical analysis of this complex question

are set forth below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1496\ As noted above, however, CEA section 4a(a) reflects the

underlying assumption that position limits may be useful for that

purpose.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. Trader Identity and Role: Incomplete Data

As many economic researchers observe in their studies, there is no

decisive accounting on whether a particular trade or set of trades is

speculative or hedging. In practice, researchers often use a rough

proxy based on the nature of the trader: Whether they are commercial or

non-commercial. However, in both practice and theory, this proxy may

fail: Commercial traders may speculate and non-commercial traders may

well hedge. For example, a commercial trader might speculate and take

an outsize position, in the sense that it exceeds a given hedging

business need, in a commodity on the belief that the price will go up

and down. Thus ``traders sometimes may be misclassified between

commercial and noncommercial positions, and some traders classified as

commercial may have speculative motives.'' \1497\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1497\ International Monetary Fund, IMF Global Financial

Stability Report: Financial Stress and Deleveraging: Macrofinancial

Implications and Policy (Oct. 2008).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Further compounding these classification problems, the publicly

available data also aggregates traders' positions across maturity dates

for futures contracts, while the price for any given commodity futures

contract is not aggregated by maturity.\1498\ In addition, section 8 of

the Commodity Exchange Act limits the distribution of detailed trade

positon data to academic researchers. The identity of individual

traders for specific trades, and their position in the market at the

time of name, is not disseminated publicly to economic

researchers.\1499\ Thus, even when a position limit breach occurs, it

is difficult to measure the impact on individual participants in the

marketplace.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1498\ Id.

\1499\ Julien Chevallier, Price relationships in crude oil

futures: new evidence from CFTC disaggregated data, 15 Environmental

Economics and Policy Studies 135 (2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Even when an economic researcher can find detailed information on

specific trades and the nature of the traders, that might not be

sufficient to characterize an individual trade as hedging or

speculative. A market participant may have business needs it hedges

with derivatives and also engage in speculative trading. Thus the

identity of the market participant purchasing the commodity futures

contracts alone does not accurately capture the motivation for or

purpose of the trade. Thus, an economic researcher faces significant

data constraints in reliably characterizing trades as speculative or

hedging, making it difficult to determine whether position limits are

useful in curbing certain speculative activity.

b. Limitations on Studying Markets With Pre-Existing Position Limits

Designing an economic study of the effect of position limits is

complicated by the fact that for many commodity markets, position

limits are already in place. There is therefore not reliable empirical

data for how certain modern commodity futures markets would operate in

the absence of position limits. For all the agricultural commodities

referenced in the rule, the futures markets have already had in place

spot-month position limits at least as strict as those proposed in the

rule. For energy commodities such as crude oil, there have been pre-

existing ``accountability levels,'' meaning an exchange has the option

(but not the requirement) to ask a trader to reduce its position if it

exceeds a certain level. For crude oil, the current all-months-combined

accountability level is 20,000 contracts. The position limit in the

proposed rule for the all-months-combined limit is 109,200 contracts.

The existence of binding position limits in agricultural

commodities and accountability levels in the energy markets does not

mean that traders do not transgress these limits in current markets and

take outsized market positions for speculative reasons. But the

existence of current limits does make the economist's task of measuring

position limit impact more difficult. When an economist studies an

agricultural futures market and attempts to assess the economic

advantages and disadvantages of imposing position limits, he or she

does not have a dataset of market prices in a marketplace

[[Page 96897]]

without position limits. Thus economists are dependent upon economic

models and model interpretation when they attempt to describe how a

marketplace without position limits would function. Many economic

studies do not account in their models for pre-existing position limits

or accountability levels. In fact, many economic studies that bear on

the rulemaking do not endeavor to reach the ultimate question of the

impact of position limits on prices and market dynamics at all.

There may be fewer instances of dramatic, large-scale ``excessive

speculation'' because position limits have been in place in many of

these commodity futures markets since 1938. There have thus been few

opportunities to study the effect of the imposition of a position

limits rule.\1500\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1500\ CFTC, A Study of the Silver Market, Report To The

Congress In Response To Section 21 Of The Commodity Exchange Act,

Part Two, 123 (May 19, 1981) (observing that the imposition of a

position limit in silver futures contracts by the Chicago Board of

Trade in 1979 did not raise prices); id. at 123-24 (observing that

price reaction to position limits involves a variety of factors and

``it is not possible to predict in advance the effect of imposition

of position limits'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

c. Inherent Difficulties of Modelling Complex Economic Phenomena

There is no singularly persuasive study, because these studies use

economic models that are, by nature, simplifications of a complex

reality. Each of the various models and statistical methods used in

these diverse studies has advantages and disadvantages, but they deploy

imperfect market data to answer ambitious and complex economic

questions. Given the data and modeling limitations, it is unreasonable

to expect an economic model that is fulsome (extending to position

limits and market speculation), accurate (accommodating and reflecting

economic history), and predictive. This is particularly true in the

context of market data involving volatile and complex events.

Some studies are better-designed and better-executed than others,

which means that they used defensible models with transparent source

data. These are discussed throughout this review. Much of the analysis

below highlights the flexibility of model design choices and the

sensitivity of the results to these modelling choices.

3. Staff-Level Congressional Determinations

There have been findings by policymakers that excessive speculation

exists in various commodity futures markets, as the Commission observed

in its notice of proposed rulemaking. For example, the Staff of the

Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations of the Homeland Security and

Government Affairs found \1501\ that excessive speculation has had

``undue'' influence on wheat price movements,\1502\ the natural gas

market,\1503\ and oil prices.\1504\ Congress itself found ``excessive

speculation'' in futures contracts to be ``an undue and unnecessary

burden on interstate commerce.'' \1505\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1501\ See Analysis, Section III(B), infra (discussing an

economic analysis of these reports).

\1502\ Permanent Subcomm. on Investigations of the U.S. Senate,

Comm. on Homeland Sec. & Governmental Affairs, Excessive Speculation

in the Wheat Market, (2009), available at http://hsgac.senate.gov/public/_files/REPORTExcessiveSpecullationintheWheatMarketwoexhibitschartsJune2409.pdf.

\1503\ Permanent Subcomm. on Investigations of the U.S. Senate,

Comm. on Homeland Sec. & Governmental Affairs, Excessive Speculation

in the Natural Gas Market, (2007), available at http://www.hsgac.senate.gov//imo/media/doc/REPORTExcessiveSpeculationintheNaturalGasMarket.pdf?attempt=2.

\1504\ Permanent Subcomm. on Investigations of the U.S. Senate,

Comm. on Homeland Sec. & Governmental Affairs, The Role of Market

Speculation in Rising Oil and Gas Prices: A Need to Put the Cop Back

on the Beat, at 19-32 (2006) available at http://www.hsgac.senate.gov//imo/media/doc/REPORTExcessiveSpeculationintheNaturalGasMarket.pdf?attempt=2

(finding increased speculation in energy commodities and an effect

of speculation on prices).

\1505\ 7 U.S.C. 6a(a)(1).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

These studies, like all the studies analyzed here, were undertaken

in an absence of definitive economic definitions and tests for

excessive speculation; limitations on data quality and availability;

and the inherent difficulty of modelling complex phenomena.

Discussion

1. Empirical Studies: Economic Studies with Statistical Analysis

Bearing on Speculative Positions in the Commodity Markets or

Speculation Generally

Economic studies presented in the context of this rulemaking may

involve theoretical models; statistical analysis based upon market

data; and, most commonly, a combination of both. The economic studies

using statistical methods can be categorized into basic statistical

methods, such as models of fundamental supply and demand (and related

methods), Granger causality, or other methods. The economic studies

presented or cited in the comment letters in this rulemaking are best

grouped and analyzed by the statistical method they employ, for there

are advantages and disadvantages particular to each statistical method.

This discussion evaluates 244 papers in connection with the

position limits rule: 133 studies submitted as comments or mentioned in

the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal; over 100 additional studies

or articles listed in the Henn Letter; and ten additional studies

submitted by commenters not included in the above sets.

This group of 244 papers can be categorized below by statistical

methodology: 36 Granger causality analyses; 25 comovement or

cointegration analyses; 46 studies creating models of fundamental

supply and demand; 8 switching regressions or similar analyses; 3

studies using eigenvalue stability analysis; 26 papers presenting

theoretical models; and 73 papers that were primarily surveys of the

economic literature, perhaps with some aspect of empirical testing or

analysis.\1506\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1506\ The remaining 27 papers fall into two groups. Two

additional papers presented unique methodologies involving

volatility are interwoven into the analysis below. The remaining

twenty-five papers were not ultimately susceptible to meaningful

economic analysis. These papers included pure opinion pieces,

studies written in foreign languages, press releases, background

documents on basic points of economics or law, studies unavailable

due to broken hyperlinks that could not be resolved, or studies

founded on methodologies too suspect to warrant extensive

discussion. In the latter category, for example, was an unpublished

study purported to use a ``novel source of information''--Google

metrics involving user searches--as a proxy for the demand

associated with ``corn price dynamics.'' Massimo Peri, Daniela

Vandone & Lucia Baldi, Internet, noise trading and commodity futures

prices, 33 International Review of Economics & Finance 82-89 (2014)

(cited by Henn Letter). See also, Letter from Markus Henn, World

Economic, Ecology & Development, to CFTC (Feb. 10, 2014). See also,

Markus Henn, Evidence on the Negative Impact of Commodity

Speculation by Academics, Analysis and Public Institutions, (Nov.

26, 2013).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. Granger ``Causality''

i. Overview of the Granger Method

Below is a discussion of the 36 analyses employing the ``Granger''

or ``Granger causality'' method of statistical analysis. This

discussion includes a description of the method and its advantages and

disadvantages.

The Granger method seeks to find whether a linear correlation

exists between two sets of data that are known as ``time series.'' An

example of a time series would be a pair of numbers constituting future

prices and time, with the time between the different future prices

being a fixed amount of time. This fixed time is known as the ``time

step.'' The Granger method takes two time series, such as Series A

(futures price returns, each for a different time, for a fixed time

step) and Series B

[[Page 96898]]

(changes in speculative positions over the same time step). It then

seeks to determine whether there is a linear correlation between Series

A and Series B. This is done by using position data that is lagged over

time.

For example, for the time of 12:00 p.m. and the price of $20 for a

May cotton futures contract, the researcher using Granger ``causality''

would associate a position in May cotton futures from a set time prior

to 12:00 p.m. If the time step were one minute, that time would be

11:59 a.m. The researcher performs a regression analysis on these two

time series (price and time on the one side of the equation, and

position and lagged time on the other). They estimate the correlation

(technically, they look at the coefficient of the regression) through

this analysis to come to a conclusion of whether, over that minute-

interval, it can be said that there is a linear correlation between

futures prices and positions.

While the Granger test is referred to as the ``Granger causality

test,'' it is important to note that, notwithstanding this shorthand,

``Granger causality'' does not establish an actual cause-and-effect

relationship. What the Granger method gives as a result is evidence of

the existence of a linear correlation between the two time series or a

lack thereof.

Moreover, the Granger method only tests for linear correlations. It

cannot exclude causation associated with other statistical

relationships.

The persuasiveness of a Granger study often turns on the soundness

of the modelling choices, as discussed further in subsection 3

below.\1507\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1507\ See generally Grosche, Limitations of Granger Causality

Analysis To Assess the Price Effects From the Financialization of

Agricultural Commodity Markets Under Bounded Rationality, at 2-5

(Agricultural and Resource Economics 2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Advantages of the Granger Method

At the highest level, the Granger method is based on well-

credentialed statistical methodology. It has been used for several

decades by economists and its properties are well-established and well-

debated in the economic literature. In that sense, unlike some of the

other methods employed in this context, it has stood the test of time.

It has been deployed in macroeconomics and financial economics.

The Granger test has several advantages. It is auditable in the

sense that it can be fully replicated by a third party. The method is

relatively simple to apply. It need not depend on complex mathematics.

The method's straightforward approach permits a great deal of

transparency in analyzing both inputs and results. Although the results

can be highly sensitive to modelling choices, the modelling choices are

made explicitly. That is, the equations that are used for the linear

regression can easily be viewed together with the definitions for the

variables.

iii. Disadvantages of the Granger Method

Not all statistical methods apply well to all situations. In the

particular context of speculation and positions limits, application of

the Granger methodology has some disadvantages and causes for concern.

While the statistical answers are, by their nature, fairly precise, the

drafting of the question and the economic interpretation of the results

can cause problems. This limitation of the Granger method of course is

shared with some other statistical methods. However, we discuss below

why this is particularly true of Granger in the context of these

studies on speculation and prices. Many of the potential problems in

these studies do not so inhere so much in the method itself as in the

modelling choices, other operational choices such as the length of time

step and time lag, and the interpretation of the results.\1508\ Below,

we analyze why this is so.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1508\ See, e.g., Grosche, Limitations of Granger Causality

Analysis To Assess the Price Effects From the Financialization of

Agricultural Commodity Markets Under Bounded Rationality

(Agricultural and Resource Economics 2012); Williams, Dodging Dodd-

Frank: Excessive Speculation, Commodities Markets, and the Burden of

Proof, Law & Policy Journal of the University of Denver (2015).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

First, the typical application of the Granger method in the studies

review assumes a linear relation between the variables of interest: For

example, prices and positions. The technique is useful for describing

statistical patterns in data among variables ordered in time. But

Granger does not claim to discuss simultaneous events. It is a

statistical test which, in rough terms, says that if event A typically

precedes event B, then event A ``Granger-causes'' event B. Granger is a

statistical method for analyzing data for correlations, and ``Granger

causation'' is not ``causation'' per se. It does not illustrate the

method and means of actual causation nor does it claim to establish

actual causation in reality.

For example, the Granger method cannot explain what causal

mechanism links two events, events A and B, and a Granger model cannot

detect all real-world causation. For example, an individual Granger

model cannot conclude whether there is a relation between event A and

event B that is ``hidden'' because the time step chosen is so long that

the events look to occur simultaneously over the observed interval (be

it a day or a week).

A second disadvantage concerns the sensitivity of the test to the

time period studied. Especially in the context of the Granger method,

the selection of the particular time internal is important to obtain

the most useful results: Selection of too large a time period may hide

correlations. Some of the position studies use daily price data, while

others use weekly price data. When commodity prices are quite volatile,

and positions are more gradual in changes, daily time steps may have

greater unexplained variation in the commodity prices than when the

time series for price data is constructed based on weekly sampling. A

study by International Monetary Fund economists, using weekly data,

observed that this time interval ``may hamper the identification of

very short-run effects, given that the transmission from positions to

prices may happen at higher frequency. Indeed, some market participants

anecdotally suggest that there are short-run effects that may last only

a matter of days.'' \1509\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1509\ Antoshin, Canetti, and Miyajima, IMF Global Financial

Stability Report: Financial Stress and Deleveraging: Macrofinancial

Implications and Policy, Annex 1.2, Financial Investment in

Commodities Markets at p. 65 (October 2008) (footnote and citation

omitted).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another potential problem is picking a time lag that is too short

to detect possible market phenomenon. ``[K]nowing whether price changes

lead or lag position changes over short horizons (a few days) is of

limited value for assessing the price pressure effects of flows into

commodity derivatives markets.'' \1510\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1510\ Singleton, The 2008 Boom/Bust in Oil Prices, at 15

(working paper March 23, 2011) (``Of more relevance is whether flows

affect returns and risk premiums over weeks and months.'') (footnote

omitted).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the statistical calculations underlying the Granger method, this

greater volatility may lead to a larger denominator in what is called

the ``t-statistic,'' and that will in turn lead to a lower t-statistic

(in absolute value). The t-statistic is used in the Granger method to

assess how well a variable, such as positions, explains another

variable, such as commodity prices. In this way, the selection of the

time interval can easily affect the strength of the Granger method

result.

A third disadvantage of Granger inheres in the selection of the

time lag. A Granger analysis will not capture an effect that is delayed

beyond the length of the time lag. And a Granger analysis with too long

a time lag may not detect

[[Page 96899]]

price changes during periods of price volatility. The Granger technique

does not guide the selection of the time lag. There are some heuristic

techniques to help determine the time lag based on the ``goodness-of-

fit'' \1511\ of regressions, but these supplemental techniques may

yield time lags that do not have a strong theoretical footing.\1512\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1511\ Roughly speaking, ``goodness-of-fit'' analyses examine

how well the data fits the model. Using a goodness of fit criteria

allows the data to select the number of lags that empirically fits

the data the best.

\1512\ See generally Williams, Dodging Dodd-Frank: Excessive

Speculation, Commodities Markets, and the Burden of Proof, Law &

Policy Journal of the University of Denver (2015) at 136-38

(discussing problems associated with Granger test's assumptions and

parameters).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In such ways, and others, the authors of such study have wide

license in modelling design. The results can be highly dependent upon

and sensitive to model design choices. Key design decisions of

seemingly little import, such as the selection of time steps, can in

fact make a substantial difference in the study's result. While such

flexibility can be useful, this flexibility also permits Granger

results to be sensitive to modelling assumptions. Such sensitivity,

especially in the particular context of the volatile commodity prices,

is problematic. Volatility in commodity prices is a complex phenomenon,

with possibly overlapping effects of short- and long-term volatility

and many exogenous variables that can affect prices. In short, ``care

must be taken not to overstate the interpretive power'' of Granger

causality studies.\1513\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1513\ Id. at 138.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Finally, the method cannot discern the true cause of something when

event A and B occur almost simultaneously. Granger cannot say whether A

caused B or whether C causes A and then C causes B with a brief time

lag. In this way, Granger correlation analysis is fundamentally

incapable of establishing a cause and effect relationship.

There can also be limitations with regard to the data used in

Granger studies on position limits, the majority of which used

Commission data. There is a problem which inheres in this data in the

particular context of position limit studies. The trade data used

identifies the entity doing the trade as ``commercial'' or ``non-

commercial.'' The data does not identify whether a particular trade is

a hedge or a speculative gamble.\1514\ While the studies' authors may

infer that a trader's identity as a commercial trader is strongly

associated with hedging (or at least non-speculative trades), in

practice that may be far from the case.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1514\ There are other difficulties in the CFTC dataset that

complicate empirical analysis of herding activity. See Acharya,

Ramadorai, and Lochstoer, Limits to Arbitrage and Hedging: Evidence

from the Commodity Markets, at 19 (Journal of Financial Economics

2013).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

There is also the statistical concept of ``robustness,'' meaning

roughly that the results of a study are not qualitatively different

based on different applications (different data sets, different tweaks

of assumptions). In several ways, application of the Granger method in

this particular context offers grounds for caution for study authors

seeking statistical robustness. First, for a given time step and

commodity, the particular time interval chosen may affect the result.

Second, a Granger method is, by its nature, very sensitive to which

particular dataset is chosen. Once again, a study's author(s) have wide

discretion in the selection of which datasets to study, and Granger

methodology will be highly sensitive to this selection.

There is the related problem of economic robustness. For example,

because of individual market characteristics, a study limited to a

particular commodity or time period may fail to detect patters that

would be detectable applying the same method in to other time periods

of commodities. Applying Granger analysis to commodity prices presents

special challenges in this context because many commodity prices can be

quite volatile, especially in the short-term. That is, the Granger

method may have low ``statistical power'' in this context. In

mathematical terms, high volatility in one of the Granger variables can

lead to large standard errors for regression coefficients for the t-

statistic.\1515\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1515\ See Bahattin B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Jeffrey H.

Harris, The Role of Speculators in the Crude Oil Futures Market

(working paper 2009) (later published in The Energy Journal, Vol.

32, No. 2, 167-202 (2011) under the title Do Speculators Drive Crude

Oil Futures Prices?).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A modelling choice to include other variables can further reduce

the statistical power of the statistical test used in the Granger

method.\1516\ Other economic variables in the regression analysis, if

not properly chosen, can compromise the Granger ``causality'' test. For

instance, explanatory variables may not be uncorrelated to the

speculative position or position change variables. To the extent that

the variables are correlated to speculative positions, they may, in the

estimation of the regression, wash out the price effect. The t-

statistic of the regression coefficient remains small because the

standard error estimate of the coefficient is large due to common

correlation between explanatory variables.\1517\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1516\ These test statistics is a t-test for one lag in the

relevant variable or an F-test for multiple lags.

\1517\ This argument is also correct for F-tests (a

multivariable extension of t-tests).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Authors of Granger method studies may add ``control variables'' in

order to reflect other factors that may be affecting or relevant to the

two main variables of primary interest (such as price and position).

The introduction of control variables will help to discount spurious

corrections between the variables of primary interest by studying

whether another variable could be correlated to (and thus ``Granger

causing'') variables such as price and position. Adding extra variables

can, on the one hand, affect for third factors which may be relevant.

On the other hand, the introduction of the third factors may compromise

the statistical power of the primary question of interest.

Finally, there are also economic studies casting doubt on the

suitability of commodities data for meaningful Granger tests, given

volatility in commodities price data.\1518\ This is because volatility

increases the standard error of the estimated coefficient for the

lagged variable(s). Thus, Granger tests examining commodities data may

lack statistical power to detect Granger causality.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1518\ David Frenk, Review of Irwin and Sanders 2010 OECD

Report, at p. 6 (Better Markets June 20, 2010) and citations

therein, cited in Henn Letter at 6-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iv. Comparison of Strengths and Weaknesses

Granger techniques provide great flexibility. This flexibility also

provides great license to economists on selection of critical factors

such as the length of the time lag and the time step. The ultimate

conclusions of such studies may be influenced by model design.

Unsurprisingly, different economists reach different results. In this

sense, the conclusions of Granger-based papers are vulnerable to

criticism.

v. Analysis of Studies Reviewed That Use Granger Methodology

Overall, when the Granger studies find a correlation (in the sense

of a lead-lag relationship) between speculative positions and price

returns, they do so not with respect to price returns as a whole, but

the risk premium component of price returns. The risk premium is the

portion of expected return of a futures contract associated with

holding the contract. It is not an express term of the contract, but an

amount that can be derived from economic analysis as the difference

between the futures price return and a hypothesized price return

[[Page 96900]]

for a futures contract. The risk premium is the return required to bear

the undiversifiable risk on the relevant side of a futures

contract.\1519\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1519\ In theory, if the futures contract at expiration is a

perfect substitute for the spot commodity, then the expiring futures

price should converge to the spot price. It is important to note

that many expiring futures contracts are imperfect substitutes for

the spot commodity and this might prevent convergence. Moreover, the

risk premium decreases to zero as the futures contract approaches

expiration. Thus, the risk premium has no effect on the final

convergence of the futures to the spot price at expiration of the

futures contract, but could, in theory, impact the rate of

convergence (although any impact may be negligible).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

There are also Granger studies that analyze speculative positions

with respect to price returns as a whole or price volatility; these do

not find a statistically significant correlation. Moreover, those

studies that do find a lead-lag correlation using the Granger

methodology in the risk premium context are limited to studies in

particular markets in particular time frames: Studies using weekly, not

daily, price data and analyzing crude oil and ethanol-related

commodities (including wheat, which is an economic substitute for corn)

during the 2007-2010 timeframe.

There are 36 primarily Granger-based economic studies in the

administrative record. For analysis purposes, these papers are grouped

according to whether they discuss primarily crude oil or other energy

derivatives (8 studies); the possible impact of commodity index funds

across multiple commodities (13); and agricultural commodities (15).

Crude Oil and Other Energy Derivatives

There was a substantial increase in crude oil prices through July

2008, followed by a significant price collapse from July 2008 through

March of 2009.\1520\ Several Granger analyses have looked at price

returns and/or price volatility in the crude oil markets, or the energy

markets generally, in the 2007-2009 timeframe.\1521\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1520\ Bahattin B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Jeffrey H.

Harris, The Role of Speculators in the Crude Oil Futures Market at 2

(working paper 2009).

\1521\ See, e.g., Goyal and Tripathi, Regulation and Price

Discovery: Oil Spot and Futures Markets (working paper 2012); Irwin

and Sanders, Energy Futures Prices and Commodity Index Investment:

New Evidence from Firm-Level Position Data (working paper 2014);

Kaufmann and Ullman, Oil Prices, Speculation, and Fundamentals:

Interpreting Causal Relations Among Spot and Futures Prices, Energy

Economics, Vol. 31, Issue 4 (July 2009); Kaufman, The role of market

fundamentals and speculation in recent price changes for crude oil,

Energy Policy, Vol. 39, Issue 1 (January 2011); Mobert, Do

Speculators Drive Crude Oil Prices? (2009 working paper); Sanders,

Boris, and Manfredo, Hedgers, Funds, and Small Speculators in the

Energy Futures Markets: An Analysis of the CFTC's Commitment of

Traders Reports, Energy Economics (2004); Singleton, Investor Flows

and the 2008 Boom/Bust in Oil Prices (working paper March 23, 2011)

(published in final form in Management Science in 2013); Singleton,

The 2008 Boom/Bust in Oil Prices (working paper May 17, 2010).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Professor Kenneth Singleton found evidence that speculative

positions Granger-caused risk premium on weekly time intervals during

the 2007 to 2009 period when studying the crude oil futures

markets.\1522\ Part of Singleton's results were replicated in part in a

paper by Hamilton and Wu using a different methodology than Granger

causality analysis.\1523\ Professor Singleton found a link between the

volume of speculative positions and an increase in risk premium.

Because risk premium is a component of price returns and hence price,

he thus found a link--Granger causal link--between speculative

positions and price. However, because risk premium is just a relatively

small component of price, this study does not purport to explain

entirely the large 2008 changes in crude oil prices.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1522\ Kenneth J. Singleton, Investor Flows and the 2008 Boom/

Bust in Oil Prices, SSRN Electronic Journal 15 (2011) 18. (Equation

6, lagged correlation analysis that is, functionally, a Granger

analysis).

\1523\ Hamilton and Wu, Risk Premia in Crude Oil Futures Prices,

Journal of International Money and Finance (2013) (replicating

Singleton's result using a different methodology, a two-factor

linear model of fundamental supply and demand).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the case of index funds, many funds take long positions. The

presence of large index funds positions raises an issue of whether what

economists would call this ``heterogeneity of views'' can affect

marketplace health. Singleton presents, with his Granger-like analysis,

a discussion of heterogeneity in this context. He conjectures--without

supporting empirical analysis--that learning about economic

fundamentals with heterogeneous views may induce excessive price

volatility, drift in commodity prices, and a tendency towards booms and

busts. He asserts that under these conditions the flow of financial

index investments into commodity markets may harm price discovery and

thus social welfare.\1524\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1524\ Kenneth J. Singleton, Investor Flows and the 2008 Boom/

Bust in Oil Prices, SSRN Electronic Journal 15 (2011) 5-8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another paper using Granger analysis concluded that speculators did

have an impact on price volatility in the crude oil market.\1525\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1525\ Jochen M[ouml]bert, Deutsche Bank Research, Dispersion in

beliefs among speculators 9-10 (2009). This paper concluded that as

net long positions increased, volatility increased. This paper was

inconclusive of the impact of speculation on price levels (id. at 8-

9), and observed caveats on the difficulty of accurate modelling in

the complex crude oil market (id. at 11).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some commenters have suggested that using a weekly, not a daily,

time interval for a Granger analysis in this context is a better choice

because speculative positions change gradually and there is, on a daily

basis, substantial price volatility, especially in the crude oil

market.\1526\ The common sense explanation for this may be that prices

change more often and more rapidly than position sizes, as a general

rule. A weekly time interval is a good way to filter out price changes

that speculative position changes cannot explain.\1527\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1526\ Frenk, Review of Irwin and Sanders 2010 OECD Report, at 6

(Better Markets June 10, 2010).

\1527\ There are not many other economic studies in the

administrative record duplicating the results of Singleton and

Hamilton and Wu. A few others reached similar conclusions regarding

the crude oil market using Granger analysis, but these are

relatively modest or narrowly constructed studies that are not often

cited by economic peers. See Goyal and Tripathi, Regulation and

Price Discovery: Oil Spot and Futures Markets (working paper 2012)

(concluding that regulations of the nation of India, including

position limits, may have mitigated short duration ``bubbles'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Other Granger analyses of the crude oil market use shorter time

intervals and do not find Granger-causality between speculative

position changes and either price returns, price changes or price

volatility.\1528\ The academic literature contains a divergence of

views on whether the existence of ``excess speculation'' in the crude

oil market would necessarily result in something that is easy to

measure, like increases in oil inventories. Some economists argue

against the role of ``excess speculation'' in crude oil, observing that

when there was a run-up in prices of certain commodities, there was no

noticeable increase in inventories.\1529\ This assumes that a

fundamental shock in the oil prices, for example, is likely to increase

or decrease inventories, as hedgers in the physical market anticipate

future price increases or decreases. However, other economists have

explained that, at least in theory, speculation can affect spot oil

prices without causing substantial increases in inventory (providing

the price elasticity of oil demand is small).\1530\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1528\ Kaufmann and Ullman, Oil Prices, Speculation, and

Fundamentals: Interpreting Causal Relations Among Spot and Futures

Prices, Energy Economics, Vol. 31, Issue 4 (July 2009); Kaufman, The

role of market fundamentals and speculation in recent price changes

for crude oil, Energy Policy, Vol . 39, Issue 1 (January 2011);

Sanders, Boris, and Manfredo, Hedgers, Funds, and Small Speculators

in the Energy Futures Markets: An Analysis of the CFTC's Commitment

of Traders Reports, Energy Economics (2004).

\1529\ Irwin and Sanders, Index Funds, Financialization, and

Commodity Futures Markets, at 14-15, Applied Economic Perspectives

and Policy (2010).

\1530\ Hamilton, Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of

2007-2008, Brookings Paper on Economic Activity (2009); Parsons,

Black Gold & Fool's Gold: Speculation in the Oil Futures Market at

82, 106-107 (Economia 2009) (if oil prices were driven above the

level determined by fundamental factors of supply and demand by

forces such as speculation, storage would not necessarily increase,

for ``successful innovations in the financial industry made it

possible for paper oil to be a financial asset in a very complete

way''); accord Lombardi and Van Robays, Do Financial Investors

Destabilize the Oil Price?, at 21-22, European Central Bank Working

Paper Series No. 1346 (June 2011). The ability drawdown or stock

pile inventory is limited by storage capacity. Further, since it is

expensive to store oil above ground, buy and hold strategies are

only a loose constraint on prices.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96901]]

Irwin and Sanders conclude that there is no Granger-causation

between positions in a particular commodity index fund and price

returns in four energy commodity markets.\1531\ Irwin and Sanders'

paper contains a fairly robust Granger analysis which analyzes several

models in conjunction with their standard model equation for position

and price. However, all of the equations that they test for Granger

causation contain a possible prejudice: The use of variables that may

be correlated with price other than the position variable, thus masking

the power of the position variable. Moreover, their paper fails to show

that the particular index fund data they used was generally

representative of index funds by statistical testing.\1532\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1531\ Dwight R. Sanders & Scott H. Irwin, Energy Futures Prices

and Commodity Index Investment: New Evidence from Firm-Level

Position Data, 46 Energy Economics (working paper 2014).

\1532\ In this paper, Irwin and Sanders critiqued Singleton's

results, concluding that Singleton found Granger causation because

he improperly calculated positon data. This debate cannot be

resolved definitively. In the absence of better daily data on

position in both swaps and position markets, it is unclear who is

correct here.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

There is an earlier paper by Sanders, Boris, and Manfredo that has

a similar result.\1533\ However, this 2004 paper uses variables that

may be correlated with price other than position data, and so, in the

Granger analysis, the price equation used for Granger testing may mask

some or all of the impact of positions on price (if any).\1534\ As

discussed, Irwin and Sanders' 2014 paper is also not completely free

from this masking problem. However, it has only one, not several,

variables that could mask correlation between position changes and

price returns: A lagged price return variable. Irwin and Sanders, aware

of the possibility of this masking of correlation, present a defense of

their choice to include a lagged price return variable in their model.

They argue that one does not know whether positions will affect just

current price returns or both current and lagged price returns, and in

this way it is not necessarily the case that there is a masking effect.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1533\ Dwight R. Sanders, Keith Boris & Mark Manfredo, Hedgers,

funds, and small speculators in the energy futures markets: An

analysis of the CFTC's Commitments of Traders reports, 26 Energy

Economics 425-445 (2004).

\1534\ Id. at 439, Equation 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

This argument does not prove that there is no masking effect. There

is at least the concern that the Irwin and Sanders model, as

constructed, masks possible Granger-causality between position changes

and price returns. Theoretically, one could learn more by examining the

linear correlation between explanatory variables (lagged price returns

and changes in position) by performing additional diagnostic

regressions. These regressions would estimate correlations between

explanatory variables and resolve the open question of whether the

price equation is significantly ``masking'' Granger-causality between

position changes and price returns.

Selecting between competing models with divergent results becomes

more of a judgment call than a science. Irwin and Sanders' 2014 paper

is well-done, as are papers with opposite conclusions, which find an

empirical relationship between position changes and price returns (risk

premia), such as the Singleton Granger analysis discussed above, and a

paper by Hamilton and Wu based on a different statistical method

discussed below.\1535\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1535\ James D. Hamilton & Jing Cynthia Wu, Risk premia in crude

oil futures prices, 42 Journal of International Money and Finance 9-

37 (2014).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

It is impossible to easily discern who is correct or what accounts

for the difference in result. It could be the ``masking'' issue in the

Irwin and Sanders model. It could also be the focus in the Irwin and

Sanders work on price returns, as opposed to the focus in both

Singleton's as well as Hamilton and Wu's on just a component of price

returns, risk premia. Irwin and Sanders, by focusing on price returns,

are doing Granger-causality testing with a model less sensitive to

changes in just risk premia. The differing results could also be due to

the different time horizons (weekly versus daily time increments) used

in the competing studies.

This clash of well-executed studies is on an important issue--the

dramatic changes in crude oil prices in 2006-2009. The study by Kaufman

is not directly on point.\1536\ He finds Granger-causation between

different types of crude oil contracts, but does not look to positions

or whether positions Granger-cause changes in price returns.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1536\ Robert K. Kaufmann, The role of market fundamentals and

speculation in recent price changes for crude oil, 39 Energy Policy

105-115 (2011).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Kaufmann also finds that far-out futures contracts and spot crude

oil are not correlated and he concludes that the reason for this lack

of correlation is speculation in the crude oil market. However, there

are gaps in this inference. Kaufmann assumes there should be a long-run

equilibrium between the spot and the futures price but cannot discern a

supply and demand reason for the lack of correlation. There are many

factors of supply and demand that would lead to differences between

far-out futures prices and spot prices in the crude oil market during

the time period studied--1986-2007. These factors include the depletion

of oil fields; variability in economic growth; discovery of new oil

sources and better modes of extraction; adaption of oil

infrastructure.\1537\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1537\ Cf. Kaufmann and Ullman, Oil Prices, Speculation, and

Fundamentals: Interpreting Causal Relations Among Spot and Futures

Prices, 31 Energy Economics (July 2009) (concluding that there is

Granger-price causation between different types of crude oil). This

study does not look for causation between position and price and so,

again, is of marginal relevance in the position limits context.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Index Funds Generally

Some economists have used the Granger methodology to study a group

of commodity markets and to analyze, overall, the effect, or lack

thereof, of commodity index fund investments on both energy and

agricultural commodity prices.\1538\ These relatively few Granger

studies on the ``financialization'' effect vary in their conclusions.

Overall, as a group, the Granger studies on the effect of index funds

across a swath of

[[Page 96902]]

commodity futures prices do not agree.\1539\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1538\ See, e.g., Antoshin, Canetti, and Miyajima, IMF Global

Financial Stability Report: Financial Stress and Deleveraging:

Macrofinancial Implications and Policy, Annex 1.2, Financial

Investment in Commodities Markets (October 2008); Jeffrey H. Harris

and Bahattin B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, The Role of Speculators in

the Crude Oil Futures Market (working paper 2009); Brunetti and

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Is Speculation Destabilizing? (working

paper 2009); Frenk, Review of Irwin and Sanders 2010 OECD Report

(Better Markets June 10, 2010); Gilbert, Speculative Influences on

Commodity Futures Prices, 2006-2008, UN Conference on Trade and

Development (2010) (page citations are to the 2009 working paper

version placed in the administrative record); Gilbert, Commodity

Speculation and Commodity Investment (powerpoint presentation 2010);

Irwin and Sanders, The Impact of Index and Swap Funds on Commodity

Futures Markets: A Systems Approach, Journal of Alternative

Investments (2011); Irwin and Sanders, The Impact of Index and Swap

Funds on Commodity Futures Markets: Preliminary Results (working

paper 2010); Mayer, The Growing Interdependence Between Financial

and Commodity Markets, UN Conference on Trade and Development

(discussion paper 2009); Stoll and Whaley, Commodity Index Investing

and Commodity Futures Prices (working paper 2010); Tse and Williams,

Does Index Speculation Impact Commodity Prices?, Financial Review,

Vol. 48, Issue 3 (2013); Tse, The Relationship Among Agricultural

Futures, ETFs, and the US Stock Market, Review of Futures Markets

(2012). A fairly late submission by Williams, Dodging Dodd-Frank:

Excessive Speculation, Commodities Markets, and the Burden of Proof,

Law & Policy Journal of the University of Denver (2015), studies

generally the limitations of Granger causality.

\1539\ There are many more studies using the comovement or

cointegration analysis, discussed in Section I(B) below, that look

at the financialization questions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Gilbert concluded that commodity index fund positons did Granger-

cause price increases in certain commodity futures markets during the

2006-2008 time period.\1540\ Gilbert, a Professor of Economics at the

University of Trento, Italy, found that this price impact appeared to

be lasting or ``permanent.'' \1541\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1540\ Christopher L. Gilbert, Speculative Influences on

Commodity Futures Prices, 2006-2008 (2010).

\1541\ Id. at 23; see also id. at 24, Table 6 (average price

impact by commodity, including a maximum price impact of over 16

percent for crude oil during 2006-2008 time period).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Gilbert's study is based upon a composed proxy for commodity fund

index investments. The index data they use is not explained in

sufficient detail in the paper and the results derived from this index

are therefore not replicable.\1542\ The price equation he uses for

testing is problematic.\1543\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1542\ Several statements about the index in the paper indicate

a lack of economic rigor, or at least major inferential leaps, in

the assumption that the index approximates commodity index funds.

Id. at 18, 21.

\1543\ See id. at 22 (Equation 4) (complex equation that

subtracts logarithmic prices without detailed economic justification

for the destructive of data though subtraction).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Gilbert's numerical results on price impact are dramatic, finding

substantial average impact in various commodities due to speculation,

with average impact in parts of 2008 of over 10 percent for aluminum,

copper, nickel, wheat, and corn.\1544\ Yet he provides little detail on

how he arrived at these percentages other than to say that they are

``estimates'' that he inferred from the statistical results set forth

in his Table 5.\1545\ Because his findings are not well-documented and

contain unexplained inferences, his paper is unreliable.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1544\ Id. at 24, Table 6.

\1545\ See id. at 23-24 (little or no statistical assessment of

how the results of Table 4 and 5 results translate into the large

price impact percentages in Table 6).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

By contrast, the Granger analysis of Stoll and Whaley concludes

that inflows and outflows from commodity index funds to the commodity

markets do not have Granger-caused price changes in the commodity

futures market.\1546\ The authors of this study did find a fleeting

price impact from when commodity index funds roll over to another

contract month. (This fleeting rollover impact finding may be outdated;

markets have learned to anticipate and account for index fund

rollovers.) \1547\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1546\ Hans R. Stoll & Robert E. Whaley, Commodity Index

Investing and Commodity Futures Prices (working paper 2010).

\1547\ Stoll and Whaley also found a divergence of futures and

cash prices in wheat in 2006-2009 period, especially in 2008 period,

but concluded that there were limited negative impacts on market

functioning associated with this failure to diverge. This result

should not be used to suggest that divergence is not a costly

phenomenon. Stoll and Whaley's analysis is limited to CME's wheat

futures contract. It failed to converge for a period of time because

storage was mispriced in the contract during this time period, and

market participants knew this and prices reflected this difference.

CME eventually changed the wheat contract to charge a more

appropriate amount for storage and the divergence phenomenon

dissipated. So this example of divergence is associated with

economic differences between the spot and futures contracts. It not

an example of divergence associated with market manipulation, with

attendant social welfare costs. See Frank Easterbrook, Monopoly,

Manipulation, and the Regulation of Futures Markets, S118, Journal

of Business (1986) (``When the closing price on a futures contract

significantly diverges from the price of the cash commodity

immediately before and after, this is strong evidence that someone

has reduced the accuracy of the market price and inflicted real

economic loss on participants in the market.'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Stoll and Whaley's analysis does not account for the possibility

that there could be a delayed effect on futures price changes

associated with a delay in laying off, in the futures markets, risks

acquired in commodity index swap contracts. In practices, dealers may

do this, acquiring risk in multiple markets within acceptable limits as

they manage their portfolio risk.\1548\ Moreover, a paper by Tse and

Williams criticizes Stoll and Whaley's approach for using ``low

frequency data'' and failing to use ``sufficiently granular data to

capture fast futures markets dynamics.'' \1549\ Using intraday, shorter

time intervals to analyze the possible effect of commodity fund

investments in the futures markets, Tse and Williams conclude that

there was ``transmission'' of price impacts from futures contracts in a

particular commodity fund index (the GSCI index) to commodities that

were not in the index. However, this Granger-causation result does not

necessarily establish any price impact associated with excessive

speculation. Other factors may lead to this result, such as time delay

in illiquid markets, the role of the GSCI index as a price influencing

mechanism, or the more rapid market response that tends to occur with

more liquid markets.\1550\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1548\ See Frank Easterbrook, Monopoly, Manipulation, and the

Regulation of Futures Markets S124, Journal of Business (1986) (in

the specific context of position limits, ``Offenses may be harder to

detect when they involve more than one market.'').

\1549\ Yiuman Tse & Michael R. Williams, Does Index Speculation

Impact Commodity Prices? An Intraday Analysis, 48 Financial Review

365-383 (2013).

\1550\ Stoll and Whaley also observed that commodity index funds

should not be thought of as speculators because they participated in

these markets to diversify their returns (relative to equity

holdings). In Tse, The Relationship Among Agricultural Futures,

ETFs, and the US Stock Market, Review of Futures Markets (2012), Tse

concluded that there were now positive correlations between

agricultural ETF returns and S&P 500. This result suggests that the

diversification benefit has at least decreased. In this paper, Tse

also found, using 5-minute, intraday returns, that agricultural ETF

price returns are Granger-caused by some of the underlying commodity

futures market. This result is a rare result finding causation from

the futures prices to financial or institutional traders.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

While both the Stoll and Whaley and the Gilbert papers are often

cited in the literature, they both have limitations in scope and

approach. Other studies do not fully resolve this academic debate. In a

paper by James W. Williams, the limitations of Granger causality

analysis in the position limits context is discussed.\1551\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1551\ James W. Williams, Dodging Dodd-Frank: Excessive

Speculation, Commodities Markets, and the Burden of Proof, 37 Law &

Policy 135-38 (2015). (sensitivities of Granger studies to

parameters, including time-sensitivity to time intervals, makes

``Granger-inspired studies of excessive speculation . . .

problematic,'' a problem compounded by the volatile nature of the

commodity markets).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The general findings of Irwin and Sanders support Stoll and

Whaley's conclusions.\1552\ Irwin and Sanders analyzed weekly CFTC

price data over a number of years and found that there was neither

Granger-causation between index fund positions and futures price

returns or Granger-causation between changes in fund positions and

futures price volatility. Utilizing a Working's T-index, Irwin and

Sanders also find that there was not excessive speculation in these

markets.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1552\ Dwight R Sanders & Scott H Irwin, The Impact of Index

Funds in Commodity Futures Markets: A Systems Approach, 14 The

Journal of Alternative Investments 40-49 (2011).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Frenk criticizes Irwin and Sanders for (1) both their specific

methodology, arguing that they used incorrect proxies for hedging

volumes and (2) rehearsing the general disadvantages of using Granger

analysis.\1553\ Frenk identifies difficulties in Irwin and Sanders'

data and underlying assumption.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1553\ David Frenk, Better Markets, Inc., Speculation and

Financial Fund Activity and The Impact of Index and Swap Funds on

Commodity Futures Markets 6 (2010). Some of Frenk's critiques fall

short of the mark. For example, he criticizes Irwin and Sanders for

using a one-week interval for their testing. Id. at 7. This is not a

flaw in the Irwin and Sanders paper and in fact using a one-week

time interval helps to ameliorate another problem Frenk identifies:

The difficulty of applying Granger analysis to highly volatile data

such as commodity prices.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

There is a significant problem with the Irwin and Sanders paper.

The price formula used for Granger testing in their paper is complex,

incorporating many lagged price returns and lagged positions, and risks

masking correlation due to the possible interdependence of

[[Page 96903]]

variables.\1554\ In a model designed to test whether there is Granger-

causation between position changes and price return, additional

variables may diminish the statistical power of the position change

variable in the testing equation by masking the effect of positon on

price returns. The inclusion of these lagged price returns and position

change variables in the model design may well diminish the statistical

power of the position change variable.\1555\ In this way it may also

mask a possible correlation between position changes and price

returns.\1556\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1554\ Dwight R Sanders & Scott H Irwin, The Impact of Index

Funds in Commodity Futures Markets: A Systems Approach, 14 The

Journal of Alternative Investments 40-49 (2011).

\1555\ In Table 54 of the Irwin and Sanders paper, the price

return equation used for the Granger correlation analysis diminishes

the potential impact of positions on current price returns. Irwin

and Sanders use this equation to test for Granger-causation between

price returns and position changes, but inclusion of lagged price

returns in the equation is problematic. Within the workings of the

Granger statistics, placing lagged price returns and change of

position data in the same equation can mask the impact of change of

positions on price. That is because price returns and lagged price

returns may have common correlation; a statistician would say that

lagged price return data and change in positions are competing for

common correlation with price returns in the Table 4 equation. In

this way, the explanatory power of the change in position variable

in this Irwin and Sanders paper is diminished by introduction of the

lagged price return variables.

\1556\ See James W. Williams, Dodging Dodd-Frank: Excessive

Speculation, Commodities Markets, and the Burden of Proof, 37 Law &

Policy 137-138 (2015) (Granger methodology may be problematic in

analysis of position limits, because there may be nonlinear

relationships between economic variables).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Other studies doing Granger testing for the effects of commodity

index funds on prices arrive at conflicting results.\1557\ Then-CFTC

economists who were able to access non-public, daily market data to do

Granger-based economic analysis of the possible impact of commodity

index funds have added to this debate.\1558\ A battery of Granger tests

discussed in a paper prepared by Bahattin B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin

and Jeffrey H. Harris lead to the conclusion that there was no Granger-

causation between swap dealer positions (a proxy for commodity index

fund positions) and returns in the crude oil or natural gas

futures.\1559\ This finding stayed consistent across tests using

different time periods within 2000 to 2008 and different lag periods.

Rather, B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Harris found price changes

Granger-cause changes in position. This study performs an additional

Working T analysis and concludes that this measure of speculative

positions was not Granger causing price changes in the crude oil or

natural gas markets.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1557\ Compare J[ouml]rg Mayer, United Nations Conference on

Trade and Development, The Growing Interdependence Between Financial

and Commodity Markets (2009).

\1558\ Those studies reflect the views of the individual

economists, and, not necessarily of the Commission. Compare Mayer,

The Growing Interdependence Between Financial and Commodity Markets,

UN Conference on Trade and Development (discussion paper 2009)

(finding financial investment in commodity trading Granger-cause

price changes in soybeans, soybean oil, copper, crude oilTable 4)

with IMF Global Financial Stability Report: Financial Stress and

Deleveraging: Macrofinancial Implications and Policy, Annex 1.2,

Financial Investment in Commodities Markets (October 2008) (not

providing specifications or background on study, but reporting

results finding an absence of Granger causation between position and

price in all but the copper markets).

\1559\ See Bahattin B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Jeffrey H.

Harris, The Role of Speculators in the Crude Oil Futures Market

(working paper 2009).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The study by Brunetti and B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin is also an

important contribution to the literature.\1560\ Brunetti and

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin consider price returns and positions in

several markets (crude oil, natural gas, corn, Eurodollar, and mini-

Dow) and find no Granger causation between position and price returns

for any of these commodity markets during a time period when commodity

index funds were participating in these markets. This study also finds

that speculators in these markets during the time period are

decreasing, not increasing, volatility.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1560\ Celso Brunetti & Bahattin Buyuksahin, Is Speculation

Destabilizing?, SSRN Electronic Journal. The Commission cited this

study in particular in its December 2013 Position Limits Proposal.

See also Letter from CME Group, Inc., to CFTC (Mar. 28, 2011).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

These CFTC-staff studies have the advantage of using non-public,

daily data. However, such studies are subject to the same limitations

that are inherent in Granger analysis in this context: The open

question of whether the proper time lag was selected, the ad hoc

assumption of the time step selected to compute the volatility, and the

inclusion in both studies of variables such as lagged price returns

that may inadvertently mask correlation. The inherent limitations of

Granger analysis may well bear on the conflicting results of these

Granger papers.

Agricultural Commodities

The final set of Granger papers concern the agricultural commodity

markets. These include a series of papers by Irwin and Sanders and co-

authors not finding Granger causation between positions and price

returns.\1561\ A few papers arrive at nuanced or inconclusive results,

but generally cannot find significant Granger causation between

position and price in the agricultural commodity markets.\1562\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1561\ See, e.g.,Irwin and Sanders, The ``Necessity'' of New

Position Limits in Agricultural Futures Markets: The Verdict from

Daily Firm-Level Position Data (working paper 2014); Irwin and

Sanders, The Performance of CBOT Corn, Soybean, and Wheat Futures

Contracts after Recent Changes in Speculative Limits (working paper

2007); Sanders, Irwin, and Merrin, Smart Money? The Forecasting

Ability of CFTC Large Traders, Journal of Agricultural and Resource

Economics (2009); Sanders, Irwin, and Merrin, A Speculative Bubble

in Commodity Futures? Cross-Sectional Evidence, Agricultural

Economics (2010); Irwin, Sanders, and Merrin, Devil or Angel: The

Role of Speculation in the Recent Commodity Price Boom, Journal of

Agricultural and Applied Economics (2009); Sanders, Irwin, and

Merrin, The Adequacy of Speculation in Agricultural Futures Markets:

Too Much of a Good Thing?, Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy

(2010). An additional paper is, for the most part, in accord with

Irwin and Sanders' work. Aulerich, Irwin, and Garcia, Bubbles, Food

Prices, and Speculation: Evidence from the CFTC's Daily Large Trader

Data Files (NBER Conference 2012) (concluding overall that buying

pressure from financial index investment in recent years did not

cause massive price ``bubbles'' in agricultural futures prices, and

any such evidence of price increase is weak evidence of small and

fleeting price impact).

\1562\ See, e.g., Borin and Di Nino, The Role of Financial

Investments in Agricultural Commodity Derivatives Markets (working

paper 2012) (finding ``sparse'' evidence of Granger causation

between traders' investment decisions and futures prices and also

``scarce evidence of hearing behavior except in the cotton

market''); Grosche, Limitations of Granger Causality Analysis to

Assess the Price Effects From the Financialization of Agricultural

Commodity Markets Under Bounded Rationality, Agricultural and

Resource Economics (2012); Gilbert, How to Understand High Food

Prices, Journal of Agricultural Economics (2008); Robles, Torero,

and von Braun, When Speculation Matters (working paper 2009)

(speculative trading may have influenced agricultural commodity

prices ``but the evidence is far from conclusive'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

There are studies (some are more properly categorized as articles)

that do purport to find Granger causation between positions and price

returns.\1563\ The papers finding substantial price impacts caused by

speculative positions in the commodity futures markets are not

published in academic, peer-reviewed economic or agricultural

journals.\1564\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1563\ See, e.g., Algieri, Price Volatility, Speculation and

Excessive Speculation in Commodity Markets: Sheep or Shepherd

Behaviour? (working paper 2012) (``excessive speculation'' has

driven price volatility for maize, rice, soybeans, and wheat for a

particular timeframe); Cooke and Robles, Recent Food Prices

Movements: A Time Series Analysis (working paper 2009) (concluding

that financial activity in futures market and proxies for

speculation can help explain observed changes in international food

prices for corn, wheat, rice, and soybeans); Timmer, Did Speculation

Affect World Rice Prices?, UN Food and Agricultural Organization

(working paper 2009) (concluding that the price of rice was not

affected by financial speculators, but run-ups in wheat and corn

prices ``was almost certainly caused by financial speculators'');

Varadi, An Evidence of Speculation in Indian Commodity Markets

(working paper 2012) (inferring the unexplained price increases must

be due to speculation).

\1564\ Other limitations arise from fairly cryptic inferential

reasoning that the cause of any price-run up must be due to

speculation. See, e.g., Timmer, Did Speculation Affect World Rice

Prices?, 38, UN Food and Agricultural Organization (working paper

2009) (regarding theory that financial speculators are the cause for

price run-ups, the paper states that ``[t]hese conclusions are

reached mostly by eliminating the other explanations and by logical

reasoning''); Varadi, An Evidence of Speculation in Indian Commodity

Markets (working paper 2012) (asserting author's ``estimations''

that speculation has played a ``decisive role'' in creating

commodity price bubbles in Indian commodity markets, without

provision of a theoretical framework to reach this conclusion).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96904]]

Gilbert, in a 2008 paper, reaches a different result with respect

to agricultural commodities.\1565\ Gilbert performs Granger testing on

other variables that could explain (in the sense of Granger-causing)

run-ups in agricultural commodity futures prices. Specifically, he

looks at macroeconomic and financial factors that affected the price of

many commodities during the 2005-2008 time period.\1566\ Gilbert

obtains results suggesting that the main determinants in agricultural

commodity futures prices during this time period are macroeconomic

(such as GDP growth) and financial factors (such as the value of the

dollar and interest rates).\1567\ Gilbert concludes that (1) there is

little Granger-causation evidence that speculation by commodity index

funds caused the run-up in agricultural commodity prices during this

time period; and (2) moreover, there is evidence that macroeconomic

factors other than ``excessive speculation'' might have caused the

price run-up. Gilbert's work does not purport to show that

macroeconomic and financial factors account for all price changes.

Moreover, his 2008 piece is difficult to reconcile with his 2010 work,

which does find price impacts from speculation using Granger analysis

for some agricultural commodities.\1568\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1565\ Christopher J. Gilbert, How to Understand High Food

Prices, Journal of Agricultural Economics (2008).

\1566\ Id.

\1567\ Id. at 27-28.

\1568\ Gilbert, Speculative Influences on Commodity Futures

Prices, 2006-2008, 24 (Table 4), UN Conference on Trade and

Development (2010) (referencing price impacts in wheat, corn, and

soybean).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The work of Gilbert, as well as Irwin and Sanders, also suggest a

cautious approach is warranted in concluding how sizeable or lasting

any price impact associated with ``excessive speculation'' can be, at

least when employing a Granger analysis. One paper authored by Irwin

emphasized that the only evidence of Granger-causation between

positions and price returns in the agricultural market was weak

evidence of temporary changes in price.\1569\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1569\ Aulerich, Irwin, and Garcia, Bubbles, Food Prices, and

Speculation: Evidence from the CFTC's Daily Large Trader Data Files,

22 (NBER Conference 2012) (finding some weak evidence of temporary

changes in price Granger-caused by positions, but observing that the

``size of the estimated system impact is too small'' to be

consistent with the commodity index funds causing a huge run-up in

prices).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The debate is hard to resolve, including for the fairly technical

reasons provided in Grosche.\1570\ Grosche observes that index trading

and other financial investment may be based on a mixture of speculative

and hedging motives in the agricultural sphere.\1571\ The interaction

between the physical and financial contracts in the agricultural

commodity sphere is under-researched and the possible ``spillover''

effects from financial to agricultural markets is unknown.\1572\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1570\ Grosche, Limitations of Granger Causality Analysis to

Assess the Price Effects from the Financialization of Agricultural

Commodity Markets Under Bounded Rationality, Agricultural and

Resource Economics (2012).

\1571\ Id. at 18.

\1572\ Id. at 17. See also Williams, Dodging Dodd-Frank:

Excessive Speculation, Commodities Markets, and the Burden of Proof,

Law & Policy Journal of the University of Denver (2015).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Comovement, Cointegration and ``Financialization''

i. Description

These studies employ a statistical method that can be viewed

mathematically as a special case of Granger causality, a method

frequently referred to as comovement. This method looks for whether

there is correlation that is contemporaneous and not lagged. (This is

effectively similar to a Granger analysis where the type period of lag

is set to zero.) Like Granger causality, this method employs linear

regression to establish correlation between market prices or price

returns and speculative positions. When the time step is set to zero,

the economist can no longer seek to establish an inference of cause and

effect between prices or price returns and positions. Instead, the

economist is using a Granger-type analysis to establish whether there

is a correlation that is contemporaneous. A subset of these comovement

studies uses a technique called cointegration for testing correlation

between two sets of data, to see if there is a statistical relationship

notwithstanding the ``white noise'' of price data.\1573\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1573\ Two time series of price data are said to be cointegrated

if the error term in the modeling of their statistical correlation

is a term that is, among other things, independent of time. In

layperson's terms, the two streams of price data each roughly follow

a random walk through time. (In more technical terms, cointegration

means there is a linear connection between the two streams of data

where the difference is ``white noise'' (Brownian motion) or a

random walk. There is some cointegrating vector of coefficients that

can be used to form a linear combination of the two time series.)

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

This technique can be used to ferret out unexpected divergences in

prices. For example, many economists perform cointegration tests

comparing futures and spot prices, which generally should constrain

each other by staying within reasonable bands of each other. If they

find a discrepancy, they consider whether excess speculation or a price

``bubble'' could explain this price discrepancy.

ii. Advantages and Disadvantages

Such approaches are useful to compare commodity markets with other

markets in seeking a correlation over time between these sets of

prices. For example, a study may look at a price index for commodities

for one time series and a price index for equities for another time

series. In rough terms, studying the linear regressions of these price

data over time establishes whether there is a confluence of price

trends in these two markets. It may capture correlations that a Granger

causality approach may miss if the latter uses too large a time lag. In

this way, comovement analyses may be stronger than Granger analyses at

finding correlations, avoiding the problem of correlations being hidden

by the improper selection of length of time lag.

But the complementary disadvantage is that a comovement result

cannot establish even weak, Granger-style causation. In the particular

context of position limits, this disadvantage is significant. As

further explained below in the discussion of specific studies,

correlations between prices or price returns and positions can be

caused by external factors such as broad macroeconomic trends. In

particular, using comovement to try to establish a ``price bubble''

over time ranges that are short-term (months) or medium-term (18 months

to two years) is problematic because of the impact macroeconomic or

other external factors (wars, recessions, etc.) can have on short-term

prices. A comovement study showing a correlation between two sets of

data--crude oil futures and spot prices--over just a year or two years

is, all else being equal, a fairly weak basis to infer a price bubble.

There can be other factors that cause decoupling of prices over such a

time period.

iii. ``Financialization''

Many of the papers in this category focus on a documented

correlation between returns to commodity futures and the financial

(including equity) markets that has increased strongly in

[[Page 96905]]

recent years.\1574\ This is often called comovement between the

commodity and financial markets. The many factors that have driven

explosive growth in commodity derivatives trading in recent years are

well-documented in a study by Basu and Gavin.\1575\ There has been

substantial growth in commodity index investments; this includes

commodity exchange-traded funds and other commodity indices that fund

managers and other financial investors use. Both the number of such

indices, and the volume of trading involving them, has grown

substantially in the last decade. There have also been significant

changes in the long positions held in commodity futures index funds

during the financial crisis:\1576\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1574\ Tang and Xiong, Index Investment and Financialization of

Commodities, Financial Analysts Journal (2012).

\1575\ Basu and Gavin, What Explains the Growth in Commodity

Derivatives?, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (2011).

\1576\ Id. at 40.

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.001

Figure 1B. Over-the-counter trading in commodity derivatives by

swap dealers has also increased over time, with a pronounced spike

during the 2007-2008 time period.\1577\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1577\ Id. at 41.

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.002

Figure 2B. The factors driving this growth include the desire of

institutional portfolio managers to hedge against stock risk, based on

the belief by some academic and industry economics that there were

negative correlations between returns on equity and commodity

futures.\1578\ This belief may not be economically justifiable.\1579\

Investors also sought higher yields in a low-yield environment.\1580\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1578\ Id. at 38, 44-45.

\1579\ See id. at 44 (however, following the collapse of

commodity prices in the summer of 2008 and subsequent financial

panic in September of 2008, the correlation between commodity prices

and equities became highly and positively correlated). Use of

commodities to hedge equity or business cycle risk is controversial.

Basu and Gavin, What Explains the Growth in Commodity Derivatives?,

at 44 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (2011), citing

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Haigh, and Robe (2008) (unconditional

correlation between equity and commodity futures returns is near

zero).

\1580\ Id. at 38, 44.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96906]]

iv. The Masters Hypothesis

One variation on this financialization theme is the Masters

``hypothesis.'' Michael W. Masters, a hedge fund manager, is a leading

proponent of the view that commodity index investments have been a

major driver of increases in the commodity futures prices. In brief,

his views are expressed in the following statement:

Institutional Investors, with nearly $30 trillion in assets

under management, have decided en masse to embrace commodities

futures as an investable asset class. In the last five years, they

have poured hundreds of billions of dollars into the commodities

futures markets, a large fraction of which has gone into energy

futures. While individually these Investors are trying to do the

right thing for their portfolios (and stakeholders), they are

unaware that collectively they are having a massive impact on the

futures markets that makes the Hunt brothers pale in comparison. In

the last 4\1/2\, years assets allocated to commodity index

replication trading strategies have grown from $13 billion in 2003

to $317 billion in July 2008. At the same time, the prices for the

25 commodities that make up these indices have risen by an average

of over 200%. Today's commodities futures markets are excessively

speculative. . . .\1581\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1581\ M.W. Masters, A.K. White, The Accidental Hunt brothers:

How Institutional Investors Are Driving up Food and Energy Prices,

www.accidentalhuntbrothers.com (2008). Mr. Masters, Portfolio

Manager for Masters Capital Management, LLC, has often referred to

these large investors as ``passive'' investors. ``Passive

speculators are an invasive species that will continue to damage the

markets until they eradicated.'' Masters Statement, CFTC March 2010

hearing at 5. According to Barclay's, index fund investment fund in

commodities reached $431 billion as of July 2011. Algieri, A Roller

Coaster Ride, 5 (working paper 2011).

Statements are not, in themselves, rigorous economic studies, nor

do they purport to be. Several economists have attempted to formalize

and study rigorously the ``Masters hypothesis'' or related conjectures

using comovement or cointegration methods. These studies are discussed

below.

v. Discussion of Specific Studies

There are 25 papers that use some form of comovement or

cointegration analysis, broadly defined. Former and current economists

within the Office of Chief Economist have used this method repeatedly

(7 papers); \1582\ several government and policy researchers deploy

this method (4 papers); \1583\ and other academicians have used this

method (14 papers).\1584\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1582\ See, e.g., Boyd, B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, and Haigh,

The Prevalence, Sources, and Effects of Herding (working paper

2013); B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe, Does it Matter Who

Trades Energy Derivatives?, Review of Env't, Energy, and Economics

(2013); B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe, Speculators,

Commodities, and Cross-Market Linkages (working paper 2012);

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe, Does ``Paper Oil'' Matter?

(working paper 2011); B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Harris, and

Haigh, Fundamentals, Trader Activity, and Derivatives Pricing

(working paper 2008); Cheng, Kirilenko, and Xiong, Convective Risk

Flows in Commodity Futures Markets (working paper 2012); and Haigh,

Harris, and Overdahl, Market Growth, Trader Participation and

Pricing in Energy Futures Markets (working paper 2007).

\1583\ See, e.g., Baffes and Haniotos, Placing the 2006/08

Commodity Boom into Perspective, World Bank Policy Research Working

Paper 5371 (2010); Belke, Bordon, and Volz, Effects of Global

Liquidity on Commodity and Food Prices, German Institute for

Economic Research (2013); Kawamoto, Kimura, et al., What Has Caused

the Surge in Global Commodity Prices and Strengthened Cross-market

Linkage?, Bank of Japan Working Papers Series No.11-E-3 (May 2011);

and Pollin and Heintz, How Wall Street Speculation is Driving Up

Gasoline Prices Today (AFR working paper 2011).

\1584\ See, e.g., Ad[auml]mmer, Bohl and Stephan, Speculative

Bubbles in Agricultural Prices (working paper 2011); Algieri, A

Roller Coaster Ride: An Empirical Investigation of the Main Drivers

of Wheat Price (working paper 2013); Babula and Rothenberg, A

Dynamic Monthly Model of U.S. Pork Product Markets: Testing for and

Discerning the Role of Hedging on Pork-Related Food Costs, Journal

of Int'l Agricultural Trade and Development (2013); Basu and Miffre,

Capturing the Risk Premium of Commodity Futures: The Role of Hedging

Pressure, Journal of Banking and Risk (2013); Hoff, Herding Behavior

in Asset Markets, Journal of Financial Stability (2009); Tang and

Xiong, Index Investment and Financialization of Commodities,

Financial Analysts Journal (2012); Creti, Joets, and Mignon, On the

Links Between Stock and Commodity Markets' Volatility, Energy

Economics (2010); Bichetti and Maystre, The Synchronized and Long-

lasting Structural Change on Commodity Markets: Evidence from High

Frequency Data (working paper 2012); Bunn, Chevalier, and Le Pen,

Fundamental and Financial Influences on the Co-movement of Oil and

Gas Prices (working paper 2012); Coleman and Dark, Economic

Significance of Non-Hedger Investment in Commodity Markets (working

paper 2012); Dorfman and Karali, Have Commodity Index Funds

Increased Price Linkages between Commodities? (working paper 2012);

Korniotis, Does Speculation Affect Spot Price Levels? The Case of

Metals With and Without Futures Markets (working paper, FRB Finance

and Economic Discussion Series 2009) (also submitted as a comment by

CME); Le Pen and S[eacute]vi, Futures Trading and the Excess

Comovement of Commodity Prices (working paper 2012); and Windawi,

Speculation, Embedding, and Food Prices: A Cointegration Analysis

(working paper 2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Example of Oil Prices 2006-2008

One of the key challenges for application of the Masters hypothesis

is reconciliation of a supposed speculative price with what is

happening in the physical market. The debate within academia,

practitioners and policymakers on this topic has been considerable,

especially given the run-up in prices in certain commodities, such as

the 2006-2008 rise in crude oil prices. ``Dramatic swings in crude oil

prices have led Congress to examine the functioning of the markets

where prices are set.'' \1585\ The correlation of oil with economic

trends is not necessarily evidence that they are causing increases in

oil prices. As a Congressional Research Study observed, this might

suggest that certain traders with ``better information on macroeconomic

trends, which strongly influence energy demand, take more aggressive

positions, which would then influence oil prices.'' \1586\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1585\ Jickling and Austin, Hedge Fund Speculation and Oil

Prices 1 (Congressional Research Service R41902 June 29, 2011).

\1586\ Id. at 16, (Congressional Research Service R41902 June

29, 2011).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The economics of the crude oil market are a good example of the

dangers of applying comovement or cointegration methods over short- and

medium-term. Short-term crude oil prices are less elastic than longer-

term prices. This means, in the short term, changes in price do not

affect the supply of crude oil as much as long-term price changes do.

There are many reasons why this is so, having to do with the cost of

storing crude oil above ground and the cost of starting and stopping

crude oil extraction. So it is unsurprising that there are short- and

medium-term divergences in price between spot and longer-term futures

contracts in the crude oil markets.

On the supply side of crude oil market economics, a short-term

shock to supply (wars, embargoes, or other events) will not necessarily

translate into a long-term change in prices, even though it may cause

substantial short-term price changes and volatility. Similarly, on the

demand side of crude oil market economics, short-term changes to demand

can impact short-term crude oil prices without causing lasting long-

term price impact.\1587\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1587\ This is true for a variety of reasons, including the fact

that refining production is expensive to change on short notice. See

generally Hamilton, Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of

2007-2008, at 17-23, Brookings Paper on Economic Activity (2009)

(while oil prices may have been ``too high'' in July 2009, ``low

price elasticity of demand, and the failure of physical production

to increase'' are more likely the predominant causes than

``speculation per se'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For such reasons, comovement and cointegration studies of crude oil

prices over medium time frames are unpersuasive.\1588\

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe showed that correlations between

equity and energy commodity investments increased massively after

Lehman's

[[Page 96907]]

collapse in 2008.\1589\ As explained in another paper by

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe, this raises the question of

whether hedge fund and index fund inflows are transmitting financial

shocks to commodity prices.\1590\ However, as

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe's survey of Granger and comovement

economic literature demonstrate, it does not appear that index traders

and hedge funds had an impact on crude oil prices during this time

period.\1591\ Further, Celso Brunetti and Bahattin

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin separately found that hedge funds exert a

calming influence on crude oil prices by lowering oil price

volatility.\1592\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1588\ Pollin and Heintz, How Wall Street Speculation is Driving

Up Gasoline Prices Today, at 10, Americans for Financial Reform

(working paper 2011) (``Lagged values of both gasoline prices and

crude oil prices can affect current gas prices. This implies that

past speculative pressures are carried over, at least for several

months, to current prices.''); Bunn, Chevalier, Le Pen, and Sevi,

Fundamental and Financial Influences on the Co-movement of Oil and

Gas Prices, at 18 (working paper 2012) (``we find significant

evidence that speculation, with its focus on index trading,

increases the correlation between oil and gas'').

\1589\ B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe, Does ``Paper Oil''

Matter? (working paper 2011).

\1590\ B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe, Does it Matter Who

Trades Energy Derivatives?, Review of Env't, Energy, and Economics

(2013).

\1591\ Id. at 5.

\1592\ Celso Brunetti and Bahattin B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin,

Is Speculation Destabilizing? (working paper 2009). See also Haigh,

Harris, and Overdahl, Market Growth, Trader Participation and

Pricing in Energy Futures Markets (working paper 2007)

(participation of swap dealers and arbitrageurs has assisted in

improved price efficiency--price converge--in crude oil futures

contracts, with nearby, one, and two-year crude oil futures

contracts statistically cointegrated through the period studied,

July 2004 to mid-2006).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Cointegration results suggest that financial traders' influence of

crude oil futures prices is desirable. For example, then-CFTC

economists, B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Harris, and Haigh show how the

increased presence of swap dealers, hedge funds, and other financial

traders have led to the cointegration of various crude oil futures

contracts (the nearby contract, the one-year contract, and the two-year

contract).\1593\ This co-integration result by these economists

suggests that there was a long-term relation between the strength of

price cointegration and the market activities of financial

traders,\1594\ but this result does not suggest any harm to the

marketplace or price discovery from the cointegration of various crude

oil contracts. The authors conjecture that the greater market activity

by these traders can ``enhance market quality'' through ``enhance[d]

linkages among various futures prices'' that make these commodity

markets ``more informationally efficient.'' \1595\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1593\ B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Harris, and Haigh,

Fundamentals, Trader Activity, and Derivatives Pricing (working

paper 2008).

\1594\ Id. at 3.

\1595\ Id. at 4-5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Both research papers \1596\ are correct that, respectively, there

is increased comovement between crude oil prices with financial

investments and cointegration between nearby, one-year, and two-year

crude oil futures contracts. At least for the crude oil market, these

price linkages exist. However, one cannot obtain, using comovement and

cointegration techniques, decisive evidence on whether this effect

improves market efficiency; such a conclusion involves interpreting the

informational linkages between the markets. To the extent that the

paper by B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Harris, and Haigh moves beyond

establishing the linkage to inferring that the linkage has salutary

effects on commodity markets, that conclusion was not empirically

tested, because it was not modelled explicitly. At most, these studies

establish the existence of such price linkages.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1596\ B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe, Does it Matter Who

Trades Energy Derivatives?, Review of Env't, Energy, and Economics

(2013); B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Harris, and Haigh,

Fundamentals, Trader Activity, and Derivatives Pricing (working

paper 2008).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Financialization Comovement Literature

Some studies have examined ``financialization'' by using comovement

analysis to ask whether increased investment flows into commodity

indices (typically composed with substantial long futures positions)

are correlated with increases in futures prices or the volatility of

commodity futures prices across many different types of studies. Some

of these financializaton comovement studies have looked to whether

these investment flows decrease the risk premium for holding a long

futures contract, thereby causing a non-transient increase in the long

futures contract price (which, in turn, may increase the price of the

underlying commodity).

There is consensus in the economic literature that equities and

commodities no longer exhibit the strong negative correlations that

index fund investment managers may have sought in hedging their

portfolios. In recent years there has been an increased positive

correlation between equity and commodity prices since 2008.\1597\ There

is also substantial consensus among economists who study this issue

that risk premiums for holding long futures contracts have decreased

due to financialization.\1598\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1597\ E.g., Basu and Gavin, What Explains the Growth in

Commodity Derivatives?, at 44 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

(2011) (commodity and equity prices highly and positively correlated

in February 2010); Tang and Xiong, Index Investment and

Financialization of Commodities, Financial Analysts Journal (2012);

Inamura, Kimata, et al., Recent Surge in Global Commodity Prices

(Bank of Japan Review March 2011).

\1598\ Hamilton and Wu, Risk Premia in Crude Oil Futures Prices,

Journal of International Money and Finance (2013).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

However, there is a divergence of views among economists on the

impacts, if any, on the large positions taken by index funds on

commodity futures prices or price volatility.\1599\ These hypothesized

effects of financialization are debated among academics, practitioners,

and policymakers. Results of studies that test for a bubble component

in commodity futures prices--regardless of the cause--are decidedly

mixed.\1600\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1599\ See Irwin and Sanders, Index Funds, Financialization, and

Commodity Futures Markets, at 15, Applied Economic Perspectives and

Policy (2010) (surveying literature in support and against the idea

of a speculative bubble in prices arising from commodity index fund

participation in the futures market). Compare Gilbert, Speculative

Influences on Commodity Futures Prices, 2006-2008, UN Conf. On Trade

Development (2010); Einloth, Speculation and Recent Volatility in

the Price of Oil (working paper 2009), and Tang and Xiong, Index

Investment and Financialization of Commodities, Financial Analysts

Journal (2012) with Bahattin B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Jeffrey

H. Harris, The Role of Speculators in the Crude Oil Futures Market

(working paper 2009); Brunetti and B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Is

Speculation Destabilizing? (working paper 2009); Stoll and Whaley,

Commodity index Investing and Commodity Futures Prices, Journal of

Applied Finance (2010), Irwin and Sanders (multiple studies).

\1600\ See, e.g., B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe,

Speculators, Commodities, and Cross-Market Linkages (working paper

2012); Irwin and Sanders, Index Funds, Financialization, and

Commodity Futures Markets, at 15, Applied Economic Perspectives and

Policy (2010), citing, inter alia, Phillips and Yu, Dating the

Timeline of Financial Bubbles During the Subprime Crisis,

Quantitative Economics (2011); and Kilian and Murphy, The Role of

Inventories and Speculative Trading in the Global Market for Crude

Oil, Journal of Applied Econometrics (2010).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commission-affiliated economists have confirmed a general decrease

in volatility associated with financialization, a salutary effect

associated with increased liquidity.\1601\ In theoretical models

outside the comovement methodology, competition from index investment

reduces the risk premium that accrues to long position holders, and

this can have the net effect of lowering the cost of hedging to

traditional physical market participants.\1602\ Some economists rely

upon the efficient market hypothesis that market prices fully

incorporate all the available public ``information'' into prices--in

support of conclusion that financialization provides benefits such as

better price discovery, liquidity, and transfer of risks to entities

better

[[Page 96908]]

prepared to assume it.\1603\ Comovement and cointegration analyses are

some of the statistical tools used to test whether these purported

benefits of greater market participation hold true under particular

market conditions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1601\ Brunetti and B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Is Speculation

Destabilizing? (working paper 2009) (finding that hedge funds in the

commodity markets take the opposite position to other market

participants, therefore providing liquidity to the market in various

commodity market places studied, including crude oil, natural gas,

corn, and two financial contracts).

\1602\ Acharya, Ramadorai, and Lochstoer, Limits to Arbitrage

and Hedging: Evidence from Commodity Markets, Journal of Financial

Economics (2013) (existence of financial commodity index trading

will tend to decrease risk premium, thereby generally making it

cheaper for producers to hedge through short futures contracts).

\1603\ Filimonov, Bicchetti, and Maystre, Quantification of the

High Level of Endogeneity and of Structural Regime Shifts in

Commodity Markets, at3 and citations therein (working paper 2013).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

While competition and increased trading volume can generally help

markets, inflows do not universally benefit market welfare. In a paper

by Cheng, Kirilenko, and Xiong, the authors use comovement methodology

to conclude that in times of distress, financial traders reduce their

net long position, causing risk to flow from financial traders to

commercial hedgers.\1604\ ``[J]ust when the uncertainty in the economy

was rising, the number of futures contracts used by commercial hedgers

to hedge their risk was going down.'' \1605\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1604\ Cheng, Kirilenko, and Xiong, Convective Risk Flows in

Commodity Futures Markets (working paper 2012).

\1605\ Id. at 2 (citing papers on a growing body of theoretical

work indicating that at times of financial crisis, funding and risk

constraints may force financial traders to unwind positions, which,

in turn, forces hedgers to reduce their hedging positions).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Cheng, Kirilenko, and Xiong argue that tests such as Granger, which

look to whether financial traders' positions and futures prices are

negatively correlated when they trade to accommodate hedgers, overlook

an important lesson from the distressed financial literature.\1606\

When financial entities trade in response to their own financial

distress, their trades may be correlated positively to futures price

changes. These correlations may net out, so that any significant

correlation between their positions and price changes may be masked by

trading during financial distress.\1607\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1606\ Id. at 3.

\1607\ Id. See also Acharya, Ramadorai, and Lochstoer, Limits to

Arbitrage and Hedging: Evidence from the Commodity Markets, Journal

of Financial Economics (2013) (decreases in financial traders' risk

capacity should lead to increases in hedgers' hedging cost, all else

being equal).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Using cointegration techniques and non-public trading data, then-

CFTC economists, B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe demonstrate that

the correlations between equity indices and commodities increase with

greater participation by financial speculators.\1608\ There is no such

effect for other types of traders. In concert with the work of Cheng,

Kirilenko, and Xiong, they find that this cointegration effect, the

price linkages between equity indices and investible commodities, is

lower during times market stress.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1608\ B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe, Speculators,

Commodities, and Cross-Market Linkages (working paper 2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Another comovement study provided an empirical link between

commodity index investment and futures price movements, including

increased price volatility.\1609\ Tang and Xiong find that the

increasing presence of index traders in commodity futures markets

improves risk sharing in these markets with concomitant volatility

spillover from outside markets. This study finds evidence of volatility

spillovers from the financial crisis in the 2006-2009 time period,

spillovers that may have been a key driver of recent commodity price

volatility.\1610\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1609\ Tang and Xiong, Index Investment and Financialization of

Commodities, Financial Analysts Journal (2012).

\1610\ Of course, the spillover effect may not be limited to

domestic markets. Cf. UN Food and Agricultural Org., Price

Volatility in Agricultural Markets. Economic and Social Perspectives

Policy Brief 12 (2010) (citing financialization as a possible basis

for short-term volatility and observing that international

integration of markets can propagate price risks to domestic markets

quicker than before).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

This Tang and Xiong finding of volatility ``spillovers'' is

frequently cited by commenters in support of position limits. However,

some academics are skeptical of their results. Irwin and Sanders

concede that the Tang and Xiong paper ``appears to offer concrete

evidence'' of some form of financialization, but offers several reasons

to view these findings with caution.\1611\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1611\ Irwin and Sanders, Index Funds, Financialization, and

Commodity Futures Markets, 15, Applied Economic Perspectives and

Policy (2010) (questioning the small magnitude of correlation and

suggesting that Tang and Xiong may not have adequately controlled

for fundamental factors affecting price).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Tang and Xiong's results do not necessarily point to lasting

difficulties associated with the integration of financial and commodity

markets. Instead, they argue that commodity markets were not integrated

with financial markets prior to the development of commodity index

funds. In their paper, Tang and Xiong view financialization as a

``process'' which helps explain ``the synchronized price boom and bust

of a broad set of seemingly unrelated commodities'' during the 2006-

2008 time period.\1612\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1612\ Tang and Xiong, Index Investment and Financialization of

Commodities, Financial Analysts Journal (2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A problem with this line of reasoning that critics have identified

is that there could be other factors which lead to increased

correlation between equities and futures during this time period. After

all, 2006-2009 was an eventful time where broad macroeconomic factors

held sway and could have led to large positive correlations between

these markets. According to many, one of the factors leading to the

influx of investment funds in during the 2006-2008 time period was

negative correlations between commodities returns and equities returns.

Yet this factor is less prevalent today. ``The positive correlation

between the agriculture ETFs and S&P 500 suggests that the

diversification benefits of using an agricultural index have

decreased.'' \1613\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1613\ Tse, The Relationship Among Agricultural Futures, EFTs,

and the US Stock Market, at 16, Review of Futures Markets (2012).

Indeed, this decreased correlation may be due, in part, to ethanol,

an economic substitute for gasoline as an additive to reformulated

blend stock, being manufactured with corn and other grains.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some commenters have pointed to studies such as Tang and Xiong's in

support of the position limits rule.\1614\ However, most financial

investors' exposure to commodities through commodity index funds or

ETFs would not be prevented by position limits. Studies on the price

returns or price volatility effect of commodity index funds are thus

not directly relevant to the placement of position limits on individual

commodities contract.\1615\ Moreover, commodity index funds are not the

only large investors whose activities may affect commodity futures

prices.\1616\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1614\ See generally Henn Letter.

\1615\ See December 2013 Position Limits Proposal at 75740 n.483

(``The speculative position limits that the Commission proposes

apply only to transactions involving one commodity or the spread

between two commodities . . . . They do not apply to diversified

commodity index contracts involving more than two commodities . . .

. [C]ommenters assert that such contracts, which this proposal does

not address, consume liquidity and damage the price discovery

function of the marketplace'').

\1616\ Irwin and Sanders, Index Funds, Financialization, and

Commodity Futures Markets, at 26, Applied Economic Perspectives and

Policy (2010) (emergency evidence that ``other traders, such as

broker-dealers and hedge funds, play key roles in transmitting

shocks to commodity futures markets from other sectors''), citing,

inter alia B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Robe, Does it Matter Who

Trades Energy Derivatives?, Review of Env't, Energy, and Economics

(2013); Haigh, Hranaiova, and Overdahl, Hedge Funds, Volatility, and

Liquidity Provisions in the Energy Futures Markets, Journal of

Alternative Investments (Spring 2007); Basu and Gavin, What Explains

the Growth in Commodity Derivatives?, Federal Reserve Bank of St.

Louis (2011) (documenting increased participation in commodity

trading by swap dealers).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A paper by Korniotis contains an important caveat in the

financialization debate: The effects of financialization may vary

widely depending on the type of commodity.\1617\ Crude oil is an

important component of the S&P Goldman-Sachs Commodity Index

[[Page 96909]]

(GSCI), more so than industrial metals. Federal Reserve Board economist

George Korniotis found that there was cointegration between metals with

and without futures contracts that did not weaken as financial

speculation increased in the marketplace and the spot prices for

industrial metals were unrelated to the GSCI.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1617\ Korniotis, Does Speculation Affect Spot Price Levels? The

Case of Metals With and Without Futures Markets (working paper, FRB

Finance and Economic Discussion Series 2009).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With the exceptions discussed in detail above, many of the studies

in this vein do not warrant detailed discussion. Even well-executed

economic studies using comovement methodology that do not focus on

position limits may be of little or marginal relevance.\1618\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1618\ See Baffes and Haniotos, Placing the 2006/08 Commodity

Boom into Perspective, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5371

(2010); Kawamoto, Kimura, et al., What Has Caused the Surge in

Global Commodity Prices and Strengthened Cross-market Linkage?, Bank

of Japan Working Papers Series No.11-E-3 (May 2011); Coleman and

Dark, Economic Significance of Non-Hedger Investment in Commodity

Markets (working paper 2012); Dorfman and Karali, Have Commodity

Index Funds Increased Price Linkages between Commodities? (working

paper 2012); Le Pen and S[eacute]vi, Futures Trading and the Excess

Comovement of Commodity Prices (working paper 2012); Creti, Joets,

and Mignon, On the Links Between Stock and Commodity Markets'

Volatility, Energy Economics (2010); Bichetti and Maystre, The

Synchronized and Long-lasting Structural Change on Commodity

Markets: Evidence from High Frequency Data (working paper 2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Herding

There are other possible ways in which additional trading volume

may not be an unalloyed benefit to the wellbeing of a marketplace. A

few comovement studies attempt to test for the existence of

``herding.'' This is a formalized version of price trending. The idea

here is that traders may initiate a trade with the expectation that

positive-feedback traders will purchase the traded instruments at a

higher price later.\1619\ Some economists argue that financialization

aggravates ``herding'' behavior and herding creates price

bubbles.\1620\ Others dispute any such effect.\1621\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1619\ Boyd, B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, and Haigh, The

Prevalence, Sources, and Effects of Herding (working paper 2013);

Hoff, Herding Behavior in Asset Markets, Journal of Financial

Stability (2009). See also Froot, Scharfstein, and Stein, Herd on

the Street: Informational Inefficiencies in a Market with Short Term

Speculation (working paper 1990) (theoretical paper discussing

herding); Weiner, Do Birds of A Feather Flock Together? Speculator

Herding in the Oil Market (working paper 2006) (doing a herding

analysis to conclude that there are subgroups within speculators

that act in parallel, and this amplifies their effect on crude oil

prices).

\1620\ Hoff, Herding Behavior in Asset Markets, Journal of

Financial Stability (2009); Mayer, The Growing Interdependence

Between Financial and Commodity Markets, UN Conference on Trade and

Development (discussion paper 2009) (Granger analysis).

\1621\ E.g., Brunetti and B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Is

Speculation Destabilizing?, at 5 n.3 (working paper 2009) (``the

moderate level of herding in futures markets [among hedge funds]

serves to stabilize prices'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Though the evidence for herding is meager, the underlying idea is

consistent with accepted and theoretically plausible results on risk

premia. Risk premiums rise with the volatility of the futures markets,

and risk premiums depend in part on speculators' hedging pressure and

inventory levels.\1622\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1622\ Basu and Miffre, Capturing the Risk Premium of Commodity

Futures: The Role of Hedging Pressure, Journal of Banking and Risk

(2013).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Agricultural Commodities and Financialization

Agricultural economists have reached similarly conclusions on the

cointegration of financial speculators and food prices. While there are

respectable empirical results suggesting that financial speculation

have affected some recent agricultural commodity price dynamics, there

is no unanimity in the academic community on conclusive empirical

evidence of the causal dynamics, breadth, and magnitude of such

effects.\1623\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1623\ See Aulerich, Irwin, and Garcia, Bubbles, Food Prices,

and Speculation: Evidence from the CFTC's Daily Large Trader Data

Files, at 3 n.4, NBER Conference on Economics of Food Price

Volatility (2012) (studies testing for the existence of price

bubbles in agricultural futures markets have led to ``mixed

results''). See also.Belke, Bordon, and Volz, Effects of Global

Liquidity on Commodity and Food Prices, German Institute for

Economic Research (2013); Ad[auml]mmer, Bohl and Stephan,

Speculative Bubbles in Agricultural Prices (working paper 2011);

Algieri, A Roller Coaster Ride: an Empirical Investigation of the

Main Drivers of Wheat Price (working paper 2013); Babula and

Rothenberg, A Dynamic Monthly Model of U.S. Pork Product Markets:

Testing for and Discerning the Role of Hedging on Pork-Related Food

Costs, Journal of Int'l Agricultural Trade and Development (2013);

Windawi, Speculation, Embedding, and Food Prices: A Cointegration

Analysis (working paper 2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

c. Models of Fundamental Supply and Demand and Related Methods

i. Description

Some economists have developed economic models for the supply and

demand of a commodity. These models often include theories of how

storage capacity and use affect supply and demand, often a critical

factor in the case of physical commodities and their inter-temporal

price (that is, their price over time). Using models of supply and

demand, the economists then attempt to arrive at a ``fundamental''

price (or price return) for commodity based on the model. Specifically,

the economists look at where the model is in equilibrium with respect

to quantities supplied and quantities demanded to arrive at this price.

The fundamental price given by such a model is then compared with

actual prices. The economists look for deviations between the

fundamental price, based on the model, and the actual price of the

commodity. When pursuing this method, economists look for whether the

price deviations are statistically significant. When there are

statistically significant deviations of the actual price from market

fundamentals, they infer that the price is not driven by market

fundamentals.

Many of these studies present a model for one particular commodity

or set of commodities. Some looked at volatile markets. Others used at

very predictable markets.

We group together for analysis a diverse set of studies that fall

within this broad category of economic models of fundamental supply and

demand. Some asserted that their models generally could explain prices.

Some papers were neutral. And some papers reached the conclusion that

market fundamentals could not explain certain price data in the markets

they studied.

ii. Advantages

This methodology is well-recognized and accepted means for

detecting price deviations. This is a centuries-old technique, as old

as the quantification of economics. The model forces the economist to

explain supply and demand. This requirement thus provides welcome

transparency.

Moreover, the models are auditable: When the fundamental price

deviates from the actual price, the economists may well be able to look

at the model and see which aspects of supply and/or demand created the

deviation. If the economist cannot ascertain the source of the

deviation, (1) the economist may seek to add additional variables to

the models for supply or demand to better model supply and demand or

(2) conclude that this unexplained deviation is empirical support for

the existence of a non-fundamental price.

Another advantage of this model is that the loose language of

``bubble'' is replaced by the term ``non-fundamental price.'' The model

supplies an economically motivated specification for the price of a

commodity. This feature permits deeper economic analysis and debate on

whether a non-fundamental price exists without a digression into

debates about what the term ``bubble'' means.\1624\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1624\ Nobel laureates in economics cannot agree on whether

bubbles exist or what the proper definition of a bubble is. Studies

that focus on the causes of price formation avoid these definitional

uncertainties. See Easterbrook, Frank, Monopoly, Manipulation, and

the Regulation of Futures Markets, at S117, Journal of Business

(1986) (it is not necessarily market manipulation to exploit an

advantageous position in the marketplace in anticipation of changes

in supply and demand.'')

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96910]]

iii. Disadvantages

As applied to position limits, this approach has several drawbacks

as well.

First and foremost, the analyses and conclusions that flow from

these studies are only as good as the models themselves. Specifically,

the price benchmark is based on the model, and an analysis of deviation

from the benchmark is only as strong as the model itself. These models

incorporate many simplifying assumptions. Market behavior and the real

world in general, are much more complicated.

Moreover, these models do not function well when there is a supply

shock or when demand falls precipitously. Another disadvantage is model

construction using variables that are highly correlated with the price.

If the correlation between price and a variable is too high, then using

the variable in the model may permit the variable to function as a

proxy for price. This will hobble the model's ability to detect price

deviations.

A substantial disadvantage of this model is the inherent difficulty

of modelling fundamentals of supply and demand in a market of any

complexity. Or even, in a model, in anticipating or measuring the

impact of large macroeconomic trends. For example, economists have a

notoriously bad track record of predicting economic recessions. Thus it

is difficult to conclude that a model with a few variables, designed

without this hindsight, would be successful in predicting how crude oil

prices would behave during the advent of an economic recession. With

hindsight, economists know now that September 2008 was at the outset of

a substantial global recession, or at least a point of dramatic

decrease in the output of the world economy. And with hindsight, it is

apparent that the recession dramatically reduced the demand for crude

oil. But at the outset of a recession, a model designed without

knowledge of the recession (or of its severity) might confuse a

statistically significant deviation of actual crude oil prices for the

fundamental price derived from the model.

In addition, while this statistical method replaces the loose

language of ``bubbles'' with a statistically derived fundamental price,

studies offering economic analysis of the fundamentals of price and

demand do not eliminate all subjectivity in determining whether a non-

fundament price has occurred. An economist will often obtain from these

models a ``price band,'' a band for which prices falling within that

range remain reflective of fundamental supply and demand. Prices

outside the price band are non-fundamental prices. Determining the

height of the band depends on what is viewed as a statistically

significant deviation, by definition. But determining what a

statistically significant deviation is requires the economist to make

an assumption that can be quite consequential. The economist must set a

level of price changes that his or her model will ignore as

attributable merely to chance. Nothing in underlying statistics of the

price data will provide the economist with this level. If the level is

fixed so that the price band is relatively tall, less prices are likely

to be labelled statistically significant deviation by the test.

iv. Analysis of Specific Papers Using Fundamental Models

Crude Oil Models

Even before 2007, there were suspicions about prices in the crude

oil market. The Governor of the Federal Reserve Board said in 2004:

``The sharp increases and extreme volatility of oil prices have led

observers to suggest that some part of the rise in prices reflects a

speculative component arising from the activities of traders in the oil

markets.'' \1625\ Then the price of crude oil doubled from June 2007 to

June 2008, and then rapidly declined in the second-half of 2008. Many

economists thereafter published papers saying that the increase in

demand up to June 2008 and/or the decrease in demand for September 2008

crude oil could not be explained by market fundamentals. Many attempted

to infer from this fact that speculative trading was causing changes in

crude oil prices or price volatility.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1625\ Ben S. Bernake, Oil and the Economy, Remarks by then

Governor Bernake at the Distinguished Lecture Series, Darton

College, Albany, Georgia (2004).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

To understand these papers' strengths and weaknesses, it is

important to appreciate a critical factor about crude oil market

economics--storage.\1626\ Data on storage is often used to study crude

oil prices for speculative price influences.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1626\ Brennan and Schwartz, Arbitrage in Stock Index Futures

(Journal of Business 1990).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Crude oil is storable, and so its price reflects, in particular,

the demand for crude oil inventory. Speculators influence the spot

price of crude oil by placing physical crude oil into storage when

future prices are anticipated to be higher and out of storage when

future prices are anticipated to be lower. Given this, some economists

have studied crude oil storage to determine whether crude oil

inventories could be contributing to the boom and bust in crude oil

prices during the 2007-2008 time period. Specifically, using models of

fundamental supply and demand, they study the elasticity of crude oil

prices to determine whether the effect of speculators' trading on crude

oil inventories could affect crude oil prices.

Several economists have examined above-ground oil inventories in

the United States during this 2007-2008 timeframe and examined the

interplay of crude oil inventories and prices. They concluded that the

short-term elasticity of crude oil demand would have had to have been

unusually low--quite inelastic--for inventory demand to fully explain

the unusual crude oil prices in 2007-2008. (Price inelasticity of

demand means that the price of crude oil is sensitive to changes in

quantity demand: A small decrease in demand is likely to cause a large

drop in price, for example, when the short-term elasticity of demand is

inelastic, all else being equal.) From this, they conclude that

speculative traders' effect on inventory demand was unlikely to be a

complete explanation for the 2007-2008 crude oil price swings. That is,

it would be unlikely for speculators to be able to (at least easily)

cause substantial movements in crude oil prices by speculators'

influence on the amount of crude oil stored in above-ground crude oil

inventories.\1627\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1627\ Byun, Speculation in Commodity Futures Market,

Inventories and the Price of Crude Oil (working paper 2013);

Hamilton, Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of 2007-2008,

Brookings Paper on Economic Activity (2009); Kilian and Lee,

Quantifying the Speculative Component in the Real Price of Oil: The

Role of Global Oil Inventories (working paper 2013); Kilian and

Murphy, The Role of Inventories and Speculative Trading in the

Global Market for Crude Oil, Journal of Applied Econometrics (2010);

Knittel and Pindyck, The Simple Economics of Commodity Price

Speculation (working paper 2013).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Nonetheless, inventories may still explain part of the unusual

price behavior of crude oil in 2007-2008. Even if the short-term

elasticity of demand would have to have been very small in absolute

value, speculation may have also affected below-ground

inventories.\1628\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1628\ Hamilton, Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of

2007-2008, Brookings Paper on Economic Activity (2009) (below-ground

inventories should also be considered and are not included in the

data) (concluding that speculative trading did affect both the speed

and magnitude of the price decline in 2008).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Many economists conclude that there was a substantial demand shock

to crude oil during this time period, a

[[Page 96911]]

demand arising from the onset of a global recession. As the deep

recession of 2008 and 2009 began to set in, there was a decrease in

demand for September 2008 crude oil in the crude oil futures market. It

is unlikely that a demand shock associated with the recession was

anticipated by the marketplace, including speculators, given the

notorious difficulty of predicting recessions. Kilian and Murphy \1629\

assert, if a global recession causes the demand shock, the economics of

the crude oil market suggests that there is little policymakers can do

to prevent this kind of price bubble from appearing in the crude oil

market at the outset of the recession.\1630\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1629\ Kilian and Murphy, The Role of Inventories and

Speculative Trading in the Global Market for Crude Oil, Journal of

Applied Econometrics (2010).

\1630\ See id. at 6 & n. 8 (economic theory suggests a link

between cyclical fluctuations in global real activity and the real

price of oil).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several economists wrote papers suggesting that their results

indicated that crude oil price changes during this time period

reflected uneconomic or ``bubble-like'' behavior. Generally, these

authors find that their models of supply and demand could not track

well the run up in crude oil prices to around $145 in mid-2008 or the

bust to close to $30 a barrel just a few weeks later, and they

concluded that activity by speculators in these markets was or might be

affecting the rapid crude oil price changes.\1631\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1631\ E.g., Cifarelli and Paladino, Oil Price Dynamics and

Speculation: A Multivariate Financial Approach, at p.1, Energy

Economics (2010) (``Despite the difficulties, we identify a

significant role played by speculation in the oil market, which is

consistent with the observed large daily upward and downward shifts

in prices--a clear evidence that it is not a fundamental-driven

market''); Einloth, Speculation and Recent Volatility in the Price

of Oil (working paper 2009) (using convenience yields to conclude

that speculation did not play a major role in rise of crude oil to

$100 a barrel in March of 2008, did play a role in its subsequent

rise to $140 a barrel, and did not play a role in subsequent

decline); Hamilton, Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of

2007-2008, Brookings Paper on Economic Activity (2009) (speculative

trading increased the speed and magnitude of mid-2008 price

collapse). Papers using this methodology reach a broad range of

conclusions. See also Eckaus, The Oil Price Really is a Speculative

Bubble (working paper 2008) (reject the hedging pressure hypothesis

that inventory positions are an important determinant of risk

premiums, and concludes that oil prices are speculative because he

cannot perceive a reason for the prices based on supply and demand);

Morana, Oil Price Dynamics, Macro-finance Interactions and the Role

of Financial Speculation, at 206-226, Journal of Banking & Finance,

Vol. 37, Issue 1 (Jan. 2013) (concluding that there is excessive

speculation in the crude oil market that did lead to a substantial

price impact in 2007-2008); Sornette, Woodard and Zhou, The 2006-

2008 Oil Bubble and Beyond: Evidence of Speculation, and Prediction,

Physica A. (2009) (find evidence of a bubble, but only based upon an

undocumented model largely presented by graphs); Stevans and

Sessions, Speculation, Futures Prices, and the U.S. Real Price of

Crude Oil, American Journal of Social and Management Science (2010)

(contending that there is ``hoarding'' in the crude oil market and

that elimination of the longer-term futures contracts would curb

excessive speculation); Weiner, Speculation in International Crises:

Report from the Gulf, Journal of Int'l Business Studies (2005) (a

combination of political and market events, not speculation, was

behind the price volatility in 1990-1991); Breitenfellner, Crespo,

and Keppel, Determinants of Crude Oil Prices: Supply, Demand,

Cartel, or Speculation?, at 134, Monetary Policy and the Economy

(2009) (concluding ``it is conceivable'' that interaction between

crude oil production and financial markets exacerbated pressure on

crude oil prices, but finding no proof of this).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

These studies do not, in total, lead to consensus. There are

distinctive differences and disagreement in the papers on the existence

of excessive speculation in the crude oil market during 2007-2009. Even

within the Federal Reserve system, there is disagreement, for instance,

Plante and Y[uuml]cel, in Did Speculation Drive Oil Prices? Futures

Market Points to Fundamentals,\1632\ and Juvenal and Petrella, in

Speculation in the Oil Market.\1633\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1632\ Plante and Y[uuml]cel, Did Speculation Drive Oil Prices?

Futures Market Points to Fundamentals (working paper Federal Reserve

of Dallas 2011) (crude oil data for the 2007-2009 time period ``are

consistent with how a well-functioning futures market would

behave,'' and if speculation had been to blame, there would have

been ``very large positive spreads . . . followed by significant

increases in inventory'').

\1633\ Juvenal and Petrella, Speculation in the Oil Market

(working paper of Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 2012)

(concluding that speculation played a ``significant role'' in both

the price increases in 2008 and the subsequent collapse, but they

did not carefully model ``excess speculation.'' Instead, they

interpreted the second principle component as being ``excess

speculation'' even though the second component may be assigned many

other interpretations or even be deemed uninterpretable.).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The methodology of fundamentals of supply and demand does not zero

in precisely on causation and leaves room for interpretation of why a

price does not follow modelled supply and demand behavior. Labelling

prices ``bubbles'' caused by speculation simply because one does not

understand or cannot otherwise account for price movements is

problematic. One explanation for the failure of these models to track

such fast-moving prices that is speculative activity is at work. But

there are other explanations. On some level, there is a tautological

error in labelling price changes as ``bubble-like'' simply because

economists could not, as of a certain time and with certain model,

otherwise explain or predict price movements. These models are trying

to explain very complex phenomena and make difficult choices on how to

use imperfect data.

Some models performed better at modelling the real-world crude oil

prices, using models of fundamental supply and demand, by selecting one

of the stronger proxies for crude oil, such as the Dry Baltic Index or

macroeconomic variables such as global gross domestic product as

explanatory variables.\1634\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1634\ E.g., Kilian and Murphy, The Role of Inventories and

Speculative Trading in the Global Market for Crude Oil, Journal of

Applied Econometrics (2010). In the construction of his study,

Kilian used a shipping index, the Dry Baltic Index. In shipping, a

predominant factor in the cost of shipping is the cost of crude oil.

By using the Dry Baltic Index to attempt to compose a model to

explain crude oil prices, the economist chose a variable which would

naturally be highly correlated to crude oil prices. However, by

using a proxy, the effectiveness of the model is lessened. It is

unclear whether the results are attributable to fundamentals driving

crude oil prices or crude oil prices driving the Dry Baltic Index.

See also Morana, Oil Price Dynamics, Macro-finance Interactions and

the Role of Financial Speculation, pp. 206-226, Journal of Banking &

Finance, Vol. 37, Issue 1 (Jan. 2013) (careful, large-scale modeling

of the oil market macro-finance interface, finding the existence of

``excess speculation'' in these markets using Workings T and other

tests, and concluding that financial factors may have up to a 30

percent contribution to oil price fluctuations). Id. at p.220 (using

Working's T and model to conclude that there is a significant

liquidity effect associated with non-fundamental financial shocks in

the oil market, leading to a higher real oil price without affecting

inventories); id. at 223-224 (macro-finance factors played a larger

role than ``financial factors'' in the 2007-2009 crude oil ``price

shock,'' but ``excessive speculation'' did have a price impact).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

One of the best studies in this area is Hamilton, Causes and

Consequences of the Oil Shock of 2007-2008.\1635\ He concludes that

fundamentals of supply and demand are responsible for most of the run-

up in prices, while speculative trading may have increased both the

speed and absolute magnitude of the mid-2008 decline in prices. As to

the first point, he concludes that while oil prices may have been ``too

high'' in July 2008, ``low price elasticity of demand, and the failure

of physical production to increase'' are more likely the predominant

causes than ``speculation per se.'' \1636\ He acknowledges, however,

that the speed and magnitude of the price decline in mid-2008 may have

been induced, in part, by speculative trading.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1635\ Hamilton, Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of

2007-2008, Brookings Paper on Economic Activity (2009).

\1636\ See id. at 17-23.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Given this mixed result, both proponents and opponents of position

limits cite various aspects of this Hamilton study. His study follows

the data closely; his model discusses key issues such as inventory. He

does not leap to strained interpretations based on theoretical model

assumptions. When his model does not provide a full explanation for

price behavior based on supply and demand, he does not simply jump to

the conclusion that speculation is at work. Instead, he offers measured

[[Page 96912]]

judgments on the possibility that speculation may have affected the

precipitous mid-2008 crude oil price decline and presents statistical

evidence that this may have occurred.

Other Studies Based on Supply and Demand Models

A discussion of crude oil prices during the 2007-2008 timeframe is

illustrative of other commodities during this time period. For example,

there is considerable comovement between the real price of crude oil

and the real price of other industrial commodities during times of

major fluctuation in global real activity (such as global

recessions).\1637\ All commodities during this time period were

buffeted by macroeconomic factors, including a global recession, and a

deep one at that during 2008 and 2009.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1637\ Kilian and Murphy, The Role of Inventories and

Speculative Trading in the Global Market for Crude Oil, at p.7 n. 9,

Journal of Applied Econometrics (2010).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Outside of the crude oil context, there are some noteworthy studies

of fundamental supply and demand that bear on the position limits

rulemaking.

Allen, Litov, and Mei, in Large Investors, Price Manipulation, and

Limits to Arbitrage: An Anatomy of Market Corners,\1638\ examine

historical corners and squeezes in security and commodity markets and

conclude that a corner or squeeze may induce arbitragers to exit the

market, since arbitragers will only take short positions when the

prospect of profits is high enough. Two papers, Gorton, Hayashi,

Rouwenhorst, The Fundamentals of Commodity Futures Returns,\1639\ and

Ederington, Dewally, and Fernando, Determinants of Trader Profits in

Futures Markets,\1640\ offer empirical support for the hedging pressure

hypothesis: That the returns on long futures positions vary inversely

with inventory and price volatility.\1641\ Haigh, Hranaiova, and

Overdahl, in Hedge Funds, Volatility, and Liquidity Provisions in the

Energy Futures Markets,\1642\ suggest that hedge funds supply liquidity

and that there is little linkage between price volatility and hedge

fund position change. They claim that hedge fund participation in

futures markets, at least as of 2007, was not injecting unwarranted

volatility into futures prices.\1643\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1638\ Allen, Litov, and Mei, Large Investors, Price

Manipulation, and Limits to Arbitrage: An Anatomy of Market Corners,

Review of Finance (2006).

\1639\ Gorton, Hayashi, Rouwenhorst, The Fundamentals of

Commodity Futures Returns, Review of Finance (2013).

\1640\ Ederington, Dewally, and Fernando, Determinants of Trader

Profits in Futures Markets (working paper 2013).

\1641\ All else being equal, the more inventory available for

delivery the less costly it is for shorts to hedge their exposure.

Similarly, the more volatile the commodity prices are, the more

price risk is being accepted by the longs (all else being equal).

This means that in volatile markets hedgers that are short will pay

higher risk premia to hedge.

\1642\ Haigh, Hranaiova, and Overdahl, Hedge Funds, Volatility,

and Liquidity Provisions in the Energy Futures Markets, Journal of

Alternative Investments (2007).

\1643\ See also Harrison and Kreps, Speculative Investor

Behavior in a Stock Market With Heterogeneous Expectations,

Quarterly Journal of Economics (1978) (differences in subjective

beliefs induce trading and speculation); Manera, Nicolini and

Vignati, Futures Price Volatility in Commodities Markets: The Role

of Short-Term vs Long-Term Speculation (working paper 2013) (short-

term speculation, as estimated by daily volume divided by open

interest, increases volatility while long term speculation, using a

Working's T analysis, decreases it); Trostle, Global Agricultural

Supply and Demand: Factors Contributing to the Recent Increase in

Food Commodity Prices, USDA Economic Research Service (2008)

(surveying supply and demand fundamentals explain a lot of the

futures prices and price volatility: Slow growth in production

relative to demand for biofuels, declining US dollar, rising oil

prices, bad weather 2006 to 2007, growing holdings by foreign

countries, and increased cost of production for agriculture in

general).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Other papers on the fundamentals of supply and demand do not bear

directly on position limits. Some discuss matters far afield from the

impact of positions on price or other matters bearing on position

limits.\1644\ Others rest on unreliable model assumptions.\1645\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1644\ Chan, Trade Size, Order Imbalance, and Volatility-Volume

Relation, Journal of Financial Economics (2000) (studying the equity

market to determine the role that trade size has on volatility for

equities); Chordia, Subrahmanyam and Roll, Order imbalance,

Liquidity, and Market Returns, Journal of Financial Economics (2002)

(show that order imbalances in either direction for equity markets

affect daily returns after controlling for aggregate volume and

liquidity); Doroudian and Vercammen, First and Second Order Impacts

of Speculation and Commodity Price Volatility (working paper 2012)

(claiming a ``second order'' price distortion caused by

institutional investors); Frankel and Rose, Determinants of

Agricultural and Mineral Commodity Prices (working paper 2010) (two

macroeconomic fundamentals--global output and inflation--have

positive effects on real commodities, but microeconomic variables

have greatest overall effects, including volatility, inventories,

and spot-forward spread); Girardi, Do Financial Investors Affect

Commodity Prices? (working paper 2011) (during the late 2000s there

was a positive, statistically significant and substantial

correlation between hard red winter wheat price and the U.S. equity

market, as well as a substantial correlation between hard red winter

wheat prices and crude oil prices); Hong and Yogo, Digging into

Commodities (working paper 2009) (investors use commodities to hedge

market fluctuations, as evidenced by yield spread analysis); Kyle

and Wang, Speculation Duopoly with Agreement to Disagree: Can

Overconfidence Survive the Market Test?, Journal of Finance (1997)

(theoretical model explaining how overconfidence by fund managers

can lead to a persistence in market prices); Plato and Hoffman,

Measuring the Influence of Commodity Fund Trading on Soybean Price

Discovery (working paper 2007) (``finding that the price discovery

performance of the soybean futures market has improved along with

the increased commodity fund trading''); Westcott and Hoffman, Price

Determination for Corn and Wheat: The Role of Market Factors and

Government Programs (working paper 1999) (analysis of supply and

demand fundamentals for wheat and corn that does not include

position data); and Wright, International Grain Reserves and Other

Instruments to Address Volatility in Grain Markets, World Bank

Research Observer (2012) (about price limits, not position limits).

\1645\ Bos and van der Molen, A Bitter Brew? How Index Fund

Speculation Can Drive Up Commodity Prices, Journal of Agricultural

and Applied Economics (2010) (most of the changes in spot prices can

be attributed to shifts in demand and supply, and failure to account

properly for these inputs in the coffee price generation process may

lead to serious overestimation of the effects of speculation;

nevertheless, asserting without detailed analysis that speculation

is an important part of the coffee price generation process), Gupta

and Kamzemi, Factor Exposures and Hedge Fund Operational Risk: The

Case of Amaranth (working paper 2009) (trying to explain the

behavior of Amaranth on the mistaken notion that a hedge fund should

be diversified); Henderson, Pearson and Wang, New Evidence on the

Financialization of Commodity Markets (working paper 2012) (analysis

founded on questionable assumption that commodity link note

investors are uninformed investors); Van der Molen, Speculators

Invading the Commodity Markets (working paper 2009) (data handling

problems: Dataset which covers twenty years, while the variable

index speculators is only available for two to three years, and

assumes that net position is in indication of index speculators).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96913]]

d. Switching Regressions

i. Switching Regression Analysis Described

In a switching regression analysis, an economist poses the

existence of a model with more than one state. In the particular

context of position limits, there are typically two states: (1) A

normal state--where prices are viewed as what they theoretically should

be following market fundamentals and (2) a second state--often

described as a ``bubble'' state in these papers. Using price data,

authors of these studies calculate the probability of a transition

between these two states. The point of transition between the two

states under this methodology is called a structural ``breakpoint.''

Examination of these breakpoints permits the researcher to date and

time the existence of a second state, such as a bubble state.

These authors sometimes find empirical support in the data for the

existence of a second state by calculating the probability of

breakpoints. When the probability is high enough, the research will say

that there is evidence for a second state.

ii. Advantages

A variant of this method was first published in 1973. It is fairly

well-credentialed within academia. If there are two states of the

world, it makes sense that distinct states would have different

economic models. Because switching regressions uses at least a two-

state regression, this method satisfies the economist's view that

different states would be better described using different models. A

one-size-fits-all model, applied to varying economic states, could

potentially be compromised in order to accommodate disparate states.

This model is flexible, allowing for many different specifications

(of model design) as explanatory variables of speculative positions and

futures prices.

When using this method, the economic researcher permits the data

itself to choose the structural breakpoints. This differs from some

other statistical methods, where the economic researcher may choose

exogenously, based on interpretation of the data or historical

knowledge, where and when a transition to a supposed bubble state

occurs. The model's selection of the breakpoint permits data to be

tested against known historical events and thus lend a measure of

credence to the model's choices for structural breaks.

The model also permits close study of particular time periods. An

economist may well be aware of historical events that were market-

transition events such as ``bubbles,'' and this method permits the

economist to zero-in on that time period and to investigate potential

causes and/or confounding events associated with a suspected market

transition.\1646\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1646\ This method is particularly good at ``accommodating''

abrupt shifts in market data. Some statistic methods, such as those

based on linear regression, may have difficulty with volatile data

or data discontinuity. This method is also particularly well-suited

for studying policy changes. For example, if the Federal Reserve

makes a policy change that is expected to have a long-term, but not

necessarily an immediate, impact, this method will permit an

economist to infer, based on the model, the duration of the lag

before the policy change begins to affect the markets.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iii. Disadvantages

This method has a significant disadvantage that is highlighted in

the position limit context. This statistical technique tests for a

second state. There could, however, be reasons for a non-normal state

other than a ``bubble'' state. This method leaves quite a bit to

economic interpretation of the model, not raw data analysis, to reach

their inference that the second state is a ``bubble'' state.

While the existence of a second state may indicate a ``bubble''

state and may indicate a problem with excessive speculation, this

statistical method cannot definitively prove these inferences, even if

position data were used in the analysis. The probability of the

existence of second state in these studies in only circumstantial

evidence of (1) a ``bubble'' state and (2) a ``bubble'' state caused by

excessive speculation.

Consider an example of why data alone cannot explain why a

deviation from a normal market state is a bubble state: The case of

feeder cattle. If there is a drought and feed becomes scarce and

expensive, the cattlemen may sell off part of their herd. Prices of

feeder cattle may then drop in the short term as well, because

cattleman may sell young calves, too. But subsequently, because so many

cattle have been slaughtered, there is a shortage of feeder cattle the

next season and the prices of feeder cattle rise. So in this case,

there is theoretical and empirical support for two states, but they

correspond to non-drought and drought states and not normal and

``bubble'' state. Switching regression analysis if applied to feeder

cattle prices during a time period encompassing both drought and non-

drought state would not establish the existence of what we could

typically view as a ``bubble'' in the post-drought price rise.\1647\ In

any event, none of this price phenomenon can be viewed as a problem of

``excessive speculation.'' One could still use the ill-defined word

``bubble'' to describe the second state, but it would be a dearth of

rainfall, not excessive speculation, which created this second state.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1647\ This example is taken from an academic paper not within

the administrative record that found non-fundamental (or ``bubble'')

prices in crude oil and feeder cattle markets. Brooks et al, Boom

and Busts in Commodity Markets: Bubbles or Fundamentals? (working

paper 2014).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The theoretical level of the analysis, and in particular the lack

of firm empirical data linking non-normal states to speculative

``bubble'' markets, are weaknesses of this statistical method. The

studies following this method do not provide categorical proof of the

existence of speculative ``bubble'' markets and they do not provide

statistical evidence of whether positions limits would be effective in

ameliorating ``bubble'' markets.\1648\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1648\ These models are difficult to design well in this context

for several other reasons. The economist is making an informed,

probabilistic inference that a transition has occurred. This

inference is more than a seat-of-the-pants determination, but it is

less than a mathematical certainty. The result of this statistical

method is also highly dependent upon what set of data the

econometrician selects for analysis. An economic model founded on

this method should be given more credence when it is applied to more

than one dataset and the results are replicated with different data.

Selection of controlling variables that would account for position

data is a difficult task with this statistical model. The data-

driven nature of the model does not help in selection of proper

controlling and explanatory variables. Ingenuity is required to

design explanatory variables that would account well for position

data.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iv. Analysis of Studies Reviewed That Used Switching Regression

Five studies used a standard form of switching regressions

analysis.\1649\

[[Page 96914]]

Three studies used a related methodologies, multi-state regressions or

conditional correlations.\1650\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1649\ These are: Cifarelli and Paladino, Commodity Futures

Returns: A non-linear Markov Regime Switching Model of Hedging and

Speculative Pressures (working paper 2010) (concluding that

speculation, not supply and demand factors, drive some daily price

swings in certain energy futures); Chevallier, Price Relationships

in Crude oil Futures: New Evidence from CFTC Disaggregated Data,

Environmental Economics and Policy Studies (2012) (the influence of

financial investors through the S&P GSCI Energy Spot may have

contributed to price changes in the crude oil market) (discussed in

ensuing text); Hache and Lantz, Speculative Trading & Oil Price

Dynamic: A Study of the WTI Market, Energy Economics, Vol. 36, 340

(March 2013) (cannot reject hypothesis that variations in the

positions of non-commercial players may have played a

``destabilising role in petroleum markets'' and ``speculative

trading can be considered an important factor during market

instability and `oil bubbling' process''); Lammerding, Stephan,

Trede, and Wifling, Speculative Bubbles in Recent Oil Price

Dynamics: Evidence from a Bayesian Markov Switching State-Space

Approach, Energy Economics Vol. 36 (2013) (claims to find robust

evidence of ``bubbles'' in oil prices associated with speculation);

and Sigl-Gr[uuml]b and Schiereck, Speculation and Nonlinear Price

Dynamics in Commodity Futures Markets, Investment Management and

Financial Innovations, Vol. 77, pp. 59-73 (2010) (``short-run

autoregressive behavior'' of commodity markets is driven not only by

fundamentals but also by trading of speculators).

\1650\ These are: Fan and Xu, What Has Driven Oil Prices Since

2000? A Structural Change Perspective, Energy Economics (2011)

(multi-state); Baldi and Peri, Price Discovery in Agricultural

Commodities: The Shifting Relationship Between Spot and Futures

Prices (working paper 2011) (multi-state); Silvernnoinen and Thorp,

Financialization, Crisis and Commodity Correlation Dynamics, Journal

of Int'l Financial Markets, Institutions, and Money (2013)

(conditional correlations). All three of these papers are of mixed

methodology, applying switching regression analysis to relationships

between prices that are viewed by the papers' authors as

cointegrated.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Most of these studies are not helpful because they do not use

position data or because they have technical issues.\1651\ It is

difficult to perform these types of studies well. A study finding the

existence of transitions between states can be unconvincing if it does

not have solid theoretical and economic justifications for the data

selected and the model's design. Many of the disadvantages of this

methodology, discussed above, find expression in these papers.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1651\ For example, the study by Sigl-Gr[uuml]b and Schiereck

employs a smooth transition (as opposed to an abrupt change) between

states. Unfortunately, the study's model does not have a high

goodness-of-fit values (all adjusted-R2 are below 0.05

and most are below 0.01), nor fundamental economic explanatory

variables (only lagged prices and speculative positions in the

transition component between states). These are shortcomings. In

particular, the latter omission may overstate the importance of

speculative positions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

However, there is one switching regression study worthy of further

discussion in our view. It is well-executed and employs position data:

Chevallier, Price Relationships in Crude oil Futures: New Evidence from

CFTC Disaggregated Data.\1652\ Of course, it inherits all the

difficulties of speculative position data, such as the difficulty

separating hedgers from speculators. Yet Chevalier's effort does

persuasively suggest the existence of two states in price structure

during 2008 crude oil market price swings. His paper suggests that with

highly inelastic supply and demand, the influence of financial

investors through the S&P GSCI Energy Spot may have contributed to

price changes in the crude oil market.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1652\ Chevallier, Price Relationships in Crude oil Futures: New

Evidence from CFTC Disaggregated Data, Environmental Economics and

Policy Studies (2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Using switching regressions, Chevallier attempts to reconcile two

strands of economic literature: Papers that posit the predominance of

supply and demand fundamentals and other papers that investigate

speculative trading. Chevallier employs macroeconomic variables,

proxies for supply and demand fundamentals, and speculative positions

(net open position of speculators) in his model specifications. Using

switching regression analysis, he concludes that one cannot eliminate

the possibility of speculation (a reason why the physical commodity may

move into and out of storage) as one of the main reasons behind the

2008 oil price swings.

This is an important result. Other economic studies using models of

supply and demand purport to explain the 2008 price swings in crude oil

without incorporating speculation into demand. Chevallier's paper

suggests that speculation cannot be ruled out as a cause. Specifically,

using net speculative positions as one of his variables in his test, he

found that this variable was statistically significant on crude oil

futures natural logarithm of price returns during the 2008 time

period.\1653\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1653\ Specifically, Chevallier found that in the first state,

the coefficient of the logarithmic returns of net speculative

positions is positive and significant (1 percent level). In the

second state, this coefficient is negative and mildly significant

(10 percent level). Chevallier's results show statistically

significant relationships between the volume of speculative

positions in particular and logarithmic price returns.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

This result posits that speculation may have played some role

during the 2008 crude oil futures price swings. It suggests that

studies that look only to supply and demand without incorporating

speculative demand to explain the crude oil market in 2008 may be

overlooking an important factor. The switching regression methodology

in this context functions as a cross-check to determine whether models

of fundamental supply and demand can, in fact, account for all the

price swings in crude oil during this time. In at least this particular

commodity market and timeframe, Chevallier's finding that net

speculative positions are correlated with crude oil future prices

suggests a price effect from net speculative positions.

e. Eigenvalue Stability

i. Description

Some economists have run regressions on price and time-lagged

values of price. They estimate the time-lagged regression over short

time internals. They do this to detect, through examination of specific

terms in their lagged price model, unusual price changes. In technical

terms, they use a difference equation for lagged price with different

estimated values (i.e., coefficients) for different time-lagged price

variables. They then solve for the roots of that characteristic

equation and look for the eigenvalues (latent values) with absolute

value greater than one. They conclude that eigenvalue indicates that

the price of the commodity is in an ``exploding'' state or a

``bubble.'' \1654\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1654\ See, e.g., Goyal and Tripathi, Regulation and Price

Discovery: Oil Spot and Futures Markets at 15-16 (working paper

2012) (describing methodology in more detail).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Advantages and Disadvantages

This method can be applied after-the-fact to historical data to try

to ascertain whether past price changes constituted a ``bubble.'' Or it

can be applied to real-time data to predict whether a current state of

affairs is a ``bubble.'' For these reasons, some economists perceive,

as an advantage of this method, the ability through statistical means

to date and time ``bubbles'' in prices.

On the other hand, this method is based on a model and the results

of any analysis are only as strong as the model. The model is limited

to price data and a constant. Models using this technique do not permit

the study authors to include other explanatory variables. This is a

disadvantage because it is likely that there are variables of interest

other than lagged prices when considering whether price instability

exists. For example, someone interested in position limits would want

to include an explanatory variable such as speculative positions in the

regressions, but this technique does not permit this.

Further, the model allows for wide discretion in the number of

lagged prices used. The studies' authors often look at ``goodness of

fit'' results to determine how many lags to select, seeking to set the

model based upon the data. This step may make the model uniquely

tailored to a particular dataset but not easily applicable to another.

Put another way, selecting an important model feature based on testing

of the data runs the risk of a selection that is not based on any

theoretical or economic fact, but instead on ad hoc assumptions made by

the modelers and any idiosyncrasies of the dataset.\1655\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1655\ Even if there were not such problems, the methodology has

an insurmountable theoretical difficulty. The use of the ``unit

root'' test, as a part of this eigenvalue methodology, is an

inherently suspect way of identifying explosive price behavior. That

is because the unit root tests rely upon a small a set of

observations to approximate long-term price behavior.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iii. Analysis

Economists using this methodology attempt to find the existence of

price ``bubbles'' using eigenvalue stability methods. Three such papers

were

[[Page 96915]]

submitted.\1656\ All the authors find ``evidence'' of various

``bubbles.'' However, in none of these studies is there reasonable

empirical evidence to support the inferential leap between instability,

``bubbles,'' and excess speculation. In particular, for all of these

studies, there is no link made in the data between price instability

and positions. These studies do not use position data. The problem

inheres in the method, which, while purporting to detect the existence

of ``bubbles,'' does not permit the research to link supposed bubble to

speculative positions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1656\ These are: Phillips and Yu, Dating the Timeline of

Financial Bubbles During the Subprime Crisis, Quantitative Economics

(2011); Czudaj and Beckman, Spot and Futures Commodity Markets and

the Unbiasedness Hypothesis--Evidence from a Novel Panel Unit Root

Test, Economic Bulletin (2013); Gutierrez, Speculative Bubbles in

Agricultural Commodity Markets, European Review of Agricultural

Economics (2012) (Monte Carlo variant of eigenvalue stability

approach).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In modern markets, prices can change rapidly for many reasons. The

``explosion'' of a price over a short time interval does not

necessarily reflect uneconomic behavior or a price ``bubble.'' It could

simply represent a ``shock.'' That shock need not come from speculative

activity. The price path may not be smooth. For this reason, these

models are conceptually flawed when applied to commodity prices and

commodity futures prices.

For example, in Gilbert, Speculative Influences on Commodity

Futures Prices,\1657\ Gilbert uses a variant of this methodology in an

early section of his paper to find ``clear evidence'' of ``bubble

periods'' for copper and soybeans lasting days and weeks.\1658\ He

finds unexplained price increases in crude oil for periods of time that

are ``insufficient to qualify as bubbles.'' \1659\ Using just price

data, and not positions, Gilbert's attribution of lingering price

spikes cannot be attributed to speculative positions.\1660\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1657\ Gilbert, Speculative Influences on Commodity Futures

Prices, 2006-2008, UN Conference on Trade and Development (2010).

\1658\ Id. at 9 at ] iii.

\1659\ Id. at ] ii.

\1660\ This is perhaps why he proceeds to a Granger-based

analysis using position data in the second half of his paper.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

There is a subtler disadvantage that inheres in the inference

between the identification of price growth without bound and the

existence of a bubble. To examine intervals where a price series is

appearing to grow without bound and to infer that that implies a bubble

is problematic. A time series for price of an asset is unlikely to tend

to infinity because, eventually, this would likely lead to infeasible

prices (generally, in the absence of hyperinflation). We do not expect

the real price of an asset, which is the price is adjusted for

inflation, to grow without bound.

2. Theoretical Models

Some economic papers cited in this rulemaking perform little or no

empirical analysis and instead, present a general theoretical model

that may bear, directly or indirectly, on the effect of excessive

speculation in the commodity marketplace. Within the 26 theoretical

model papers in the administrative record, there is a subset of papers

which may be viewed as generally supportive or disapproving of position

limits. Because these papers do not include empirical analysis, they

contain many untested assumptions and conclusory statements. In the

specific context of academic analysis of position limits (as opposed to

policy formulation) theories are useful but must be tested empirically.

Theoretical Papers Directly or Indirectly Support Position Limits

Two studies presented theoretical models establishing the risk of

price manipulation in the derivatives markets, including cash-settled

contracts, suggesting that position limits might be particularly

helpful in cash-settled contracts.\1661\ A few studies presented

theoretical reasons why financial investors might increase or

``destabilize'' commodity futures prices \1662\ or the spot

price.\1663\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1661\ Kumar and Seppi, Futures Manipulation with ``Cash

Settlement'', Journal of Finance (1992) (while, without physical

delivery, corners and squeezes are infeasible, cash-settled

contracts are still susceptible to cash-to-futures price

manipulation, and this price manipulation transfers liquidity from

futures to cash markets); Dutt and Harris, Position Limits for Cash-

Settled Derivative Contracts, Journal of Futures Markets (2005)

(arguing that cash settled contracts appear to be particularly

susceptible to manipulation, but appearing to conflate SEC options

with CFTC-regulated commodity contracts).

\1662\ Lombardi and van Robays, Do Financial Investors

Destabilize the Oil Price? (working paper, European Central Bank,

2011) (giving theoretical grounds for the ability of financial

investors in futures to destabilize oil prices, but only in the

short run); Vansteenkiste, What is Driving Oil Price Futures?

Fundamentals Versus Speculation (working paper, European Central

Bank, 2011); Liu, Financial-Demand Based Commodity Pricing: A

Theoretical Model for Financialization of Commodities (working paper

2011).

\1663\ Schulmeister, Torero, and von Braun, Trading Practices

and Price Dynamics in Commodity Markets (working paper 2009)

(finding that price movements in crude oil and wheat are lengthened

and strengthened by ``speculation'' in respective futures prices).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Theoretical Studies Indirectly Criticizing at Least Some Position

Limits

On the other hand, there were theoretical papers that reached

conclusions which could be helpful to position limit skeptics, such as

the power of the marketplace to ``self-discipline'' would-be excessive

speculators.\1664\ Some papers offer theoretical grounds for the

concern that more restrictive or ``extreme'' position limits might

increase price volatility.\1665\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1664\ Pirrong, Manipulation of the Commodity Futures Market

Delivery Process, Journal of Business (1993); Pirrong, The Self-

Regulation of Commodity Exchanges: The Case of Market Manipulation,

Journal of Law and Economics (1995); Ebrahim and ap Gwilym, Can

Position Limits Restrain Rogue Traders?, at 832 Journal of Banking &

Finance (2013) (``Our results illustrate that excess speculation,

with or without the intent to manipulate the futures markets, is not

worthwhile for the speculator'' and concluding that position limits

are ``counterproductive'' because excessive speculation enriches

other market players at the expense of the speculator).

\1665\ Pliska and Shalen, The Effects of Regulation on Trading

Activity and Return Volatility in Futures Markets, at 148, Journal

of Futures Markets (2006) (``[W]ell-meaning regulatory policies can

be counterproductive by reducing the liquidity which is

characteristic of futures markets,'' including policies such as

``extreme margins and position limits''); Lee, Cheng and Koh, An

Analysis of Extreme Price Shocks and Illiquidity Among Systematic

Trend Followers (working paper 2010) (using an agent-based model and

assuming trend-followers in the market, finds no reason to believe

position limits will help as opposed to leading to erratic price

behavior).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Even these papers are not firm in their opposition. In The Self-

Regulation of Commodity Exchanges: The Case of Market Manipulation,

Journal of Law and Economics (1995),\1666\ Craig Pirrong (an economic

expert for ISDA/SIFMA in the position limits rulemaking) argues that

there ``is no strong theoretical or empirical reason to believe that

self-regulating exchanges effectively deter corners.'' \1667\ He simply

disagrees that other forms of regulation such as position limits

``could do better.'' \1668\ Pirrong does not discount the harm of price

manipulation. Pirrong's Manipulation of the Commodity Futures Market

Delivery Process,\1669\ documents these harms.\1670\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1666\ Pirrong, The Self-Regulation of Commodity Exchanges: The

Case of Market Manipulation, Journal of Law and Economics (1995).

\1667\ Id. at 143.

\1668\ Id. (asserting that position limits are ``excessively

costly'' and concluding that self-regulation, along with after-the-

fact civil and criminal penalties for manipulation, may be more

efficient, but this assertion is unaccompanied by quantitative

analysis or a detailed qualitative cost-benefit analysis).

\1669\ Pirrong's Manipulation of the Commodity Futures Market

Delivery Process, Journal of Business (1993).

\1670\ Id. at 363 (futures market manipulations ``distorts

prices and creates deadweight losses;'' ``causes shorts to utilize

real resources to make excessive deliveries;'' and ``distorts

consumption'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Other Theoretical Papers

A set of papers suggest that there can be excessive speculation in

oil without

[[Page 96916]]

a significant increase in crude oil inventories.\1671\ The remaining

theoretical papers in the administrative record focus on useful

economic background on price manipulation; \1672\ comovement effects in

the equity or options markets,\1673\ high-frequency trading,\1674\ or

other matters of marginal relevance.\1675\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1671\ Avriel and Reisman, Optimal Option Portfolios in Markets

with Position Limits and Margin Requirements, Journal of Risk (2000)

(a theoretical model suggesting that speculation may push crude oil

prices above the price level is justified by physical-market

fundamentals without necessarily resulting in a significant increase

in oil inventories); Pierru and Babusiaux, Speculation without Oil

Stockpiling as a Signature: A Dynamic Perspective (working paper

2010); Routledge, Seppi, and Spatt, Equilibrium Forward Curves for

Commodities, Journal of Finance (2000) (important work on the theory

of storage). See Parsons, Black Gold & Fool's Gold: Speculation in

the Oil Futures Market at 82, 106-107 (Economia 2009) (not a

theoretical model paper, but a survey piece, that indicates that if

oil prices were driven above the level determined by fundamental

factors of supply and demand by forces such as speculation, storage

would not necessarily increase; an argument that this would occur

``overlooks how paper oil markets have been transformed'' and

``successful innovations in the financial industry made it possible

for paper oil to be a financial asset in a very complete way'').

\1672\ Kyle and Viswanathan, How to Define Illegal Price

Manipulation, American Economic Review (2008); Westerhoff,

Speculative Markets and the Effectiveness of Price Limits, Journal

of Economic Dynamics and Control (2003) (discussing when price

limits can be welfare-improving).

\1673\ Dai, Jin and Liu, Illiquidity, Position Limits, and

Optimal Investment (working paper 2009); Edirsinghe, Naik, and

Uppal, Optimal Replication of Options with Transaction Costs and

Trading Restrictions, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis

(1993); Shleifer and Vishney, The Limits of Arbitrage, Journal of

Finance (1997).

\1674\ Schulmeister, Technical Trading and Commodity Price

Fluctuations (working paper 2012).

\1675\ Morris, Speculative Investor Behavior and Learning,

Quarterly Journal of Economics (1996); Kyle and Wang, Speculation

Duopoly with Agreement to Disagree: Can Overconfidence Survive the

Market Test?, Journal of Finance (1997); Leitner, Inducing Agents to

Report Hidden Trades: A Theory of an Intermediary, Review of Finance

(2012); Sockin and Xiong, Feedback Effects of Commodity Futures

Prices (working paper 2012); Froot, Scharfstein, and Stein, Herd on

the Street: Informational Inefficiencies in a Market with Short Term

Speculation (working paper 1990) (theoretical paper discussing

herding); Dicembrino and Scandizzo, The Fundamental and Speculative

Components of the Oil Spot Price: A Real Option Value (working paper

2012).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. Surveys and Opinions

The remaining 73 papers are survey pieces. Some of these papers

provide useful background material.\1676\ But on the whole, these

survey pieces offer opinion unsupported by rigorous empirical analysis.

These papers, if they presented statistics at all, presented

descriptive statistics. An inherent difficulty with this approach is

that the facts that the author presents to support the author's theory

may be incomplete and not fully representative of economic reality.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1676\ Basu and Gavin, What Explains the Growth in Commodity

Derivatives?, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (2011), provides an

excellent analysis of the factors driving rapid increases in volume

in commodity derivatives trading. See also Easterbrook, Monopoly,

Manipulation, and the Regulation of Futures Markets, Journal of

Business (1986); Pirrong, Squeezes, Corners, and the Anti-

Manipulation Provisions of the Commodity Exchange Act, Regulation

(1994).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

While they may be useful for developing hypotheses, they often

exhibit policy bias and are not neutral, reliable bases for judgments

in the academic context (again, as opposed to the judgments of

policymakers).\1677\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1677\ For example, a CME Group white paper, Excessive

Speculation and Position Limits in Energy Derivatives Markets

(undated), lacks empirical data or other economically valid

supporting analysis. It also uses confusing terminology. For

example, CME quotes a Wall Street Journal survey of economists,

which in turn summarily concludes: ``[t]he global surge in food and

energy prices is being driven primarily by fundamental market

conditions, rather than an investment bubble.'' Id. at p.5. Even

economists who find some price impact from outsized speculative

positions would not disagree that, in the main, prices remain

determined ``primarily'' by market fundamentals. And many of these

economists finding price impact would not ascribe the result to an

``investment bubble.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

We have reviewed all 73 papers in this category and discuss below

only those few that add marginal value to the empirical analyses

discussed above.

a. Frenk and Turbeville (Better Markets)

Frenk and Turbeville, in Commodity Index Traders and the Boom/Bust

Cycle in Commodities Prices,\1678\ present a survey of economic

literature that incorporates some empirical testing for the price

impact of index fund ``rolling'' of commodity index fund positions.

Rolling refers to the time when commodity index funds, such as those

tracking a popular commodity index such as the Standard & Poor's

Goldman Sachs Commodity Index (GSCI), must roll forward their expiring

futures contracts to maintain their (typically long) positions.\1679\

Frenk and Turbeville argue that the index fund roll ``systematically

distorts forward commodities futures price curves toward a contango

\1680\ state, which is likely to contribute to speculative `boom/bust'

cycles. . . .'' \1681\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1678\ Frenk and Turbeville, Commodity Index Traders and the

Boom/Bust Cycle in Commodities Prices (Better Markets 2011).

\1679\ See id. at 8-9 for a description of the mechanics of the

roll. See also Mou, Limits to Arbitrage and Commodity Index

Investment: Front-Running the Goldman Roll (working paper 2011).

\1680\ See id. at 5-6 for a description of contango, an upward-

sloping forward price curve for a commodity. Market participants may

view contango as evidence that commodity prices will increase in the

future.

\1681\ Id. at 2. See id. at 4 (focusing on crude oil and wheat

price spreads before, during, and after the role from January 1983

to June 2011).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

This set of inferences is problematic for several reasons. First,

it depends on the current existence of a price impact from rolling. Yet

the roll price impact is a market phenomenon that may no longer be as

substantial as it once was. The market now has general knowledge of the

influx of commodity index traders and their established rolling

behavior. Moreover, many ETFs announce in their prospectus how they

will trade, and most large exchange-traded funds now ``sunshine'' their

rolls: To announce to the market in advance when and how they will

roll.\1682\ These trends have lessened the price impact of the rolls.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1682\ Otherwise, other market participants may assume that the

rolling activity reflects an informed trader reacting to market

fundamentals and the roll could well impair the price discovery

function of the commodities market. See Urbanchuk, Speculation and

the Commodity Markets, at p. 12 (working paper 2011) (``traders can

misinterpret an index inflow as a bullish statement by a trader with

superior information''). While not every large institutional trader

has to ``sunshine,'' those that announce their rolling timing in

their prospectus are bound by SEC rules to follow their prospectus

procedures.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Moreover, the Frenk and Turbeville article ascribes the contango

state of commodity futures prices to the price impact of roll without

empirical analysis to support a causal link. There has historically

been an alternation between contango and backwardation in the crude oil

commodity market: This phenomenon has been attributed to changes in

short-term supply or demand, increased market participation on the long

side to earn the risk premium associated with going long, and other

reasons, but not the technical aspects of commodity index rolls.\1683\

Frenk and Turbeville's article is unpersuasive in ascribing large boom/

bust cycles in price to waning and temporary price impacts of rolls.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1683\ See Parsons, Black Gold & Fool's Gold: Speculation in the

Oil Futures Market, at 99-101, Economia (2009) (discussing crude oil

market economics that explain why crude oil futures prices are

sometimes in contango); id. at 101 (``Although oil futures fluctuate

between backwardation and contango, on average they have been

backwarded'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several other survey papers posit the existence of a speculative

bubble in price due to speculation along the lines of the Frenk and

Tuberville article. But these studies also do not present an empirical

analysis to support this conclusion.\1684\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1684\ See, e.g., Cooper, Excessive Speculation and Oil Price

Shock Recessions: A Case of Wall Street ``D[eacute]j[agrave] vu all

over again'', Consumer Federation of America (2011); Berg, The Rise

of Commodity Speculation: From Villainous to Venerable (UN FAO

2011); Eckaus, The Oil Price Really Is a Speculative Bubble, at p.8,

MIT Center for Energy and Env'l Research (2008) (``there is no

reason based on current and expected supply and demand that

justifies the current price of oil''); Parsons, Black Gold & Fool's

Gold: Speculation in the Oil Futures Market, Economia (2009)

(explaining why, on a theoretical level, the absence of large crude

oil inventories does not preclude a crude oil price bubble); Tokic,

Rational destabilizing speculation, positive feedback trading, and

the oil bubble of 2008, Energy Economics (2011) (survey with

theoretical model adjunct). See also Urbanchuk, Speculation and the

Commodity Markets, at 8-9 (working paper 2011) (observing that the

share of corn futures held by commercial traders has fallen from

more than 70 percent in January 2005 to about 40 percent in August

2011); id. at 12 (arguing that speculators are a major factor behind

the sharp increase in the level and volatility of corn prices in

2011 because ``traders can misinterpret an index inflow as a bullish

statement by a trader with superior information''); Inamura, Kimata,

et al., Recent Surge in Global Commodity Prices (Bank of Japan

Review March 2011) (contending that global monetary policies have

tended to boost commodity prices).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96917]]

b. Senate Reports

i. Senate Report on Oil and Gas Prices

The U.S. Senate staff report on oil prices concludes that increased

participation by speculators in the energy commodity futures markets

has had an effect on energy prices.\1685\ Other survey pieces assert

that market fundamentals fully explain commodity price spikes.\1686\

These survey articles do not present rigorous statistical models to

support their competing conclusions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1685\ The Role of Market Speculation in Rising Oil and Gas

Prices: A Need to Put the Cop Back on the Beat, Permanent

Subcommittee on Investigations of the U.S. Senate Committee on

Homeland Security and Governmental Affairs at pp. 19-32 (June 27,

2006) (``Senate Report on oil and gas prices'').

\1686\ See, e.g., Plante and Y[uuml]cel, Did Speculation Drive

Oil Prices? Futures Market Points to Fundamentals (Federal Reserve

Bank of Dallas Econ. Ltr. Oct. 2011) (if speculating were the cause

of crude oil spokes, it would ``leave telltale signs in certain

data, such as inventories'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Senate report points out that fundamental supply and demand

were factors increasing energy prices.\1687\ But it determines that

these factors ``do not tell the whole story.'' \1688\ It asserts that

the large purchases of crude oil futures contractors by financial

speculators ``have, in effect, created an additional demand for oil. .

. .'' \1689\ The report acknowledges that the price effect is

``difficult to quantify,'' and cites unspecified analysts on estimated

price impact.\1690\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1687\ The Role of Market Speculation in Rising Oil and Gas

Prices: A Need to Put the Cop Back on the Beat at p.12.

\1688\ Id. at 13.

\1689\ Id.

\1690\ Id. at 14. See id. at 23.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

But in the general economics of the futures market, demand for

futures contracts does not necessarily increase the demand for, or

price of, the physical commodity. In the particular context of the

crude oil markets, as discussed above, demand for ``paper oil'' may not

directly translate into spot price impact due to storage

economics.\1691\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1691\ See Parsons, Black Gold & Fool's Gold: Speculation in the

Oil Futures Market, Economia (2009); n.1491, supra. Contra Senate

Report on oil and gas prices at 13 (``As far as the market is

concerned, the demand for a barrel of oil that results from the

purchase of a futures contract by a speculator is just as real as

the demand for a barrel that results from a purchase of a futures

contract by a refiner'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Regarding price effect, the Senate report relies on anecdotal

evidence because of the difficulty in quantification. The Senate report

cites reports from energy industry participants that financial

speculators have caused the price of oil to rise.\1692\ The report also

acknowledges that analyses of the effect of speculation on these energy

markets have reached divergent conclusions.\1693\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1692\ Senate Report on oil and gas prices at 22 (claiming that

financial investors have created ``runaway demand''), 24 n. 128

(traders assert cross-market arbitrage in energy between futures and

over-the-counter markets may be driving speculative pressure).

\1693\ Id. at 24, 26 (observing that Goldman Sachs issued a

report concluding that speculators were impacting crude oil prices,

peaking at $7 per barrel in the spring of 2004, and that industry

traders and CFTC staff in a 2005 analysis disagreed as to whether a

speculative price was caused by financial speculators).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Senate Report does not analyze how position limits would

ameliorate the problem it identifies. While not all the speculators

referenced in this report would be affected by a position limit rule,

the Senate Report does list Brian Hunter, then a trader in natural gas

for Amaranth Advisors hedge fund, among the top 2005 energy

traders.\1694\ These reports, which include factual recitation and

anecdotal evidence, contain no models or methods that can be audited by

economists.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1694\ Id. at p.30.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Senate Report on Wheat

The Senate staff report concerning wheat \1695\ surveys economic

literature and certain market data, but, like the Senate Report on oil

and gas prices, this report does not use statistical or theoretical

models to reach an economically rigorous conclusion. The Senate wheat

report does include anecdotal evidence: Virtually all of the commercial

traders interviewed by the Senate staff ``identified the large presence

of index traders in the Chicago market as a major cause'' of a problem

with price convergence in wheat in 2008.\1696\ The staff report states

that the demand for wheat futures contracts has itself increased the

price of wheat futures contracts relative to the cash market for wheat:

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1695\ Excessive Speculation in the Wheat Market, Majority and

Minority Staff Report, Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations of

the U.S. Senate, Committee on Homeland Security and Governmental

Affairs (June 24, 2009).

\1696\ Excessive Speculation in the Wheat Market at 11-12.

These index traders, who buy wheat futures contracts and hold

them without regard to the fundamentals of supply and demand in the

cash market for wheat, have created a significant additional demand

for wheat futures contracts that has as much as doubled the overall

demand for wheat futures contracts. Because this significant

increase in demand in the futures market is unrelated to any

corresponding supply or demand in the cash market, the price of

wheat futures contracts has risen relative to the price of wheat in

the cash market. The very large number of index traders on the

Chicago exchange has, thus, contributed to ``unwarranted changes''

in the prices of wheat futures relative to the price of wheat in the

cash market. These ``unwarranted changes'' have, in turn,

significantly impaired the ability of farmers and other grain

businesses to price crops and manage price risks over time, thus

creating an undue burden on interstate commerce. The activities of

these index traders constitute the type of excessive speculation

that the CFTC should diminish or prevent through the imposition and

enforcement of position limits as intended by the Commodity Exchange

Act.\1697\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1697\ Id. at 12.

However, there are other reasons that can also explain this 2008 price

divergence. The CME wheat contract was poorly designed to account for

the cost of storage, and this has been cited as a reason for the price

divergence between futures and spot wheat contracts during the 2008

time period. When CME revised its wheat contract, this price divergence

dissipated.\1698\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1698\ See supra note 1547. When CME revised its wheat contract,

this price divergence dissipated. The futures wheat contract, at

expiration, had a valuable real option to store the wheat at a

below-market price. This may have been a primary reason why it was

more valuable at expiration than spot wheat.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

That said, the more formal statistical studies discussed throughout

establish rationales for concern with index traders that are grounded

in more rigorous economic reasoning. There are circumstances when a

large volume of financial index investment flows may causes market

prices to deviate from fundamental values.\1699\ Alternatively, a

[[Page 96918]]

classical economist would argue that prices are still determined by

supply and demand, but that the aggregate risk appetite for financial

assets affects the demand for commodities through a more complicated

process than previously envisioned.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1699\ See Aulerich, Irwin, and Garcia, Bubbles, Food Prices,

and Speculation: Evidence from the CFTC's Daily Large Trader Data

Files, at pp.2-3, NBER Conference on Economics of Food Price

Volatility (2012) (summarizing that this could happen when (1) the

futures market is insufficiently liquid to absorb large order flow,

(2) the index traders are in effect noise traders who make arbitrage

risky, or (3) large order flow on the long side of the market is

seen erroneously as traders taking bullish positions based on

valuable information about market fundamentals). See id. at pp.3-4

(observing contrasting findings depending on impact of index trading

depending on liquidity of the agricultural commodity market);

Singleton, Investor Flows and the 2008 Boom/Bust in Oil Prices, at

5-8 (March 23, 2011 working paper) (learning about economic

fundamentals with heterogeneous information may induce excessive

price volatility, drift in commodity prices, and a tendency towards

booms and busts); Tang and Xiong, Index Investment and

Financialization of Commodities, at p.30, Financial Analysts Journal

(2012) (``the price of an individual commodity is no longer simply

determined by its supply and demand''); id. at 29-30 (``Instead,

prices are also determined by a whole set of financial factors such

as the aggregate risk appetite for financial assets'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For reasons similar to the Senate Report on Oil and Gas Prices, the

Senate Report on Wheat is less useful to an academic than it may be to

policymakers.

iii. Senate Report on Natural Gas

A similar analysis applies to the Senate report on natural gas,

Excessive Speculation in the Natural Gas Market. The report, which

focuses at length on Amaranth's natural gas trading, does not include a

statistical analysis of empirical data and, as the minority report

notes, some `` facts . . . support the conclusion that Amaranth's

trading activity was the primary cause of'' natural gas price spikes,''

but other facts point to market fundamentals.\1700\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1700\ Id. at 135 (while price of natural gas declined after

Amaranth's demise, ``this alone does not prove Amaranth's ability to

elevate prices above supply and demand fundamentals'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The report does argue that if Amaranth's large-scale speculative

trading was causing ``large jumps in the price differences'' and prices

that were ``ridiculous,'' \1701\ the current regulatory regime would be

unable to prevent this price disruption.\1702\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1701\ Id. at 3.

\1702\ Id. at 3 (NYMEX exchange did not have routine access to

Amaranth's trading positions on ICE, and therefore NYMEX could not

have a complete and accurate view of whether ``a trader's position .

. . is too large.'' In addition, there were no accountability limits

on the ICE exchange).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

4. Comments That Consist of Economic Studies or Discuss Economics in

Depth

Several comment letters perform substantial summary analysis of

other economic studies bearing on position limits, present original

economic analysis or formal economic studies. These submissions thus

warrant individual analysis. The following submissions are summarized

and analyzed in this section:

(A) the February 10, 2014, comment letter by Markus Henn of World

Economic, Ecology & Development, including, as an attachment, a

November 26, 2013, list of studies entitled ``Evidence on the Negative

Impact of Commodity Speculation by Academics, Analysis and Public

Institutions'' (``Henn Letter''); \1703\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1703\ See Letter from Markus Henn, World Economic, Ecology &

Development, to CFTC (Feb. 10, 2014), available at http://comments.cftc.gov/PublicComments/ViewComment.aspx?id=59628&SearchText=henn. See also, Markus Henn,

Evidence on the Negative Impact of Commodity Speculation by

Academics, Analysis and Public Institutions, (Nov. 26, 2013),

available at http://comments.cftc.gov/PublicComments/ViewComment.aspx?id=59628&SearchText=henn.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

(B) the analysis of Philip K. Verleger of the economic consulting

firm PKVerleger LLC, attached as Annex A to the February 10, 2014

comment letter by the International Swaps and Derivatives Association

(ISDA) and the Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association

(SIFMA) (``2/10/14 ISDA/SIFMA Comment Letter'');

(C) the analysis of Craig Pirrong, Professor of Finance at the

University of Houston Business School, attached as Annex B to the 2/10/

14 ISDA/SIFMA Comment Letter;

(D) two studies by Sanders and Irwin, The ``Necessity'' of New

Position Limits in Agricultural Futures Markets: The Verdict from Daily

Firm-Level Position Data (working paper 2014), and Energy Futures

Prices and Commodity Index Investment: New Evidence from Firm-Level

Position Data (working paper 2014);

(E) two studies by Hamilton and Wu, Effects of Index-Fund Investing

on Commodity Futures Prices, International Economic Review, Vol. 56,

No. 1 (February 2015), and Risk Premia in Crude Oil Futures Prices,

Journal of International Money and Finance (2013) (submitted as second

paper in the same electronic comment submission); and

(F) materials that CME Group submitted for inclusion in the

administrative record, include 3 sets of materials submitted on March

28, 2011 (first set, second set, and third set); an undated CME study

on conditional spot-month limits; and a CME Group's white paper,

Excessive Speculation and Position Limits in Energy Derivatives

Markets.\1704\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1704\ The CME white paper, while technically not submitted

formally by CME in the administrative record, warrants

individualized analysis. It is cited in the Commission's December

2013 Position Limits Proposal; it is posted on the CME Group's Web

site; and it is cited in arguments by such commenters as MFA. (MFA

February 9, 2014 comment letter at 11-12, n.26).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. The Markus Henn List of Studies

Markus Henn's February 10, 2014, comment letter acknowledges that

there is an ongoing debate about whether speculators can dominate a

marketplace and exacerbate market volatility and market prices. He

nonetheless asks the Commission to take into account a list of studies

he submits with his letter. He then presents numerous economic studies

as well as media articles.

As a group, this list of studies, opinion pieces, and news articles

documents the existence of concern and suspicion about large

speculative positions in commodity markets. Many of the studies cited

by the Henn Letter look for evidence of financialization and in this

sense suffer from interpretational bias.\1705\ As a group, these

opinion pieces and studies do not consistently seek alternative

explanations for their conclusions. As Markus Henn acknowledges in his

cover letter, these papers are part of an ongoing debate among

economists, not conclusive evidence of the harmful effects of excessive

speculation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1705\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Three of the most persuasive papers, persuasive insofar as they

employ well-accepted, defensible, scientific methodology, document and

present facts and results that can be replicated, and are on point

regarding issues relevant to position limits, cited in the Henn Letter

involve the crude oil market during the financial crisis: Singleton,

Investor Flows and the 2008 Boom/Bust in Oil Prices (March 23, 2011

working paper); \1706\ Hamilton and Wu, Risk Premia in Crude Oil

Futures Prices, Journal of International Money and Finance (2013) (an

earlier working paper version is cited by Henn); and Hamilton, Causes

and Consequences of the Oil Shock of 2007-2008, Brookings Paper on

Economic Activity (2009). The first two conclude that there is a

statistical link between the volume of speculative positions and a

component of price, risk premium, at least for some commodities in some

timeframes. Hamilton's Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of

2007-2008 concludes that the oil price run-up was caused by strong

demand confronting stagnating world production, but the price collapse

was perhaps not driven by fundamentals.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1706\ Markus Henn cites the 2011 version of the Singleton

paper, which is the only version of this paper in the administrative

record. A subsequent May 2012 version is available from Professor

Singleton's Stanford Web site at http://web.stanford.edu/~kenneths/.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96919]]

b. Verleger's Analysis, Attached to ISDA/SIFMA Comment Letter

Philip K. Verleger provided an analysis as a retained expert for

ISDA. Annex A to the 2/10/14 ISDA/SIFMA Comment Letter. He contends,

without quantitative modelling or empirical evidence, that in the

energy markets ``unwarranted price fluctuations'' have historically

been due to ``confluence of contributing factors'' such as weather,

geopolitical events, or changes in industry structure. 2/10/14 ISDA/

SIFMA Comment Letter, Annex A at pp. 2-3. In passing, he opines,

without analysis or citation, that the high energy prices in 2008 ``are

attributable to environmental regulation.'' Id. Verleger also asserts

that his expertise is in the energy markets, yet opines (contrary to

many comment letters from other energy market participants) that the

energy markets are ``subject to conditions and dynamics'' of other

commodity markets. Id. at p.2. For these reasons, we view Verleger's

analysis as weak and conclusory and lacking in economic rigor and

empirical data.

By way of further example, Verleger contends that if the position

limits rule had been in effect in 2013, oil prices would have been $15

per barrel higher and the cost to American consumers would have been

roughly $100 billion. Annex A at p.3. He provides no quantitative

reasoning in support of these numbers.\1707\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1707\ Verleger argues that limits in the non-spot month would

have an especially chilling effect, ``very likely leading to, among

other things, higher energy prices;'' and that position limits

should not apply to cash-settled markets because traders holding

cash-settled contracts do not have any ability to influence the

physical market prices of commodities. Id. at 2-3. Pirrong also

makes these arguments but provides further analysis, so we discuss

this critique in subsection C below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Verleger also asserts that exploration for sources of energy has

resulted in a large increase in oil supply in recent years, and states

that these companies use swaps and futures to hedge their position. Id.

at p.7. He then summarily asserts that independent companies exploring

for and developing oil and gas production would ``not have achieved

this success without hedging'' and that hedging would not have occurred

if the Commission's position limits had been in place. Id. at p.8.

Verleger overlooks several critical facts.

First, companies actively engaged in oil and gas exploration might

either qualify for bona fide hedging treatment or fall within the

position limit. As to non-spot month limits, Verleger concedes that

``it may be argued that the initial non-spot month position limits are

high enough (109,000 contracts for crude as an example)'' to avoid

liquidity impacts. Id. at 12.\1708\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1708\ See Berg, The Rise of Commodity Speculation: From

Villainous to Venerable, at p.263 (UN FAO 2011) (former CBOT trader

suggests that spot month limit positions should be in place for at

least a few days in the non-spot months to lesson price distortions

from the roll).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Second, he argues that these exploration companies have ``benefited

indirectly because passive investors such as retirement funds have

taken long positions in commodities through the swap markets,'' and

suggests that with position limits there would be an absence of non-

commercials to take positions opposite oil and gas development

companies. Id. at 9. To the contrary, with the Commission's

disaggregation exemption for managed funds (the independent account

controller exemption), there is no basis to believe that there will be

a shortage of long positions in the market. He presents no empirical

evidence to support his thesis that position limits could thus

``adversely affect[ ] investment in the oil and gas industry.'' \1709\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1709\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Third, the way energy derivatives markets work, if there is demand

on the short side of the market, this may create liquidity on the long

side of the market to transact with at some price. Verleger himself

notes the diversity of market participants--commodity-based exchange-

traded funds, hedge funds, retirement funds, and the like--and does not

document that the exclusion of a particular long would reduce liquidity

from the marketplace. For example, commodity-based exchange-traded

funds trade intermediate long positions for their investors, and if the

funds themselves could not take long positions in the market, there is

no reason to assume that the investors might through other vehicles

take long positions. Verleger has an expressed fear, not an analysis,

that liquidity in markets will be harmed by position limits.\1710\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1710\ See, e.g., id. at 12 (after observing that non-spot month

limits are high enough to perhaps not impact the market, stating

that non-spot limits will ``adversely affect the ability of

commercial participants to use some futures market'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

c. Pirrong's Analysis, Attached to ISDA/SIFMA Comment Letter

Professor Pirrong agrees that the nation's commodity markets have

been subject to significant and disruptive corners and squeezes, such

as the Hunt Silver episode of 1979-1980.\1711\ He concedes that the

``ability of position limits to prevent corners and squeezes could

provide a justification for application of these limits during the spot

month,'' at least in theory.\1712\ He concedes that in theory there is

such a thing as ``sudden and unwarranted price fluctuations.'' \1713\

Subject to these concessions, Pirrong opposes many aspects of the rule.

Overall, Pirrong argues that position limits are an undesirable

solution to an economic problem that has not been proven to

exist.\1714\ We analyze below his objections only when and to the

extent that they rest on economic arguments.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1711\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611, Annex B, at 2, ]] 6-9.

\1712\ Id. at ] 7.

\1713\ Id. at 6, ] 27.

\1714\ Id. at pp. 3-10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

i. Amaranth and the Possible Utility of Position Limits in Non-Spot

Months

Pirrong states that the possibility of a corner or a squeeze

``provides no justification of the necessity of imposing position

limits outside the spot month.'' \1715\ Pirrong argues that Amaranth's

market activity in 2006 is not evidence of the utility of position

limits in the non-spot month. Id. at p.2, ] 7. In this context, Pirrong

discusses corners and squeezes as the rationale for non-spot month

position limits. Id. However, the Commission's December 2013 Position

Limits Proposal discusses rationales other than corners and squeezes:

Economic factors such as outsized market power, disorderly liquidation,

and the ability to manipulate prices.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1715\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611, Annex B, at p.2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the context of non-spot month position limits, Pirrong focusses

just on corners and squeezes. If that were the only regulatory concern,

his analysis on this, see id. at ]] 27-30, would be largely correct.

Many traders exit futures contracts before the spot month because they

are there for the exposure, for price risk transfer, not to make or

take delivery.

One key reason why ETFs ``sunshine-trade'' their rolls--announcing

in their prospectus when they will roll--is because rolling these large

positions in non-spot months can have a price impact, apart from

corners and squeezes.\1716\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1716\ Sanders and Irwin, The ``Necessity'' of New Position

Limits in Agricultural Futures Markets: The Verdict from Daily Firm-

Level Position Data, at p.19 (working paper 2014) (preannounced

trades can have a ``sunshine trading'' effect of increasing

liquidity and lowering trading costs). See, e.g., Frenk and

Turbeville, Commodity Index Traders and the Boom/Bust Cycle in

Commodities Prices (Better Markets 2011) (very large institutional

players rolls have had a temporary price impact that is expensive to

the ETF investors).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A good example of the risk of price impact in non-spot months from

outsized positions, apart from corners

[[Page 96920]]

and squeezes, is Amaranth. Amaranth's position was so large that it may

have impacted price by virtue of its outsized market position in not

just the spot month, but other months. Amaranth may have influenced

prices not just upon liquidation, not just when banging the close in

the spot month, but also well before then, according to a congressional

study cited in the Commission's December 2013 Position Limits

Proposal.\1717\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1717\ There have been other examples of price manipulations

that extended over a period of months. See CFTC staff, A Study of

the Silver Market, Report To The Congress In Response To Section 21

Of The Commodity Exchange Act, Part One at 2-4, 9-10 (May 29, 1981)

(price of silver rose and fell over a period of months, with long

futures positions in silver held by members of the Hunt family in

the summer and fall of 1979 and prices peaking in late January 1980,

and prices falling though the first quarter of 1980); id., Part Two

at p.100 (``behavior of silver prices during 1979-80 appears

consistent with, but is not entirely explained by, fundamental

developments in the silver market over this period''); p.112 (Hunt

family acquired actual and potential control of approximately 18

percent of world silver market and stood for delivery on a

significant portion of their futures contracts, causing silver

prices to rise significantly).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

An economist could argue that because the commodity futures price

should reflect all demand, Amaranth's very large positions in the non-

spot month was appropriately incorporated in market prices. After all,

at a given point in time and price, demand is defined as the quantity

desired by all those who are willing and able to hold a commodity

futures position. Prof. Pirrong's approach does conceive of the

possibility that outsized market power in the non-spot month or the

price impact of Amaranth's positions could have deleterious effects on

the marketplace. From a classical economical perspective, Amaranth's

outsized market position in the non-spot months is just an input into

price demand.

However, outsized market power may have economic outcomes that are

undesirable. Outsized market power permits a player to do more than

``bang the close,'' and Amaranth's natural gas trading is an example of

this. One could influence prices in the swaps market through such

aggregation of market powers or one could manipulate related markets.

Amaranth's exercise of market power may have been real and substantial.

Even after it left the natural gas market, its activities may have left

a lasting price effect. That is, prices of the underlying commodity,

natural gas, may have been higher when Amaranth was in the market

(including in the non-spot months), and prices were substantially less

for a substantial time period after Amaranth left the market.\1718\

Pirrong's discussion of Amaranth does not address this economic history

or its possible relevance to non-spot position limits. Although Pirrong

criticizes the Commission for not engaging in a ``rigorous empirical

analysis'' of Amaranth (2/10/14 ISDA/SIFMA Comment Letter, Annex B, at

p.2, ] 10), the establishment of outsized market power in economics is

more straight forward in the case of Amaranth. The question is whether

the disappearance of an Amaranth from the market with its formerly

outsized position led to a significant decline in price.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1718\ This observation presumes no other confounding events

such as the occurrence of warmer winter. Unfortunately, we do not

know whether or not the lower price resulted from the exit of

Amaranth, the warmer winter, something else, or some combination of

the preceding.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

By focusing simply on Amaranth's activities in the spot month,

Prof. Pirrong does not discuss the potential for harm arising from

Amaranth's outsized positions in the non-spot month. If someone is

exerting market power, they can cause a negative externality for other

purchases of natural gas if they, for example, bid up the price of

natural gas. A higher price for a natural gas purchaser due to another

entity's trading may simply be an example of a healthy market at work.

However, there is definite harm to purchasers of natural gas if the

price they pay is higher for reasons that are associated with another

market participant's price influence though the exertion of market

power.

Pirrong does not provide a direct factual rebuttal to the Senate

investigative report finding that Amaranth's speculative activity

affected overall price levels in natural gas. He argues that the

Commission's reliance upon a Senate investigatory report would not be

``accepted as evidence of causation in any peer reviewed academic

work.'' \1719\ Id. at 2, ] 9. Prof. Pirrong is correct that the

Commission has not, in the case of Amaranth, shown causation: That it

was Amaranth's departure from the markets that caused the natural gas

price decline in substantial part, as opposed to confounding factors

(such as, in the case of natural gas, evidence that the upcoming winter

would be warmer than expected). However, proof of causation is not

required for publication in peer reviewed journals in a case such as

this.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1719\ Id. at 2, ] 9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

To establish evidence of causation, one would need a theoretical

model and empirical evidence to support it. There have been peer-

reviewed studies on Amaranth such as one cited in the Commission's

December 2013 Position Limits Proposal.\1720\ That study observed that

not just a Senate investigatory committee, but one of the exchanges

that Amaranth was trading on, was alarmed by their exercise of market

power in months prior to the spot months. The New York Mercantile

Exchange (NYMEX) on August 9, 2006: \1721\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1720\ See Ludwig Chincarini, Natural Gas Futures and Spread

Position Risk: Lessons from the Collapse of Amaranth Advisors LLC,

Journal of Applied Finance (2008).

\1721\ Id. at p.24.

called Amaranth with continued concern about the September 2006

contract and warned that October 2006 was large as well and they

should not simply reduce the September exposure by shifting

contracts to the October contract. In fact, by the close of business

that day, Amaranth increased their October 2006 position by 17,560

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

positions and their ICE positions by 105.75

This study documents that even though many of the Amaranth

positions were not with NYMEX, and instead with ICE, these positions

were extremely large relative to the average daily trading volume of

the largest natural gas futures exchange. ``In some cases, the

positions are hundreds of times the 30-day average daily trading

volume.'' \1722\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1722\ Id. at p.22.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Pirrong also argues as a normative matter that the costs exceed the

benefits. While he concedes that it is ``plausible'' that a sudden

liquidation of a large position by a trader facing distress'' could

``cause sudden and unwarranted price fluctuations,'' he argues that

there is ``no evidence that this problem occurs with sufficient

frequency, or has sufficiently damaging effects, to warrant

continuously imposed constraints on risk transfer.'' Id. at 6, ] 27.

The Commission considers the costs and benefits formally elsewhere in

this release.

ii. The Possible Harms of Corners and Squeezes

Pirrong also questions the extent of harm associated with

activities such as the Hunt brothers. 2/10/14 ISDA/SIFMA Comment

Letter, Annex B, at pp. 2-3. He downplays the harms of corners and

squeezes. Id. at ]] 11-12, 38-43.

Prof. Pirrong is incorrect in asserting that the Commission's view

was groundless. In the December 2013 Position Limits Proposal, the

Commission did ground its concern about outsized speculative positions

in particular examples. The Commission did present evidence of

inefficient resource allocation with respect to the Hunt brothers. It

is as much a public

[[Page 96921]]

policy matter as an economic matter how position limits fare as a

solution to the question of these negative externalities. Even if one

assumes away the existence of market imperfections, as Pirrong does,

one is still left to contend with the consequences of what Pirrong

assumes to be natural market events. In the case of the Hunt brothers,

the Commission gave multiple examples of negative externalities in the

broader economy. People sold their silverware which was melted down

into silver bars. A photo supply company dependent on silver supply

went out of business.\1723\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1723\ December 2013 Position Limits Proposal 78 FR at 75680,

75689.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Pirrong's assumption that persons act optimally at any given moment

does not mean, across time, that resources have been allocated

efficiently. While much of economic analysis is static, dynamic effects

over time can have inefficient allocation of resources,

intertemporally. It may have been optimal for a possessor of silverware

to melt down their silver into silver bars during the Hunt silver

market disruption, but just a few months later a possessor of

silverware would likely prefer silverware to silver bars. See Pirrong's

Manipulation of the Commodity Futures Market Delivery Process, at p.

383, Journal of Business (1993) (futures market manipulations

``distorts prices and creates deadweight losses;'' ``causes shorts to

utilize real resources to make excessive deliveries;'' and ``distorts

consumption'').

Pirrong thus errs in asserting that the Commission does not provide

an ``empirical basis'' for ``inefficient allocation of resources.'' 2/

10/14 ISDA/SIFMA Comment Letter, Annex B, at p.3.

iii. Claim That the Spot-Month Limits Are Arbitrary

Pirrong claims that spot month limits are set too low at 25 percent

of deliverable supply. Id. at p.8, ]] 38-40. He contends that a single

long trader has to control over 50 percent of deliverable supply to

perfect a corner. Id. at ] 40. He is incorrect. Assuming, quite

reasonably, that long commercials are going to stay in the market and

consume, because it would be very expensive for them to leave the

market, a certain percentage of deliverable supply is ``locked up'' in

this sense. For example, a natural gas utility needs to deliver natural

gas for its customers to heat their homes (among other things) and

would therefore still take delivery of a substantial percentage of the

deliverable supply of natural gas.

Pirrong says that ``[f]ive or more perfectly colluding traders each

with positions at the 25 percent level might be able to manipulate the

market.'' Id. at p.8, ] 41. However, these five traders do not all need

to collude in order to permit one of them to manipulate price. Some of

these traders may simply be those who value the commodity highly, much

higher than the market price, and therefore will not let go of their

contractual right to delivery. Such commercials may be willing to stay

and pay a higher price, even when a corner is in effect, because the

cost, for example, of not providing natural gas to customers to heat

their homes is substantially more.

Many exchanges, including CME, set position limits lower than 25

percent. It is hard for Pirrong to argue that 25 percent is excessively

low when it is higher than CME limits for all of the 19 CME-traded

commodities covered by the proposed CFTC position limits.

Pirrong's final critique of spot month limits is his assertion that

application of the same limits to short and long positions is

arbitrary. Id. at p.9, ]] 42-43. The reasons he gives for this are

problematic and not well-developed. Pirrong states that for storable

commodities, manipulation by long traders is more likely than with

short traders. Id., ] 42. It may well be more difficult to manipulate

price through a corner or squeeze as a short because there is generally

a fixed limit for deliverable supply (unless one creates the impression

that there is more deliverable supply than there is). Moreover, shorts

may well have a bona fide hedging exemption anyway. However, for shorts

as well as longs, position limits help to ensure an orderly exit and a

smoother delivery process. For example, a short trader with a large

position might take a partially offsetting long position in an illiquid

market in the spot month; this might cause unwarranted price volatility

due to the price impact of establishing the offsetting long position.

Pirrong criticizes the depth of the Commission's basis for treating

short and long positions symmetrically, he also does not suggest an

alternative or explain how a proper ratio should be calculated.\1724\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1724\ Pirrong argues that the Commission's cost-benefit

analysis fails to identify, let alone analyze, important potential

costs. 2/10/14 ISDA/SIFMA Comment Letter, Annex B, at 4-6. The

Commission addresses all commenter criticisms in the cost-benefit

section of this release. Pirrong also argues that the Commission's

bona fide hedging exemptions are unnecessarily narrow and critiques

the Commission's decision to establish different position limits for

cash-settled (as opposed to delivery-settled) contracts. The

Commission addresses such comments in the relevant sections of this

release.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iv. Whether Position Limits Cause Economic Harm

Pirrong contends that commodity ETFs, pension funds, and other

``real money'' investors would be harmed by position limits and that

this is unfair because not all such market participants impose the same

risks. 2/10/14 ISDA/SIFMA Comment Letter, Annex B, at pp.3-4, ]] 16-18.

The claim that it is ``unfair'' to impose limits on all market players

uniformly is a policy argument, not an economic argument.

d. Hamilton/Wu Papers on Risk Premia and Effects of Index Fund

Investing

Professors James Hamilton and Jing Cynthia Wu of the University of

California at San Diego and University of Chicago Business School,

respectively, authored a well-executed set of papers (well-executed

because they used reasonably defensible models with relatively

transparent assumptions and data sources) that examine the effect of

positions on prices.

Their paper, Hamilton and Wu, Risk Premia in Crude Oil Futures

Prices, Journal of International Money and Finance (2013), is a well-

reasoned explanation for how outsized speculative futures positions

could impact risk premium, the return for accepting undiversifiable

risk, a component of the return of holding a commodity futures

contract. Examining the crude oil futures market, they find that crude

oil risk premia fundamentally changed in response to financial investor

flows into the crude oil market. Id. at p.31.

Hamilton and Wu found that, for crude oil futures, risk premiums,

post-2005, were smaller than they were in the pre-2005 sample. This

study contains an important conclusion founded in the interplay of

positions and prices in the crude oil markets:

While traders taking the long position in near contracts earned

a positive return on average prior to 2005, that premium decreased

substantially after 2005, becoming negative when the slope of the

futures curve was high. This observation is consistent with the

claim that historically commercial producers paid a premium to

arbitrageurs for the privilege of hedging price risk, but in more

recent periods financial investors have become natural

counterparties for commercial hedgers.

Hamilton and Wu, Risk Premia in Crude Oil Futures Prices, at p.10,

Journal of International Money and Finance (2013).

Their paper tests the idea that risk premia have been bid down by

long, speculative investments in the crude oil market. That is, they

test the idea that the futures price has become higher as

[[Page 96922]]

it has been bid up by long speculators, so the return from holding the

long futures contract has been lowered. In theory, this phenomenon

would make hedging cheap for the short side of the market, but would

also increase the price of the futures, all else being equal.

Hamilton and Wu use a two-factor model for price: The futures

contract price less the rational expectation of the futures price

equals the risk premium, the component of price associated with holding

the price risk of the futures contract. A commodity that is more likely

to be affected by long passives in this way is crude oil, because (1)

crude oil as a commodity dominates these indices--substantial portion

of the GSFI for example; (2) the economics of storage.

All else being equal, if outsized market positions affect price, we

should expect risk premium to be the component of price that would be

affected when market participants take outsized positions. That is

because risk premium is a return for taking on undiversifiable risk. A

risk premium does not include that portion of risk that can be easily

diversified through other instruments. Through the workings of market,

a participant who takes on a price exposure will expect to be

compensated through a premium for bearing this risk. For a futures

commodity contract, there are many components of the return, and the

risk premium is only one of them. It can be a fairly small component,

although the fraction depends on the commodity and other the market

conditions.

Hamilton and Wu construct a theoretical price return: The return of

holding a long futures contract based on a rational expectations model.

Hamilton and Wu, Risk Premia in Crude Oil Futures Prices, Journal of

International Money and Finance (2013). Their risk premium is the

difference between futures return and theoretical price return. They

find that risk premiums for crude oil decreased over time and became

more volatile. While Hamilton and Wu listed many assets in the paper's

introductory discussion of the theoretical model, in their empirical

analysis they use two factors, that involve only futures price data.

This omission fails to take into account potentially relevant data

about the level of various commodities in storage \1725\ and

observations about other financial assets.\1726\ Consequently, there

may be some disconnect between their theoretical and their empirical

model. This may mean that the study's theoretical price return is on

less sound theoretical footing than it may first appear. Nevertheless,

the benchmark rational expectation return may still be a suitable

approximation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1725\ Risk premia may vary based on the amount of a commodity

in storage at any given time. While discussing storage as a

component of risk premia seems overly technical, in many of these

papers, including the Hamilton and Wu paper, it might play an import

role. One could go long a crude oil futures contract, or one could

buy crude oil and storage it. If you do the latter, you could draw

down the physical commodity available for near-term use. Also, the

storing of the physical commodity has a real option component to it

(one can take the crude oil out of storage and consume it relatively

quickly). The value of the real option depends on how much society

might need crude oil in storage, and that value depends on how much

crude oil is stored elsewhere.

\1726\ The papers discussed in the financialization section

suggest that the returns of financial assets may affect commodity

returns and vice versa.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In a second paper, Effects of Index-Fund Investing on Commodity

Futures Prices, International Economic Review, (February 2015),

Hamilton and Wu were able to replicate Singleton's result for the crude

oil market during the 2006-2009 period. They found an effect from

speculative positions of index investors on risk premium in crude

oil.\1727\ Hamilton and Wu also did not find evidence of speculative

positions influencing risk premia in crude oil after 2009. Nor did they

find evidence that speculative positions affected the risk premia in

the agricultural commodities markets. ``Our conclusion is that although

in principle index-fund buying of commodity futures could influence

pricing of risk, we do not find confirmation of that in the week-to-

week variability of the notional value of reported commodity index

trader positions.'' Id. at p.193; see id. at p.195 (no persuasive

evidence that changes in index trader positions is related to risk

premium in agricultural commodities, whether the data is studied for

change on a weekly or 13-week basis). Consequently, they find only

limited evidence for a theoretically reasonable version of the Master's

hypothesis, i.e., that long speculators bid down the risk premia and as

a result induce a higher futures price in various commodity futures

markets. ``Overall,'' Hamilton and Wu conclude, their work indicates

that ``there seems to be little evidence that index-fund investing is

exerting a measurable effect on commodity futures prices.'' Id. at

p.204 (adding that it is ``difficult to find much empirical foundation

for a view that continues to have a significant impact on policy

decisions'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1727\ Professor Kenneth Singleton found evidence that

speculative positions Granger-causing risk premium on weekly time

intervals during the 2007 to 2009 period when studying the crude oil

futures markets. Singleton, Investor Flows and the 2008 Boom/Bust in

Oil Prices (March 23, 2011 working paper).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

e. Sanders/Irwin on the ``Necessity'' of Limits and Energy Futures

Prices

Professors Dwight Sanders and Scott Irwin submitted two working

papers: (1) One paper arguing that new limits on speculation in

agricultural futures markets are unnecessary; \1728\ and (2) a paper on

energy futures prices, using high frequency daily position data for

energy markets and concluding that there is no compelling evidence of

predictive links between commodity index investment and changes in

energy futures prices.\1729\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1728\ Sanders and Irwin, The ``Necessity'' of New Position

Limits in Agricultural Futures Markets: The Verdict from Daily Firm-

Level Position Data (working paper 3/13/2014), comment letter at 1-

46.

\1729\ Sanders and Irwin, Energy Futures Prices and Commodity

Index Investment: New Evidence from Firm-Level Position Data

(working paper 2/17/2014), comment letter at 47-89.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

i. The ``Necessity'' of New Position Limits

In Sanders and Irwin, The ``Necessity'' of New Position Limits in

Agricultural Futures Markets: The Verdict from Daily Firm-Level

Position Data (working paper 2014), the authors use price and position

data shared by an unnamed large investment company.\1730\ They do

various statistical analyses to concluding that the large investment

company's roll of its position does not have any lasting price impact

on the market. The find that the price impact of the roll is, at most,

a small and temporary price impact; there is not a day-over-day impact

and the impact is smaller than the bid/ask spread.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1730\ Id. at 4-5. They argue that this dataset will be more

comprehensive than the CFTC's commitment of trader data, but they

did not test to verify this assumption. They correctly observe that

prior work using CFTC data suffers from limitations in the frequency

of data and the availability of swaps data. Id. at 3, 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

This result does not disprove, generally, the possibility that the

fund's long, speculative positions impact price because it focuses only

on one aspect of the fund's trading: Its rolling of positions. The firm

data used is from a large commodity index fund that is registered

investment company, and such a firm is likely put into their prospectus

how they are going to roll their positions. This pre-announcement of

when the commodity index fund will roll may dampen the price impact of

these particular changes in position. See n.1682 and associated text,

supra; Aulerich, Irwin, and Garcia, Bubbles, Food Prices, and

Speculation: Evidence from the CFTC's Daily Large Trader Data Files,

id. at p.29 (NBER Conference

[[Page 96923]]

2012) (firms preannounce their rolls, and thus these position changes

can be anticipated by the marketplace and thus lead to less price

impact). Sanders and Irwin's result thus is not obviously extensible to

any price impact of this large index fund's positions apart from its

positions and trading at the time of roll.

This fund did have days of heavy trading, apart from rolling, but

Sanders and Irwin did not study the price impact arising from these

changes in position. The fund traded cotton contracts representing 5.8%

of average daily trading in cotton and wheat trades constituting 3.5%

of average daily volume in the MGEX wheat contract. Sanders and Irwin

did not attempt to study price impact on these un-announced trades.

They stated that because the sizes of the roll transactions are

``larger than changes in outright position,'' ``investigating the

impact of rolling on market spreads'' is ``particularly interesting.''

Id. at p.10. On the other hand, the non-roll position changes are

presumptively not preannounced to the marketplace, so studying this

rich dataset for price impacts from those position changes might also

be interesting.

This paper by Sanders and Irwin thus has a limitation of scope

based on its focus on just the rolling of positions. This large

commodity index fund presumptively pre-announced its rolling of

positions in its prospectus. However, this leaves open the question of

what would be the effect if this same fund did not pre-announce in the

future. The analysis by Sanders and Irwin, if credited as true within a

reasonable degree of certainty, would address whether regulators should

employ position limits prophylactically to diminish the price impact of

any future, non-announced rolls. At least prior to sunshine trading of

rolls, there is evidence of a price impact associated with rolling.

Frenk and Turbeville, Commodity Index Traders and the Boom/Bust Cycle

in Commodities Prices (Better Markets 2011).\1731\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1731\ An example of a study that is, in part, forward-looking,

is Cheng, Kirilenko, and Xiong, Convective Risk Flows in Commodity

Futures Markets (working paper 2012). The authors use comovement

methodology to conclude that in times of distress, financial traders

reduce their net long position, causing risk to flow from financial

traders to commercial hedgers. See also Acharya, Ramadorai, and

Lochstoer, Limits to Arbitrage and Hedging: Evidence from the

Commodity Markets, Journal of Financial Economics (2013) (decreases

in financial traders' risk capacity should lead to increases in

hedgers' hedging cost, all else being equal).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Moreover, not all large players pre-announce their rolls. The fact

that Sanders and Irwin found no price impact with respect to rolls that

were (assumedly) pre-announced does not mean that unannounced rolls

might be mistaken for informed trading by the marketplace and cause a

price impact.\1732\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1732\ Sanders and Irwin's piece does not directly test the

effect of pre-existing position limits in these markets. Examining

agricultural markets for whether there can be price impact on

positions generally is complicated by the fact that the agricultural

markets have been subject to federal position limits since 1920s. On

the other hand, in the case of a commodity index fund, they may well

not be carrying substantial positions into the spot month, and so

even their large source of firm data may not be useful for testing

the impact or effectiveness of position limits during the spot

month.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Despite these limitations in scope, Sanders and Irwin's article is

one of the more useful Granger analysis papers for several reasons.

First, it does present a working definition of ``excessive

speculation:'' speculation that is ``causing'' price fluctuations that

are ``sudden'' or ``unreasonable'' or ``unwarranted.'' Sanders and

Irwin correctly state that their ``definition of excessive speculation

seemingly excludes speculation that cannot be shown to cause price

changes. . . .'' Id. at p.3. It is important to note, however, that

Sanders and Irwin repeatedly use the word ``necessary'' to analyze the

desirability of position limits, which elevates the requirements for

establishing causation of price fluctuations to a very high level. High

quality economic studies often use empirical data, typically the tools

of statistics, to achieve reasonable certainty within a specified

degree of error.

Second, the data source is a novel and fairly comprehensive data

set. It includes both swaps and futures, and encompasses many different

commodities. The data does indicate the volume and nature of this large

commodity fund's positions in the market place. All positions taken by

the firm during the 2007-2012 time period were long positions, not

short positions. Id. at p.5. The fund's total position size (including

futures and swaps) grew from under $4 billion in 2007 to $12 billion in

2011. Id.

Third, with respect to the paper's conclusion on rolling of

positions, the statistical result of Sanders and Irwin--concluding that

there was no price impact from positions--is stronger than many other

studies in some respects. Unlike Hamilton and Wu's work on just a

component of the return from holding a futures contract (risk premium),

Sanders and Irwin consider the entire return from holding the futures

contract. They studied data over a long time period. If their model is

correct, they have found evidence against (at least their formulation

of) the Masters hypothesis. There is a potential concern, however, with

their statistical result. The price equation used for their Granger

analysis uses both lagged returns and changes in positions. See id. at

p.16 (``Rt-i'' are lagged returns and ``Positions'' are

changes in position in Equation 5a). To the extent that lagged returns

and position changes are correlated with each other, their price

equation may mask correlations between price returns and position

changes.

ii. Energy Futures Prices

Using the same commodity index fund data, Sanders and Irwin examine

energy contracts: Crude oil, heating oil, natural gas, and reformulated

blend stock gas (with ethanol added). Sanders and Irwin, Energy Futures

Prices and Commodity Index Investment: New Evidence from Firm-Level

Position Data (working paper 2014). This paper attempts to challenge

the findings of an impact on price from positions by Singleton,

Hamilton and Wu. Sanders and Irwin contend that their richer data

source compels a conclusion that positions in commodity energy markets

do not impact price.

This paper also has a potential problem with the price return

equation. The equation, see id. at p. 15 (Equation No. 7), uses lagged

returns and positions to test against a correlation with price.

Sometimes they use multiple lagged returns. For example, for their

natural gas analysis, they used two sets of lagged returns. Id. at p.35

(Table 5). Again, use of lagged returns in the price equation can mask

a possible correlation.

Sanders and Irwin argue that their results from a richer data

source indicate that Singleton and Hamilton and Wu's results may be

``artifacts'' of poor data. They contend that these authors' use of

agricultural data as proxy for energy positions was problematic. Id. at

p.3. They suggest this may explain the differing results of Singleton,

as well as Hamilton and Wu.

But there are other explanations for this difference in results.

Singleton, Hamilton and Wu focus on risk premium, not, as Sanders and

Irwin do, on price returns. This distinction can be quite important in

this context. If positions impact price by impacting risk premium, that

effect will not necessarily reveal itself in a study of just price

returns. Perhaps more fundamentally, Sanders and Irwin and are asking a

[[Page 96924]]

slightly different question than Hamilton and Wu or Singleton. Sanders

and Irwin are attempting to measure speculative position changes impact

on price returns over a long time period, February of 2007 to May 2012.

Hamilton and Wu, and also Singleton, use narrower timeframes in their

papers and find a component of return, the risk premium, during a

narrow time window, during a period of economic stress.

f. CME Group Study Submissions

The CME Group filed in the administrative record several studies

and reports on March 28, 2011. It did so in three sets, all filed on

March 28, 2011.

In the first set, CME filed: Tackling the Challenges in Commodity

Markets and Raw Materials, European Commission (2011) (2.2.2011);

Issues Involving the Use of the Futures Market to Invest in Commodity

Indexes, Government Accountability Office Letter to the Hon. Collin

Peterson, Chair, House Committee on Agriculture (June 30, 2009); and

Korniotis, Does Speculation Affect Spot Price Levels? The Case of

Metals With and Without Futures Markets, Working Paper of the Finance

and Economic Discussion Series, Federal Reserve Board (2009).

In a second set, CME filed: Stoll and Whaley, Commodity Index

Investing and Commodity Futures Prices, Journal of Applied Finance

(2010); and Irwin and Sanders, The Impact of Index and Swap Funds on

Commodity Markets: Preliminary Results (OECD Food, Agriculture and

Fisheries Working Papers, No. 27 2010).

In a third set, CME filed: Celso Brunetti and Bahattin

B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin, Is Speculation Destabilizing? (working

paper 2009); Bahattin B[uuml]y[uuml]k[scedil]ahin and Jeffrey H.

Harris, The Role of Speculators in the Crude Oil Futures Market

(working paper 2009); and Interagency Task Force on Commodity Markets,

Interim Report on Crude Oil (July 2008).

Finally, CME submitted an undated CME study on conditional spot-

month limits and CME Group's white paper, Excessive Speculation and

Position Limits in Energy Derivatives Markets.

As a group, these studies are not new to the Commission. All of

these papers, except the CME undated submission on conditional spot

limits and the European Commission publication, were cited by the

Commission in its December 2013 Position Limits Proposal and so are

covered in the above analysis of various studies.\1733\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1733\ The undated CME study on conditional spot-month limits is

the only empirical work submitted by CME in is opposition to the

position limits rulemaking. It has been proven wrong. The Commission

has previously explained that CME made technical data errors in

doing its analysis. Position Limits for Futures and Swaps, 76 FR

71626, 71635 nn. 100-101 (Nov. 18, 2011). The European Commission

publication in CME's first set of submissions, Tackling the

Challenges in Commodity Markets and Raw Materials, European

Commission (2011) (2.2.2011), is simply a discussion of policy

initiatives. It concedes that it is difficult to know which way

causation forms between financial and physical markets and states

that ``the debate . . . is still open'' on whether financial inflows

have affected prices. Id. at 2, 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Conclusion

Economists debate whether ``excessive speculation'' meaning, as an

economic matter, a link between large speculation positions and

unwarranted price changes or price volatility, exists in these

regulated markets, and if so to what degree. The question presented is

a surprisingly difficult one to answer. All the empirical studies on

this question have drawbacks, and none is conclusive. This

inconclusivity is not surprising. It is inevitable, given the economic

uncertainties that inhere in the data and the complexity of the

question. There are many theoretical and empirical assumptions and

leaps, that are needed to transform and interpret raw market data into

meaningful and persuasive results. There is no decisive statistical

method for establishing evidence for or against position limits in the

commodity.

Those studies that use Granger causality methodology tend to

conclude that there is no evidence of excessive speculation or its

consequences on price returns and price volatility, and many industry

commenters opposed to position limits used this methodology. But that

methodology is peculiarly sensitive to model design choices, and this

review has highlighted the modelling decisions that may have affected

the ultimate conclusions of these studies. Moreover, there are

countervailing Granger studies showing a link between large speculative

positions and price volatility. And studies such as Cheng, Kirilenko,

and Xiong, Convective Risk Flows in Commodity Futures Markets (working

paper 2012), indicate that some Granger studies may mask the impact of

speculation in times of financial stress.

Those studies that use comovement and cointegration methods tend to

conclude there is evidence of deleterious effects of ``excessive

speculation.'' Yet comovement tests for correlation, not causation, and

a correlation between large financial trading in the commodity markets

and price changes and volatility could be driven by a common causal

agent such as macroeconomic factors.

Those studies that use models of fundamental supply and demand

reach a whole host of divergent opinions on the subject, each opinion

only as strong as the many modelling choices.

In this way, the economic literature is inconclusive. Even clearly

written, well-respected papers often contain nuances. It is telling

that Hamilton, Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of 2007-2008,

Brookings Paper on Economic Activity (2009), has been cited by both

proponents and opponents of position limits.

What can be said with certainty is summarized in the Commission's

Notice of Proposed Rulemaking: That large speculative positions and

outsized market power pose risks to a well-functioning marketplace.

These risks may very well differ depending on commodity market

structure, but can in some markets cause real-world price impacts

through a higher risk premium as a component of total price. There are

also economic studies indicating some correlation between increased

speculation and price volatility in times of financial stress, but this

correlation does not imply causation.

Comment letters on either side declaring that the matter is settled

in their favor among respectable economists are simply incorrect. The

best economists on both sides of the debate concede that there is a

legitimate debate. This analysis concludes that the academic debate

amongst economists about the effects of outsized market positions has

reputable and legitimate standard-bearers for opposing positions.

B. Appendix B--List of Comment Letters Cited in this Rulemaking

1. Agri-Mark, Inc.; (CL-Agri-Mark-59609, 2/10/2014)

2. Airlines for America (``A4A''); (CL-A4A-59714, 2/10/2014); (CL-

A4A-59686, 2/10/2014)

3. Alternative Investment Management Association (``AIMA''); (CL-

AIMA-59618, 2/10/2014); (CL-AIMA-59619, 2/10/2014)

4. American Bakers Association (``Bakers''); (CL-Bakers-59691, 2/10/

2014)

5. American Benefits Council (``ABC''); (CL-ABC-59670, 2/10/2014)

6. American Cotton Shippers Association (``ACSA''); (CL-ASCA-59667,

2/10/2014)

7. American Farm Bureau Federation (``AFBF''); (CL-AFBF-59730, 2/10/

2014)

8. American Feed Industry Association (``AFIA''); (CL-AFIA-60955, 7/

13/2016)

9. American Gas Association (``AGA''), (CL-AGA-59632, 2/10/2014);

(CL-AGA-

[[Page 96925]]

59633, 2/10/2014); (CL-AGA-60382, 3/30/2015); (CL-AGA-60943, 7/13/

2016)

10. American Petroleum Institute (``API''); (CL-API-59694, 2/10/

2014); (CL-API-59944, 8/4/2014); (CL-API-60939, 7/13/2016)

11. American Public Gas Association (``APGA''); (CL-APGA-59722, 2/

10/2014)

12. American Sugar Refining, Inc.; (CL-ASR-59668, 2/10/2014); (CL-

ASR-60933, 7/13/2016)

13. Americans for Financial Reform (``AFR''); (CL-AFR-59711, 2/10/

2014); (CL-AFR-59685, 2/10/2014); (CL-AFR-60953, 7/13/2016)

14. Archer Daniels Midland Company (``ADM''); (CL-ADM-59640, 2/10/

2014); (CL-ADM-60300, 1/22/2015); (CL-ADM-60934, 7/13/2016)

15. Armajaro Asset Management; (CL-Armajaro-59729, 2/10/2014)

16. Atmos Energy Holdings, Inc. (``Atmos''); (CL-Atmos-59705, 2/10/

2014)

17. Better Markets, Inc.; (CL-Better Markets-59715, 2/10/2014); (CL-

Better Markets-59716, 2/10/2014); (CL-Better Markets-60325, 1/22/

2015); (CL-Better Markets-60401, 3/30/2015); (CL-Better Markets-

60928, 7/13/2016)

18. BG Energy Merchants, LLC (``BG Group''); (CL-BG Group-59656, 2/

10/2014); (CL-BG Group-59937, 8/4/2014); (CL-BG Group-60383, 3/30/

2015)

19. Cactus Feeders, Inc., et al.; (CL-Cactus-59660, 2/10/2014)

20. Calpine Corporation; (CL-Calpine-59663, 2/10/2014)

21. Cargill, Incorporated; (CL-Cargill-59638, 2/10/2014)

22. Castleton Commodities International LLC (``CCI''); (CL-CCI-

60935, 7/13/2016)

23. Center for Capital Markets Competitiveness, U.S. Chamber of

Commerce (``Chamber''); (CL-Chamber-59684, 2/10/2014); (CL-Chamber-

59721, 2/10/2014)

24. Chairman, U.S. Senate Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations

of the Committee on Homeland Security and Governmental Affairs; (CL-

Sen. Levin-59637, 2/10/2014)

25. Citadel LLC; (CL-Citadel-59717, 2/10/2014); (CL-Citadel-59933,

8/1/2014)

26. CME Group Inc. (``CME''); (CL-CME-59719, 2/10/2014); (CL-CME-

59718, 2/10/2014); (CL-CME-59970, 8/4/2014); (CL-CME-59971, 8/4/

2014); (CL-CME-60307, 1/22/2015); (CL-CME-60406, 3/30/2015); (CL-

CME-60926, 7/13/2016)

27. Coalition of Physical Energy Companies (``COPE''); (CL-COPE-

59662, 2/10/2014); (CL-COPE-59653, 2/10/2014); (CL-COPE-59950, 8/4/

2014); (CL-COPE-60388, 3/30/2015); (CL-COPE-60932, 7/13/2016)

28. Commercial Energy Working Group; (CL-Working Group-59647, 2/10/

2014)

29. Commodities Working Group of GFMA (``GFMA''); (CL-GFMA-60314, 1/

22/2015)

30. Commodity Markets Council (``CMC''); (CL-CMC-59634, 2/10/2014);

(CL-CMC-59925, 7/25/2014); (CL-CMC-60318, 1/22/2015); (CL-CMC-60391,

3/30/2015); (CL-CMC-60950, 7/13/2016)

31. Commodity Markets Oversight Coalition (``CMOC''); (CL-CMOC-

59720, 2/10/2014); (CL-CMOC-60324, 1/22/2015); (CL-CMOC-60400, 3/30/

2015)

32. Committee on Capital Markets Regulation (``CCMR''); (CL-CCMR-

59623, 2/10/2014)

33. Copperwood Asset Management LP (``CAM''); (CL-CAM-60097, 12/22/

2014)

34. Cota, Sean; (CL-Cota-59706, 2/10/2014); (CL-Cota-60322, 1/22/

2015)

35. CSC Sugar, LLC (``CSC''); (CL-CSC-59676, 2/10/2014); (CL-CSC-

59677, 2/10/2014)

36. Dairy Farmers of America (``DFA''); (CL-DFA-59621, 2/10/2014);

(CL-DFA-59948, 8/4/2014); (CL-DFA-60309, 1/22/2015); (CL-DFA-60927,

7/13/2016)

37. Darigold; (CL-Darigold-59651, 2/10/2014)

38. Davis Wright Tremaine LLP on behalf of Dairy America, Inc.; (CL-

Dairy America-59683, 2/10/2014)

39. DB Commodity Services LLC (``DBCS''); (CL-DBCS-59569, 2/6/2014)

40. Duke Energy Utilities; (CL-DEU-59627, 2/10/2014)

41. Ecom Agro Industrial, Inc.; (CL-Ecom-60308, 1/22/2015)

42. EDF Trading North America, LLC (``EDF''); (CL-EDF-59961, 8/4/

2014); (CL-EDF-60398, 3/30/2015); (CL-EDF-60944, 7/13/2016)

43. Edison Electric Institute (``EEI''); (CL-EEI-59945, 8/4/2014);

(CL-EEI-Sup-60386, 3/30/2015)

44. Electric Power Supply Association (``EPSA''); (CL-EPSA-55953, 8/

4/2014); (CL-EPSA-59999, 11/12/2014); (CL-EPSA-60381, 3/30/2015)

45. EEI and EPSA, jointly (``EEI-EPSA''); (CL-EEI-EPSA-59602, 2/7/

2014); (CL-EEI-EPSA-60925, 7/13/2016)

46. Energy Transfer Partners, L.P. (``ETP''); (CL-ET-59958, 8/4/

2014); (CL-ETP-60915, 7/12/2016)

47. FC Stone LLC; (CL-FCS-59675, 2/10/2014)

48. Fonterra Co-operative Group Limited (``Fonterra''); (CL-

Fonterra-59608, 2/9/2014)

49. Futures Industry Association (``FIA''), (CL-FIA-59595, 2/7/

2014); (CL-FIA-59566, 2/6/2014); (CL-FIA-59931, 7/31/2014); (CL-FIA-

60303, 1/22/2015); (CL-FIA-60392, 3/30/2015); (CL-FIA-60937, 7/13/

2016)

50. Grain Service Corporation (``GSC''); (CL-GSC-59703, 2/10/2014)

51. HP Hood LLC (``Hood''), (CL-Hood-59582, 2/7/2014)

52. ICE Futures U.S., Inc.; (CL-ICE-59645, 2/10/2014); (CL-ICE-

59649, 2/10/2014); (CL-ICE-59938, 8/4/2014); (CL-ICE-60310, 1/22/

2015); (CL-ICE-60311, 1/22/2015); (CL-ICE-60378, 3/30/2015)

53. Industrial Energy Consumers of America; (CL-IECA-59671, 2/10/

2014); (CL-IECA-59713, 2/10/2014); (CL-IECA-59964, 8/4/2014); (CL-

IECA-60389, 3/30/2015)

54. Innovation Center for US Dairy; (CL-US Dairy-59952, 8/4/2014)

55. Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy (``IATP''); (CL-IATP-

59701, 2/10/2014); (CL-IATP-59704, 2/10/2014); (CL-IATP-60394, 3/30/

2015); (CL-IATP-60951, 7/13/2016)

56. IATP and AFR, jointly; (CL-IATP-60323, 1/22/2015)

57. Intercontinental Exchange, Inc. (``ICE''); (CL-ICE-59669, 2/10/

2014); (CL-ICE-59962, 8/4/2014); (CL-ICE-59966, 8/4/2014); (CL-ICE-

60387, 3/30/2015); (CL-ICE-60929, 7/13/2016)

58. International Dairy Foods Association (``IDFA''); (CL-IDFA-

59771, 2/10/2014)

59. International Energy Credit Association; (CL-IECAssn-9679, 2/10/

2014); (CL-IECAssn-59957, 8/4/2014); (CL-IECAssn-60395, 3/30/2015);

(CL-IECAssn-60949, 7/13/2016)

60. International Swaps and Derivatives Association, Inc.

(``ISDA''); (CL-ISDA-60370, 3/26/2015); (CL-ISDA-60931, 7/13/2016)

61. Investment Company Institute (``ICI''); (CL-ICI-59614, 2/10/

2014)

62. ISDA and SIFMA, jointly; (CL-ISDA/SIFMA-59611, 2/10/2014); (CL-

ISDA/SIFMA-59917, 7/7/2014)

63. Just Energy Group Inc.; (CL-Just-59692, 2/10/2014)

64. Leprino Foods Company; (CL-Leprino-59707, 2/10/2014)

65. Louis Dreyfus Commodities LLC; (CL-LDC-59643, 2/10/2014)

66. Managed Funds Association (``MFA''); (CL-MFA-59600, 2/7/2014);

(CL-MFA-59606, 2/9/2014); (CL-MFA-60385, 3/30/2015)

67. MidAmerican Energy Holdings Company; (CL-MidAmerican-59585, 2/7/

2014)

68. Minneapolis Grain Exchange, Inc. (``MGEX''); (CL-MGEX-59610, 2/

10/2014); (CL-MGEX-59932, 8/1/2014); (CL-MGEX-60301, 1/22/2015);

(CL-MGEX-60380, 3/30/2015); (CL-MGEX-60936, 7/13/2016); (CL-MGEX-

60938, 7/13/2016)

69. Morgan Stanley; (CL-MSCGI-59708, 2/10/2014)

70. National Association of Wheat Growers; (CL-NAWG-59687, 2/10/

2014)

71. National Cattlemen's Beef Association (``NCBA''); (CL-NCBA-

59624, 2/10/2014)

72. National Corn Growers Association & American Soybeans

Association, jointly; (CL-NCGA-ASA-60917, 7/12/2016)

73. National Corn Growers Association & Natural Gas Supply

Association, jointly; (CL-NCGA-NGSA-60919, 7/13/2016)

74. National Cotton Council of America, American Cotton Shippers

Association, and Amcot, jointly; (CL-NCC-ACSA-60972, 7/18/2016)

75. National Council of Farmer Cooperatives; (CL-NCFC-59613, 2/10/

2014); (CL-NCFC-59942, 8/4/2014); (CL-NCFC-60930, 7/13/2016)

76. National Energy Marketers Association; (CL-NEM-59586, 2/7/2014);

(CL-NEM-59620, 2/10/2014)

77. National Grain and Feed Association; (CL-NGFA-59681, 2/10/2014);

(CL-NGFA-59956, 8/4/2014); (CL-NGFA-60267, 1/17/2015); (CL-NGFA-

60312, 1/22/2015); (CL-NGFA-60941, 7/13/2016)

78. National Milk Producers Federation; (CL-NMPF-59652, 2/10/2014);

(CL-NMPF-60956, 7/13/2016)

[[Page 96926]]

79. National Rural Electric Cooperative Association, American Public

Power Association, and the Large Public Power Council, jointly (the

``NFP Electric Associations''); (CL-NFP-59690, 2/10/2014); (CL-NFP-

59934, 8/1/2014); (CL-NFP-60393, 3/30/2015); (CL-NFP-60942, 7/13/

2016)

80. Natural Gas Supply Association; (CL-NGSA-59673, 2/10/2014); (CL-

NGSA-59674, 2/10/2014); (CL-NGSA-59900, 6/26/2014); (CL-NGSA-59941,

8/4/2014); (CL-NGSA-60379, 3/30/2015)

81. Nebraska Cattlemen Inc.; (CL-NC-59696, 2/10/2014)

82. New York State Department of Agriculture & Markets; (CL-NYS

Agriculture-59657, 2/10/2014)

83. Nodal Exchange, LLC; (CL-Nodal-59695, 2/10/2014); (CL-Nodal-

60948, 7/13/2016)

84. NRG Energy, Inc.; (CL-NRG-60434, 1/20/2015)

85. Occupy the SEC (``OSEC''); (CL-OSEC-59972, 8/7/2014)

86. Olam International Limited; (CL-Olam-59658, 2/10/2014); (CL-

Olam-59946, 8/4/2014)

87. Pedestal Commodity Group, LLC; (CL-Pedestal-59630, 2/10/2014)

88. Petroleum Marketers Association of America and the New England

Fuel Institute; (CL-PMAA-NEFI-60952, 7/13/2016)

89. Plains All American Pipeline, L.P.; (CL-PAAP-59664, 2/10/2014);

(CL-PAAP-59951, 8/4/2014)

90. Private Equity Growth Capital Council (``PEGCC''); (CL-PEGCC-

59650, 2/10/2014); (CL-PEGCC-59913, 7/3/2014); (CL-PEGCC-59987, 10/

24/2014)

91. Public Citizen, Inc.; (CL-Public Citizen-59648, 2/10/2014); (CL-

Public Citizen-60390, 3/30/2015); (CL-Public Citizen-60313, 1/22/

2015); (CL-Public Citizen-60940, 7/13/2016)

92. Rice Dairy LLC; (CL-Rice Dairy-59601, 2/7/2014); (CL-Rice Dairy-

59960, 8/4/2014)

93. RightingFinance; (CL-RF-60372, 3/28/2015)

94. Risk Management Work Group, Globalization Operating Committee,

Innovation Center for US Dairy; (CL-US Dairy-59597, 2/7/2014)

95. Rutkowski, Robert; (CL-Rutkowski-60961, 7/14/2016); (CL-

Rutkowski-60962, 7/14/2016)

96. Sempra Energy; (CL-SEMP-59926, 7/25/2014); (CL-SEMP-60384, 3/30/

2015)

97. SIFMA AMG (``SIFMA''); (CL-AMG-59709, 2/10/2014); (CL-AMG-59710,

2/10/2014); (CL-AMG-59935, 8/1/2014); (CL-AMG-60946, 7/13/2016)

98. Southern Company Services, Inc.; (CL-SCS-60399, 3/30/2015)

99. Sutherland Asbill & Brennan LLP on behalf of The Commercial

Energy Working Group; (CL-Working Group-59693, 2/10/2014); (CL-

Working Group-59955, 8/4/2014); (CL-Working Group-59959, 8/4/2014);

(CL-Working Group-60396, 3/30/2015); (CL-Working Group-60947, 7/13/

2016)

100. T.C. Jacoby & Company, Inc.; (CL-Jacoby-59622, 2/10/2014)

101. Texas Cattle Feeders Association (``TCFA''); (CL-TCFA-59680, 2/

10/2014); (CL-TCFA-59723, 2/10/2014)

102. The Andersons, Inc.; (CL-Andersons-60256, 1/15/2015)

103. The McCully Group LLC; (CL-McCully-59592, 2/7/2014)

104. Thornton, Pamela; (CL-Thornton-59702, 2/10/2014)

105. Traditum Group LLC; (CL-Traditum-59655, 2/10/2014)

106. Tri-State Coalition for Responsible Investment, et al.; (CL-

Tri-State-59682, 2/10/2014)

107. United States Commodity Funds LLC (``USCF''); (CL-USCF-59644,

2/10/2014)

108. Vectra Capital LLC; (CL-Vectra-60369, 3/26/2015)

109. Wholesale Markets Brokers Association, Americas (``WMBA'');

(CL-WMBA-60945, 7/13/2016)

110. World Economy, Ecology & Development (``WEED''); (CL-WEED-

59628, 2/10/2014)

111. World Gold Council (``WGC''); (CL-WGC-59558, 2/6/2014)

List of Subjects

17 CFR Part 1

Agricultural commodity, Agriculture, Brokers, Committees, Commodity

futures, Conflicts of interest, Consumer protection, Definitions,

Designated contract markets, Directors, Major swap participants,

Minimum financial requirements for intermediaries, Reporting and

recordkeeping requirements, Swap dealers, Swaps.

17 CFR Part 15

Brokers, Commodity futures, Reporting and recordkeeping

requirements, Swaps.

17 CFR Part 17

Brokers, Commodity futures, Reporting and recordkeeping

requirements, Swaps.

17 CFR Part 19

Commodity futures, Cottons, Grains, Reporting and recordkeeping

requirements, Swaps.

17 CFR Part 37

Registered entities, Registration application, Reporting and

recordkeeping requirements, Swaps, Swap execution facilities.

17 CFR Part 38

Block transaction, Commodity futures, Designated contract markets,

Reporting and recordkeeping requirements, Transactions off the

centralized market.

17 CFR Part 140

Authority delegations (Government agencies), Conflict of interests,

Organizations and functions (Government agencies).

17 CFR Part 150

Bona fide hedging, Commodity futures, Cotton, Grains, Position

limits, Referenced Contracts, Swaps.

17 CFR Part 151

Bona fide hedging, Commodity futures, Cotton, Grains, Position

limits, Referenced Contracts, Swaps.

For the reasons stated in the preamble, the Commodity Futures

Trading Commission proposes to amend 17 CFR chapter I as follows:

PART 1--GENERAL REGULATIONS UNDER THE COMMODITY EXCHANGE ACT

0

1. The authority citation for part 1 continues to read as follows:

Authority: 7 U.S.C. 1a, 2, 5, 6, 6a, 6b, 6c, 6d, 6e, 6f, 6g, 6h,

6i, 6k, 6l, 6m, 6n, 6o, 6p, 6r, 6s, 7, 7a-1, 7a-2, 7b, 7b-3, 8, 9,

10a, 12, 12a, 12c, 13a, 13a-1, 16, 16a, 19, 21, 23, and 24 (2012).

Sec. 1.3(z) [Removed and Reserved]

0

2. Remove and reserve Sec. 1.3(z).

Sec. 1.47 [Removed and Reserved]

0

3. Remove and reserve Sec. 1.47.

Sec. 1.48 [Removed and Reserved]

0

4. Remove and reserve Sec. 1.48.

PART 15--REPORTS--GENERAL PROVISIONS

0

5. The authority citation for part 15 continues to read as follows:

Authority: 7 U.S.C. 2, 5, 6a, 6c, 6f, 6g, 6i, 6k, 6m, 6n, 7, 7a,

9, 12a, 19, and 21, as amended by Title VII of the Dodd-Frank Wall

Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. 111-203, 124

Stat. 1376 (2010).

0

6. In Sec. 15.00, revise paragraph (p) to read as follows:

Sec. 15.00 Definitions of terms used in parts 15 through 19, and 21

of this chapter.

* * * * *

(p) Reportable position means:

(1) For reports specified in parts 17 and 18 and in Sec.

19.00(a)(2) and (a)(3) of this chapter any open contract position that

at the close of the market on any business day equals or exceeds the

quantity specified in Sec. 15.03 of this part in either:

(i) Any one futures of any commodity on any one reporting market,

excluding futures contracts against which notices of delivery have been

stopped by a trader or issued by the clearing organization of a

reporting market; or

(ii) Long or short put or call options that exercise into the same

future of any commodity, or long or short put or call options for

options on physicals that have identical expirations and exercise

[[Page 96927]]

into the same physical, on any one reporting market.

(2) For the purposes of reports specified in Sec. 19.00(a)(1) of

this chapter, any position in commodity derivative contracts, as

defined in Sec. 150.1 of this chapter, that exceeds a position limit

in Sec. 150.2 of this chapter for the particular commodity.

* * * * *

0

7. In Sec. 15.01, revise paragraph (d) to read as follows:

Sec. 15.01 Persons required to report.

* * * * *

(d) Persons, as specified in part 19 of this chapter, who either:

(1) Hold or control commodity derivative contracts (as defined in

Sec. 150.1 of this chapter) that exceed a position limit in Sec.

150.2 of this chapter for the commodities enumerated in that section;

or

(2) Are merchants or dealers of cotton holding or controlling

positions for future delivery in cotton that equal or exceed the amount

set forth in Sec. 15.03.

* * * * *

0

8. Revise Sec. 15.02 to read as follows:

Sec. 15.02 Reporting forms.

Forms on which to report may be obtained from any office of the

Commission or via the Internet (http://www.cftc.gov). Forms to be used

for the filing of reports follow, and persons required to file these

forms may be determined by referring to the rule listed in the column

opposite the form number.

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Form No. Title Rule

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

40................................... Statement of Reporting Trader............................ 18.04

71................................... Identification of Omnibus Accounts and Sub-accounts...... 17.01

101.................................. Positions of Special Accounts............................ 17.00

102.................................. Identification of Special Accounts, Volume Threshold 17.01

Accounts, and Consolidated Accounts.

204.................................. Statement of Cash Positions of Hedgers................... 19.00

304.................................. Statement of Cash Positions for Unfixed-Price Cotton ``On 19.00

Call''.

504.................................. Statement of Cash Positions for Conditional Spot Month 19.00

Exemptions.

604.................................. Statement of Pass-Through Swap Exemptions................ 19.00

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

(Approved by the Office of Management and Budget under control

numbers 3038-0007, 3038-0009, and 3038-0103.)

PART 17--REPORTS BY REPORTING MARKETS, FUTURES COMMISSION

MERCHANTS, CLEARING MEMBERS, AND FOREIGN BROKERS

0

9. The authority citation for part 17 continues to read as follows:

Authority: 7 U.S.C. 2, 6a, 6c, 6d, 6f, 6g, 6i, 6t, 7, 7a, and

12a, as amended by Title VII of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform

and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010).

0

10. In Sec. 17.00, revise paragraph (b) to read as follows:

Sec. 17.00 Information to be furnished by futures commission

merchants, clearing members and foreign brokers.

* * * * *

(b) Interest in or control of several accounts. Except as otherwise

instructed by the Commission or its designee and as specifically

provided in Sec. 150.4 of this chapter, if any person holds or has a

financial interest in or controls more than one account, all such

accounts shall be considered by the futures commission merchant,

clearing member or foreign broker as a single account for the purpose

of determining special account status and for reporting purposes.

* * * * *

0

11. In Sec. 17.03, revise paragraph (h) to read as follows:

Sec. 17.03 Delegation of authority to the Director of the Office of

Data and Technology or the Director of the Division of Market

Oversight.

* * * * *

(h) Pursuant to Sec. 17.00(b), and as specifically provided in

Sec. 150.4 of this chapter, the authority shall be designated to the

Director of the Office of Data and Technology to instruct a futures

commission merchant, clearing member or foreign broker to consider

otherwise than as a single account for the purpose of determining

special account status and for reporting purposes all accounts one

person holds or controls, or in which the person has a financial

interest.

* * * * *

0

12. Revise part 19 to read as follows:

PART 19--REPORTS BY PERSONS HOLDING POSITIONS EXEMPT FROM POSITION

LIMITS AND BY MERCHANTS AND DEALERS IN COTTON

Sec.

19.00 General provisions.

19.01 Reports on stocks and fixed price purchases and sales.

19.02 Reports pertaining to cotton on call purchases and sales.

19.03 Reports pertaining to special commodities.

19.04 Delegation of authority to the Director of the Division of

Market Oversight.

19.05-19.10 [Reserved]

Appendix A to Part 19--Forms 204, 304, 504, 604, and 704

Authority: 7 U.S.C. 6g, 6c(b), 6i, and 12a(5), as amended by

Title VII of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer

Protection Act, Pub. L. 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010).

Sec. 19.00 General provisions.

(a) Who must file series `04 reports. The following persons are

required to file series `04 reports:

(1) Persons filing for exemption to speculative position limits.

All persons holding or controlling positions in commodity derivative

contracts, as defined in Sec. 150.1 of this chapter, in excess of any

speculative position limit provided under Sec. 150.2 of this chapter

and for any part of which a person relies on an exemption to

speculative position limits under Sec. 150.3 of this chapter as

follows:

(i) Conditional spot month limit exemption. A conditional spot

month limit exemption under Sec. 150.3(c) of this chapter for any

commodity specially designated by the Commission under Sec. 19.03 for

reporting;

(ii) Pass-through swap exemption. A pass-through swap exemption

under Sec. 150.3(a)(1)(i) of this chapter and as defined in paragraph

(2)(ii)(B) of the definition of bona fide hedging position in Sec.

150.1 of this chapter, reporting separately for:

(A) Non-referenced-contract swap offset. A swap that is not a

referenced contract, as that term is defined in Sec. 150.1 of this

chapter, and which is executed opposite a counterparty for which the

swap would qualify as a bona fide hedging position and for which the

risk is offset with a referenced contract; and

(B) Spot-month swap offset. A cash-settled swap, regardless of

whether it is

[[Page 96928]]

a referenced contract, executed opposite a counterparty for which the

swap would qualify as a bona fide hedging position and for which the

risk is offset with a physical-delivery referenced contract in its spot

month;

(iii) Other exemption. Any other exemption from speculative

position limits under Sec. 150.3 of this chapter, including for a bona

fide hedging position as defined in Sec. 150.1 of this chapter or any

exemption granted under Sec. 150.3(b) or (d) of this chapter; or

(iv) Anticipatory exemption. An anticipatory exemption under Sec.

150.7 of this chapter.

(2) Persons filing cotton on call reports. Merchants and dealers of

cotton holding or controlling positions for futures delivery in cotton

that are reportable pursuant to Sec. 15.00(p)(1)(i) of this chapter;

or

(3) Persons responding to a special call. All persons exceeding

speculative position limits under Sec. 150.2 of this chapter or all

persons holding or controlling positions for future delivery that are

reportable pursuant to Sec. 15.00(p)(1) of this chapter who have

received a special call for series `04 reports from the Commission or

its designee. Persons subject to a special call shall file CFTC Form

204, 304, 504, or 604 as instructed in the special call. Filings in

response to a special call shall be made within one business day of

receipt of the special call unless otherwise specified in the call. For

the purposes of this paragraph, the Commission hereby delegates to the

Director of the Division of Market Oversight, or to such other person

designated by the Director, authority to issue calls for series `04

reports.

(b) Manner of reporting. The manner of reporting the information

required in Sec. 19.01 is subject to the following:

(1) Excluding certain source commodities, products or byproducts of

the cash commodity hedged. If the regular business practice of the

reporting person is to exclude certain source commodities, products or

byproducts in determining his cash positions for bona fide hedging

positions (as defined in Sec. 150.1 of this chapter), the same shall

be excluded in the report, provided that the amount of the source

commodity being excluded is de minimis, impractical to account for,

and/or on the opposite side of the market from the market participant's

hedging position. Such persons shall furnish to the Commission or its

designee upon request detailed information concerning the kind and

quantity of source commodity, product or byproduct so excluded.

Provided however, when reporting for the cash commodity of soybeans,

soybean oil, or soybean meal, the reporting person shall show the cash

positions of soybeans, soybean oil and soybean meal.

(2) Cross hedges. Cash positions that represent a commodity, or

products or byproducts of a commodity, that is different from the

commodity underlying a commodity derivative contract that is used for

hedging, shall be shown both in terms of the equivalent amount of the

commodity underlying the commodity derivative contract used for hedging

and in terms of the actual cash commodity as provided for on the

appropriate series `04 form.

(3) Standards and conversion factors. In computing their cash

position, every person shall use such standards and conversion factors

that are usual in the particular trade or that otherwise reflect the

value-fluctuation-equivalents of the cash position in terms of the

commodity underlying the commodity derivative contract used for

hedging. Such person shall furnish to the Commission upon request

detailed information concerning the basis for and derivation of such

conversion factors, including:

(i) The hedge ratio used to convert the actual cash commodity to

the equivalent amount of the commodity underlying the commodity

derivative contract used for hedging; and

(ii) An explanation of the methodology used for determining the

hedge ratio.

Sec. 19.01 Reports on stocks and fixed price purchases and sales.

(a) Information required--(1) Conditional spot month limit

exemption. Persons required to file '04 reports under Sec.

19.00(a)(1)(i) shall file CFTC Form 504 showing the composition of the

cash position of each commodity underlying a referenced contract that

is held or controlled including:

(i) The as of date;

(ii) The quantity of stocks owned of such commodity that either:

(A) Is in a position to be delivered on the physical-delivery core

referenced futures contract; or

(B) Underlies the cash-settled core referenced futures contract;

(iii) The quantity of fixed-price purchase commitments open

providing for receipt of such cash commodity in:

(A) The delivery period for the physical-delivery core referenced

futures contract; or

(B) The time period for cash-settlement price determination for the

cash-settled core referenced futures contract;

(iv) The quantity of unfixed-price sale commitments open providing

for delivery of such cash commodity in:

(A) The delivery period for the physical-delivery core referenced

futures contract; or

(B) The time period for cash-settlement price determination for the

cash-settled core referenced futures contract;

(v) The quantity of unfixed-price purchase commitments open

providing for receipt of such cash commodity in:

(A) The delivery period for the physical-delivery core referenced

futures contract; or

(B) The time period for cash-settlement price determination for the

cash-settled core referenced futures contract; and

(vi) The quantity of fixed-price sale commitments open providing

for delivery of such cash commodity in:

(A) The delivery period for the physical-delivery core referenced

futures contract; or

(B) The time period for cash-settlement price determination for the

cash-settled core referenced futures contract.

(2) Pass-through swap exemption. Persons required to file '04

reports under Sec. 19.00(a)(1)(ii) shall file CFTC Form 604:

(i) Non-referenced-contract swap offset. For each swap that is not

a referenced contract and which is executed opposite a counterparty for

which the transaction would qualify as a bona fide hedging position and

for which the risk is offset with a referenced contract, showing:

(A) The underlying commodity or commodity reference price;

(B) Any applicable clearing identifiers;

(C) The notional quantity;

(D) The gross long or short position in terms of futures-

equivalents in the core referenced futures contract; and

(E) The gross long or short positions in the referenced contract

for the offsetting risk position; and

(ii) Spot-month swap offset. For each cash-settled swap executed

opposite a counterparty for which the transaction would qualify as a

bona fide hedging position and for which the risk is offset with a

physical-delivery referenced contract held into a spot month, showing

for such cash-settled swap that is not a referenced contract the

information required under paragraph (a)(2)(i) of this section and for

such cash-settled swap that is a referenced contract:

(A) The gross long or short position for such cash-settled swap in

terms of futures-equivalents in the core referenced futures contract;

and

[[Page 96929]]

(B) The gross long or short positions in the physical-delivery

referenced contract for the offsetting risk position.

(3) Other exemptions. Persons required to file `04 reports under

Sec. 19.00(a)(1)(iii) shall file CFTC Form 204 reports showing the

composition of the cash position of each commodity hedged or underlying

a reportable position in units of such commodity and in terms of

futures equivalents of the core referenced futures contract, including:

(i) The as of date, the commodity derivative contract held or

controlled, and the equivalent core referenced futures contract;

(ii) The quantity of stocks owned of such commodities and their

products and byproducts;

(iii) The quantity of fixed-price purchase commitments open in such

cash commodities and their products and byproducts;

(iv) The quantity of fixed-price sale commitments open in such cash

commodities and their products and byproducts;

(v) The quantity of unfixed-price purchase and sale commitments

open in such cash commodities and their products and byproducts, in the

case of offsetting unfixed-price cash commodity sales and purchases;

and

(vi) For cotton, additional information that includes:

(A) The quantity of equity in cotton held, by merchant, producer or

agent, by the Commodity Credit Corporation under the provisions of the

Upland Cotton Program of the Agricultural Stabilization and

Conservation Service of the U.S. Department of Agriculture;

(B) The quantity of certificated cotton owned; and

(C) The quantity of non-certificated stocks owned.

(4) Anticipatory exemptions. Persons required to file '04 reports

under Sec. 19.00(a)(1)(iv) shall file CFTC Form 204 monthly on the

remaining unsold, unfilled and other anticipated activity for the

Specified Period that was reported on such person's most recent initial

statement or annual update filed on Form 704, pursuant to Sec. 150.7

(e) of this chapter.

(b) Time and place of filing reports--(1) General. Except for

reports specified in paragraphs (b)(2) or (b)(3) of this section, each

report shall be made monthly:

(i) As of the close of business on the last Friday of the month,

and

(ii) As specified in paragraph (b)(4) of this section, and not

later than 9 a.m. Eastern Time on the third business day following the

date of the report.

(2) Spot month reports. Persons required to file `04 reports under

Sec. 19.00(a)(1)(i) for special commodities as specified by the

Commission under Sec. 19.03 or under Sec. 19.00(a)(1)(ii)(B) shall

file each report:

(i) As of the close of business for each day the person exceeds the

limit during a spot period up to and through the day the person's

position first falls below the position limit; and

(ii) As specified in paragraph (b)(4) of this section, and not

later than 9 a.m. Eastern Time on the next business day following the

date of the report.

(3) Special calls. Persons required to file '04 reports in response

to special calls made under Sec. 19.00(a)(3) shall file each report as

specified in paragraph (b)(4) of this section within one business day

of receipt of the special call unless otherwise specified in the call.

(4) Electronic filing. CFTC `04 reports must be transmitted using

the format, coding structure, and electronic data transmission

procedures approved in writing by the Commission.

Sec. 19.02 Reports pertaining to cotton on call purchases and sales.

(a) Information required. Persons required to file `04 reports

under Sec. 19.00(a)(2) shall file CFTC Form 304 reports showing the

quantity of call cotton bought or sold on which the price has not been

fixed, together with the respective futures on which the purchase or

sale is based. As used herein, call cotton refers to spot cotton bought

or sold, or contracted for purchase or sale at a price to be fixed

later based upon a specified future.

(b) Time and place of filing reports. Each report shall be made

weekly as of the close of business on Friday and filed using the

procedure under Sec. 19.01(b)(3), not later than 9 a.m. Eastern Time

on the third business day following the date of the report.

Sec. 19.03 Reports pertaining to special commodities.

From time to time to facilitate surveillance in certain commodity

derivative contracts, the Commission may designate a commodity

derivative contract for reporting under Sec. 19.00(a)(1)(i) and will

publish such determination in the Federal Register and on its Web site.

Persons holding or controlling positions in such special commodity

derivative contracts must, beginning 30 days after notice is published

in the Federal Register, comply with the reporting requirements under

Sec. 19.00(a)(1)(i) and file Form 504 for conditional spot month limit

exemptions.

Sec. 19.04 Delegation of authority to the Director of the Division of

Market Oversight.

(1) The Commission hereby delegates, until it orders otherwise, to

the Director of the Division of Market Oversight or such other employee

or employees as the Director may designate from time to time, the

authority in Sec. 19.01 to provide instructions or to determine the

format, coding structure, and electronic data transmission procedures

for submitting data records and any other information required under

this part.

(2) The Director of the Division of Market Oversight may submit to

the Commission for its consideration any matter which has been

delegated in this section.

(3) Nothing in this section prohibits the Commission, at its

election, from exercising the authority delegated in this section.

Sec. Sec. 19.05-19.10 [Reserved]

Appendix A to Part 19--Forms 204, 304, 504, 604, and 704

BILLING CODE 6351-01-P

[[Page 96930]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.003

[[Page 96931]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.004

[[Page 96932]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.005

[[Page 96933]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.006

[[Page 96934]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.007

[[Page 96935]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.008

[[Page 96936]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.009

[[Page 96937]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.010

[[Page 96938]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.011

[[Page 96939]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.012

[[Page 96940]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.013

[[Page 96941]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.014

[[Page 96942]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.015

[[Page 96943]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.016

[[Page 96944]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.017

[[Page 96945]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.018

[[Page 96946]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.019

[[Page 96947]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.020

[[Page 96948]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.021

[[Page 96949]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.022

[[Page 96950]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.023

[[Page 96951]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.024

[[Page 96952]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.025

[[Page 96953]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.026

[[Page 96954]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.027

[[Page 96955]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.028

[[Page 96956]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.029

[[Page 96957]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.030

[[Page 96958]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.031

[[Page 96959]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.032

[[Page 96960]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.033

[[Page 96961]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.034

[[Page 96962]]

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP30DE16.035

[[Page 96963]]

BILLING CODE 6351-01-C

PART 37--SWAP EXECUTION FACILITIES

0

13. The authority citation for part 37 continues to read as follows:

Authority: 7 U.S.C. 1a, 2, 5, 6, 6c, 7, 7a-2, 7b-3, and 12a, as

amended by Titles VII and VIII of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform

and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376.

0

14. Revise Sec. 37.601 to read as follows:

Sec. 37.601 Additional sources for compliance.

A swap execution facility that is a trading facility must meet the

requirements of part 150 of this chapter, as applicable.

0

15. In Appendix B to part 37, under the heading Core Principle 6 of

Section 5h of the Act--Position Limits or Accountability, revise

paragraphs (A) and (B) to read as follows:

Appendix B to Part 37--Guidance on, and Acceptable Practices in,

Compliance with Core Principles

* * * * *

Core Principle 6 of Section 5h of the Act--Position Limits or

Accountability

(A) In general. To reduce the potential threat of market

manipulation or congestion, especially during trading in the

delivery month, a swap execution facility that is a trading facility

shall adopt for each of the contracts of the facility, as is

necessary and appropriate, position limitations or position

accountability for speculators.

(B) Position limits. For any contract that is subject to a

position limitation established by the Commission pursuant to

section 4a(a), the swap execution facility shall:

(1) Set its position limitation at a level not higher than the

Commission limitation; and

(2) Monitor positions established on or through the swap

execution facility for compliance with the limit set by the

Commission and the limit, if any, set by the swap execution

facility.

(a) Guidance.

(1) Until a swap execution facility has access to sufficient

swap position information, a swap execution facility that is a

trading facility need not demonstrate compliance with Core Principle

6(B). A swap execution facility has access to sufficient swap

position information if, for example:

(i) It has access to daily information about its market

participants' open swap positions; or

(ii) It knows, including through knowledge gained in

surveillance of heavy trading activity occurring on or pursuant to

the rules of the swap execution facility, that its market

participants regularly engage in large volumes of speculative

trading activity that would cause reasonable surveillance personnel

at a swap execution facility to inquire further about a market

participant's intentions or open swap positions.

(2) When a swap execution facility has access to sufficient swap

position information, this guidance is no longer applicable. At such

time, a swap execution facility is required to demonstrate

compliance with Core Principle 6(B).

(b) Acceptable practices. [Reserved]

* * * * *

PART 38--DESIGNATED CONTRACT MARKETS

0

16. The authority citation for part 38 continues to read as follows:

Authority: 7 U.S.C. 1a, 2, 6, 6a, 6c, 6d, 6e, 6f, 6g, 6i, 6j,

6k, 6l, 6m, 6n, 7, 7a-2, 7b, 7b-1, 7b-3, 8, 9, 15, and 21, as

amended by the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection

Act, Pub. L. 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376.

0

17. Revise Sec. 38.301 to read as follows:

Sec. 38.301 Position limitations and accountability.

A designated contract market must meet the requirements of part 150

of this chapter, as applicable.

0

18. In Appendix B to part 38, under the heading Core Principle 5 of

section 5(d) of the Act: Position Limitations or Accountability, revise

paragraphs (A) and (B) to read as follows:

Appendix B to Part 38--Guidance on, and Acceptable Practices in,

Compliance with Core Principles

* * * * *

Core Principle 5 of Section 5(d) of the Act: Position Limitations or

Accountability

(A) In general.--To reduce the potential threat of market

manipulation or congestion (especially during trading in the

delivery month), the board of trade shall adopt for each contract of

the board of trade, as is necessary and appropriate, position

limitations or position accountability for speculators.

(B) Maximum allowable position limitation.--For any contract

that is subject to a position limitation established by the

Commission pursuant to section 4a(a), the board of trade shall set

the position limitation of the board of trade at a level not higher

than the position limitation established by the Commission.

(a) Guidance.

(1) Until a board of trade has access to sufficient swap

position information, a board of trade need not demonstrate

compliance with Core Principle 5(B) with respect to swaps. A board

of trade has access to sufficient swap position information if, for

example:

(i) It has access to daily information about its market

participants' open swap positions; or

(ii) It knows, including through knowledge gained in

surveillance of heavy trading activity occurring on or pursuant to

the rules of the designated contract market, that its market

participants regularly engage in large volumes of speculative

trading activity that would cause reasonable surveillance personnel

at a board of trade to inquire further about a market participant's

intentions or open swap positions.

(2) When a board of trade has access to sufficient swap position

information, this guidance is no longer applicable. At such time, a

board of trade is required to demonstrate compliance with Core

Principle 5(B) with respect to swaps.

(b) Acceptable Practices. [Reserved]

* * * * *

PART 140--ORGANIZATION, FUNCTIONS, AND PROCEDURES OF THE COMMISSION

0

19. The authority citation for part 140 continues to read as follows:

Authority: 7 U.S.C. 2(a)(12), 12a, 13(c), 13(d), 13(e), and

16(b).

Sec. 140.97 [Removed and reserved]

0

20. Remove and reserve Sec. 140.97.

PART 150--LIMITS ON POSITIONS

0

21. The authority citation for part 150 continues to read as follows:

Authority: 7 U.S.C. 1a, 2, 5, 6, 6a, 6c, 6f, 6g, 6t, 12a, 19,

as amended by Title VII of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and

Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010).

0

22. Revise Sec. 150.1 to read as follows:

Sec. 150.1 Definitions.

As used in this part--

Bona fide hedging position means--

(1) Hedges of an excluded commodity. For a position in commodity

derivative contracts in an excluded commodity, as that term is defined

in section 1a(19) of the Act:

(i) Such position is economically appropriate to the reduction of

risks in the conduct and management of a commercial enterprise and is

enumerated in paragraph (3), (4) or (5) of this definition; or

(ii) Is otherwise recognized as a bona fide hedging position by the

designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a trading

facility, pursuant to such market's rules submitted to the Commission,

which rules may include risk management exemptions consistent with

Appendix A of this part; and

(2) Hedges of a physical commodity--general definition. For a

position in commodity derivative contracts in a physical commodity:

(i) Such position:

(A) Represents a substitute for transactions made or to be made, or

positions taken or to be taken, at a later time in a physical marketing

channel;

(B) Is economically appropriate to the reduction of risks in the

conduct and management of a commercial enterprise;

(C) Arises from the potential change in the value of--

[[Page 96964]]

(1) Assets which a person owns, produces, manufactures, processes,

or merchandises or anticipates owning, producing, manufacturing,

processing, or merchandising;

(2) Liabilities which a person owes or anticipates incurring; or

(3) Services that a person provides, purchases, or anticipates

providing or purchasing; or

(ii)(A) Pass-through swap offsets. Such position reduces risks

attendant to a position resulting from a swap in the same physical

commodity that was executed opposite a counterparty for which the swap

would qualify as a bona fide hedging position pursuant to paragraph

(2)(i) of this definition (a pass-through swap counterparty), provided

that the bona fides of the pass-through swap counterparty may be

determined at the time of the transaction;

(B) Pass-through swaps. Such swap position was executed opposite a

pass-through swap counterparty and to the extent such swap position has

been offset pursuant to paragraph (2)(ii)(A) of this definition; or

(C) Offsets of bona fide hedging swap positions. Such position

reduces risks attendant to a position resulting from a swap that meets

the requirements of paragraph (2)(i) of this definition.

(iii) Additional requirements for enumeration or other recognition.

Notwithstanding the foregoing general definition, a position in

commodity derivative contracts in a physical commodity shall be

classified as a bona fide hedging position only if:

(A) The position satisfies the requirements of paragraph (2)(i) of

this definition and is enumerated in paragraph (3), (4), or (5) of this

definition;

(B) The position satisfies the requirements of paragraph (2)(ii) of

this definition, provided that no offsetting position is maintained in

any physical-delivery commodity derivative contract during the lesser

of the last five days of trading or the time period for the spot month

in such physical-delivery commodity derivative contract; or

(C) The position has been otherwise recognized as a non-enumerated

bona fide hedging position by either a designated contract market or

swap execution facility, each in accordance with Sec. 150.9(a); or by

the Commission.

(3) Enumerated hedging positions. A bona fide hedging position

includes any of the following specific positions:

(i) Hedges of inventory and cash commodity purchase contracts.

Short positions in commodity derivative contracts that do not exceed in

quantity ownership or fixed-price purchase contracts in the contract's

underlying cash commodity by the same person.

(ii) Hedges of cash commodity sales contracts. Long positions in

commodity derivative contracts that do not exceed in quantity the

fixed-price sales contracts in the contract's underlying cash commodity

by the same person and the quantity equivalent of fixed-price sales

contracts of the cash products and by-products of such commodity by the

same person.

(iii) Hedges of unfilled anticipated requirements. Provided that

such positions in a physical-delivery commodity derivative contract,

during the lesser of the last five days of trading or the time period

for the spot month in such physical-delivery contract, do not exceed

the person's unfilled anticipated requirements of the same cash

commodity for that month and for the next succeeding month:

(A) Long positions in commodity derivative contracts that do not

exceed in quantity unfilled anticipated requirements of the same cash

commodity, for processing, manufacturing, or use by the same person;

and

(B) Long positions in commodity derivative contracts that do not

exceed in quantity unfilled anticipated requirements of the same cash

commodity for resale by a utility to its customers.

(iv) Hedges by agents. Long or short positions in commodity

derivative contracts by an agent who does not own or has not contracted

to sell or purchase the offsetting cash commodity at a fixed price,

provided that the agent is responsible for merchandising the cash

positions that are being offset in commodity derivative contracts and

the agent has a contractual arrangement with the person who owns the

commodity or holds the cash market commitment being offset.

(4) Other enumerated hedging positions. A bona fide hedging

position also includes the following specific positions, provided that

no such position is maintained in any physical-delivery commodity

derivative contract during the lesser of the last five days of trading

or the time period for the spot month in such physical-delivery

contract:

(i) Hedges of unsold anticipated production. Short positions in

commodity derivative contracts that do not exceed in quantity unsold

anticipated production of the same commodity by the same person.

(ii) Hedges of offsetting unfixed-price cash commodity sales and

purchases. Short and long positions in commodity derivative contracts

that do not exceed in quantity that amount of the same cash commodity

that has been bought and sold by the same person at unfixed prices:

(A) Basis different delivery months in the same commodity

derivative contract; or

(B) Basis different commodity derivative contracts in the same

commodity, regardless of whether the commodity derivative contracts are

in the same calendar month.

(iii) Hedges of anticipated royalties. Short positions in commodity

derivative contracts offset by the anticipated change in value of

mineral royalty rights that are owned by the same person, provided that

the royalty rights arise out of the production of the commodity

underlying the commodity derivative contract.

(iv) Hedges of services. Short or long positions in commodity

derivative contracts offset by the anticipated change in value of

receipts or payments due or expected to be due under an executed

contract for services held by the same person, provided that the

contract for services arises out of the production, manufacturing,

processing, use, or transportation of the commodity underlying the

commodity derivative contract.

(5) Cross-commodity hedges. Positions in commodity derivative

contracts described in paragraph (2)(ii), paragraphs (3)(i) through

(iv) and paragraphs (4)(i) through (iv) of this definition may also be

used to offset the risks arising from a commodity other than the same

cash commodity underlying a commodity derivative contract, provided

that the fluctuations in value of the position in the commodity

derivative contract, or the commodity underlying the commodity

derivative contract, are substantially related to the fluctuations in

value of the actual or anticipated cash position or pass-through swap

and no such position is maintained in any physical-delivery commodity

derivative contract during the lesser of the last five days of trading

or the time period for the spot month in such physical-delivery

contract.

(6) Offsets of commodity trade options. For purposes of this

definition, a commodity trade option, meeting the requirements of Sec.

32.3 of this chapter for a commodity option transaction, may be deemed

a cash commodity purchase or sales contract, as appropriate, provided

that such option is adjusted on a futures-equivalent basis. By way of

example, a commodity trade option with a fixed strike price may be

converted to a futures-equivalent basis, and, on that futures-

equivalent basis,

[[Page 96965]]

deemed a cash commodity sale, in the case of a short call option or

long put option, or a cash commodity purchase, in the case of a long

call option or short put option.

Calendar spread contract means a cash-settled agreement, contract,

or transaction that represents the difference between the settlement

price in one or a series of contract months of an agreement, contract

or transaction and the settlement price of another contract month or

another series of contract months' settlement prices for the same

agreement, contract or transaction.

Commodity derivative contract means, for this part, any futures,

option, or swap contract in a commodity (other than a security futures

product as defined in section 1a(45) of the Act).

Commodity index contract means an agreement, contract, or

transaction that is not a location basis contract or any type of spread

contract, based on an index comprised of prices of commodities that are

not the same or substantially the same.

Core referenced futures contract means a futures contract that is

listed in Sec. 150.2(d).

Eligible affiliate. An eligible affiliate means an entity with

respect to which another person:

(1) Directly or indirectly holds either:

(i) A majority of the equity securities of such entity, or

(ii) The right to receive upon dissolution of, or the contribution

of, a majority of the capital of such entity;

(2) Reports its financial statements on a consolidated basis under

Generally Accepted Accounting Principles or International Financial

Reporting Standards, and such consolidated financial statements include

the financial results of such entity; and

(3) Is required to aggregate the positions of such entity under

Sec. 150.4 and does not claim an exemption from aggregation for such

entity.

Eligible entity \1\ means a commodity pool operator, the operator

of a trading vehicle which is excluded or who itself has qualified for

exclusion from the definition of the term ``pool'' or ``commodity pool

operator,'' respectively, under Sec. 4.5 of this chapter; the limited

partner or shareholder in a commodity pool the operator of which is

exempt from registration under Sec. 4.13 of this chapter; a commodity

trading advisor; a bank or trust company; a savings association; an

insurance company; or the separately organized affiliates of any of the

above entities:

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1\ The definition of the term, eligible entity, was amended by

the Commission in a final rule published on December 16, 2016 (81 FR

91454, 91489). The unamended version of the definition presented

here is included solely to maintain the continuity of this

regulatory section and for the convenience of the reader. The

definition of the term, eligible entity, is not a subject of this

reproposal and will be revised when the amended definition takes

effect on February 14, 2017.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

(1) Which authorizes an independent account controller

independently to control all trading decisions for positions it holds

directly or indirectly, or on its behalf, but without its day-to-day

direction; and

(2) Which maintains:

(i) Only such minimum control over the independent account

controller as is consistent with its fiduciary responsibilities and

necessary to fulfill its duty to supervise diligently the trading done

on its behalf; or

(ii) If a limited partner or shareholder of a commodity pool the

operator of which is exempt from registration under Sec. 4.13 of this

chapter, only such limited control as is consistent with its status.

Entity means a ``person'' as defined in section 1a of the Act.

Excluded commodity means an ``excluded commodity'' as defined in

section 1a of the Act.

Futures-equivalent means

(1) An option contract, whether an option on a future or an option

that is a swap, which has been adjusted by an economically reasonable

and analytically supported risk factor, or delta coefficient, for that

option computed as of the previous day's close or the current day's

close or contemporaneously during the trading day, and converted to an

economically equivalent amount of an open position in a core referenced

futures contract, provided however, if a participant's position exceeds

position limits as a result of an option assignment, that participant

is allowed one business day to liquidate the excess position without

being considered in violation of the limits;

(2) A futures contract which has been converted to an economically

equivalent amount of an open position in a core referenced futures

contract; and

(3) A swap which has been converted to an economically equivalent

amount of an open position in a core referenced futures contract.

Independent account controller \2\ means a person--

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\2\ The definition of the term, independent account controller,

was amended by the Commission in a final rule published on December

16, 2016 (81 FR 91454, 91489). The unamended version of the

definition presented here is included solely to maintain the

continuity of this regulatory section and for the convenience of the

reader. The definition of the term, independent account controller,

is not a subject of this reproposal and will be revised when the

amended definition takes effect on February 14, 2017.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

(1) Who specifically is authorized by an eligible entity, as

defined in this section, independently to control trading decisions on

behalf of, but without the day-to-day direction of, the eligible

entity;

(2) Over whose trading the eligible entity maintains only such

minimum control as is consistent with its fiduciary responsibilities to

fulfill its duty to supervise diligently the trading done on its behalf

or as is consistent with such other legal rights or obligations which

may be incumbent upon the eligible entity to fulfill;

(3) Who trades independently of the eligible entity and of any

other independent account controller trading for the eligible entity;

(4) Who has no knowledge of trading decisions by any other

independent account controller; and

(5) Who is registered as a futures commission merchant, an

introducing broker, a commodity trading advisor, an associated person

or any such registrant, or is a general partner of a commodity pool the

operator of which is exempt from registration under Sec. 4.13 of this

chapter.

Intercommodity spread contract means a cash-settled agreement,

contract or transaction that represents the difference between the

settlement price of a referenced contract and the settlement price of

another contract, agreement, or transaction that is based on a

different commodity.

Intermarket spread position means a long (short) position in one or

more commodity derivative contracts in a particular commodity, or its

products or its by-products, at a particular designated contract market

or swap execution facility and a short (long) position in one or more

commodity derivative contracts in that same, or similar, commodity, or

its products or its by-products, away from that particular designated

contract market or swap execution facility.

Intramarket spread position means a long position in one or more

commodity derivative contracts in a particular commodity, or its

products or its by-products, and a short position in one or more

commodity derivative contracts in the same, or similar, commodity, or

its products or its by-products, on the same designated contract market

or swap execution facility.

Location basis contract means a commodity derivative contract that

is cash-settled based on the difference in:

(1) The price, directly or indirectly, of:

(i) A particular core referenced futures contract; or

[[Page 96966]]

(ii) A commodity deliverable on a particular core referenced

futures contract, whether at par, a fixed discount to par, or a premium

to par; and

(2) The price, at a different delivery location or pricing point

than that of the same particular core referenced futures contract,

directly or indirectly, of:

(i) A commodity deliverable on the same particular core referenced

futures contract, whether at par, a fixed discount to par, or a premium

to par; or

(ii) A commodity that is listed in Appendix B to this part as

substantially the same as a commodity underlying the same core

referenced futures contract.

Long position means, on a futures-equivalent basis, a long call

option, a short put option, a long underlying futures contract, or a

swap position that is equivalent to a long futures contract.

Physical commodity means any agricultural commodity as that term is

defined in Sec. 1.3 of this chapter or any exempt commodity as that

term is defined in section 1a(20) of the Act.

Pre-enactment swap means any swap entered into prior to enactment

of the Dodd-Frank Act of 2010 (July 21, 2010), the terms of which have

not expired as of the date of enactment of that Act.

Pre-existing position means any position in a commodity derivative

contract acquired in good faith prior to the effective date of any

bylaw, rule, regulation or resolution that specifies an initial

speculative position limit level or a subsequent change to that level.

Referenced contract means a core referenced futures contract listed

in Sec. 150.2(d) or, on a futures equivalent basis with respect to a

particular core referenced futures contract, a futures contract,

options contract, or swap that is:

(1) Directly or indirectly linked, including being partially or

fully settled on, or priced at a fixed differential to, the price of

that particular core referenced futures contract; or

(2) Directly or indirectly linked, including being partially or

fully settled on, or priced at a fixed differential to, the price of

the same commodity underlying that particular core referenced futures

contract for delivery at the same location or locations as specified in

that particular core referenced futures contract.

(3) The definition of referenced contract does not include any

guarantee of a swap, a location basis contract, a commodity index

contract, or a trade option that meets the requirements of Sec. 32.3

of this chapter.

Short position means, on a futures-equivalent basis, a short call

option, a long put option, a short underlying futures contract, or a

swap position that is equivalent to a short futures contract.

Speculative position limit means the maximum position, either net

long or net short, in a commodity derivatives contract that may be held

or controlled by one person, absent an exemption, such as an exemption

for a bona fide hedging position. This limit may apply to a person's

combined position in all commodity derivative contracts in a particular

commodity (all-months-combined), a person's position in a single month

of commodity derivative contracts in a particular commodity, or a

person's position in the spot month of commodity derivative contacts in

a particular commodity. Such a limit may be established under federal

regulations or rules of a designated contract market or swap execution

facility. An exchange may also apply other limits, such as a limit on

gross long or gross short positions, or a limit on holding or

controlling delivery instruments.

Spot month means--

(1) For physical-delivery core referenced futures contracts, the

period of time beginning at the earlier of the close of business on the

trading day preceding the first day on which delivery notices can be

issued by the clearing organization of a contract market, or the close

of business on the trading day preceding the third-to-last trading day,

until the contract expires, except as follows:

(i) For ICE Futures U.S. Sugar No. 11 (SB) referenced contract, the

spot month means the period of time beginning at the opening of trading

on the second business day following the expiration of the regular

option contract traded on the expiring futures contract until the

contract expires;

(ii) For ICE Futures U.S. Sugar No. 16 (SF) referenced contract,

the spot month means the period of time beginning on the third-to-last

trading day of the contract month until the contract expires;

(iii) For Chicago Mercantile Exchange Live Cattle (LC) referenced

contract, the spot month means the period of time beginning at the

close trading on the fifth business day of the contract month until the

contract expires;

(2) For cash-settled core referenced futures contracts:

(i) [Reserved]

(3) For referenced contracts other than core referenced futures

contracts, the spot month means the same period as that of the relevant

core referenced futures contract.

Spread contract means either a calendar spread contract or an

intercommodity spread contract.

Swap means ``swap'' as that term is defined in section 1a of the

Act and as further defined in Sec. 1.3 of this chapter.

Swap dealer means ``swap dealer'' as that term is defined in

section 1a of the Act and as further defined in Sec. 1.3 of this

chapter.

Transition period swap means a swap entered into during the period

commencing after the enactment of the Dodd-Frank Act of 2010 (July 21,

2010), and ending 60 days after the publication in the Federal Register

of final amendments to this part implementing section 737 of the Dodd-

Frank Act of 2010.

0

23. Revise Sec. 150.2 to read as follows:

Sec. 150.2 Speculative position limits.

(a) Spot-month speculative position limits. No person may hold or

control positions in referenced contracts in the spot month, net long

or net short, in excess of the level specified by the Commission for:

(1) Physical-delivery referenced contracts; and, separately,

(2) Cash-settled referenced contracts;

(b) Single-month and all-months-combined speculative position

limits. No person may hold or control positions, net long or net short,

in referenced contracts in a single month or in all months combined

(including the spot month) in excess of the levels specified by the

Commission.

(c) For purposes of this part:

(1) The spot month and any single month shall be those of the core

referenced futures contract; and

(2) An eligible affiliate is not required to comply separately with

speculative position limits.

(d) Core referenced futures contracts. Speculative position limits

apply to referenced contracts based on the core referenced futures

contracts listed in Table Core Referenced Futures Contracts:

Core Referenced Futures Contracts

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commodity type Designated contract market Core referenced futures contract \1\

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Legacy Agricultural............... Chicago Board of Trade.... Corn (C).

[[Page 96967]]

Oats (O).

Soybeans (S).

Soybean Meal (SM).

Soybean Oil (SO).

Wheat (W).

Hard Winter Wheat (KW).

ICE Futures U.S........... Cotton No. 2 (CT).

Minneapolis Grain Exchange Hard Red Spring Wheat (MWE).

Other Agricultural................ Chicago Board of Trade.... Rough Rice (RR).

Chicago Mercantile Live Cattle (LC).

Exchange.

ICE Futures U.S........... Cocoa (CC).

Coffee C (KC).

FCOJ-A (OJ).

U.S. Sugar No. 11 (SB).

U.S. Sugar No. 16 (SF).

Energy............................ New York Mercantile Light Sweet Crude Oil (CL).

Exchange.

NY Harbor ULSD (HO).

RBOB Gasoline (RB).

Henry Hub Natural Gas (NG).

Metals............................ Commodity Exchange, Inc... Gold (GC).

Silver (SI).

Copper (HG).

New York Mercantile Palladium (PA).

Exchange.

Platinum (PL).

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1\ The core referenced futures contract includes any successor contracts.

(e) Levels of speculative position limits--(1) Initial levels. The

initial levels of speculative position limits are fixed by the

Commission at the levels listed in Appendix D to this part; provided

however, compliance with such initial speculative limits shall not be

required until January 3, 2018, which date shall be the initial

establishment date for purposes of paragraphs (e)(3) and (4) of this

section.

(2) Subsequent levels. (i) The Commission shall fix subsequent

levels of speculative position limits in accordance with the procedures

in this section and publish such levels on the Commission's Web site at

http://www.cftc.gov.

(ii) Such subsequent speculative position limit levels shall each

apply beginning on the close of business of the last business day of

the second complete calendar month after publication of such levels;

provided however, if such close of business is in a spot month of a

core referenced futures contract, the subsequent spot-month level shall

apply beginning with the next spot month for that contract.

(iii) All subsequent levels of speculative position limits shall be

rounded up to the nearest hundred contracts.

(3) Procedure for computing levels of spot-month limits. (i) No

less frequently than every two calendar years, the Commission shall fix

the level of the spot-month limit no greater than one-quarter of the

estimated spot-month deliverable supply in the relevant core referenced

futures contract. Unless the Commission determines to rely on its own

estimate of deliverable supply, the Commission shall utilize the

estimated spot-month deliverable supply provided by a designated

contract market. If the Commission determines to rely on its own

estimate of deliverable supply, then the Commission shall publish such

estimate for public comment in the Federal Register; provided however,

that the Commission may determine to fix the level of the spot-month

limit at a level, recommended by the designated contract market listing

the relevant core referenced futures contract for good cause shown,

that is less than one-quarter of the estimated spot-month deliverable

supply, or not to change the level of the spot-month limit.

(ii) Estimates of deliverable supply. (A) Each designated contract

market in a core referenced futures contract shall supply to the

Commission an estimated spot-month deliverable supply. A designated

contract market may use the guidance regarding deliverable supply in

Appendix C to part 38 of this chapter. Each estimate must be

accompanied by a description of the methodology used to derive the

estimate and any statistical data supporting the estimate, and must be

submitted no later than the following:

(1) For energy commodities, January 31 of the second calendar year

following the most recent Commission action establishing such limit

levels;

(2) For metals commodities, March 31 of the second calendar year

following the most recent Commission action establishing such limit

levels;

(3) For legacy agricultural commodities, May 31 of the second

calendar year following the most recent Commission action establishing

such limit levels; and

(4) For other agricultural commodities, August 31 of the second

calendar year following the most recent Commission action establishing

such limit levels.

(B) Notwithstanding paragraph (e)(3)(ii)(A) of this section, each

designated contract market may petition the Commission not less than

two calendar months before the due date for submission of an estimate

of deliverable supply under paragraph (e)(3)(ii)(A) of this section,

recommending that the Commission not change the spot-month limit. Such

recommendation should include a summary of the designated contract

market's experience administering its spot-month limit. The Commission

shall determine not less than one calendar month before such due date

whether to accept the designated contract market's recommendation. If

the Commission accepts such recommendation, then the designated

contract market need not submit an estimated spot-month deliverable

supply for such due date.

(4) Procedure for computing levels of single-month and all-months-

combined limits. No less frequently than every two calendar years, the

Commission shall fix the level, for each referenced contract, of the

single-month limit and the all-

[[Page 96968]]

months-combined limit. Each such limit shall be based on 10 percent of

the estimated average open interest in referenced contracts, up to

25,000 contracts, with a marginal increase of 2.5 percent thereafter;

provided however, the Commission may determine not to change the level

of the single-month limit or the all-months-combined limit.

(i) Time periods for average open interest. The Commission shall

estimate average open interest in referenced contracts based on the

largest annual average open interest computed for each of the past two

calendar years. The Commission may estimate average open interest in

referenced contracts using either month-end open contracts or open

contracts for each business day in the time period, as practical.

(ii) Data sources for average open interest. The Commission shall

estimate average open interest in referenced contracts using data

reported to the Commission pursuant to part 16 of this chapter, and

open swaps reported to the Commission pursuant to part 20 of this

chapter or data obtained by the Commission from swap data repositories

collecting data pursuant to part 45 of this chapter. Options listed on

designated contract markets shall be adjusted using an option delta

reported to the Commission pursuant to part 16 of this chapter. Swaps

shall be counted on a futures equivalent basis, equal to the

economically equivalent amount of core referenced futures contracts

reported pursuant to part 20 of this chapter or as calculated by the

Commission using swap data collected pursuant to part 45 of this

chapter.

(iii) Publication of average open interest. The Commission shall

publish estimates of average open interest in referenced contracts on a

monthly basis, as practical, after such data is submitted to the

Commission.

(iv) Minimum levels. Provided however, notwithstanding the above,

the minimum levels shall be the greater of the level of the spot month

limit determined under paragraph (e)(3) of this section or 5,000

contracts.

(f) Pre-existing positions--(1) Pre-existing positions in a spot-

month. Other than pre-enactment and transition period swaps exempted

under Sec. 150.3(d), a person shall comply with spot month speculative

position limits.

(2) Pre-existing positions in a non-spot-month. A single-month or

all-months-combined speculative position limit established under this

section shall not apply to any commodity derivative contract acquired

in good faith prior to the effective date of such limit, provided

however, that if such position is not a pre-enactment or transition

period swap then that position shall be attributed to the person if the

person's position is increased after the effective date of such limit.

(g) Positions on foreign boards of trade. The aggregate speculative

position limits established under this section shall apply to a person

with positions in referenced contracts executed on, or pursuant to the

rules of a foreign board of trade, provided that:

(1) Such referenced contracts settle against any price (including

the daily or final settlement price) of one or more contracts listed

for trading on a designated contract market or swap execution facility

that is a trading facility; and

(2) The foreign board of trade makes available such referenced

contracts to its members or other participants located in the United

States through direct access to its electronic trading and order

matching system.

(h) Anti-evasion provision. For the purposes of applying the

speculative position limits in this section, a commodity index contract

used to circumvent speculative position limits shall be considered to

be a referenced contract.

(i) Delegation of authority to the Director of the Division of

Market Oversight. (1) The Commission hereby delegates, until it orders

otherwise, to the Director of the Division of Market Oversight or such

other employee or employees as the Director may designate from time to

time, the authority in paragraph (e) of this section to fix and publish

subsequent levels of speculative position limits, including the

authority not to change levels of such limits, and the authority in

paragraph (e)(3)(iii) of this section to relieve a designated contract

market from the requirement to submit an estimate of deliverable

supply.

(2) The Director of the Division of Market Oversight may submit to

the Commission for its consideration any matter which has been

delegated in this section.

(3) Nothing in this section prohibits the Commission, at its

election, from exercising the authority delegated in this section.

(j) The Commission will periodically update these initial levels

for speculative position limits and publish such subsequent levels on

its Web site at: http://www.cftc.gov.

0

24. Revise Sec. 150.3 to read as follows:

Sec. 150.3 Exemptions.

(a) Positions which may exceed limits. The position limits set

forth in Sec. 150.2 may be exceeded to the extent that:

(1) Such positions are:

(i) Bona fide hedging positions that comply with the definition in

Sec. 150.1, provided that:

(A) For non-enumerated bona fide hedges, the person has not

otherwise been notified by the Commission under Sec. 150.9(d)(4) or,

under rules adopted pursuant to Sec. 150.9(a)(4)(iv)(B), by the

designated contract market or swap execution facility; and

(B) For anticipatory bona fide hedging positions under paragraphs

(3)(iii), (4)(i), (4)(iii), (4)(iv) and (5) of the bona fide hedging

position definition in Sec. 150.1, the person complies with the filing

requirements found in Sec. 150.7 or the filing requirements adopted,

in accordance with Sec. 150.11(a)(3), by a designated contract market

or swap execution facility, as applicable;

(ii) Financial distress positions exempted under paragraph (b) of

this section;

(iii) Conditional spot-month limit positions exempted under

paragraph (c) of this section;

(iv) Spread positions recognized by a designated contract market or

swap execution facility, each in accordance with Sec. 150.10(a), or

the Commission, provided that the person has not otherwise been

notified by the Commission under Sec. 150.10(d)(4) or by the

designated contract market or swap execution facility under rules

adopted pursuant to Sec. 150.10(a)(4)(iv)(B); or

(v) Other positions exempted under paragraph (e) of this section;

and that

(2) The recordkeeping requirements of paragraph (g) of this section

are met; and further that

(3) The reporting requirements of part 19 of this chapter are met.

(b) Financial distress exemptions. Upon specific request made to

the Commission, the Commission may exempt a person or related persons

under financial distress circumstances for a time certain from any of

the requirements of this part. Financial distress circumstances include

situations involving the potential default or bankruptcy of a customer

of the requesting person or persons, an affiliate of the requesting

person or persons, or a potential acquisition target of the requesting

person or persons.

(c) Conditional spot-month limit exemption. The position limit set

forth in Sec. 150.2 may be exceeded for natural gas cash-settled

referenced contracts, provided that such positions do not exceed 10,000

contracts and the person holding or controlling such positions does not

hold or control positions in spot-month physical-delivery referenced

contracts.

[[Page 96969]]

(d) Pre-enactment and transition period swaps exemption. The

speculative position limits set forth in Sec. 150.2 shall not apply to

positions acquired in good faith in any pre-enactment swap, or in any

transition period swap, in either case as defined by Sec. 150.1;

provided however, that a person may net such positions with post-

effective date commodity derivative contracts for the purpose of

complying with any non-spot-month speculative position limit.

(e) Other exemptions. Any person engaging in risk-reducing

practices commonly used in the market, which they believe may not be

specifically enumerated in the definition of bona fide hedging position

in Sec. 150.1, may request:

(1) An interpretative letter from Commission staff, under Sec.

140.99 of this chapter, concerning the applicability of the bona fide

hedging position exemption; or

(2) Exemptive relief from the Commission under section 4a(a)(7) of

the Act.

(3) Appendix C to this part provides a non-exhaustive list of

examples of bona fide hedging positions as defined under Sec. 150.1.

(f) Previously granted exemptions. (1) Exemptions granted by the

Commission under Sec. 1.47 of this chapter for risk management of

positions in financial instruments shall not apply to positions in

financial instruments entered into after the effective date of initial

position limits implementing section 737 of the Dodd-Frank Act of 2010.

(2) Exemptions for risk management of positions in financial

instruments granted by a designated contract market or swap execution

facility shall not apply to positions in financial instruments entered

into after the effective date of initial position limits implementing

section 737 of the Dodd-Frank Act of 2010, provided that, for positions

in financial instruments entered into on or before the effective date

of initial position limits implementing section 737 of the Dodd-Frank

Act of 2010, the exemption shall apply for purposes of position limits

under Sec. 150.2 if the exemption:

(i) Applies to positions outside of the spot month only; and

(ii) Was granted prior to the compliance date provided under Sec.

150.2(e)(1).

(g) Recordkeeping. (1) Persons who avail themselves of exemptions

under this section, including exemptions granted under section 4a(a)(7)

of the Act, shall keep and maintain complete books and records

concerning all details of their related cash, forward, futures, futures

options and swap positions and transactions, including anticipated

requirements, production and royalties, contracts for services, cash

commodity products and by-products, and cross-commodity hedges, and

shall make such books and records, including a list of pass-through

swap counterparties, available to the Commission upon request under

paragraph (h) of this section.

(2) Further, a party seeking to rely upon the pass-through swap

offset in paragraph (2)(B) of the definition of ``bona fide hedging

position'' in Sec. 150.1, in order to exceed the position limits of

Sec. 150.2 with respect to such a swap, may only do so if its

counterparty provides a written representation (e.g., in the form of a

field or other representation contained in a mutually executed trade

confirmation) that, as to such counterparty, the swap qualifies in good

faith as a ``bona fide hedging position,'' as defined in Sec. 150.1,

provided that the bona fides of the pass-through swap counterparty may

be determined at the time of the transaction. That written

representation shall be retained by the parties to the swap for a

period of at least two years following the expiration of the swap and

furnished to the Commission upon request.

(3) Any person that represents to another person that a swap

qualifies as a pass-through swap under paragraph (2)(ii)(B) of the

definition of ``bona fide hedging position'' in Sec. 150.1 shall keep

and make available to the Commission upon request all relevant books

and records supporting such a representation for a period of at least

two years following the expiration of the swap.

(h) Call for information. Upon call by the Commission, the Director

of the Division of Market Oversight or the Director's delegee, any

person claiming an exemption from speculative position limits under

this section must provide to the Commission such information as

specified in the call relating to the positions owned or controlled by

that person; trading done pursuant to the claimed exemption; the

commodity derivative contracts or cash market positions which support

the claim of exemption; and the relevant business relationships

supporting a claim of exemption.

(i) Aggregation of accounts. Entities required to aggregate

accounts or positions under Sec. 150.4 of this part shall be

considered the same person for the purpose of determining whether they

are eligible for a bona fide hedging position exemption under paragraph

(a)(1)(i) of this section with respect to such aggregated account or

position.

(j) Delegation of authority to the Director of the Division of

Market Oversight. (1) The Commission hereby delegates, until it orders

otherwise, to the Director of the Division of Market Oversight or such

other employee or employees as the Director may designate from time to

time, the authority in paragraph (b) of this section to provide

exemptions in circumstances of financial distress.

(2) The Director of the Division of Market Oversight may submit to

the Commission for its consideration any matter which has been

delegated in this section.

(3) Nothing in this section prohibits the Commission, at its

election, from exercising the authority delegated in this section.

0

25. Revise Sec. 150.5 to read as follows:

Sec. 150.5 Exchange-set position limits.

(a) Requirements and acceptable practices for commodity derivative

contracts subject to federal position limits. (1) For any commodity

derivative contract that is subject to a speculative position limit

under Sec. 150.2, a designated contract market or swap execution

facility that is a trading facility shall set a speculative position

limit no higher than the level specified in Sec. 150.2.

(2) Exemptions to exchange-set limits--(i) Grant of exemption. Any

designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a trading

facility may grant exemptions from any speculative position limits it

sets under paragraph (a)(1) of this section, provided that exemptions

from federal limits conform to the requirements specified in Sec.

150.3, and provided further that any exemptions to exchange-set limits

not conforming to Sec. 150.3 are capped at the level of the applicable

federal limit in Sec. 150.2.

(ii) Application for exemption. Any designated contract market or

swap execution facility that grants exemptions under paragraph

(a)(2)(i) of this section:

(A) Must require traders to file an application requesting such

exemption in advance of the date that such position would be in excess

of the limits then in effect, provided however, that it may adopt rules

that allow a trader to file an application for an enumerated bona fide

hedging exemption within five business days after the trader assumed

the position that exceeded a position limit.

(B) Must require, for any exemption granted, that the trader

reapply for the exemption at least on an annual basis.

[[Page 96970]]

(C) May deny any such application, or limit, condition, or revoke

any such exemption, at any time, including if it determines such

positions would not be in accord with sound commercial practices, or

would exceed an amount that may be established and liquidated in an

orderly fashion.

(3) Pre-enactment and transition period swap positions. Speculative

position limits set forth in Sec. 150.2 shall not apply to positions

acquired in good faith in any pre-enactment swap, or in any transition

period swap, in either case as defined by Sec. 150.1. Provided

however, that a designated contract market or swap execution facility

that is a trading facility shall allow a person to net such position

with post-effective date commodity derivative contracts for the purpose

of complying with any non-spot month speculative position limit.

(4) Pre-existing positions--(i) Pre-existing positions in a spot-

month. A designated contract market or swap execution facility that is

a trading facility must require compliance with spot month speculative

position limits for pre-existing positions in commodity derivative

contracts other than pre-enactment and transition period swaps.

(ii) Pre-existing positions in a non-spot month. A single-month or

all months-combined speculative position limit established under Sec.

150.2 shall not apply to any commodity derivative contract acquired in

good faith prior to the effective date of such limit, provided however,

that such position shall be attributed to the person if the person's

position is increased after the effective date of such limit.

(5) Aggregation. Designated contract markets and swap execution

facilities that are trading facilities must have aggregation rules that

conform to Sec. 150.4.

(6) Additional acceptable practices. A designated contract market

or swap execution facility that is a trading facility may:

(i) Impose additional restrictions on a person with a long position

in the spot month of a physical-delivery contract who stands for

delivery, takes that delivery, then re-establishes a long position;

(ii) Establish limits on the amount of delivery instruments that a

person may hold in a physical-delivery contract; and

(iii) Impose such other restrictions as it deems necessary to

reduce the potential threat of market manipulation or congestion, to

maintain orderly execution of transactions, or for such other purposes

consistent with its responsibilities.

(b) Requirements and acceptable practices for commodity derivative

contracts in a physical commodity as defined in Sec. 150.1 that are

not subject to the limits set forth in Sec. 150.2--(1) Levels at

initial listing. At the time of each commodity derivative contract's

initial listing, a designated contract market or swap execution

facility that is a trading facility should base speculative position

limits on the following:

(i) Spot month position limits--(A) Commodities with a measurable

deliverable supply. For all commodity derivative contracts not subject

to the limits set forth in Sec. 150.2 that are based on a commodity

with a measurable deliverable supply, the spot month limit level should

be established at a level that is no greater than one-quarter of the

estimated spot month deliverable supply, calculated separately for each

month to be listed (Designated Contract Markets and Swap Execution

Facilities may refer to the guidance in paragraph (b)(1)(i) of Appendix

C of part 38 of this chapter for guidance on estimating spot-month

deliverable supply);

(B) Commodities without a measurable deliverable supply. For

commodity derivative contracts that are based on a commodity with no

measurable deliverable supply, the spot month limit level should be set

at a level that is necessary and appropriate to reduce the potential

threat of market manipulation or price distortion of the contract's or

the underlying commodity's price or index.

(ii) Individual non-spot or all-months combined position limits.

For agricultural or exempt commodity derivative contracts not subject

to the limits set forth in Sec. 150.2, the individual non-spot or all-

months-combined levels should be equal to or less than the greater of:

The level of the spot month limit; or 5,000 contracts, when the

notional quantity per contract is no larger than a typical cash market

transaction in the underlying commodity. If the notional quantity per

contract is larger than the typical cash market transaction, then the

individual non-spot month limit or all-months combined limit level

should be scaled down accordingly. If the commodity derivative contract

is substantially the same as a pre-existing commodity derivative

contract, then the designated contract market or swap execution

facility may adopt the same limit as applies to that pre-existing

commodity derivative contract.

(iii) Commodity derivative contracts that are cash-settled by

referencing a daily settlement price of an existing contract. For

commodity derivative contracts that are cash-settled by referencing a

daily settlement price of an existing contract listed on a designated

contract market or swap execution facility that is a trading facility,

the cash-settled contract should adopt spot-month, individual non-spot-

month, and all-months combined position limits comparable to those of

the original price referenced contract.

(2) Adjustments to levels. Designated contract markets and swap

execution facilities that are trading facilities should adjust their

speculative limit levels as follows:

(i) Spot month position limits. The spot month position limit level

should be reviewed no less than once every twenty-four months from the

date of initial listing and should be maintained at a level that is:

(A) No greater than one-quarter of the estimated spot month

deliverable supply, calculated separately for each month to be listed;

or

(B) In the case of a commodity derivative contract based on a

commodity without a measurable deliverable supply, necessary and

appropriate to reduce the potential threat of market manipulation or

price distortion of the contract's or the underlying commodity's price

or index.

(ii) Individual non-spot or all-months-combined position limits.

Individual non-spot or all-months-combined levels should be based on

position sizes customarily held by speculative traders on the contract

market or equal to or less than the greater of: The spot-month position

limit level; 10% of the average combined futures and delta adjusted

option month-end open interest for the most recent calendar year up to

25,000 contracts, with a marginal increase of 2.5% thereafter; or 5,000

contracts. In any case, such levels should be reviewed no less than

once every twenty-four months from the date of initial listing.

(3) Position accountability in lieu of speculative position limits.

A designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a

trading facility may adopt a bylaw, rule, regulation, or resolution,

substituting for the exchange-set speculative position limits specified

under this paragraph (b), an exchange rule requiring traders to consent

to provide information about their position upon request by the

exchange and to consent to halt increasing further a trader's position

or to reduce their positions in an orderly manner, in each case upon

request by the exchange as follows:

(i) Physical commodity derivative contracts. On a physical

commodity derivative contract that is not subject to the limits set

forth in Sec. 150.2, having an average month-end open interest of

50,000 contracts and an average daily

[[Page 96971]]

volume of 5,000 or more contracts during the most recent calendar year

and a liquid cash market, a designated contract market or swap

execution facility that is a trading facility may adopt individual non-

spot month or all-months-combined position accountability levels,

provided however, that such designated contract market or swap

execution facility that is a trading facility should adopt a spot month

speculative position limit with a level no greater than one-quarter of

the estimated spot month deliverable supply.

(ii) New commodity derivative contracts that are substantially the

same as an existing contract. On a new commodity derivative contract

that is substantially the same as an existing commodity derivative

contract listed for trading on a designated contract market or swap

execution facility that is a trading facility, which has adopted

position accountability in lieu of position limits, the designated

contract market or swap execution facility may adopt for the new

contract when it is initially listed for trading the position

accountability levels of the existing contract.

(4) Calculation of trading volume and open interest. For purposes

of this paragraph, trading volume and open interest should be

calculated by:

(i) Open interest. (A) Averaging the month-end open positions in a

futures contract and its related option contract, on a delta-adjusted

basis, for all months listed during the most recent calendar year; and

(B) Averaging the month-end futures equivalent amount of open

positions in swaps in a particular commodity (such as, for swaps that

are not referenced contracts, by combining the notional month-end open

positions in swaps in a particular commodity, including options in that

same commodity that are swaps on a delta-adjusted basis, and dividing

by a notional quantity per contract that is no larger than a typical

cash market transaction in the underlying commodity), except that a

designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a trading

facility shall include swaps in their open interest calculation only if

such entities administer position limits on swap contracts of their

facilities.

(ii) Trading volume. (A) Counting the number of contracts in a

futures contract and its related option contract, on a delta-adjusted

basis, transacted during the most recent calendar year; and

(B) Counting the futures-equivalent number of swaps in a particular

commodity transacted during the most recent calendar year, except that

a designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a

trading facility shall include swaps in their trading volume count only

if such entities administer position limits on swap contracts of their

facilities.

(5) Exemptions--(i) Hedge exemption. (A) Any hedge exemption rules

adopted by a designated contract market or a swap execution facility

that is a trading facility should conform to the definition of bona

fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1 and may provide for recognition as

a non-enumerated bona fide hedge in a manner consistent with the

process described in Sec. 150.9(a).

(B) Any hedge exemption rules adopted under paragraph (b)(5)(i)(A)

of this section may allow a person to file an application for

enumerated hedging positions, which application should be filed not

later than five business days after the person assumed the position

that exceeded a position limit.

(ii) Other exemptions. A designated contract market or swap

execution facility may grant other exemptions for:

(A) Financial distress. Upon specific request made to the

designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a trading

facility, the designated contract market or swap execution facility

that is a trading facility may exempt a person or related persons under

financial distress circumstances for a time certain from any of the

requirements of this part. Financial distress circumstances include

situations involving the potential default or bankruptcy of a customer

of the requesting person or persons, an affiliate of the requesting

person or persons, or a potential acquisition target of the requesting

person or persons.

(B) Conditional spot-month limit exemption. Exchange-set spot-month

speculative position limits may be exceeded for cash-settled contracts,

provided that such positions should not exceed two times the level of

the spot-month limit specified by the designated contract market or

swap execution facility that is a trading facility, that lists a

physical-delivery contract to which the cash-settled contracts are

directly or indirectly linked, and the person holding or controlling

such positions should not hold or control positions in such spot-month

physical-delivery contract.

(C) Intramarket spread positions and intermarket spread positions,

each as defined in Sec. 150.1, provided that the designated contract

market or swap execution facility, in considering whether to grant an

application for such exemption, should take into account whether

exempting the spread position from position limits would, to the

maximum extent practicable, ensure sufficient market liquidity for bona

fide hedgers, and not unduly reduce the effectiveness of position

limits to:

(1) Diminish, eliminate, or prevent excessive speculation;

(2) Deter and prevent market manipulation, squeezes, and corners;

and

(3) Ensure that the price discovery function of the underlying

market is not disrupted.

(iii) Application for exemption. Traders should be required to

apply to the designated contract market or swap execution facility that

is a trading facility for any exemption from its speculative position

limit rules. In considering whether to grant such an application for

exemption, a designated contract market or swap execution facility that

is a trading facility should take into account whether the requested

exemption is in accord with sound commercial practices and results in a

position that does not exceed an amount that may be established and

liquidated in an orderly fashion.

(6) Pre-enactment and transition period swap positions. Speculative

position limits should not apply to positions acquired in good faith in

any pre-enactment swap, or in any transition period swap, in either

case as defined by Sec. 150.1. Provided however, that a designated

contract market or swap execution facility that is a trading facility

may allow a person to net such position with post-effective date

commodity derivative contracts for the purpose of complying with any

non-spot month speculative position limit.

(7) Pre-existing positions--(i) Preexisting positions in a spot-

month. A designated contract market or swap execution facility that is

a trading facility should require compliance with spot month

speculative position limits for pre-existing positions in commodity

derivative contracts other than pre-enactment and transition period

swaps.

(ii) Pre-existing positions in a non-spot month. A single-month or

all-months-combined speculative position limit should not apply to any

commodity derivative contract acquired in good faith prior to the

effective date of such limit, provided however, that such position

should be attributed to the person if the person's position is

increased after the effective date of such limit.

(8) Aggregation. Designated contract markets and swap execution

facilities that are trading facilities must have aggregation rules that

conform to Sec. 150.4.

(9) Additional acceptable practices. Particularly in the spot

month, a

[[Page 96972]]

designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a trading

facility may:

(i) Impose additional restrictions on a person with a long position

in the spot month of a physical-delivery contract who stands for

delivery, takes that delivery, then re-establishes a long position;

(ii) Establish limits on the amount of delivery instruments that a

person may hold in a physical-delivery contract; and

(iii) Impose such other restrictions as it deems necessary to

reduce the potential threat of market manipulation or congestion, to

maintain orderly execution of transactions, or for such other purposes

consistent with its responsibilities.

(c) Requirements and acceptable practices for excluded commodity

derivative contracts as defined in section 1a(19) of the Act--(1)

Levels at initial listing. At the time of each excluded commodity

derivative contract's initial listing, a designated contract market or

swap execution facility that is a trading facility should base

speculative position limits on the following:

(i) Spot month position limits.--(A) Excluded commodity derivative

contracts with a measurable deliverable supply. For all excluded

commodity derivative contracts that are based on a commodity with a

measurable deliverable supply, the spot month limit level should be

established at a level that is no greater than one-quarter of the

estimated spot month deliverable supply, calculated separately for each

month to be listed (Designated Contract Markets and Swap Execution

Facilities may refer to the guidance in paragraph (b)(1)(i) of Appendix

C of part 38 of this chapter for guidance on estimating spot-month

deliverable supply);

(B) Excluded commodity derivative contracts without a measurable

deliverable supply. For excluded commodity derivative contracts that

are based on a commodity with no measurable deliverable supply, the

spot month limit level should be set at a level that is necessary and

appropriate to reduce the potential threat of market manipulation or

price distortion of the contract's or the underlying commodity's price

or index.

(ii) Individual non-spot or all-months combined position limits.

For excluded commodity derivative contracts, the individual non-spot or

all-months-combined levels should be equal to or less than the greater

of: The level of the spot month limit; or 5,000 contracts, when the

notional quantity per contract is no larger than a typical cash market

transaction in the underlying commodity. If the notional quantity per

contract is larger than the typical cash market transaction, then the

individual non-spot month limit or all-months combined limit level

should be scaled down accordingly. If the commodity derivative contract

is substantially the same as a pre-existing commodity derivative

contract, then the designated contract market or swap execution

facility may adopt the same limit as applies to that pre-existing

commodity derivative contract.

(iii) Commodity derivative contracts that are cash-settled by

referencing a daily settlement price of an existing contract. For

excluded commodity derivative contracts that are cash-settled by

referencing a daily settlement price of an existing contract listed on

a designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a

trading facility, the cash-settled contract should adopt spot-month,

individual non-spot-month, and all-months combined position limits that

are comparable to those of the original price referenced contract.

(2) Adjustments to levels. Designated contract markets and swap

execution facilities that are trading facilities should adjust their

speculative limit levels as follows:

(i) Spot month position limits. The spot month position limit level

for excluded commodity derivative contracts should be reviewed no less

than once every twenty-four months from the date of initial listing and

should be maintained at a level that is necessary and appropriate to

reduce the potential threat of market manipulation or price distortion

of the contract's or the underlying commodity's price or index.

(ii) Individual non-spot or all-months-combined position limits.

Individual non-spot or all-months-combined levels should be based on

position sizes customarily held by speculative traders on the contract

market or equal to or less than the greater of: the spot-month position

limit level; 10% of the average combined futures and delta adjusted

option month-end open interest for the most recent calendar year up to

25,000 contracts, with a marginal increase of 2.5% thereafter; or 5,000

contracts. In any case, such levels should be reviewed no less than

once every twenty-four months from the date of initial listing.

(3) Position accountability in lieu of speculative position limits.

A designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a

trading facility may adopt a bylaw, rule, regulation, or resolution,

substituting for the exchange-set speculative position limits specified

under this paragraph (c), an exchange rule requiring traders to consent

to provide information about their position upon request by the

exchange and to consent to halt increasing further a trader's position

or to reduce their positions in an orderly manner, in each case upon

request by the exchange as follows:

(i) Spot month. On an excluded commodity derivative contract for

which there is a highly liquid cash market and no legal impediment to

delivery, a designated contract market or swap execution facility that

is a trading facility may adopt position accountability in lieu of

position limits in the spot month. For an excluded commodity derivative

contract based on a commodity without a measurable deliverable supply,

a designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a

trading facility may adopt position accountability in lieu of position

limits in the spot month. For all other excluded commodity derivative

contracts, a designated contract market or swap execution facility that

is a trading facility should adopt a spot-month position limit with a

level no greater than one-quarter of the estimated deliverable supply;

(ii) Individual non-spot or all-months combined position limits. On

an excluded commodity derivative contract, a designated contract market

or swap execution facility that is a trading facility may adopt

position accountability levels in lieu of position limits in the

individual non-spot month or all-months-combined.

(iii) New commodity derivative contracts that are substantially the

same as an existing contract. On a new commodity derivative contract on

an excluded commodity derivative contract that is substantially the

same as an existing commodity derivative contract listed for trading on

a designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a

trading facility, which has adopted position accountability in lieu of

position limits, the designated contract market or swap execution

facility may adopt for the new contract when it is initially listed for

trading the position accountability levels of the existing contract.

(4) Calculation of trading volume and open interest. For purposes

of this paragraph, trading volume and open interest should be

calculated by:

(i) Open interest. (A) Averaging the month-end open positions in a

futures contract and its related option contract, on a delta-adjusted

basis, for all months listed during the most recent calendar year; and

[[Page 96973]]

(B) Averaging the month-end futures equivalent amount of open

positions in swaps in a particular commodity (such as, for swaps that

are not referenced contracts, by combining the notional month-end open

positions in swaps in a particular commodity, including options in that

same commodity that are swaps on a delta-adjusted basis, and dividing

by a notional quantity per contract that is no larger than a typical

cash market transaction in the underlying commodity), except that a

designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a trading

facility should include swaps in their open interest calculation only

if such entities administer position limits on swap contracts of their

facilities.

(ii) Trading volume. (A) Counting the number of contracts in a

futures contract and its related option contract, on a delta-adjusted

basis, transacted during the most recent calendar year; and

(B) Counting the futures-equivalent number of swaps in a particular

commodity transacted during the most recent calendar year, except that

a designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a

trading facility should include swaps in their trading volume count

only if such entities administer position limits on swap contracts of

their facilities.

(5) Exemptions--(i) Hedge exemptions. Any hedge exemption rules

adopted by a designated contract market or a swap execution facility

that is a trading facility should conform to the definition of bona

fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1.

(ii) Other exemptions for excluded commodities. A designated

contract market or swap execution facility may grant, in addition to

the exemptions under paragraphs (b)(5)(ii)(A), (b)(5)(ii)(B), and

(b)(5)(ii)(C) of this section, a risk management exemption pursuant to

rules submitted to the Commission, including for a position that is

consistent with the guidance in Appendix A of this part.

(iii) Application for exemption. Traders should be required to

apply to the designated contract market or swap execution facility that

is a trading facility for any exemption from its speculative position

limit rules. Such exchange may allow a person to file an application

after the person assumed the position that exceeded a position limit.

In considering whether to grant such an application for exemption, a

designated contract market or swap execution facility that is a trading

facility should take into account whether the requested exemption is in

accord with sound commercial practices and results in a position that

does not exceed an amount that may be established and liquidated in an

orderly fashion.

(6) Pre-enactment and transition period swap positions. Speculative

position limits should not apply to positions acquired in good faith in

any pre-enactment swap, or in any transition period swap, in either

case as defined by Sec. 150.1. Provided however, that a designated

contract market or swap execution facility that is a trading facility

may allow a person to net such position with post-effective date

commodity derivative contracts for the purpose of complying with any

non-spot month speculative position limit.

(7) Pre-existing positions--(i) Pre-existing positions in a spot-

month. A designated contract market or swap execution facility that is

a trading facility should require compliance with spot month

speculative position limits for pre-existing positions in commodity

derivative contracts.

(ii) Pre-existing positions in a non-spot month. A single-month or

all-months-combined speculative position limit should not apply to any

commodity derivative contract acquired in good faith prior to the

effective date of such limit, provided however, that such position

should be attributed to the person if the person's position is

increased after the effective date of such limit.

(8) Aggregation. Designated contract markets and swap execution

facilities that are trading facilities should have aggregation rules

for excluded commodity derivative contracts that conform to Sec.

150.4.

(9) Additional acceptable practices. A designated contract market

or swap execution facility that is a trading facility may impose such

other restrictions on excluded commodity derivative contracts as it

deems necessary to reduce the potential threat of market manipulation

or congestion, to maintain orderly execution of transactions, or for

such other purposes consistent with its responsibilities.

(d) Requirements for security futures products. For security

futures products, position limitations and position accountability

requirements are specified in Sec. 41.25(a)(3) of this chapter.

0

26. Revise Sec. 150.6 to read as follows:

Sec. 150.6 Ongoing application of the Act and Commission

regulations.

This part shall only be construed as having an effect on position

limits set by the Commission or a designated contract market or swap

execution facility, including any associated recordkeeping and

reporting regulations. Nothing in this part shall be construed to

affect any other provisions of the Act or Commission regulations,

including but not limited to those relating to manipulation, attempted

manipulation, corners, squeezes, fraudulent or deceptive conduct or

prohibited transactions, unless incorporated by reference.

0

27. Add Sec. Sec. 150.7 through 150.11 to read as follows:

Sec. 150.7 Requirements for anticipatory bona fide hedging position

exemptions.

(a) Statement. Any person who wishes to avail himself of exemptions

for unfilled anticipated requirements, unsold anticipated production,

anticipated royalties, anticipated services contract payments or

receipts, or anticipatory cross-commodity hedges under the provisions

of paragraphs (3)(iii), (4)(i), 4(iii), 4(iv), or (5), respectively, of

the definition of bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1 shall file

an application on Form 704 with the Commission in advance of the date

the person expects to exceed the position limits established under this

part. Filings in conformity with the requirements of this section shall

be effective ten days after submission, unless otherwise notified by

the Commission.

(b) Commission notification. At any time, the Commission may, by

notice to any person filing an application or annual update on Form

704, specify its determination as to what portion, if any, of the

amounts described in such filing does not meet the requirements for

bona fide hedging positions. In no case shall such person's

anticipatory bona fide hedging positions exceed the levels specified in

paragraph (f) of this section.

(c) Call for additional information. At any time, the Commission

may request a person who has on file an application or annual update

Form 704 under paragraph (a) of this section to file specific

additional or updated information with the Commission to support a

determination that the application or annual update on file accurately

reflects unsold anticipated production, unfilled anticipated

requirements, anticipated royalties, or anticipated services contract

payments or receipts.

(d) Initial statement and annual update. Initial Form 704

concerning the classification of positions as bona fide hedging

pursuant to paragraphs (3)(iii), or 4(i), 4(iii), 4(iv) or anticipatory

cross-commodity hedges under paragraph (5) of the definition of bona

fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1 shall be filed with the Commission

at least ten days in advance of the date that such positions would be

in excess of limits then in effect pursuant to section 4a of the Act.

[[Page 96974]]

Each person that has filed an initial statement on Form 704 for an

anticipatory bona fide hedge exemption shall provide annual updates on

the utilization of the anticipatory exemption, including actual cash

activity utilizing the anticipatory exemption for the preceding year,

as well as the cumulative utilization since the filing of the initial

or most recent annual statement. Such statements shall set forth in

detail for a specified operating period the person's anticipated

activity, i.e., unfilled anticipated requirements, unsold anticipated

production, anticipated royalties, or anticipated services contract

payments or receipts, and explain the method of determination thereof,

including, but not limited to, the following information:

(1) For each anticipated activity: (i) The type of cash commodity

underlying the anticipated activity;

(ii) The name of the actual cash commodity underlying the

anticipated activity and the units in which the cash commodity is

measured;

(iii) An indication of whether the cash commodity is the same

commodity (grade and quality) that underlies a core referenced futures

contract or whether a cross-hedge will be used and, if so, additional

information for cross hedges specified in paragraph (d)(2) of this

section;

(iv)(A) Annual production, requirements, royalty receipts or

service contract payments or receipts, in terms of futures equivalents,

of such commodity for the three complete fiscal years preceding the

current fiscal year, if filing an initial statement; or

(B) For the prior fiscal year if filing an annual update;

(v) The specified time period for which the anticipatory hedge

exemption is claimed;

(vi) Anticipated production, requirements, royalty receipts or

service contract payments or receipts, in terms of futures equivalents,

of such commodity for such specified time period;

(vii) Fixed-price forward sales, inventory, and fixed-price forward

purchases of such commodity, including any quantity in process of

manufacture and finished goods and byproducts of manufacture or

processing (in terms of such commodity);

(viii) Unsold anticipated production, unfilled anticipated

requirements, unsold anticipated royalty receipts, and anticipated

service contract payments or receipts the risks of which have not been

offset with cash positions, of such commodity for the specified time

period; and

(ix) The maximum number of long positions and short positions in

referenced contracts expected to be used to offset the risks of such

anticipated activity.

(2) Additional information for cross hedges. Cash positions that

represent a commodity, or products or byproducts of a commodity, that

is different from the commodity underlying a commodity derivative

contract that is expected to be used for hedging, shall be shown both

in terms of the equivalent amount of the commodity underlying the

commodity derivative contract used for hedging and in terms of the

actual cash commodity as provided for on Form 704. In computing their

cash position, every person shall use such standards and conversion

factors that are usual in the particular trade or that otherwise

reflect the value-fluctuation-equivalents of the cash position in terms

of the commodity underlying the commodity derivative contract used for

hedging. Such person shall furnish to the Commission upon request

detailed information concerning the basis for and derivation of such

conversion factors, including:

(i) The hedge ratio used to convert the actual cash commodity to

the equivalent amount of the commodity underlying the commodity

derivative contract used for hedging; and

(ii) An explanation of the methodology used for determining the

hedge ratio.

(e) Monthly reporting. Monthly reporting of remaining anticipated

hedge exemption shall be reported on Form 204, along with reporting

other exemptions pursuant to Sec. 19.01(a)(3)(vii) of this chapter.

(f) Maximum sales and purchases. Sales or purchases of commodity

derivative contracts considered to be bona fide hedging positions under

paragraphs (3)(iii)(A) or (4)(i) of the bona fide hedging position

definition in Sec. 150.1 shall at no time exceed the lesser of:

(1) A person's anticipated activity (including production,

requirements, royalties and services) as described by the information

most recently filed pursuant to this section that has not been offset

with cash positions; or

(2) Such lesser amount as determined by the Commission pursuant to

paragraph (b) of this section.

(g) Delegation of authority to the Director of the Division of

Market Oversight. (1) The Commission hereby delegates, until it orders

otherwise, to the Director of the Division of Market Oversight or such

other employee or employees as the Director may designate from time to

time, the authority:

(i) In paragraph (b) of this section to provide notice to a person

that some or all of the amounts described in a Form 704 filing does not

meet the requirements for bona fide hedging positions;

(ii) In paragraph (c) of this section to request a person who has

filed an application or annual update on Form 704 under paragraph (a)

of this section to file specific additional or updated information with

the Commission to support a determination that the Form 704 filed

accurately reflects unsold anticipated production, unfilled anticipated

requirements, anticipated royalties, or anticipated services contract

payments or receipts; and

(iii) In paragraph (d)(2) of this section to request detailed

information concerning the basis for and derivation of conversion

factors used in computing the cash position provided in any

applications or annual updates filed on Form 704.

(2) The Director of the Division of Market Oversight may submit to

the Commission for its consideration any matter which has been

delegated in this section.

(3) Nothing in this section prohibits the Commission, at its

election, from exercising the authority delegated in this section.

Sec. 150.8 Severability.

If any provision of this part, or the application thereof to any

person or circumstances, is held invalid, such invalidity shall not

affect other provisions or application of such provision to other

persons or circumstances which can be given effect without the invalid

provision or application.

Sec. 150.9 Process for recognition of positions as non-enumerated

bona fide hedges.

(a) Requirements for a designated contract market or swap execution

facility to recognize non-enumerated bona fide hedging positions. (1) A

designated contract market or swap execution facility that elects to

process non-enumerated bona fide hedging position applications to

demonstrate why a derivative position satisfies the requirements of

section 4a(c) of the Act shall maintain rules, submitted to the

Commission pursuant to part 40 of this chapter, establishing an

application process for recognition of non-enumerated bona fide hedging

positions consistent with the requirements of this section and the

general definition of bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1. A

[[Page 96975]]

designated contract market or swap execution facility may elect to

process non-enumerated bona fide hedging position applications for

positions in commodity derivative contracts only if, in each case:

(i) The commodity derivative contract is a referenced contract;

(ii) Such designated contract market or swap execution facility

lists such commodity derivative contract for trading;

(iii) Such commodity derivative contract is actively traded on such

designated contract market or swap execution facility;

(iv) Such designated contract market or swap execution facility has

established position limits for such commodity derivative contract; and

(v) Such designated contract market or swap execution facility has

at least one year of experience and expertise administering position

limits for a referenced contract in a particular commodity. A

designated contract market or swap execution facility shall not

recognize a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position involving a

commodity index contract and one or more referenced contracts.

(2) A designated contract market or swap execution facility may

establish different application processes for persons to demonstrate

why a derivative position constitutes a non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position under novel facts and circumstances and under facts

and circumstances substantially similar to a position for which a

summary has been published on such designated contract market's or swap

execution facility's Web site, pursuant to paragraph (a)(7) of this

section.

(3) Any application process that is established by a designated

contract market or swap execution facility shall elicit sufficient

information to allow the designated contract market or swap execution

facility to determine, and the Commission to verify, whether the facts

and circumstances in respect of a derivative position satisfy the

requirements of section 4a(c) of the Act and the general definition of

bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1, and whether it is

appropriate to recognize such position as a non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position, including at a minimum:

(i) A description of the position in the commodity derivative

contract for which the application is submitted and the offsetting cash

positions;

(ii) Information to demonstrate why the position satisfies the

requirements of section 4a(c) of the Act and the general definition of

bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1;

(iii) A statement concerning the maximum size of all gross

positions in derivative contracts for which the application is

submitted;

(iv) Information regarding the applicant's activity in the cash

markets for the commodity underlying the position for which the

application is submitted during the past year; and

(v) Any other information necessary to enable the designated

contract market or swap execution facility to determine, and the

Commission to verify, whether it is appropriate to recognize such

position as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position.

(4) Under any application process established under this section, a

designated contract market or swap execution facility shall:

(i) Require each person intending to exceed position limits to

submit an application, to reapply at least on an annual basis by

updating that application, and to receive notice of recognition from

the designated contract market or swap execution facility of a position

as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position in advance of the date

that such position would be in excess of the limits then in effect

pursuant to section 4a of the Act;

(ii) Notify an applicant in a timely manner if a submitted

application is not complete. If an applicant does not amend or resubmit

such application within a reasonable amount of time after such notice,

a designated contract market or swap execution facility may reject the

application;

(iii) Determine in a timely manner whether a derivative position

for which a complete application has been submitted satisfies the

requirements of section 4a(c) of the Act and the general definition of

bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1, and whether it is

appropriate to recognize such position as a non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position;

(iv) Have the authority to revoke, at any time, any recognition

issued pursuant to this section if it determines the recognition is no

longer in accord with section 4a(c) of the Act and the general

definition of bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1; and

(v) Notify an applicant in a timely manner:

(A) That the derivative position for which a complete application

has been submitted has been recognized by the designated contract

market or swap execution facility as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging

position under this section, and the details and all conditions of such

recognition;

(B) That its application is rejected, including the reasons for

such rejection; or

(C) That the designated contract market or swap execution facility

has asked the Commission to consider the application under paragraph

(a)(8) of this section.

(5) An applicant's derivatives position shall be deemed to be

recognized as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position exempt from

federal position limits at the time that a designated contract market

or swap execution facility notifies an applicant that such designated

contract market or swap execution facility will recognize such position

as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position.

(6) A designated contract market or swap execution facility that

elects to process non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

applications shall file new rules or rule amendments pursuant to part

40 of this chapter, establishing or amending requirements for an

applicant to file reports pertaining to the use of any such exemption

that has been granted in the manner, form, and frequency, as determined

by the designated contract market or swap execution facility.

(7) After recognition of each unique type of derivative position as

a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, based on novel facts and

circumstances, a designated contract market or swap execution facility

shall publish on its Web site, on at least a quarterly basis, a summary

describing the type of derivative position and explaining why it was

recognized as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position.

(8) If a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position application

presents novel or complex issues or is potentially inconsistent with

section 4a(c) of the Act and the general definition of bona fide

hedging position in Sec. 150.1, a designated contract market or swap

execution facility may ask the Commission to consider the application

under the process set forth in paragraph (d) of this section. The

Commission may, in its discretion, agree to or reject any such request

by a designated contract market or swap execution facility.

(b) Recordkeeping. (1) A designated contract market or swap

execution facility that elects to process non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position applications shall keep full, complete, and systematic

records, which include all pertinent data and memoranda, of all

activities relating to the processing of such applications and the

disposition thereof, including the recognition by the designated

contract market or swap execution facility of any derivative position

as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, the revocation or

[[Page 96976]]

modification of any such recognition, the rejection by the designated

contract market or swap execution facility of an application, or the

withdrawal, supplementation or updating of an application by the

applicant. Included among such records shall be:

(i) All information and documents submitted by an applicant in

connection with its application;

(ii) Records of oral and written communications between such

designated contract market or swap execution facility and such

applicant in connection with such application; and

(iii) All information and documents in connection with such

designated contract market's or swap execution facility's analysis of

and action on such application.

(2) All books and records required to be kept pursuant to this

section shall be kept in accordance with the requirements of Sec. 1.31

of this chapter.

(c) Reports to the Commission. (1) A designated contract market or

swap execution facility that elects to process non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position applications shall submit to the Commission a report

for each week as of the close of business on Friday showing the

following information:

(i) For each commodity derivative position that had been recognized

that week by the designated contract market or swap execution facility

as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, and for any revocation

or modification of a previously granted recognition:

(A) The date of disposition,

(B) The effective date of the disposition,

(C) The expiration date of any recognition,

(D) Any unique identifier assigned by the designated contract

market or swap execution facility to track the application,

(E) Any unique identifier assigned by the designated contract

market or swap execution facility to a type of recognized non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position,

(F) The identity of the applicant,

(G) The listed commodity derivative contract to which the

application pertains,

(H) The underlying cash commodity,

(I) The maximum size of the commodity derivative position that is

recognized by the designated contract market or swap execution facility

as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position,

(J) Any size limitation established for such commodity derivative

position on the designated contract market or swap execution facility,

and

(K) A concise summary of the applicant's activity in the cash

markets for the commodity underlying the commodity derivative position;

and

(ii) The summary of any non-enumerated bona fide hedging position

published pursuant to paragraph (a)(7) of this section, or revised,

since the last summary submitted to the Commission.

(2) Unless otherwise instructed by the Commission, a designated

contract market or swap execution facility that elects to process non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position applications shall submit to the

Commission, no less frequently than monthly, any report such designated

contract market or swap execution facility requires to be submitted by

an applicant to such designated contract market or swap execution

facility pursuant to rules required under paragraph (a)(6) of this

section.

(3) Unless otherwise instructed by the Commission, a designated

contract market or swap execution facility that elects to process non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position applications shall submit to the

Commission the information required by paragraphs (c)(1) and (2) of

this section, as follows:

(i) As specified by the Commission on the Forms and Submissions

page at www.cftc.gov;

(ii) Using the format, coding structure, and electronic data

transmission procedures approved in writing by the Commission; and

(iii) Not later than 9:00 a.m. Eastern time on the third business

day following the date of the report.

(d) Review of applications by the Commission. (1) The Commission

may in its discretion at any time review any non-enumerated bona fide

hedging position application submitted to a designated contract market

or swap execution facility, and all records required to be kept by such

designated contract market or swap execution facility pursuant to

paragraph (b) of this section in connection with such application, for

any purpose, including to evaluate whether the disposition of the

application is consistent with section 4a(c) of the Act and the general

definition of bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1.

(i) The Commission may request from such designated contract market

or swap execution facility records required to be kept by such

designated contract market or swap execution facility pursuant to

paragraph (b) of this section in connection with such application.

(ii) The Commission may request additional information in

connection with such application from such designated contract market

or swap execution facility or from the applicant.

(2) If the Commission preliminarily determines that any non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position application or the disposition

thereof by a designated contract market or swap execution facility

presents novel or complex issues that require additional time to

analyze, or that an application or the disposition thereof by such

designated contract market or swap execution facility is potentially

inconsistent with section 4a(c) of the Act and the general definition

of bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1, the Commission shall:

(i) Notify such designated contract market or swap execution

facility and the applicable applicant of the issues identified by the

Commission; and

(ii) Provide them with 10 business days in which to provide the

Commission with any supplemental information.

(3) The Commission shall determine whether it is appropriate to

recognize the derivative position for which such application has been

submitted as a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position, or whether

the disposition of such application by such designated contract market

or swap execution facility is consistent with section 4a(c) the Act and

the general definition of bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1.

(4) If the Commission determines that the disposition of such

application is inconsistent with section 4a(c) of the Act and the

general definition of bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1, the

Commission shall notify the applicant and grant the applicant a

commercially reasonable amount of time to liquidate the derivative

position or otherwise come into compliance. This notification will

briefly specify the nature of the issues raised and the specific

provisions of the Act or the Commission's regulations with which the

application is, or appears to be, inconsistent.

(e) Review of summaries by the Commission. The Commission may in

its discretion at any time review any summary of a type of non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position required to be published on a

designated contract market's or swap execution facility's Web site

pursuant to paragraph (a)(7) of this section for any purpose, including

to evaluate whether the summary promotes transparency and fair and open

access by all market participants to information regarding bona fide

hedges. If the Commission determines that a summary is deficient in any

way, the Commission shall notify such designated contract market or

swap execution facility, and grant to the designated contract market or

swap

[[Page 96977]]

execution facility a reasonable amount of time to revise the summary.

(f) Delegation of authority to the Director of the Division of

Market Oversight. (1) The Commission hereby delegates, until it orders

otherwise, to the Director of the Division of Market Oversight or such

other employee or employees as the Director may designate from time to

time, the authority:

(i) In paragraph (a)(8) of this section to agree to or reject a

request by a designated contract market or swap execution facility to

consider a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position application;

(ii) In paragraph (c) of this section to provide instructions

regarding the submission to the Commission of information required to

be reported by a designated contract market or swap execution facility,

to specify the manner for submitting such information on the Forms and

Submissions page at www.cftc.gov, and to determine the format, coding

structure, and electronic data transmission procedures for submitting

such information;

(iii) In paragraph (d)(1) of this section to review any non-

enumerated bona fide hedging position application and all records

required to be kept by a designated contract market or swap execution

facility in connection with such application, to request such records

from such designated contract market or swap execution facility, and to

request additional information in connection with such application from

such designated contract market or swap execution facility or from the

applicant;

(iv) In paragraph (d)(2) of this section to preliminarily determine

that a non-enumerated bona fide hedging position application or the

disposition thereof by a designated contract market or swap execution

facility presents novel or complex issues that require additional time

to analyze, or that such application or the disposition thereof is

potentially inconsistent with section 4a(c) of the Act and the general

definition of bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1, to notify the

designated contract market or swap execution facility and the

applicable applicant of the issues identified, and to provide them with

10 business days in which to file supplemental information; and

(v) In paragraph (e) of this section to review any summary of a

type of non-enumerated bona fide hedging position required to be

published on a designated contract market's or swap execution

facility's Web site, to determine that any such summary is deficient,

to notify a designated contract market or swap execution facility of a

deficient summary, and to grant such designated contract market or swap

execution facility a reasonable amount of time to revise such summary.

(2) The Director of the Division of Market Oversight may submit to

the Commission for its consideration any matter which has been

delegated in this section.

(3) Nothing in this section prohibits the Commission, at its

election, from exercising the authority delegated in this section.

Sec. 150.10 Process for designated contract market or swap execution

facility exemption from position limits for certain spread positions.

(a) Requirements for a designated contract market or swap execution

facility to exempt from position limits certain positions normally

known to the trade as spreads. (1) A designated contract market or swap

execution facility that elects to process applications for exemptions

from position limits for certain positions normally known to the trade

as spreads shall maintain rules, submitted to the Commission pursuant

to part 40 of this chapter, establishing an application process for

exempting positions normally known to the trade as spreads consistent

with the requirements of this section. A designated contract market or

swap execution facility may elect to process applications for such

spread exemptions only if, in each case:

(i) Such designated contract market or swap execution facility

lists for trading at least one contract that is either a component of

the spread or a referenced contract that is a component of the spread;

(ii) The contract, in paragraph (a)(1)(i) of this section, in a

particular commodity is actively traded on such designated contract

market or swap execution facility;

(iii) Such designated contract market or swap execution facility

has established position limits for at least one contract that is

either a component of the spread or a referenced contract that is a

component of the spread; and

(iv) Such designated contract market or swap execution facility has

at least one year of experience and expertise administering position

limits for at least one contract that is either a component of the

spread or a referenced contract that is a component of the spread. A

designated contract market or swap execution facility shall not approve

a spread exemption involving a commodity index contract and one or more

referenced contracts.

(2) Spreads that a designated contract market or swap execution

facility may approve under this section include:

(i) Calendar spreads;

(ii) Quality differential spreads;

(iii) Processing spreads; and

(iv) Product or by-product differential spreads.

(3) Any application process that is established by a designated

contract market or swap execution facility under this section shall

elicit sufficient information to allow the designated contract market

or swap execution facility to determine, and the Commission to verify,

whether the facts and circumstances demonstrate that it is appropriate

to exempt a spread position from position limits, including at a

minimum:

(i) A description of the spread position for which the application

is submitted;

(ii) Information to demonstrate why the spread position should be

exempted from position limits, including how the exemption would

further the purposes of section 4a(a)(3)(B) of the Act;

(iii) A statement concerning the maximum size of all gross

positions in derivative contracts for which the application is

submitted; and

(iv) Any other information necessary to enable the designated

contract market or swap execution facility to determine, and the

Commission to verify, whether it is appropriate to exempt such spread

position from position limits.

(4) Under any application process established under this section, a

designated contract market or swap execution facility shall:

(i) Require each person requesting an exemption from position

limits for its spread position to submit an application, to reapply at

least on an annual basis by updating that application, and to receive

approval in advance of the date that such position would be in excess

of the limits then in effect pursuant to section 4a of the Act;

(ii) Notify an applicant in a timely manner if a submitted

application is not complete. If an applicant does not amend or resubmit

such application within a reasonable amount of time after such notice,

a designated contract market or swap execution facility may reject the

application;

(iii) Determine in a timely manner whether a spread position for

which a complete application has been submitted satisfies the

requirements of paragraph (a)(4)(vi) of this section, and whether it is

appropriate to exempt such spread position from position limits;

(iv) Have the authority to revoke, at any time, any spread

exemption issued pursuant to this section if it determines

[[Page 96978]]

the spread exemption no longer satisfies the requirements of paragraph

(a)(4)(vi) of this section and it is no longer appropriate to exempt

the spread from position limits;

(v) Notify an applicant in a timely manner:

(A) That a spread position for which a complete application has

been submitted has been exempted by the designated contract market or

swap execution facility from position limits, and the details and all

conditions of such exemption;

(B) That its application is rejected, including the reasons for

such rejection; or

(C) That the designated contract market or swap execution facility

has asked the Commission to consider the application under paragraph

(a)(8) of this section; and

(vi) Determine whether exempting the spread position from position

limits would, to the maximum extent practicable, ensure sufficient

market liquidity for bona fide hedgers, and not unreasonably reduce the

effectiveness of position limits to:

(A) Diminish, eliminate or prevent excessive speculation;

(B) Deter and prevent market manipulation, squeezes, and corners;

and

(C) Ensure that the price discovery function of the underlying

market is not disrupted.

(5) An applicant's derivatives position shall be deemed to be

recognized as a spread position exempt from federal position limits at

the time that a designated contract market or swap execution facility

notifies an applicant that such designated contract market or swap

execution facility will exempt such spread position.

(6) A designated contract market or swap execution facility that

elects to process applications to exempt spread positions from position

limits shall file new rules or rule amendments pursuant to part 40 of

this chapter, establishing or amending requirements for an applicant to

file reports pertaining to the use of any such exemption that has been

granted in the manner, form, and frequency, as determined by the

designated contract market or swap execution facility.

(7) After exemption of each unique type of spread position, a

designated contract market or swap execution facility shall publish on

its Web site, on at least a quarterly basis, a summary describing the

type of spread position and explaining why it was exempted.

(8) If a spread exemption application presents complex issues or is

potentially inconsistent with the purposes of section 4a(a)(3)(B) of

the Act, a designated contract market or swap execution facility may

ask the Commission to consider the application under the process set

forth in paragraph (d) of this section. The Commission may, in its

discretion, agree to or reject any such request by a designated

contract market or swap execution facility.

(b) Recordkeeping. (1) A designated contract market or swap

execution facility that elects to process spread exemption applications

shall keep full, complete, and systematic records, which include all

pertinent data and memoranda, of all activities relating to the

processing of such applications and the disposition thereof, including

the exemption of any spread position, the revocation or modification of

any exemption, the rejection by the designated contract market or swap

execution facility of an application, or the withdrawal,

supplementation or updating of an application by the applicant.

Included among such records shall be:

(i) All information and documents submitted by an applicant in

connection with its application;

(ii) Records of oral and written communications between such

designated contract market or swap execution facility and such

applicant in connection with such application; and

(iii) All information and documents in connection with such

designated contract market's or swap execution facility's analysis of

and action on such application.

(2) All books and records required to be kept pursuant to this

section shall be kept in accordance with the requirements of Sec. 1.31

of this chapter.

(c) Reports to the Commission. (1) A designated contract market or

swap execution facility that elects to process spread exemption

applications shall submit to the Commission a report for each week as

of the close of business on Friday showing the following information:

(i) The disposition of any spread exemption application, including

the exemption of any spread position, the revocation or modification of

any exemption, or the rejection of any application, as well as the

following details:

(A) The date of disposition,

(B) The effective date of the disposition,

(C) The expiration date of any exemption,

(D) Any unique identifier assigned by the designated contract

market or swap execution facility to track the application,

(E) Any unique identifier assigned by the designated contract

market or swap execution facility to a type of exempt spread position,

(F) The identity of the applicant,

(G) The listed commodity derivative contract to which the

application pertains,

(H) The underlying cash commodity,

(I) The size limitations on any exempt spread position, specified

by contract month if applicable, and

(J) Any conditions on the exemption; and

(ii) The summary of any exempt spread position newly published

pursuant to paragraph (a)(7) of this section, or revised, since the

last summary submitted to the Commission.

(2) Unless otherwise instructed by the Commission, a designated

contract market or swap execution facility that elects to process

applications to exempt spread positions from position limits shall

submit to the Commission, no less frequently than monthly, any report

such designated contract market or swap execution facility requires to

be submitted by an applicant to such designated contract market or swap

execution facility pursuant to rules required by paragraph (a)(6) of

this section.

(3) Unless otherwise instructed by the Commission, a designated

contract market or swap execution facility that elects to process

applications to exempt spread positions from position limits shall

submit to the Commission the information required by paragraphs (c)(1)

and (2) of this section, as follows:

(i) As specified by the Commission on the Forms and Submissions

page at www.cftc.gov;

(ii) Using the format, coding structure, and electronic data

transmission procedures approved in writing by the Commission; and

(iii) Not later than 9:00 a.m. Eastern time on the third business

day following the date of the report.

(d) Review of applications by the Commission. (1) The Commission

may in its discretion at any time review any spread exemption

application submitted to a designated contract market or swap execution

facility, and all records required to be kept by such designated

contract market or swap execution facility pursuant to paragraph (b) of

this section in connection with such application, for any purpose,

including to evaluate whether the disposition of the application is

consistent with the purposes of section 4a(a)(3)(B) of the Act.

(i) The Commission may request from such designated contract market

or swap execution facility records required

[[Page 96979]]

to be kept by such designated contract market or swap execution

facility pursuant to paragraph (b) of this section in connection with

such application.

(ii) The Commission may request additional information in

connection with such application from such designated contract market

or swap execution facility or from the applicant.

(2) If the Commission preliminarily determines that any application

to exempt a spread position from position limits, or the disposition

thereof by a designated contract market or swap execution facility,

presents novel or complex issues that require additional time to

analyze, or that an application or the disposition thereof by such

designated contract market or swap execution facility is potentially

inconsistent with the Act, the Commission shall:

(i) Notify such designated contract market or swap execution

facility and the applicable applicant of the issues identified by the

Commission; and

(ii) Provide them with 10 business days in which to provide the

Commission with any supplemental information.

(3) The Commission shall determine whether it is appropriate to

exempt the spread position for which such application has been

submitted from position limits, or whether the disposition of such

application by such designated contract market or swap execution

facility is consistent with the purposes of section 4a(a)(3)(B) of the

Act.

(4) If the Commission determines that it is not appropriate to

exempt the spread position for which such application has been

submitted from position limits, or that the disposition of such

application is inconsistent with the Act, the Commission shall notify

the applicant and grant the applicant a commercially reasonable amount

of time to liquidate the spread position or otherwise come into

compliance. This notification will briefly specify the nature of the

issues raised and the specific provisions of the Act or the

Commission's regulations with which the application is, or appears to

be, inconsistent.

(e) Review of summaries by the Commission. The Commission may in

its discretion at any time review any summary of a type of spread

position required to be published on a designated contract market's or

swap execution facility's Web site pursuant to paragraph (a)(7) of this

section for any purpose, including to evaluate whether the summary

promotes transparency and fair and open access by all market

participants to information regarding spread exemptions. If the

Commission determines that a summary is deficient in any way, the

Commission shall notify such designated contract market or swap

execution facility, and grant to the designated contract market or swap

execution facility a reasonable amount of time to revise the summary.

(f) Delegation of authority to the Director of the Division of

Market Oversight. (1) The Commission hereby delegates, until it orders

otherwise, to the Director of the Division of Market Oversight or such

other employee or employees as the Director may designate from time to

time, the authority:

(i) In paragraph (a)(8) of this section to agree to or reject a

request by a designated contract market or swap execution facility to

consider a spread exemption application;

(ii) In paragraph (c) of this section to provide instructions

regarding the submission to the Commission of information required to

be reported by a designated contract market or swap execution facility,

to specify the manner for submitting such information on the Forms and

Submissions page at www.cftc.gov, and to determine the format, coding

structure, and electronic data transmission procedures for submitting

such information;

(iii) In paragraph (d)(1) of this section to review any spread

exemption application and all records required to be kept by a

designated contract market or swap execution facility in connection

with such application, to request such records from such designated

contract market or swap execution facility, and to request additional

information in connection with such application from such designated

contract market or swap execution facility, or from the applicant;

(iv) In paragraph (d)(2) of this section to preliminarily determine

that a spread exemption application or the disposition thereof by a

designated contract market or swap execution facility presents complex

issues that require additional time to analyze, or that such

application or the disposition thereof is potentially inconsistent with

the Act, to notify the designated contract market or swap execution

facility and the applicable applicant of the issues identified, and to

provide them with 10 business days in which to file supplemental

information; and

(v) In paragraph (e) of this section to review any summary of a

type of spread exemption required to be published on a designated

contract market's or swap execution facility's Web site, to determine

that any such summary is deficient, to notify a designated contract

market or swap execution facility of a deficient summary, and to grant

such designated contract market or swap execution facility a reasonable

amount of time to revise such summary.

(2) The Director of the Division of Market Oversight may submit to

the Commission for its consideration any matter which has been

delegated in this section.

(3) Nothing in this section prohibits the Commission, at its

election, from exercising the authority delegated in this section.

Sec. 150.11 Process for recognition of positions as bona fide hedges

for unfilled anticipated requirements, unsold anticipated production,

anticipated royalties, anticipated service contract payments or

receipts, or anticipatory cross-commodity hedge positions.

(a) Requirements for a designated contract market or swap execution

facility to recognize certain enumerated anticipatory bona fide hedging

positions. (1) A designated contract market or swap execution facility

that elects to process applications for recognition of positions as

hedges of unfilled anticipated requirements, unsold anticipated

production, anticipated royalties, anticipated service contract

payments or receipts, or anticipatory cross-commodity hedges under the

provisions of paragraphs (3)(iii), (4)(i), (iii), (iv), or (5),

respectively, of the definition of bona fide hedging position in Sec.

150.1 shall maintain rules, submitted to the Commission pursuant to

part 40 of this chapter, establishing an application process for such

anticipatory bona fide hedges consistent with the requirements of this

section. A designated contract market or swap execution facility may

elect to process such anticipatory hedge applications for positions in

commodity derivative contracts only if, in each case:

(i) The commodity derivative contract is a referenced contract;

(ii) Such designated contract market or swap execution facility

lists such commodity derivative contract for trading;

(iii) Such commodity derivative contract is actively traded on such

derivative contract market;

(iv) Such designated contract market or swap execution facility has

established position limits for such commodity derivative contract; and

(v) Such designated contract market or swap execution facility has

at least one year of experience and expertise administering position

limits for a referenced contract in a particular commodity.

(2) Any application process that is established by a designated

contract

[[Page 96980]]

market or swap execution facility shall require, at a minimum, the

information required under Sec. 150.7(d).

(3) Under any application process established under this section, a

designated contract market or swap execution facility shall:

(i) Require each person intending to exceed position limits to

submit an application, and to reapply at least on an annual basis by

updating that application, as required under Sec. 150.7(d), and to

receive notice of recognition from the designated contract market or

swap execution facility of a position as a bona fide hedging position

in advance of the date that such position would be in excess of the

limits then in effect pursuant to section 4a of the Act;

(ii) Notify an applicant in a timely manner if a submitted

application is not complete. If the applicant does not amend or

resubmit such application within a reasonable amount of time after

notification from the designated contract market or swap execution

facility, the designated contract market or swap execution facility may

reject the application;

(iii) Inform an applicant within ten days of receipt of such

application by the designated contract market or swap execution

facility that:

(A) The derivative position for which a complete application has

been submitted has been recognized by the designated contract market or

swap execution facility as a bona fide hedging position, and the

details and all conditions of such recognition;

(B) The application is rejected, including the reasons for such

rejection; or

(C) The designated contract market or swap execution facility has

asked the Commission to consider the application under paragraph (a)(6)

of this section; and

(iv) Have the authority to revoke, at any time, any recognition

issued pursuant to this section if it determines the position no longer

complies with the filing requirements under paragraph (a)(2) of this

section.

(4) An applicant's derivatives position shall be deemed to be

recognized as a bona fide hedging position at the time that a

designated contract market or swap execution facility notifies an

applicant that such designated contract market or swap execution

facility will recognize such position as a bona fide hedging position.

(5) A designated contract market or swap execution facility that

elects to process bona fide hedging position applications shall file

new rules or rule amendments pursuant to part 40 of this chapter,

establishing or amending requirements for an applicant to file the

supplemental reports, as required under Sec. 150.7(e), pertaining to

the use of any such exemption that has been granted.

(6) A designated contract market or swap execution facility may ask

the Commission to consider any application made under this section. The

Commission may, in its discretion, agree to or reject any such request

by a designated contract market or swap execution facility, provided

that, if the Commission agrees to the request, it will have 10 business

days from the time of the request to carry out its review.

(b) Recordkeeping. (1) A designated contract market or swap

execution facility that elects to process bona fide hedging position

applications under this section shall keep full, complete, and

systematic records, which include all pertinent data and memoranda, of

all activities relating to the processing of such applications and the

disposition thereof, including the recognition of any derivative

position as a bona fide hedging position, the revocation or

modification of any recognition, the rejection by the designated

contract market or swap execution facility of an application, or

withdrawal, supplementation or updating of an application. Included

among such records shall be:

(i) All information and documents submitted by an applicant in

connection with its application;

(ii) Records of oral and written communications between such

designated contract market or swap execution facility and such

applicant in connection with such application; and

(iii) All information and documents in connection with such

designated contract market's or swap execution facility's analysis of

and action on such application.

(2) All books and records required to be kept pursuant to this

section shall be kept in accordance with the requirements of Sec. 1.31

of this chapter.

(c) Reports to the Commission. (1) A designated contract market or

swap execution facility that elects to process bona fide hedging

position applications under this section shall submit to the Commission

a report for each week as of the close of business on Friday showing

the following information:

(i) The disposition of any application, including the recognition

of any position as a bona fide hedging position, the revocation or

modification of any recognition, as well as the following details:

(A) The date of disposition,

(B) The effective date of the disposition,

(C) The expiration date of any recognition,

(D) Any unique identifier assigned by the designated contract

market or swap execution facility to track the application,

(E) Any unique identifier assigned by the designated contract

market or swap execution facility to a bona fide hedge recognized under

this section;

(F) The identity of the applicant,

(G) The listed commodity derivative contract to which the

application pertains,

(H) The underlying cash commodity,

(I) The maximum size of the commodity derivative position that is

recognized by the designated contract market or swap execution facility

as a bona fide hedging position,

(J) Any size limitation established for such commodity derivative

position on the designated contract market or swap execution facility,

and

(K) A concise summary of the applicant's activity in the cash

market for the commodity underlying the position for which the

application was submitted.

(2) Unless otherwise instructed by the Commission, a designated

contract market or swap execution facility that elects to process bona

fide hedging position applications shall submit to the Commission the

information required by paragraph (c)(1) of this section, as follows:

(i) As specified by the Commission on the Forms and Submissions

page at www.cftc.gov;

(ii) Using the format, coding structure, and electronic data

transmission procedures approved in writing by the Commission; and

(iii) Not later than 9:00 a.m. Eastern time on the third business

day following the date of the report.

(d) Review of applications by the Commission. (1) The Commission

may in its discretion at any time review any bona fide hedging position

application submitted to a designated contract market or swap execution

facility under this section, and all records required to be kept by

such designated contract market or swap execution facility pursuant to

paragraph (b) of this section in connection with such application, for

any purpose, including to evaluate whether the disposition of the

application is consistent with the Act.

(i) The Commission may request from such designated contract market

or swap execution facility records required to be kept by such

designated contract market or swap execution facility pursuant to

paragraph (b) of this section in connection with such application.

[[Page 96981]]

(ii) The Commission may request additional information in

connection with such application from such designated contract market

or swap execution facility or from the applicant.

(2) If the Commission preliminarily determines that any

anticipatory hedge application is inconsistent with the filing

requirements of Sec. 150.11(a)(2), the Commission shall:

(i) Notify such designated contract market or swap execution

facility and the applicable applicant of the deficiencies identified by

the Commission; and

(ii) Provide them with 10 business days in which to provide the

Commission with any supplemental information.

(3) If the Commission determines that the anticipatory hedge

application is inconsistent with the filing requirements of Sec.

150.11(a)(2), the Commission shall notify the applicant and grant the

applicant a commercially reasonable amount of time to liquidate the

derivative position or otherwise come into compliance. This

notification will briefly specify the specific provisions of the filing

requirements of Sec. 150.11(a)(2), with which the application is, or

appears to be, inconsistent.

(e) Delegation of authority to the Director of the Division of

Market Oversight. (1) The Commission hereby delegates, until it orders

otherwise, to the Director of the Division of Market Oversight or such

other employee or employees as the Director may designate from time to

time, the authority:

(i) In paragraph (a)(6) of this section to agree to or reject a

request by a designated contract market or swap execution facility to

consider a bona fide hedge application;

(ii) In paragraph (c) of this section to provide instructions

regarding the submission to the Commission of information required to

be reported by a designated contract market or swap execution facility,

to specify the manner for submitting such information on the Forms and

Submissions page at www.cftc.gov, and to determine the format, coding

structure, and electronic data transmission procedures for submitting

such information;

(iii) In paragraph (d)(1) of this section to review any bona fide

hedging position application and all records required to be kept by a

designated contract market or swap execution facility in connection

with such application, to request such records from such designated

contract market or swap execution facility, and to request additional

information in connection with such application from such designated

contract market or swap execution facility or from the applicant; and

(iv) In paragraph (d)(2) of this section to determine that it is

not appropriate to recognize a derivative position for which an

application for recognition has been submitted as a bona fide hedging

position, or that the disposition of such application by a designated

contract market or swap execution facility is inconsistent with the

Act, and, in connection with such a determination, to grant the

applicant a reasonable amount of time to liquidate the derivative

position or otherwise come into compliance.

(2) The Director of the Division of Market Oversight may submit to

the Commission for its consideration any matter which has been

delegated in this section.

(3) Nothing in this section prohibits the Commission, at its

election, from exercising the authority delegated in this section.

0

28. In Part 150, add Appendices A through E to read as follows:

Appendix A to Part 150--Guidance on Risk Management Exemptions for

Commodity Derivative Contracts in Excluded Commodities

(1) This appendix provides non-exclusive interpretative guidance

on risk management exemptions for commodity derivative contracts in

excluded commodities permitted under the definition of bona fide

hedging position in Sec. 150.1. The rules of a designated contract

market or swap execution facility that is a trading facility may

recognize positions consistent with this guidance as bona fide

hedging positions. The Commission recognizes that risk management

positions in commodity derivative contracts in excluded commodities

may not conform to the general definition of bona fide hedging

positions applicable to commodity derivative contracts in physical

commodities, as provided under section 4a(c)(2) of the Act, and may

not conform to enumerated bona fide hedging positions applicable to

commodity derivative contracts in physical commodities under the

definition of bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1.

This interpretative guidance for core principle 5 for designated

contract markets, section 5(d)(5) of the Act, and core principle 6

for swap execution facilities that are trading facilities, section

5h(f)(6) of the Act, is illustrative only of the types of positions

for which a trading facility may elect to provide a risk management

exemption and is not intended to be used as a mandatory checklist.

Other positions might also be included appropriately within a risk

management exemption.

(2)(a) No temporary substitute criterion. Risk management

positions in commodity derivative contracts in excluded commodities

need not be expected to represent a substitute for a subsequent

transaction or position in a physical marketing channel. There need

not be any requirement to replace a commodity derivative contract

with a cash market position in order to qualify for a risk

management exemption.

(b) Cross-commodity hedging is permitted. Risks that are offset

in commodity derivative contracts in excluded commodities need not

arise from the same commodities underlying the commodity derivative

contracts. For example, a trading facility may recognize a risk

management exemption based on the net interest rate risk arising

from a bank's balance sheet of loans and deposits that is offset

using Treasury security futures contracts or short-term interest

rate futures contracts.

(3) Examples of risk management positions. This section contains

examples of risk management positions that may be appropriate for

management of risk in the operation of a commercial enterprise.

(a) Balance sheet hedging. A commercial enterprise may have

risks arising from its net position in assets and liabilities.

(i) Foreign currency translation. One form of balance sheet

hedging involves offsetting net exposure to changes in currency

exchange rates for the purpose of stabilizing the domestic dollar

accounting value of net assets and/or liabilities which are

denominated in a foreign currency. For example, a bank may make

loans in a foreign currency and take deposits in that same foreign

currency. Such a bank is exposed to net foreign currency translation

risk when the amount of loans is not equal to the amount of

deposits. A bank with a net long exposure to a foreign currency may

hedge by establishing an offsetting short position in a foreign

currency commodity derivative contract.

(ii) Interest rate risk. Another form of balance sheet hedging

involves offsetting net exposure to changes in values of assets and

liabilities of differing durations. Examples include:

(A) A pension fund may invest in short term securities and have

longer term liabilities. Such a pension fund has a duration

mismatch. Such a pension fund may hedge by establishing a long

position in Treasury security futures contracts to lengthen the

duration of its assets to match the duration of its liabilities.

This is economically equivalent to using a long position in Treasury

security futures contracts to shorten the duration of its

liabilities to match the duration of its assets.

(B) A bank may make a certain amount of fixed-rate loans of one

maturity and fund such assets through taking fixed-rate deposits of

a shorter maturity. Such a bank is exposed to interest rate risk, in

that an increase in interest rates may result in a greater decline

in value of the assets than the decline in value of the deposit

liabilities. A bank may hedge by establishing a short position in

short-term interest rate futures contracts to lengthen the duration

of its liabilities to match the duration of its assets. This is

economically equivalent to using a short position in short-term

interest rate futures contracts, for example, to shorten the

duration of its assets to match the duration of its liabilities.

(b) Unleveraged synthetic positions. An investment fund may have

risks arising from

[[Page 96982]]

a delayed investment in an asset allocation promised to investors.

Such a fund may synthetically gain exposure to an asset class using

a risk management strategy of establishing a long position in

commodity derivative contracts that does not exceed cash set aside

in an identifiable manner, including short-term investments, any

funds deposited as margin and accrued profits on such commodity

derivative contract positions. For example:

(i) A collective investment fund that invests funds in stocks

pursuant to an asset allocation strategy may obtain immediate stock

market exposure upon receipt of new monies by establishing a long

position in stock index futures contracts (``equitizing cash'').

Such a long position may qualify as a risk management exemption

under trading facility rules provided such long position does not

exceed the cash set aside. The long position in stock index futures

contracts need not be converted to a position in stock.

(ii) Upon receipt of new funds from investors, an insurance

company that invests in bond holdings for a separate account wishes

to lengthen synthetically the duration of the portfolio by

establishing a long position in Treasury futures contracts. Such a

long position may qualify as a risk management exemption under

trading facility rules provided such long position does not exceed

the cash set aside. The long position in Treasury futures contracts

need not be converted to a position in bonds.

(c) Temporary asset allocations. A commercial enterprise may

have risks arising from potential transactional costs in temporary

asset allocations (altering portfolio exposure to certain asset

classes such as equity securities and debt securities). Such an

enterprise may hedge existing assets owned by establishing a short

position in an appropriate commodity derivative contract and

synthetically gain exposure to an alternative asset class using a

risk management strategy of establishing a long position in another

commodity derivative contract that does not exceed: the value of the

existing asset at the time the temporary asset allocation is

established or, in the alternative, the hedged value of the existing

asset plus any accrued profits on such risk management positions.

For example:

(i) A collective investment fund that invests funds in bonds and

stocks pursuant to an asset allocation strategy may believe that

market considerations favor a temporary increase in the fund's

equity exposure relative to its bond holdings. The fund manager may

choose to accomplish the reallocation using commodity derivative

contracts, such as a short position in Treasury security futures

contracts and a long position in stock index futures contracts. The

short position in Treasury security futures contracts may qualify as

a hedge of interest rate risk arising from the bond holdings. A

trading facility may adopt rules to recognize as a risk management

exemption such a long position in stock index futures.

(ii) Reserved.

(4) Clarification of bona fides of short positions.

(a) Calls sold. A seller of a call option establishes a short

call option. A short call option is a short position in a commodity

derivative contract with respect to the underlying commodity. A bona

fide hedging position includes such a written call option that does

not exceed in quantity the ownership or fixed-price purchase

contracts in the contract's underlying cash commodity by the same

person.

(b) Puts purchased and portfolio insurance. A buyer of a put

option establishes a long put option. However, a long put option is

a short position in a commodity derivative contract with respect to

the underlying commodity. A bona fide hedging position includes such

an owned put that does not exceed in quantity the ownership or

fixed-price purchase contracts in the contract's underlying cash

commodity by the same person.

The Commission also recognizes as bona fide hedging positions

strategies that provide protection against a price decline

equivalent to an owned position in a put option for an existing

portfolio of securities owned. A dynamically managed short position

in a futures contract may replicate the characteristics of a long

position in a put option.

(c) Synthetic short futures contracts. A person may establish a

synthetic short futures position by purchasing a put option and

selling a call option, when each option has the same notional

amount, strike price, expiration date and underlying commodity. Such

a synthetic short futures position is a short position in a

commodity derivative contract with respect to the underlying

commodity. A bona fide hedging position includes such a synthetic

short futures position that does not exceed in quantity the

ownership or fixed-price purchase contracts in the contract's

underlying cash commodity by the same person.

Appendix B to Part 150--Commodities Listed as Substantially the Same

for Purposes of the Definition of Location Basis Contract

The following table lists core referenced futures contracts and

commodities that are treated as substantially the same as a

commodity underlying a core referenced futures contract for purposes

of the definition of location basis contract in Sec. 150.1.

Location Basis Contract List of Substantially the Same Commodities

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Commodities

considered Source(s) for

Core referenced futures substantially the specification of

contract same (regardless of quality

location)

------------------------------------------------------------------------

NYMEX Light Sweet Crude Oil 1. Light Louisiana NYMEX Argus LLS vs.

futures contract (CL) Sweet (LLS) Crude WTI (Argus) Trade

Oil. Month futures

contract (E5).

NYMEX LLS (Argus)

vs. WTI Financial

futures contract

(WJ).

ICE Futures Europe

Crude Diff--Argus

LLS vs WTI 1st Line

Swap futures

contract (ARK).

ICE Futures Europe

Crude Diff--Argus

LLS vs WTI Trade

Month Swap futures

contract (ARL).

NYMEX New York Harbor ULSD 1. Chicago ULSD..... NYMEX Chicago ULSD

Heating Oil futures (Platts) vs. NY

contract (HO) Harbor ULSD Heating

Oil futures

contract (5C).

2. Gulf Coast ULSD.. NYMEX Group Three

ULSD (Platts) vs.

NY Harbor ULSD

Heating Oil futures

contract (A6).

NYMEX Gulf Coast

ULSD (Argus) Up-

Down futures

contract (US).

NYMEX Gulf Coast

ULSD (Argus) Up-

Down BALMO futures

contract (GUD).

NYMEX Gulf Coast

ULSD (Platts) Up-

Down BALMO futures

contract (1L).

NYMEX Gulf Coast

ULSD (Platts) Up-

Down Spread futures

contract (LT).

[[Page 96983]]

ICE Futures Europe

Diesel Diff--Gulf

Coast vs Heating

Oil 1st Line Swap

futures contract

(GOH).

CME Clearing Europe

Gulf Coast ULSD(

Platts) vs. New

York Heating Oil

(NYMEX) Spread

Calendar swap

(ELT).

CME Clearing Europe

New York Heating

Oil (NYMEX) vs.

European Gasoil

(IC) Spread

Calendar swap

(EHA).

3. California Air NYMEX Los Angeles

Resources Board CARB Diesel (OPIS)

Spec ULSD (CARB no. vs. NY Harbor ULSD

2 oil). Heating Oil futures

contract (KL).

4. Gas Oil ICE Futures Europe

Deliverable in Gasoil futures

Antwerp, Rotterdam, contract (G).

or Amsterdam Area. ICE Futures Europe

Heating Oil Arb--

Heating Oil 1st

Line vs Gasoil 1st

Line Swap futures

contract (HOT).

ICE Futures Europe

Heating Oil Arb--

Heating Oil 1st

Line vs Low Sulphur

Gasoil 1st Line

Swap futures

contract (ULL).

NYMEX NY Harbor ULSD

Heating Oil vs.

Gasoil futures

contract (HA).

NYMEX RBOB Gasoline futures 1. Chicago Unleaded NYMEX Chicago

contract (RB) 87 gasoline. Unleaded Gasoline

(Platts) vs. RBOB

Gasoline futures

contract (3C).

NYMEX Group Three

Unleaded Gasoline

(Platts) vs. RBOB

Gasoline futures

contract (A8).

2. Gulf Coast NYMEX Gulf Coast

Conventional CBOB Gasoline A1

Blendstock for (Platts) vs. RBOB

Oxygenated Blending Gasoline futures

(CBOB) 87. contract (CBA).

NYMEX Gulf Coast Unl

87 (Argus) Up-Down

futures contract

(UZ).

3. Gulf Coast CBOB NYMEX Gulf Coast

87 (Summer CBOB Gasoline A2

Assessment). (Platts) vs. RBOB

Gasoline futures

contract (CRB).

4. Gulf Coast NYMEX Gulf Coast 87

Unleaded 87 (Summer Gasoline M2

Assessment). (Platts) vs. RBOB

Gasoline futures

contract (RVG).

NYMEX Gulf Coast 87

Gasoline M2

(Platts) vs. RBOB

Gasoline BALMO

futures contract

(GBB).

NYMEX Gulf Coast 87

Gasoline M2 (Argus)

vs. RBOB Gasoline

BALMO futures

contract (RBG).

5. Gulf Coast NYMEX Gulf Coast Unl

Unleaded 87. 87 (Platts) Up-Down

BALMO futures

contract (1K).

NYMEX Gulf Coast Unl

87 Gasoline M1

(Platts) vs. RBOB

Gasoline futures

contract (RV).

CME Clearing Europe

Gulf Coast Unleaded

87 Gasoline M1

(Platts) vs. New

York RBOB Gasoline

(NYMEX) Spread

Calendar swap

(ERV).

6. Los Angeles NYMEX Los Angeles

California CARBOB Gasoline

Reformulated (OPIS) vs. RBOB

Blendstock for Gasoline futures

Oxygenate Blending contract (JL).

(CARBOB) Regular.

7. Los Angeles NYMEX Los Angeles

California CARBOB Gasoline

Reformulated (OPIS) vs. RBOB

Blendstock for Gasoline futures

Oxygenate Blending contract (JL).

(CARBOB) Premium.

8. Euro-BOB OXY NWE NYMEX RBOB Gasoline

Barges. vs. Euro-bob Oxy

NWE Barges (Argus)

(1000mt) futures

contract (EXR).

CME Clearing Europe

New York RBOB

Gasoline (NYMEX)

vs. European

Gasoline Euro-bob

Oxy Barges NWE

(Argus) (1000mt)

Spread Calendar

swap (EEXR).

9. Euro-BOB OXY FOB ICE Futures Europe

Rotterdam. Gasoline Diff--RBOB

Gasoline 1st Line

vs. Argus Euro-BOB

OXY FOB Rotterdam

Barge Swap futures

contract (ROE).

------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 96984]]

Appendix C to Part 150--Examples of Bona Fide Hedging Positions for

Physical Commodities

A non-exhaustive list of examples meeting the definition of bona

fide hedging position under Sec. 150.1 is presented below. With

respect to a position that does not fall within an example in this

appendix, a person seeking to rely on a bona fide hedging position

exemption under Sec. 150.3 may seek guidance from the Division of

Market Oversight. References to paragraphs in the examples below are

to the definition of bona fide hedging position in Sec. 150.1.

1. Portfolio Hedge Under Paragraph (3)(i) of the Bona Fide Hedging

Definition

Fact Pattern: It is currently January and Participant A owns

seven million bushels of corn located in its warehouses. Participant

A has entered into fixed-price forward sale contracts with several

processors for a total of five million bushels of corn that will be

delivered by May of this year. Participant A has no fixed-price corn

purchase contracts. Participant A's gross long cash position is

equal to seven million bushels of corn. Because Participant A has

sold forward five million bushels of corn, its net cash position is

equal to long two million bushels of corn. To reduce price risk

associated with potentially lower corn prices, Participant A chooses

to establish a short position of 400 contracts in the CBOT Corn

futures contract, equivalent to two million bushels of corn, in the

same crop year as the inventory.

Analysis: The short position in a contract month in the current

crop year for the CBOT Corn futures contract, equivalent to the

amount of inventory held, satisfies the general requirements for a

bona fide hedging position under paragraphs (2)(i)(A)-(C) and the

provisions associated with owning a commodity under paragraph

(3)(i).\1\ Because the firm's net cash position is two million

bushels of unsold corn, the firm is exposed to price risk.

Participant A's hedge of the two million bushels represents a

substitute for a fixed-price forward sale at a later time in the

physical marketing channel. The position is economically appropriate

to the reduction of price risk because the short position in a

referenced contract does not exceed the quantity equivalent risk

exposure (on a net basis) in the cash commodity in the current crop

year. Last, the hedge arises from a potential change in the value of

corn owned by Participant A.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1\ Participant A could also choose to hedge on a gross basis.

In that event, Participant A could establish a short position in the

March Chicago Board of Trade Corn futures contract equivalent to

seven million bushels of corn to offset the price risk of its

inventory and establish a long position in the May Chicago Board of

Trade Corn futures contract equivalent to five million bushels of

corn to offset the price risk of its fixed-price forward sale

contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. Lending a Commodity and Hedge of Price Risk Under Paragraph (3)(i)

of the Bona Fide Hedging Position Definition

Fact Pattern: Bank B owns 1,000 ounces of gold that it lends to

Jewelry Fabricator J at LIBOR plus a differential. Under the terms

of the loan, Jewelry Fabricator J may later purchase the gold from

Bank B at a differential to the prevailing price of the Commodity

Exchange, Inc. (COMEX) Gold futures contract (i.e., an open-price

purchase agreement is embedded in the terms of the loan). Jewelry

Fabricator J intends to use the gold to make jewelry and reimburse

Bank B for the loan using the proceeds from jewelry sales and either

purchase gold from Bank B by paying the market price for gold or

return the equivalent amount of gold to Bank B by purchasing gold at

the market price. Because Bank B has retained the price risk on

gold, the bank is concerned about its potential loss if the price of

gold drops. The bank reduces the risk of a potential loss in the

value of the gold by establishing a ten contract short position in

the COMEX Gold futures contract, which has a unit of trading of 100

ounces of gold. The ten contract short position is equivalent to

1,000 ounces of gold.

Analysis: This position meets the general requirements for bona

fide hedging positions under paragraphs (2)(i)(A)-(C) and the

requirements associated with owning a cash commodity under paragraph

(3)(i). The physical commodity that is being hedged is the

underlying cash commodity for the COMEX Gold futures contract. Bank

B's short hedge of the gold represents a substitute for a

transaction to be made in the physical marketing channel (e.g.,

completion of the open-price sale to Jewelry Fabricator J). Because

the notional quantity of the short position in the gold futures

contract is equal to the amount of gold that Bank B owns, the hedge

is economically appropriate to the reduction of risk. Finally, the

short position in the commodity derivative contract offsets the

potential change in the value of the gold owned by Bank B.

3. Repurchase Agreements and Hedge of Inventory Under Paragraph (3)(i)

of the Bona Fide Hedging Position Definition

Fact Pattern: Elevator A purchased 500,000 bushels of wheat in

April and reduced its price risk by establishing a short position of

100 contracts in the CBOT Wheat futures contract, equivalent to

500,000 bushels of wheat. Because the price of wheat rose steadily

since April, Elevator A had to make substantial maintenance margin

payments. To alleviate its cash flow concern about meeting further

margin calls, Elevator A decides to enter into a repurchase

agreement with Bank B and offset its short position in the wheat

futures contract. The repurchase agreement involves two separate

contracts: a fixed-price sale from Elevator A to Bank B at today's

spot price; and an open-price purchase agreement that will allow

Elevator A to repurchase the wheat from Bank B at the prevailing

spot price three months from now. Because Bank B obtains title to

the wheat under the fixed-price purchase agreement, it is exposed to

price risk should the price of wheat drop. Bank B establishes a

short position of 100 contracts in the CBOT Wheat futures contract,

equivalent to 500,000 bushels of wheat.

Analysis: Bank B's position meets the general requirements for a

bona fide hedging position under paragraphs (2)(i)(A)-(C) and the

provisions for owning the cash commodity under paragraph (3)(i). The

short position in referenced contracts by Bank B is a substitute for

a fixed-price sales transaction to be taken at a later time in the

physical marketing channel either to Elevator A or to another

commercial party. The position is economically appropriate to the

reduction of risk in the conduct and management of the commercial

enterprise (Bank B) because the notional quantity of the short

position in referenced contracts held by Bank B is not larger than

the quantity of cash wheat purchased by Bank B. Finally, the short

position in the CBOT Wheat futures contract reduces the price risk

associated with owning cash wheat.

4. Utility Hedge of Anticipated Customer Requirements Under Paragraph

(3)(iii)(B) of the Bona Fide Hedging Position Definition

Fact Pattern: A Natural Gas Utility A, regulated by State Public

Utility Commission, decides to hedge its purchases of natural gas in

order to reduce natural gas price risk on behalf of its residential

customers. State Public Utility Commission considers the hedging

practice to be prudent and allows gains and losses from hedging to

be passed on to Natural Gas Utility A's residential natural gas

customers. Natural Gas Utility A has about one million residential

customers who have average historical usage of about 71.5 mmBTUs of

natural gas per year per residence. The utility decides to hedge

about 70 percent of its residential customers' anticipated

requirements for the following year, equivalent to a 5,000 contract

long position in the NYMEX Henry Hub Natural Gas futures contract.

To reduce the risk of higher prices to residential customers,

Natural Gas Utility A establishes a 5,000 contract long position in

the NYMEX Henry Hub Natural Gas futures contract. Since the utility

is only hedging 70 percent of historical usage, Natural Gas Utility

A is highly certain that realized demand will exceed its hedged

anticipated residential customer requirements.

Analysis: Natural Gas Utility A's position meets the general

requirements for a bona fide hedging position under paragraphs

(2)(i)(A)-(C) and the provisions for hedges of unfilled anticipated

requirements by a utility under paragraph (3)(iii)(B). The physical

commodity that is being hedged involves a commodity underlying the

NYMEX Henry Hub Natural Gas futures contract. The long position in

the commodity derivative contract represents a substitute for

transactions to be taken at a later time in the physical marketing

channel. The position is economically appropriate to the reduction

of price risk because the price of natural gas may increase. The

commodity derivative contract position offsets the price risk of

natural gas that the utility anticipates purchasing on behalf of its

residential customers. As provided under paragraph (3)(iii), the

risk-reducing position qualifies as a bona fide hedging position in

the natural gas physical-delivery referenced contract during the

spot month, provided that the position does not exceed the unfilled

anticipated requirements for that month and for the next succeeding

month.

[[Page 96985]]

5. Processor Margins Hedge Using Unfilled Anticipated Requirements

Under Paragraph (3)(iii)(A) of the Bona Fide Hedging Position

Definition and Anticipated Production Under Paragraph (4)(i) of the

Definition

Fact Pattern: Soybean Processor A has a total throughput

capacity of 200 million bushels of soybeans per year (equivalent to

40,000 CBOT soybean futures contracts). Soybean Processor A crushes

soybeans into products (soybean oil and soybean meal). It currently

has 40 million bushels of soybeans in storage and has offset that

risk through fixed-price forward sales of the amount of products

expected to be produced from crushing 40 million bushels of

soybeans, thus locking in its processor margin on one million metric

tons of soybeans. Because it has consistently operated its plants at

full capacity over the last three years, it anticipates purchasing

another 160 million bushels of soybeans to be delivered to its

storage facility over the next year. It has not sold the 160 million

bushels of anticipated production of crushed products forward.

Processor A faces the risk that the difference in price

relationships between soybeans and the crushed products (i.e., the

crush spread) could change adversely, resulting in reduced

anticipated processing margins. To hedge its processing margins and

lock in the crush spread, Processor A establishes a long position of

32,000 contracts in the CBOT Soybean futures contract (equivalent to

160 million bushels of soybeans) and corresponding short positions

in CBOT Soybean Meal and Soybean Oil futures contracts, such that

the total notional quantity of soybean meal and soybean meal futures

contracts are equivalent to the expected production from crushing

160 million bushels of soybeans into soybean meal and soybean oil.

Analysis: These positions meet the general requirements for bona

fide hedging positions under paragraphs (2)(i)(A)-(C) and the

provisions for hedges of unfilled anticipated requirements under

paragraph (3)(iii)(A) and unsold anticipated production under

paragraph (4)(i). The physical commodities being hedged are

commodities underlying the CBOT Soybean, Soybean Meal, and Soybean

Oil futures contracts. Such positions are a substitute for purchases

and sales to be made at a later time in the physical marketing

channel and are economically appropriate to the reduction of risk.

The positions in referenced contracts offset the potential change in

the value of soybeans that the processor anticipates purchasing and

the potential change in the value of products and by-products the

processor anticipates producing and selling. The size of the

permissible long hedge position in the soybean futures contract must

be reduced by any inventories and fixed-price purchases because they

would reduce the processor's unfilled requirements. Similarly, the

size of the permissible short hedge positions in soybean meal and

soybean oil futures contracts must be reduced by any fixed-price

sales because they would reduce the processor's unsold anticipated

production. As provided under paragraph (3)(iii)(A), the risk

reducing long position in the soybean futures contract that is not

in excess of the anticipated requirements for soybeans for that

month and the next succeeding month qualifies as a bona fide hedging

position during the last five days of trading in the physical-

delivery referenced contract. As provided under paragraph (4)(i),

the risk reducing short position in the soybean meal and oil futures

contract do not qualify as a bona fide hedging position in a

physical-delivery referenced contract during the last five days of

trading in the event the Soybean Processor A does not have unsold

products in inventory.

The combination of the long and short positions in soybean,

soybean meal, and soybean oil futures contracts are economically

appropriate to the reduction of risk. However, unlike in this

example, an unpaired position (e.g., only a long position in a

commodity derivative contract) that is not offset by either a cash

market position (e.g., a fixed-price sales contract) or derivative

position (e.g., a short position in a commodity derivative contract)

would not represent an economically appropriate reduction of risk.

This is because the commercial enterprise's crush spread risk is

relatively low in comparison to the price risk from taking an

outright long position in the futures contract in the underlying

commodity or an outright short position in the futures contracts in

the products and by-products of processing. The price fluctuations

of the crush spread, that is, the risk faced by the commercial

enterprise, would not be expected to be substantially related to the

price fluctuations of either an outright long or outright short

futures position.

6. Agent Hedge Under Paragraph (3)(iv) of the Bona Fide Hedging

Position Definition

Fact Pattern: Cotton Merchant A is in the business of

merchandising (selling) cash cotton. Cotton Merchant A does not own

any cash commodity, but has purchased the right to redeem a

producer's cotton held as collateral by USDA (that is, ``cotton

equities'') and, thereby, Cotton Merchant A has incurred price risk.

A producer of cotton may borrow from the USDA's Commodity Credit

Corporation, posting their cotton as collateral on the loan. USDA

permits the producer to assign the right to redeem cotton held as

collateral. Once Cotton Merchant A purchases from a producer the

right to redeem cotton from USDA, Cotton Merchant A, in effect, is

responsible for merchandising of the cash cotton held as collateral

by USDA. For the volumes of cotton it is authorized to redeem from

USDA, Cotton Merchant A enters into economically appropriate short

positions in cotton commodity derivative contracts that offset the

price risks of the cash commodities.

Analysis: The positions meet the requirements of paragraphs

(2)(1)(A)-(C) for hedges of a physical commodity and paragraph

(3)(iv) for hedges by an agent. The positions represent a substitute

for transactions to be made in the physical marketing channel, are

economically appropriate to the reduction of risks arising from

cotton owned by the agent's contractual counterparties, and arise

from the potential change in the value of such cotton. The agent

does not own and has not contracted to purchase such cotton at a

fixed price, but is responsible for merchandising the cash positions

that are being offset in commodity derivative contracts. The agent

has a contractual arrangement with the persons who own the cotton

being offset.

7. Sovereign Hedge of a Pass-Through Swap Under Paragraph (2)(ii) of

the Bona Fide Hedging Position Definition Opposite a Deemed Bona Fide

Hedge of Unsold Anticipated Production Under Paragraph 4(i)

Fact Pattern: A Sovereign induces a farmer to sell his

anticipated production of 100,000 bushels of corn forward to User A

at a fixed price for delivery during the expected harvest, by, in

effect, granting that farmer a cash-settled call option at no cost.

In return for the farmer entering into the fixed-price forward sale

at the prevailing market price, the Sovereign agrees to pay the

farmer the difference between the market price at the time of

harvest and the price of the fixed-price forward, in the event that

the market price at the time of harvest is above the price of the

forward. The fixed-price forward sale of 100,000 bushels of corn

offsets the farmer's price risk associated with his anticipated

agricultural production. The call option provides the farmer with

upside price participation. The Sovereign faces commodity price risk

from the option it granted at no cost to the farmer. To reduce that

risk, the Sovereign establishes a long position of 20 call options

on the Chicago Board of Trade (CBOT) Corn futures contract,

equivalent to 100,000 bushels of corn.

Analysis: The farmer was induced by a long call option granted

at no cost, in return for the farmer entering into a fixed-price

forward sale at the prevailing market price.The risk profile of the

combination of the forward sale and the long call is approximately

equivalent to the risk profile of a synthetic long put.\2\ A

synthetic long put offsets the downside price risk of anticipated

production. Under these circumstances of a Sovereign granting a call

option to a farmer at no cost, the Commission deems the synthetic

position of the farmer as satisfying the general requirements for a

bona fide hedging position under paragraphs (2)(i)(A)-(C) and

meeting the requirements for anticipated agricultural production

under paragraph (4)(i), for purposes of the Sovereign's pass-through

swap offset under paragraph (2)(ii). The agreement between the

Sovereign and the farmer involves the production of a commodity

underlying the CBOT Corn futures contract. Also under these

circumstances, the Commission deems the synthetic long put as a

substitute for transactions that the farmer has made in the physical

marketing channel, because a long put would reduce the price risk

associated with the farmer's anticipated agricultural production.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\2\ Put-call parity describes the mathematical relationship

between price of a put and call with identical strike prices and

expiry.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Sovereign is the counterparty to the farmer, who under these

circumstances the Commission deems to be a bona fide hedger for

purposes of the Sovereign's pass-through swap offset. That is, the

Commission considers the Sovereign's long call position to be a

pass-through swap meeting the

[[Page 96986]]

requirements of paragraph (2)(ii)(B). As provided under paragraph

(2)(ii)(A), the Sovereign's risk-reducing position in the CBOT Corn

option would qualify as a pass-through swap offset as a bona fide

hedging position, or, alternatively, if the pass-through swap is not

a referenced contract, then the pass-through swap offset may qualify

as a cross-commodity hedge under paragraph (5), provided the

fluctuations in value of the pass-through swap offset are

substantially related to the fluctuations in value of the pass-

through swap. Such a pass-through swap offset will not qualify as a

bona fide hedging position in a physical-delivery futures contract

during the last five days of trading under paragraphs (2)(iii)(B) or

(5); however, since the CBOT Corn option will exercise into a

physical-delivery CBOT Corn futures contract prior to the last five

days of trading in that physical-delivery futures contract, the

Sovereign may continue to hold its option position as a bona fide

hedging position through option expiry.

8. Hedge of Offsetting Unfixed Price Sales and Purchases Under

Paragraph (4)(ii) of the Bona Fide Hedging Position Definition

Fact Pattern: Currently it is October and Oil Merchandiser A has

entered into cash forward contracts to purchase 600,000 of crude oil

at a floating price that references the January contract month (in

the next calendar year) for the ICE Futures Brent Crude futures

contract and to sell 600,000 barrels of crude oil at a price that

references the February contract month (in the next calendar year)

for the NYMEX Light Sweet Crude Oil futures contract. Oil

Merchandiser A is concerned about an adverse change in the price

spread between the January ICE Futures Brent Crude futures contract

and the February NYMEX Light Sweet Crude Oil futures contract. To

reduce that risk, Oil Merchandiser A establishes a long position of

600 contracts in the January ICE Futures Brent Crude futures

contract, price risk equivalent to buying 600,000 barrels of oil,

and a short position of 600 contracts in the February NYMEX Light

Sweet Crude Oil futures contract, price risk equivalent to selling

600,000 barrels of oil.

Analysis: Oil Merchandiser A's positions meet the general

requirements for bona fide hedging positions under paragraphs

(2)(i)(A)-(C) and the provisions for offsetting sales and purchases

in referenced contracts under paragraph (4)(ii). The physical

commodity that is being hedged involves a commodity underlying the

NYMEX Light Sweet Crude Oil futures contract. The long and short

positions in commodity derivative contracts represent substitutes

for transactions to be taken at a later time in the physical

marketing channel. The positions are economically appropriate to the

reduction of risk because the price spread between the ICE Futures

Brent Crude futures contract and the NYMEX Light Sweet Crude Oil

futures contract could move adversely to Oil Merchandiser A's

interests in the two cash forward contracts, that is, the price of

the ICE Futures Brent Crude futures contract could increase relative

to the price of the NYMEX Light Sweet Crude Oil futures contract.

The positions in commodity derivative contracts offset the price

risk in the cash forward contracts. As provided under paragraph (4),

the risk-reducing position does not qualify as a bona fide hedging

position in the crude oil physical-delivery referenced contract

during the spot month.

9. Anticipated Royalties Hedge Under Paragraph (4)(iii) of the Bona

Fide Hedging Position Definition and Pass-Through Swaps Hedge Under

Paragraph (2)(ii) of the Definition

a. Fact Pattern: In order to develop an oil field, Company A

approaches Bank B for financing. To facilitate the loan, Bank B

first establishes an independent legal entity commonly known as a

special purpose vehicle (SPV). Bank B then provides a loan to the

SPV. The SPV is obligated to repay principal and interest to the

Bank based on a fixed price for crude oil. The SPV in turn makes a

production loan to Company A. The terms of the production loan

require Company A to provide the SPV with volumetric production

payments (VPPs) based on a specified share of the production to be

sold at the prevailing price of crude oil (i.e., the index price) as

oil is produced. Because the price of crude oil may fall, the SPV

reduces that risk by entering into a crude oil swap with Swap Dealer

C. The swap requires the SPV to pay Swap Dealer C the floating price

of crude oil (i.e., the index price) and for Swap Dealer C to pay a

fixed price to the SPV. The notional quantity for the swap is equal

to the expected production underlying the VPPs to the SPV. The SPV

will receive a floating price at index on the VPP and will pay a

floating price at index on the swap, which will offset. The SPV will

receive a fixed price payment on the swap and repay the loan's

principal and interest to Bank B. The SPV is highly certain that the

VPP production volume will occur, since the SPV's engineer has

reviewed the forecasted production from Company A and required the

VPP volume to be set with a cushion (i.e., a hair-cut) below the

forecasted production.

Analysis: For the SPV, the swap between Swap Dealer C and the

SPV meets the general requirements for a bona fide hedging position

under paragraphs (2)(i)(A)-(C) and the requirements for anticipated

royalties under paragraph (4)(iii). The SPV will receive payments

under the VPP royalty contract based on the unfixed price sale of

anticipated production of the physical commodity underlying the

royalty contract, i.e., crude oil. The swap represents a substitute

for the price of sales transactions to be made in the physical

marketing channel. The SPV's swap position qualifies as a hedge

because it is economically appropriate to the reduction of price

risk. The swap reduces the price risk associated with a change in

value of a royalty asset. The fluctuations in value of the SPV's

anticipated royalties are substantially related to the fluctuations

in value of the crude oil swap with Swap Dealer C.

b. Continuation of Fact Pattern: Swap Dealer C offsets the price

risk associated with the swap to the SPV by establishing a short

position in cash-settled crude oil futures contracts. The notional

quantity of the short position in futures contracts held by Swap

Dealer C exactly matches the notional quantity of the swap with the

SPV.

Analysis: For the swap dealer, because the SPV enters the cash-

settled swap as a bona fide hedger under paragraph (4)(iii) (i.e., a

pass-through swap counterparty), the offset of the risk of the swap

in a futures contract by Swap Dealer C qualifies as a bona fide

hedging position (i.e., a pass-through swap offset) under paragraph

(2)(ii)(A). Since the swap was executed opposite a pass-through swap

counterparty and was offset, the swap itself also qualifies as a

bona fide hedging position (i.e., a pass-through swap) under

paragraph (2)(ii)(B). If the cash-settled swap is not a referenced

contract, then the pass-through swap offset may qualify as a cross-

commodity hedge under paragraph (5), provided the fluctuations in

value of the pass-through swap offset are substantially related to

the fluctuations in value of the pass-through swap.

10. Anticipated Royalties Hedge Under Paragraph (4)(iii) of the Bona

Fide Hedging Position Definition and Cross-Commodity Hedge Under

Paragraph (5) of the Definition

Fact Pattern: An eligible contract participant (ECP) owns

royalty interests in a portfolio of oil wells. Royalties are paid at

the prevailing (floating) market price for the commodities produced

and sold at major trading hubs, less transportation and gathering

charges. The large portfolio and well-established production history

for most of the oil wells provide a highly certain production stream

for the next 24 months. The ECP also determined that changes in the

cash market prices of 50 percent of the oil production underlying

the portfolio of royalty interests historically have been closely

correlated with changes in the calendar month average of daily

settlement prices of the nearby NYMEX Light Sweet Crude Oil futures

contract. The ECP decided to hedge some of the royalty price risk by

entering into a cash-settled swap with a term of 24 months. Under

terms of the swap, the ECP will receive a fixed payment and make

monthly payments based on the calendar month average of daily

settlement prices of the nearby NYMEX Light Sweet Crude Oil futures

contract and notional amounts equal to 50 percent of the expected

production volume of oil underlying the royalties.

Analysis: This position meets the requirements of paragraphs

(2)(i)(A)-(C) for hedges of a physical commodity, paragraph (4)(iii)

for hedges of anticipated royalties, and paragraph (5) for cross-

commodity hedges. The long position in the commodity derivative

contract represents a substitute for transactions to be taken at a

later time in the physical marketing channel. The position is

economically appropriate to the reduction of price risk because the

price of oil may decrease. The commodity derivative contract

position offsets the price risk of royalty payments, based on oil

production, that the ECP anticipates receiving. The ECP is exposed

to price risk arising from the anticipated production volume of oil

attributable to her royalty interests. The physical commodity

underlying the royalty portfolio that is being hedged involves a

commodity with fluctuations in value that are substantially related

to the fluctuations in value of the swap.

[[Page 96987]]

11. Hedges of Services Under Paragraph (4)(iv) of the Bona Fide Hedging

Position Definition

a. Fact Pattern: Company A enters into a risk service agreement

to drill an oil well with Company B. The risk service agreement

provides that a portion of the revenue receipts to Company A depends

on the value of the light sweet crude oil produced. Company A is

exposed to the risk that the price of oil may fall, resulting in

lower anticipated revenues from the risk service agreement. To

reduce that risk, Company A establishes a short position in the New

York Mercantile Exchange (NYMEX) Light Sweet Crude Oil futures

contract, in a notional amount equivalent to the firm's anticipated

share of the expected quantity of oil to be produced. Company A is

highly certain of its anticipated share of the expected quantity of

oil to be produced.

Analysis: Company A's hedge of a portion of its revenue stream

from the risk service agreement meets the general requirements for

bona fide hedging positions under paragraphs (2)(i)(A)-(C) and the

provisions for services under paragraph (4)(iv). The contract for

services involves the production of a commodity underlying the NYMEX

Light Sweet Crude Oil futures contract. A short position in the

NYMEX Light Sweet Crude Oil futures contract is a substitute for

transactions to be taken at a later time in the physical marketing

channel, with the value of the revenue receipts to Company A

dependent on the price of the oil sales in the physical marketing

channel. The short position in the futures contract held by Company

A is economically appropriate to the reduction of risk, because the

total notional quantity underlying the short position in the futures

contract held by Company A is equivalent to its share of the

expected quantity of future production under the risk service

agreement. Because the price of oil may fall, the short position in

the futures contract reduces price risk from a potential reduction

in the payments to Company A under the service contract with Company

B. Under paragraph (4)(iv), the risk-reducing position will not

qualify as a bona fide hedging position during the spot month of the

physical-delivery oil futures contract.

b. Fact Pattern: A City contracts with Firm A to provide waste

management services. The contract requires that the trucks used to

transport the solid waste use natural gas as a power source.

According to the contract, the City will pay for the cost of the

natural gas used to transport the solid waste by Firm A. In the

event that natural gas prices rise, the City's waste transport

expenses will increase. To mitigate this risk, the City establishes

a long position in the NYMEX Henry Hub Natural Gas futures contract

in an amount equivalent to the expected volume of natural gas to be

used over the life of the service contract.

Analysis: This position meets the general requirements for bona

fide hedging positions under paragraphs (2)(i)(A)-(C) and the

provisions for services under paragraph (4)(iv). The contract for

services involves the use of a commodity underlying the NYMEX Henry

Hub Natural Gas futures contract. Because the City is responsible

for paying the cash price for the natural gas used under the

services contract, the long hedge is a substitute for transactions

to be taken at a later time in the physical marketing channel. The

position is economically appropriate to the reduction of price risk

because the total notional quantity of the long position in a

commodity derivative contract equals the expected volume of natural

gas to be used over the life of the contract. The position in the

commodity derivative contract reduces the price risk associated with

an increase in anticipated costs that the City may incur under the

services contract in the event that the price of natural gas

increases. As provided under paragraph (4), the risk reducing

position will not qualify as a bona fide hedge during the spot month

of the physical-delivery futures contract.

12. Cross-Commodity Hedge Under Paragraph (5) of the Bona Fide Hedging

Position Definition and Inventory Hedge Under Paragraph (3)(i) of the

Definition

Fact Pattern: Copper Wire Fabricator A is concerned about

possible reductions in the price of copper. Currently it is November

and it owns inventory of 100 million pounds of copper and 50 million

pounds of finished copper wire. Copper Wire Fabricator A expects to

sell 150 million pounds of finished copper wire in February of the

following year. To reduce its price risk, Copper Wire Fabricator A

establishes a short position of 6,000 contracts in the February

COMEX Copper futures contract, equivalent to selling 150 million

pounds of copper. The fluctuations in value of copper wire are

expected to be substantially related to fluctuations in value of

copper.

Analysis: The Copper Wire Fabricator A's position meets the

general requirements for a bona fide hedging position under

paragraphs (2)(i)(A)-(C) and the provisions for owning a commodity

under paragraph (3)(i) and for a cross-hedge of the finished copper

wire under paragraph (5). The short position in a referenced

contract represents a substitute for transactions to be taken at a

later time in the physical marketing channel. The short position is

economically appropriate to the reduction of price risk in the

conduct and management of the commercial enterprise because the

price of copper could drop. The short position in the referenced

contract offsets the risk of a possible reduction in the value of

the inventory that it owns. Since the finished copper wire is a

product of copper that is not deliverable on the commodity

derivative contract, 2,000 contracts of the short position are a

cross-commodity hedge of the finished copper wire and 4,000

contracts of the short position are a hedge of the copper inventory.

13. Cross-Commodity Hedge Under Paragraph (5) of the Bona Fide Hedging

Position Definition and Anticipated Requirements Hedge Under Paragraph

(3)(iii)(A) of the Definition

Fact Pattern: Airline A anticipates using a predictable volume

of jet fuel every month based on scheduled flights and decides to

hedge 80 percent of that volume for each of the next 12 months.

After a review of various commodity derivative contract hedging

strategies, Airline A decides to cross hedge its anticipated jet

fuel requirements in ultra-low sulfur diesel (ULSD) commodity

derivative contracts. Airline A determined that price fluctuations

in its average cost for jet fuel were substantially related to the

price fluctuations of the calendar month average of the first nearby

physical-delivery NYMEX New York Harbor ULSD Heating Oil (HO)

futures contract and determined an appropriate hedge ratio, based on

a regression analysis, of the HO futures contract to the quantity

equivalent amount of its anticipated requirements. Airline A decided

that it would use the HO futures contract to cross hedge part of its

jet fuel price risk. In addition, Airline A decided to protect

against jet fuel price increases by cross hedging another part of

its anticipated jet fuel requirements with a long position in cash-

settled calls in the NYMEX Heating Oil Average Price Option (AT)

contract. The AT call option is settled based on the price of the HO

futures contract. The sum of the notional amounts of the long

position in AT call options and the long position in the HO futures

contract will not exceed the quantity equivalent of 80 percent of

Airline A's anticipated requirements for jet fuel.

Analysis: The positions meet the requirements of paragraphs

(2)(i)(A)-(C) for hedges of a physical commodity, paragraph

(3)(iii)(A) for unfilled anticipated requirements and paragraph (5)

for cross-commodity hedges. The positions represent a substitute for

transactions to be made in the physical marketing channel, are

economically appropriate to the reduction of risks arising from

anticipated requirements for jet fuel, and arise from the potential

change in the value of such jet fuel. The aggregation notional

amount of the airline's positions in the call option and the futures

contract does not exceed the quantity equivalent of anticipated

requirements for jet fuel. The value fluctuations in jet fuel are

substantially related to the value fluctuations in the HO futures

contract.

Airline A may hold its long position in the cash-settled AT call

option contract as a cross hedge against jet fuel price risk without

having to exit the contract during the spot month.

14. Position Aggregation Under Sec. 150.4 and Inventory Hedge Under

Paragraph (3)(i) of the Bona Fide Hedging Position Definition

Fact Pattern: Company A owns 100 percent of Company B. Company B

buys and sells a variety of agricultural products, including wheat.

Company B currently owns five million bushels of wheat. To reduce

some of its price risk, Company B establishes a short position of

600 contracts in the CBOT Wheat futures contract, equivalent to

three million bushels of wheat. After communicating with Company B,

Company A establishes an additional short position of 400 CBOT Wheat

futures contracts, equivalent to two million bushels of wheat.

Analysis: The aggregate short position in the wheat referenced

contract held by Company A and Company B meets the general

requirements for a bona fide hedging position under paragraphs

(2)(i)(A)-(C) and the provisions for owning a cash commodity under

paragraph (3)(i). Because Company A

[[Page 96988]]

owns more than 10 percent of Company B, Company A and B are

aggregated together as one person under Sec. 150.4. Entities

required to aggregate accounts or positions under Sec. 150.4 are

the same person for the purpose of determining whether a person is

eligible for a bona fide hedging position exemption under Sec.

150.3. The aggregate short position in the futures contract held by

Company A and Company B represents a substitute for transactions to

be taken at a later time in the physical marketing channel. The

aggregate short position in the futures contract held by Company A

and Company B is economically appropriate to the reduction of price

risk because the aggregate short position in the CBOT Wheat futures

contract held by Company A and Company B, equivalent to five million

bushels of wheat, does not exceed the five million bushels of wheat

that is owned by Company B. The price risk exposure for Company A

and Company B results from a potential change in the value of that

wheat.

Appendix D to Part 150--Initial Position Limit Levels

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Single month

Contract Spot-month and all months

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Legacy Agricultural:

Chicago Board of Trade Corn (C)..... 600 62,400

Chicago Board of Trade Oats (O)..... 600 5,000

Chicago Board of Trade Soybeans (S). 600 31,900

Chicago Board of Trade Soybean Meal 720 16,900

(SM)...............................

Chicago Board of Trade Soybean Oil 540 16,700

(SO)...............................

Chicago Board of Trade Wheat (W).... 600 32,800

ICE Futures U.S. Cotton No. 2 (CT).. 1,600 9,400

Chicago Board of Trade KC HRW Wheat 600 12,000

(KW)...............................

Minneapolis Grain Exchange Hard Red 1,000 12,000

Spring Wheat (MWE).................

Other Agricultural:

Chicago Board of Trade Rough Rice 600 5,000

(RR)...............................

Chicago Mercantile Exchange Live 450 12,200

Cattle (LC)........................

ICE Futures U.S. Cocoa (CC)......... 5,500 10,200

ICE Futures U.S. Coffee C (KC)...... 2,400 8,800

ICE Futures U.S. FCOJ-A (OJ)........ 2,800 5,000

ICE Futures U.S. Sugar No. 11 (SB).. 23,300 38,400

ICE Futures U.S. Sugar No. 16 (SF).. 7,000 7,000

Energy:

New York Mercantile Exchange Henry 2,000 200,900

Hub Natural Gas (NG)...............

New York Mercantile Exchange Light 10,400 148,800

Sweet Crude Oil (CL)...............

New York Mercantile Exchange NY 2,900 21,300

Harbor ULSD (HO)...................

New York Mercantile Exchange RBOB 6,800 15,300

Gasoline (RB)......................

Metal:

Commodity Exchange, Inc. Copper (HG) 1,000 7,800

Commodity Exchange, Inc. Gold (GC).. 6,000 19,500

Commodity Exchange, Inc. Silver (SI) 3,000 7,600

New York Mercantile Exchange 100 5,000

Palladium (PA).....................

New York Mercantile Exchange 500 5,000

Platinum (PL)......................

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Appendix E To Part 150--Guidance Regarding Exchange-Set Speculative

Position Limits

Guidance for Designated Contract Markets

(1) Until such time that a boards of trade has access to

sufficient swap position information, a board of trade need not

demonstrate compliance with Core Principle 5 with respect to swaps.

A board of trade should have access to sufficient swap position

information if, for example: (1) It had access to daily information

about its market participants' open swap positions; or (2) it knows

that its market participants regularly engage in large volumes of

speculative trading activity, including through knowledge gained in

surveillance of heavy trading activity, that would cause reasonable

surveillance personnel at an exchange to inquire further about a

market participant's intentions or total open swap positions.

(2) When a board of trade has access to sufficient swap position

information, this guidance would no longer be applicable. At such

time, a board of trade is required to file rules with the Commission

to implement the relevant position limits and demonstrate compliance

with Core Principle 5(A) and (B).

Guidance for Swap Execution Facilities

(1) Until such time that a swap execution facility that is a

trading facility has access to sufficient swap position information,

the swap execution facility need not demonstrate compliance with

Core Principle 6(A) or (B). A swap execution facility should have

access to sufficient swap position information if, for example: (1)

It had access to daily information about its market participants'

open swap positions; or (2) if it knows that its market participants

regularly engage in large volumes of speculative trading activity,

including through knowledge gained in surveillance of heavy trading

activity, that would cause reasonable surveillance personnel at an

exchange to inquire further about a market participant's intentions

or total open swap positions.

(2) When a swap execution facility has access to sufficient swap

position information, this guidance would no longer be applicable.

At such time, a swap execution facility is required to file rules

with the Commission to implement the relevant position limits and

demonstrate compliance with Core Principle 6(A) and (B).

PART 151--[REMOVED AND RESERVED]

0

29. Under the authority of section 8a(5) of the Commodity Exchange Act,

7 U.S.C. 12a(5), remove and reserve part 151.

Issued in Washington, DC, on December 5, 2016, by the

Commission.

Christopher J. Kirkpatrick,

Secretary of the Commission.

Note: The following appendices will not appear in the Code of

Federal Regulations.

Appendices to Position Limits for Derivatives--Commission Voting

Summary, Chairman's Statement, and Commissioners' Statements

Appendix 1--Commission Voting Summary

On this matter, Chairman Massad and Commissioners Bowen and

Giancarlo voted in the affirmative. No Commissioner voted in the

negative.

[[Page 96989]]

Appendix 2--Statement of Chairman Timothy G. Massad

Today, the Commission is issuing a revised position limits

proposal. We are also finalizing a separate but related rule on the

aggregation of positions. I am pleased that today's actions are

unanimous.

Congress directed us to implement a position limits rule to

limit excessive speculation. While speculators play a necessary and

important role in our markets, position limits can prevent the type

of excessive speculation by a few large participants that leads to

corners, squeezes and other activity that can distort markets and be

unfair to other participants. Position limits can also promote

convergence without compromising market liquidity. There are many

issues to consider in this rule, but position limits are not a new

or untested concept. They have been in place in our markets for

decades, either through federal limits or exchange-set limits, and

they have worked well.

There are two reasons why I am supporting issuing a reproposal.

First, we have made many changes to the 2013 proposal we inherited

that are reflected in today's reproposal. Certain aspects have been

previously proposed in separate pieces, and I believe the public

would benefit from seeing the proposal in its entirety, to better

understand how the various changes work together.

Second, the Commission is now in a time of transition. I do not

want to adopt a final rule today that the Commission would choose

not to implement or defend next year. Our markets and the many end-

users and consumers who rely on them are served best by having

reasonable and predictable regulation. Uncertainty and inconsistency

from one year to the next are not helpful.

Our staff has done a tremendous amount of work to devise a

position limits rule that meets the requirements of the law and

balances the various concerns at stake. This work has spanned

several years, involved review of literally thousands of pages of

comments from participants, and included many meetings and public

roundtables.

Commissioners Bowen, Giancarlo, and I have also spent

substantial time on this issue. We took office together in June 2014

and inherited a proposal that the Commission had issued six months

before. As I promised then, we have been working hard to get the

rule right. In addition to discussing the issues extensively with

staff, we have each had many meetings with market participants and

other members of the public. We have each traveled around the

country and heard from users of these markets. In particular, I have

heard from many smaller, traditional users about the importance of

position limits. I have also had the benefit of sponsoring the

Agricultural Advisory Committee, whose members have provided

important input on these issues.

We have revised the proposed limits themselves in light of

substantial work our staff has done to make sure they are based on

the latest and best information as to estimated deliverable supply.

We have considered a wide range of information, including the

recommendations of the exchanges and other data to which the

exchanges do not have access. For some contracts, the proposed

limits for the spot month are higher than the exchange-set limits

today. There have been, for example, substantial increases in

estimates of deliverable supply in the energy sector. In other

cases, we have accepted recommendations of the exchanges to set

federal limits that are actually lower than 25 percent of

deliverable supply, because we determined that the requested lower

limit was consistent with the overall policy goals and would not

compromise market liquidity.

We have proposed further adjustments to the bona fide hedging

position definition, to eliminate certain requirements that we have

decided are unnecessary, and to address other concerns raised by

market participants.

Another substantial difference from the 2013 text is our

proposal first made this summer to allow the exchanges to grant non-

enumerated hedge exemptions. This process must be subject to our

oversight as a matter of law and as a matter of policy, given the

inherent tension in the roles of the exchanges as market overseers

and beneficiaries of higher trading volumes.

The proposal we are issuing today provides extensive analysis of

the impact of the proposed spot and all months limits, which I

believe supports the view that the limits should not compromise

liquidity while addressing excessive speculation. The analysis shows

few existing positions would exceed the limits, and that is without

considering possible exemptions.

I recognize there will still be those that are critical of the

proposal. Some will complain simply because of the length of the

proposal--even though most of that is not rule text, but rather the

summaries of the extensive comments and analysis required by law.

Others may suggest broadening the bona fide hedge exemption so that

it encompasses practically any activity with a business purpose,

which is not what Congress said in the law. Still others will argue

position limits are not necessary. But while the Commission should

consider all comments, it is important to remember that the

Commission has a responsibility to implement a balanced rule that

achieves the objectives Congress has established.

Finally, while the Commission works to finalize this rule, we

still have federal limits for nine agricultural commodities and

exchange-set spot month limits for all the physical delivery

contracts covered by this rule, which the Commission will continue

to enforce.

I want to thank the staff again for their extensive work on this

rule, particularly our staff in the Division of Market Oversight,

the Office of the Chief Economist and the Office of the General

Counsel. Their expertise and dedication on this matter is truly

exemplary. I also want to thank Commissioners Bowen and Giancarlo

for their very constructive engagement on this issue.

Appendix 3--Statement of Commissioner Sharon Y. Bowen

With today's repreposal, the Commission moves one step closer to

the implementation of position limits as directed by Congress in

2010. CFTC staff has worked laboriously with market users and the

exchanges we regulate to craft a rule that will protect investors

from disruptive practices and manipulation, while simultaneously

allowing our markets to serve their critical price-discovery

function. I commend staff on their hard work and thank the hundreds

of commenters for their insightful feedback. I would also like to

thank Chairman Massad and Commissioner Giancarlo on their commitment

to this important rule and look forward to its finalization in the

near future.

Appendix 4--Statement of Commissioner J. Christopher Giancarlo

Since taking my seat on the Commission, I have traveled to well

over a dozen states where I met with many family farmers and toured

numerous energy utilities and manufacturing facilities. I have heard

the concerns of agriculture and energy producers and consumers about

market speculation and the role of position limits.

I have always been open to supporting a well-conceived and

practical position limits rule that restricts excessive speculation.

That is so long as it protects the ability of America's farmers,

ranchers and processors to hedge risks of agricultural commodities

and the ability of America's energy producers and distributors to

control risks of energy production, storage and distribution.

That is why I believe it is so important to carefully consider

the impact of this very complex rule on America's almost nine

thousand grain elevators,\1\ two million family farms \2\ and 147

million electric utility customers.\3\ That is why I support putting

out this rule as a proposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1\ U.S. Grain Storage Data, National Grain and Feed Association

Web site (last visited Dec. 5, 2016), https://www.ngfa.org/news-policy-center/resources/grain-industry-data/.

\2\ News Release, Family Farms are the Focus of New Agriculture

Census Data, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Mar. 17, 2015, http://www.usda.gov/wps/portal/usda/usdamediafb?contentid=2015/03/0066.xml&printable=true.

\3\ 2015-2016 Annual Directory & Statistical Report, American

Public Power Association, at 26 (2016), http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/USElectricUtilityIndustryStatistics.pdf.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

My concern regarding previous earlier proposals has been that

they would restrict bona fide hedging activity or harm America's

agriculture and energy industries that have been sorely impacted by

plummeting commodity prices and service provider consolidation. I am

simply not willing to support a poorly designed and unworkable rule

that ever after needs to be adjusted through a series of no-action

letters and ad hoc staff interpretations and advisories that had

become too common at the CFTC in prior years.

While some may view position limits as the ``eternal rule,'' I

disagree. The current proposal is very detailed and highly complex.

It is over 700 pages in length and has over one thousand footnotes.

In some areas, concerns expressed by market participants regarding

the 2011 rule that was struck down by the court and the 2013

proposal have been well addressed. In other

[[Page 96990]]

areas, they do not appear to have been as well addressed.

Notably, the proposal introduces a series of new estimates of

deliverable supply that have not been previously presented to the

public. It also incorporates concepts introduced in the 2016

supplemental proposal. Given these new additions and the complexity

of the proposal, one more round of public comment is appropriate.

I feel comfortable that the proposal before us provides the

basis for the implementation of a final position limits rule that I

could support. I commend the staff responsible for this proposal for

all their hard work in making the significant improvements that are

before us. I also extend my gratitude to Chairman Massad and

Commissioner Bowen for agreeing to put this proposal before the

public for comment.

I welcome commenters' views on the proposal. I expect that with

their added insight we can finalize a position limits rule in 2017

that is workable and does not undo years of standard practice in

these markets.

[FR Doc. 2016-29483 Filed 12-29-16; 8:45 am]

BILLING CODE 6351-01-P

Last Updated: December 30, 2016