2013-12133

Federal Register, Volume 78 Issue 105 (Friday, May 31, 2013)[Federal Register Volume 78, Number 105 (Friday, May 31, 2013)]

[Rules and Regulations]

[Pages 32865-32944]

From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]

[FR Doc No: 2013-12133]

[[Page 32865]]

Vol. 78

Friday,

No. 105

May 31, 2013

Part III

Commodity Futures Trading Commission

-----------------------------------------------------------------------

17 CFR Part 43

Procedures To Establish Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes for Large

Notional Off-Facility Swaps and Block Trades; Final Rule

Federal Register / Vol. 78, No. 105 / Friday, May 31, 2013 / Rules

and Regulations

[[Page 32866]]

-----------------------------------------------------------------------

COMMODITY FUTURES TRADING COMMISSION

17 CFR Part 43

RIN 3038-AD08

Procedures To Establish Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes for Large

Notional Off-Facility Swaps and Block Trades

AGENCY: Commodity Futures Trading Commission.

ACTION: Final rule.

-----------------------------------------------------------------------

SUMMARY: The Commodity Futures Trading Commission is adopting

regulations to implement certain statutory provisions enacted by Title

VII of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act.

Specifically, in accordance with section 727 of the Dodd-Frank Act, the

Commission is adopting regulations that define the criteria for

grouping swaps into separate swap categories and establish

methodologies for setting appropriate minimum block sizes for each swap

category. In addition, the Commission is adopting further measures

under the Commission's regulations to prevent the public disclosure of

the identities, business transactions and market positions of swaps

market participants.

DATES: Effective date: July 30, 2013.

FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: John W. Dunfee, Assistant General

Counsel, Office of the General Counsel, 202-418-5396, [email protected];

George Pullen, Economist, 202-418-6709, [email protected], or Nhan

Nguyen, Special Counsel, 202-418-5932, [email protected], Division of

Market Oversight; Esen Onur, Economist, Office of the Chief Economist,

202-418-6146, [email protected]; Commodity Futures Trading Commission,

Three Lafayette Center, 1155 21st Street NW., Washington, DC 20581.

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:

Table of Contents

I. Background

A. The Dodd-Frank Act

B. The Initial Proposal

1. Overview

2. Public Comments in Response to the Initial Proposal

C. Issuance of the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule

D. Further Block Proposal

1. Policy Goals

2. Summary of Proposed Approach

3. Overview of Comments Received

4. Additional Proposal Regarding Aggregation of Blocks

II. Procedures To Establish Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes for

Large Notional Off-Facility Swaps and Block Trades--Final Rules

A. Criteria for Distinguishing Among Swap Categories in Each

Asset Class

1. Interest Rate and Credit Asset Classes

a. Background

b. Interest Rate Swap Categories

i. Interest Rate Swap Data Summary

ii. Summary of Proposed Rule

c. Credit Swap Categories

i. Credit Swap Data Summary

ii. Credit Swap Data Analysis

2. Swap Category in the Equity Asset Class

3. Swap Categories in the FX Asset Class

4. Swap Categories in the Other Commodity Asset Class

5. Comments Regarding Swap Categories Across Asset Classes

B. Appropriate Minimum Block Size Methodologies for the Initial

and Post-Initial Periods

1. Phase-in of Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes

2. Overview of Proposed Approach

3. The 67-Percent Notional Amount Calculation for Determination

of Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes

4. Data for Determination of Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes in

the Post-Initial Period

5. Methodology for Determining the Appropriate Minimum Block

Sizes by Asset Class

a. Interest Rate and Credit Default Swaps

b. Equity

c. FX

i. Initial Period Methodology

ii. Post-Initial Period Methodology

d. Other Commodity

i. Initial Period Methodology

ii. Post-Initial Period Methodology

6. Special Provisions for the Determination of Appropriate

Minimum Block Sizes for Certain Types of Swaps

a. Swaps With Optionality

b. Swaps With Composite Reference Prices

c. Physical Commodity Swaps

d. Currency Conversion

e. Successor Currencies

C. Procedural Provisions

1. Sec. 43.6(a) Commission Determination

2. Sec. 43.6(f)(4) and (5) Publication and Effective Date of

Post-Initial Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes

3. Sec. 43.6(g) Notification of Election

4. Sec. 43.7 Delegation of Authority

5. Sec. 43.6(h)(6)--Aggregation

6. Sec. 43.6(i) Eligible Block Trade Participants

III. Anonymity Protections for the Public Dissemination of Swap

Transaction and Pricing Data

A. Policy Goals

B. Establishing Notional Cap Sizes for Swap Transaction and

Pricing Data To Be Publicly Disseminated in Real-Time

1. Policy Goals for Establishing Notional Cap Sizes

2. Proposed Amendments Related to Cap Sizes--Sec. 43.2

Definitions and Sec. 43.4 Swap Transaction and Pricing Data To Be

Publicly Disseminated in Real-Time

a. Initial Cap Sizes

b. Post-Initial Cap Sizes and the 75-Percent Notional Amount

Calculation

C. Masking the Geographic Detail of Swaps in the Other Commodity

Asset Class

1. Policy Goals for Masking the Geographic Detail for Swaps in

the Other Commodity Asset Class

2. Proposed Amendments to Sec. 43.4

3. Application of Proposed Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) and Proposed

Appendix E to Part 43--Geographic Detail for Delivery or Pricing

Points

a. U.S. Delivery or Pricing Points

i. Natural Gas and Related Products

ii. Petroleum and Related Products

iii. Electricity and Sources

iv. All Remaining Other Commodities

b. Non-U.S. Delivery or Pricing Points

c. Basis Swaps

d. Comments Received and Commission Determination

4. Further Revisions to Part 43

a. Additional Contracts Added to Appendix B to Part 43

b. Technical Revisions to Part 43

IV. Paperwork Reduction Act

A. Background

B. Description of the Collection

1. Sec. 43.6(g)--Notification of Election

2. Amendments to Sec. 43.4(d)(4) and 43.4(h)

V. Cost-Benefit Considerations

A. Background

B. The Statutory Mandate To Consider the Costs and Benefits of

the Commission's Action: Section 15(a) of the CEA

C. Rules Establishing Determination Criteria and Methodology

(Sec. 43.6(a)-(f) and (h))

1. Rule Summary

a. Rule 43.6(a) Commission Determination

b. Rule 43.6(b) Swap Category

c. Rules 43.6(c)-(f) and (h) Methods for Determining Appropriate

Minimum Block Sizes

2. Overview of Comments Received

3. Costs

a. Direct Costs

b. Indirect Costs

4. Benefits

5. Alternatives

a. Commission Determination of Minimum Block Sizes

b. Swap Category Alternatives

c. Block Methodology Alternatives

6. CEA Section 15(a) Factors

a. Protection of Market Participants and the Public

b. Efficiency, Competitiveness and Financial Integrity of

Markets

c. Price Discovery

d. Sound Risk Management Practices

e. Other Public Interest Considerations

D. Cost-Benefit Considerations Relevant to the Block Trade/Large

Notional Off-Facility Swap Election Process (Sec. 43.6(g))

1. Costs Relevant to the Election Process (Sec. 43.6(g))

a. Incremental, Non-Recurring Expenditure to a Non-Financial

End-user, SEF or DCM To Update Existing Technology

b. Incremental, Non-Recurring Expenditure to a Non-Financial

End-User, SEF or DCM To Provide Training to Existing Personnel and

Update Written Policies and Procedures

c. Incremental, Recurring Expenses to a Non-Financial End-User,

DCM or SEF Associated With Incremental Compliance, Maintenance and

Operational Support in Connection With the Proposed Election Process

[[Page 32867]]

d. Incremental, Non-Recurring Expenditure to an SDR To Update

Existing Technology To Capture and Publicly Disseminate Swap Data

for Block Trades and Large Notional Off-Facility Swaps

2. Comments Received

3. Benefits Relevant to the Election Process (Sec. 43.6(g))

4. Alternatives

5. Application of the Section 15(a) Factors to Sec. 43.6(g)

a. Protection of Market Participants and the Public

b. Efficiency, Competitiveness and Financial Integrity

c. Price Discovery

d. Sound Risk Management Practices

e. Other Public Interest Considerations

E. Costs and Benefits Relevant to Anonymity Protections

(Amendments to Sec. 43.4(d)(4) and (h))

1. Amendments to Sec. 43.4(d)(4)

2. Amendments to Sec. 43.4(h)

3. Costs Relevant to the Amendments to Sec. 43.4(d)(4) and (h)

4. Benefits Relevant to the Amendments to Sec. 43.4

5. Alternatives

6. Application of the Section 15(a) Factors to the Amendments to

Sec. 43.4

a. Protection of Market Participants and the Public

b. Efficiency, Competitiveness and Financial Integrity

c. Price Discovery

d. Sound Risk Management Practices

e. Other Public Interest Considerations

F. Costs and Benefits Relevant to Sec. 43.6(h)(6)--Aggregation

1. Overview of Comments Received

2. Costs

3. Benefits

4. Section 15(a) Factors

a. Protection of Market Participants and the Public

b. Efficiency, Competitiveness, and Financial Integrity of the

Futures Markets

c. Price Discovery

d. Sound Risk Management Practices

e. Other Public Interest Considerations

G. Costs and Benefits Relevant to Sec. 43.6(i)--Eligible Block

Trade Parties

1. Overview of Comments Received

2. Costs

3. Benefits

4. Section 15(a) Factors

a. Protection of Market Participants and the Public

b. Efficiency, Competitiveness, and Financial Integrity of the

Futures Markets

c. Price Discovery

d. Sound Risk Management Practices

e. Other Public Interest Considerations

VI. Regulatory Flexibility Act

VII. Example of a Post-Initial Appropriate Minimum Block Size

Determination Using the 67-Percent Notional Amount Calculation

VIII. List of Commenters Who Responded to the Further Block Proposal

I. Background

A. The Dodd-Frank Act

On July 21, 2010, President Obama signed the Dodd-Frank Wall Street

Reform and Consumer Protection Act (``Dodd-Frank Act'').\1\ Title VII

of the Dodd-Frank Act \2\ amended the Commodity Exchange Act (``CEA'')

\3\ to establish a comprehensive new regulatory framework for swaps and

security-based swaps. This legislation was enacted to reduce risk,

increase transparency and promote market integrity within the financial

system by, inter alia: (1) Providing for the registration and

comprehensive regulation of swap dealers (``SDs'') and major swap

participants (``MSPs''); (2) imposing mandatory clearing and trade

execution requirements on standardized derivative products; (3)

creating robust recordkeeping and real-time reporting regimes; and (4)

enhancing the Commission's rulemaking and enforcement authorities with

respect to, among others, all registered entities and intermediaries

subject to the Commission's oversight.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\1\ See Public Law 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010).

\2\ The short title of Title VII of the Dodd-Frank Act is the

``Wall Street Transparency and Accountability Act of 2010.''

\3\ See 7 U.S.C. 1 et seq.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Section 727 of the Dodd-Frank Act created section 2(a)(13) of the

CEA, which authorizes and requires the Commission to promulgate

regulations for the real-time public reporting of swap transaction and

pricing data.\4\ Section 2(a)(13)(A) provides that ``real-time public

reporting'' means reporting ``data relating to a swap transaction,

including price and volume, as soon as technologically practicable

after the time at which the swap transaction has been executed.'' \5\

Section 2(a)(13)(B) states that the purpose of section 2(a)(13) is ``to

authorize the Commission to make swap transaction and pricing data

available to the public in such form and at such times as the

Commission determines appropriate to enhance price discovery.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\4\ See generally CEA section 2(a)(13), 7 U.S.C. 2(a)(13).

\5\ CEA section 2(a)(13)(A).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In general, section 2(a)(13) of the CEA directs the Commission to

prescribe regulations providing for the public availability of

transaction and pricing data for certain swaps. Section 2(a)(13) places

two other statutory requirements on the Commission that are relevant to

this final rule. First, sections 2(a)(13)(E)(ii) and (iii) of the CEA

respectively require the Commission to prescribe regulations specifying

``the criteria for determining what constitutes a large notional swap

transaction (block trade) for particular markets and contracts'' and

``the appropriate time delay for reporting large notional swap

transactions (block trades) to the public.'' \6\ In promulgating

regulations under section 2(a)(13), section 2(a)(13)(E)(iv) directs the

Commission to take into account whether public disclosure of swap

transaction and pricing data ``will materially reduce market

liquidity.'' \7\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\6\ Section 2(a)(13)(E) explicitly refers to the swaps described

only in sections 2(a)(13)(C)(i) and 2(a)(13)(C)(ii) of the CEA

(i.e., clearable swaps, including swaps that are exempt from

clearing). As noted in the Commission's Initial Proposal (as defined

below), its Real-Time Reporting Final Rule (as defined below), and

its Further Block Proposal (as defined below), the Commission, in

exercising its authority under CEA section 2(a)(13)(B) to ``make

swap transaction and pricing data available to the public in such

form and at such times as the Commission determines appropriate to

enhance price discovery,'' is authorized to prescribe rules similar

to those provisions in section 2(a)(13)(E) to uncleared swaps

described in section 2(a)(13)(C)(iii) and (iv) of the CEA.

\7\ CEA section 2(a)(13)(E)(iv). Section 5h(f)(2)(C) of the CEA

imposes a similar directive upon registered swap execution

facilities (``SEF'') by requiring that they set forth rules for

block trades for swap execution purposes.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The second statutory requirement relevant to this final rule is

found in sections 2(a)(13)(E)(i) and 2(a)(13)(C)(iii) of the CEA.

Through these sections, Congress sought to ``ensure that the public

reporting of swap transaction and pricing data [would] not disclose the

names or identities of the parties to [swap] transactions.'' \8\

Accordingly, Sec. 2(a)(13)(E)(i) of the CEA requires the Commission to

protect the identities of counterparties to mandatorily-cleared swaps,

swaps excepted from the mandatory clearing requirement, and

voluntarily-cleared swaps. Section 2(a)(13)(C)(iii) of the CEA requires

the Commission to prescribe rules that maintain the anonymity of

business transactions and market positions of the counterparties to an

uncleared swap.\9\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\8\ 156 Cong. Rec. S5921 (daily ed. July 15, 2010) (Statement of

Sen. Blanche Lincoln).

\9\ This provision does not cover swaps that are ``determined to

be required to be cleared but are not cleared.'' See CEA section

2(a)(13)(C)(iv).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In order to carry out the requirements of section 2(a)(13),

including among other things the two statutory requirements regarding

blocks and anonymity described above, the Commission issued a notice of

proposed rulemaking on December 7, 2010 (the ``Initial Proposal''). On

January 9, 2012, the Commission issued a final rule regarding Real-Time

Public Reporting of Swap Transaction Data adopting several provisions

contained in the Initial Proposal (the ``Real-Time Reporting Final

Rule''). The Real-Time Reporting

[[Page 32868]]

Final Rule, however, did not adopt most of the provisions in the

Initial Proposal pertaining to appropriate block sizes and anonymity.

Instead, the Commission issued a further notice of proposed rulemaking

regarding Procedures to Establish Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes for

Large Notional Off-Facility Swaps and Block Trades on March 15, 2012

(the ``Further Block Proposal'').\10\ Each of these issuances is

described more fully below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\10\ See Procedures to Establish Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes

for Large Notional Off-Facility Swaps and Block Trades, 77 FR

15,460, Mar. 15, 2012.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

B. The Initial Proposal

1. Overview

On December 7, 2010, the Commission published in the Federal

Register a notice of proposed rulemaking to implement section 2(a)(13)

of the CEA, which included specific provisions pursuant to sections

2(a)(13)(E)(i)-(iv) and 2(a)(13)(C)(iii).\11\ In this Initial Proposal,

the Commission set out proposed provisions to satisfy, among other

things, the statutory requirements discussed above regarding minimum

block sizes and anonymity protections. With respect to the first

statutory requirement, the Commission proposed: (1) Definitions for the

terms ``large notional off-facility swap'' and ``block trade''; \12\

(2) a method for determining the appropriate minimum block sizes for

large notional off-facility swaps and block trades; \13\ and (3) a

framework for timely reporting of such transactions and trades.\14\

Proposed Sec. 43.5(g) provided that registered swap data repositories

(``SDRs'') would be responsible for calculating the appropriate minimum

block size for each ``swap instrument'' using the greater result of the

distribution test \15\ and the multiple test.\16\ Proposed Sec.

43.2(y) broadly defined ``swap instrument'' as ``a grouping of swaps in

the same asset class with the same or similar characteristics.''\17\

Proposed Sec. 43.5(h) provided that for any swap listed on a swap

execution facility (``SEF'') or designated contract market (``DCM''),

the SEF or DCM must set the appropriate minimum block trade size at a

level at or above that established by an SDR for the relevant swap

instrument.\18\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\11\ See Real-Time Public Reporting of Swap Transaction Data, 75

FR 76139, Dec. 7, 2010, as corrected in Real-Time Public Reporting

of Swap Transaction Data Correction, 75 FR 76930, Dec. 10, 2010.

Interested persons are directed to the Initial Proposal for a full

discussion of each of the proposed part 43 rules.

\12\ The Initial Proposal defined the term ``large notional

swap.'' See proposed Sec. 43.2(l), 75 FR 76171. The Real-Time

Reporting Final Rule finalized the term as ``large notional off-

facility swap,'' to denote, in relevant part, that the swap is not

executed pursuant to a SEF or designated contract market's (``DCM'')

rules and procedures. See Sec. 43.2, 77 FR 1182, 1244, Jan. 9,

2012. Specifically, the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule defined the

term as an ``off-facility swap that has a notional or principal

amount at or above the appropriate minimum block size applicable to

such publicly reportable swap transaction and is not a block trade

as defined in Sec. 43.2 of the Commission's regulations.'' Id.

Throughout this final rulemaking, the Commission uses the term

``large notional off-facility swap'' as adopted in the Real-Time

Reporting Final Rule.

The Initial Proposal's definition of ``block trade'' was similar

to the final definition in the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule. See

proposed Sec. 43.2(f), 75 FR 76171. The Real-Time Reporting Final

Rule defines the term ``block trade'' as a publicly reportable swap

transaction that: ``(1) [i]nvolves a swap that is listed on a SEF or

DCM; (2) [o]ccurs away from the [SEF's or DCM's] trading system or

platform and is executed pursuant to the [SEF's or DCM's] rules and

procedures; (3) has a notional or principal amount at or above the

appropriate minimum block applicable to such swap; and (4) [i]s

reported subject to the rules and procedures of the [SEF or DCM] and

the rules described in [part 43], including the appropriate time

delay requirements set forth in Sec. 43.5.'' See Sec. 43.2, 77 FR

1243.

\13\ See proposed Sec. 43.5, 75 FR 76174-76.

\14\ Proposed Sec. 43.5(k)(1) in the Initial Proposal provided

that the time delay for the public dissemination of data for a block

trade or large notional off-facility swap shall commence at the time

of execution of such trade or swap. See 75 FR 76176. Proposed Sec.

43.5(k)(2) provided that the time delay for standardized block

trades and large notional off-facility swaps (i.e., swaps that fall

under CEA Section 2(a)(13)(C)(i) and (iv)) would be 15 minutes from

the time of execution. Id. The Initial Proposal did not provide

specific time delays for large notional off-facility swaps (i.e.,

swaps that fall under Section 2(a)(13)(C)(ii) and (iii)). Instead,

proposed Sec. 43.5(k)(3) provided that the time delay for such

swaps shall be reported subject to a time delay that may be

prescribed by the Commission. Id.

The Real-Time Reporting Final Rule established time delays for

the public dissemination of block trades and large notional off-

facility swaps in Sec. 43.5. See 77 FR 1247-49.

\15\ The distribution test, described in proposed Sec.

43.5(g)(1)(i) of the Initial Proposal, required that an SDR take the

rounded transaction sizes of all trades executed over a period of

time for a particular swap instrument and create a distribution of

those trades. An SDR would then determine the minimum threshold

amount as an amount that is greater than 95 percent of the notional

or principal transaction sizes for the swap instrument for an

applicable period of time. See 75 FR 76175.

\16\ The multiple test, described in proposed Sec.

43.5(g)(1)(ii) in the Initial Proposal, required that an SDR

multiply the block trade multiple by the ``social size'' of a

particular swap instrument. Proposed Sec. 43.2(x) defined ``social

size'' as the greatest of the mean, median or mode transaction size

for a particular swap instrument. The Commission proposed a block

trade multiple of five. Id.

\17\ See proposed Sec. 43.2(y), 75 FR 76172.

\18\ See 75 FR 76176.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With respect to anonymity, the Initial Proposal set forth several

provisions to address issues pertinent to protecting the identities of

parties to a swap. Essentially, these proposed provisions sought to

protect the identities of parties to a swap through the limited

disclosure of information and data relevant to the swap. In particular,

proposed Sec. 43.4(e)(1) in the Initial Proposal provided that an SDR

could not publicly report swap transaction and pricing data in a manner

that discloses or otherwise facilitates the identification of a party

to a swap. Proposed Sec. 43.4(e)(2) would have placed a requirement on

SEFs, DCMs and reporting parties to provide an SDR with a specific

description of the underlying asset and tenor of a swap. This proposed

section also included a qualification with respect to the reporting of

the specific description. In particular, this section provided that

``[the] description must be general enough to provide anonymity but

specific enough to provide for a meaningful understanding of the

economic characteristics of the swap.'' \19\ This qualification would

have applied to all swaps.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\19\ See 75 FR 76174.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the Initial Proposal, the Commission acknowledged that swaps

that are executed on or pursuant to the rules of a SEF or DCM do not

raise the same level of concerns in protecting the identities, business

transactions or market positions of swap counterparties since these

swaps generally lack customization.\20\ As a result, the Commission

provided that SEFs and DCMs should tailor the description required by

proposed Sec. 43.2(e) depending on the asset class and place of

execution of each swap.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\20\ See 75 FR 76151 (``In contrast, for those swaps that are

executed on a swap market, the Commission believes that since such

contracts will be listed on a particular trading platform or

facility, it will be unlikely that a party to a swap could be

inferred based on the reporting of the underlying asset and

therefore parties to swaps executed on swap markets must report the

specific underlying assets and tenor of the swap.'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In contrast, the Commission acknowledged that the public

dissemination of a description of the specific underlying asset and

tenor of swaps that are not executed on or pursuant to the rules of a

SEF or DCM (i.e., swaps that are executed bilaterally) may result in

the unintended disclosure of the identities, business transactions or

market positions of swap counterparties, particularly for swaps in the

other commodity asset class.\21\ To address this issue, the Commission

proposed in Sec. 43.4(e)(2) that an SDR publicly disseminate a more

general description of the specific underlying asset and tenor.\22\ In

the Initial Proposal, the Commission provided a hypothetical example of

how an SDR could mask or otherwise protect the underlying asset from

public disclosure

[[Page 32869]]

in a manner too specific so as to divulge the identity of a swap

counterparty. The Commission, however, did not set forth a specific

manner in which SDRs should carry out this requirement.\23\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\21\ See 75 FR 76150-51.

\22\ See 75 FR 76174.

\23\ See 75 FR 76150. The Initial Proposal further provided that

the requirement in proposed Sec. 43.4(e)(2) was separate from the

requirement that a reporting party report swap data to an SDR

pursuant to section 2(a)(13)(G) of the CEA. See 75 FR 76174.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

To further protect the identities, business transactions or market

positions of swap counterparties, proposed Sec. 43.4(i) of the Initial

Proposal included a rounding convention for all swaps, which included a

``notional cap'' provision. The proposed notional cap provision

provided, for example, that if the notional size of a swap is greater

than $250 million, then an SDR only would publicly disseminate a

notation of ``$250+'' rather than the actual notional size of the

swap.\24\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\24\ See 75 FR 76152.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission issued the Initial Proposal for public comment for a

period of 60 days, but later reopened the comment period for an

additional 45 days.\25\ After issuing the Initial Proposal, the

Commission received 105 comment letters and held 40 meetings with

interested parties regarding the proposed provisions.\26\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\25\ The initial comment period for the Initial Proposal closed

on February 7, 2011. The comment periods for most proposed

rulemakings implementing the Dodd-Frank Act--including the proposed

part 43 rules--subsequently were reopened for the period of April 27

through June 2, 2011.

\26\ The interested parties who either submitted comment letters

or met with Commission staff included end-users, potential swap

dealers, asset managers, industry groups/associations, potential

SDRs, a potential SEF, multiple law firms on behalf of their clients

and a DCM. Of the 105 comment letters submitted in response to the

Initial Proposal, 42 letters focused on various issues relating to

block trades and large notional off-facility swaps. Of the 40

meetings, five meetings focused on various issues relating to block

trades and large notional off-facility swaps. All comment letters

received in response to the Initial Proposal may be found on the

Commission's Web site at: http://comments.cftc.gov/PublicComments/CommentList.aspx?id=919.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. Public Comments in Response to the Initial Proposal

The commenters to the Initial Proposal provided general and

specific comments relating to the proposed provisions regarding the

determination of appropriate minimum block sizes and anonymity

protections for the identities, business transactions and market

positions of swap counterparties.\27\ The comments submitted regarding

the Initial Proposal's provisions regarding appropriate minimum block

sizes and anonymity protections are summarized in detail in the Further

Block Proposal.\28\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\27\ A list of the full names and abbreviations of commenters

who responded to the Initial Proposal and who the Commission refers

to in the Further Block Proposal is included in section VI below. As

noted above, letters from these commenters and others submitted in

response to the Initial Proposal are available through the

Commission's Web site at: http://comments.cftc.gov/PublicComments/CommentList.aspx?id=919.

\28\ See Further Block Proposal at 77 FR 15463-66.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Following the close of the comment period for the Initial Proposal,

the Commission took several actions in consideration of the comments

received regarding the proposed methodology to determine appropriate

minimum block sizes, the proposed anonymity protections and the

proposed implementation approach.\29\ A discussion of the Commission's

actions and their impact on the Further Block Proposal is set out

immediately below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\29\ Commission staff also consulted with the staffs of several

other federal financial regulators in connection with the issuance

of the Further Block Proposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

C. Issuance of the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule

In consideration of the public comments submitted in response to

the Initial Proposal, the Commission obtained and analyzed swap data in

order to better understand the trading activity of swaps in certain

asset classes.\30\ The Commission also reviewed additional information,

including a study pertaining to the mandatory trade execution

requirement and post-trade transparency concerns that arose out of two

of the Commission's proposed rulemakings,\31\ as well as a report

issued by two industry trade associations on block trade reporting in

the swaps market.\32\ In addition, the Commission and the Securities

and Exchange Commission (``SEC'') held a two-day public roundtable on

Dodd-Frank Act implementation on May 2-3, 2011 (``Public

Roundtable'').\33\ During the Public Roundtable and in comment letters

submitted in support thereof, interested parties recommended that the

Commission adopt a phased-in approach with respect to establishing

block trade rules.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\30\ A detailed discussion of Commission staff's review and

analysis process is set out below in sections II.A.1.b.i. and c.i.

\31\ See ISDA, Costs and Benefits of Mandatory Electronic

Execution Requirements for Interest Rate Products, 24 (ISDA

Discussion Paper No. 2, Nov. 2011), available at http://www2.isda.org/attachment/Mzc0NA==/ISDA%20Mandatory%20Electronic%20Execution%20Discussion%20Paper.pdf.

This paper cited the Commission's notice of proposed rulemaking with

respect to SEFs (Core Principles and Other Requirements for Swap

Execution Facilities, 76 FR 1214, 1220, Jan. 7, 2011) and the

Initial Proposal.

\32\ See ISDA and SIFMA, Block trade reporting over-the-counter

derivatives markets, 6 (Jan. 2011), available at http://www.isda.org/speeches/pdf/Block-Trade-Reporting.pdf.

\33\ See Joint Public Roundtable on Issues Related to the

Schedule for Implementing Final Rules for Swaps and Security-Based

Swaps Under the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer

Protection Act, 76 FR 23211, Apr. 26, 2011. A copy of the transcript

is accessible at: http://www.cftc.gov/idc/groups/public/@newsroom/documents/file/csjac_transcript050211.pdf.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

On January 9, 2012, the Commission issued the Real-Time Reporting

Final Rule, finalizing several provisions that were proposed in the

Initial Proposal.\34\ Those provisions implement, among other things:

(1) Several definitions proposed in the Initial Proposal relevant to

this final rule, including ``asset class''; \35\ (2) the scope of part

43; (3) the reporting responsibilities of the parties to each swap; (4)

the requirement that SDRs publicly disseminate swap transaction and

pricing data; (5) the data fields that SDRs will publicly disseminate;

(6) the time-stamping and recordkeeping requirements of SDRs, SEFs,

DCMs and the ``reporting party'' to each swap; \36\ (7) the interim

time delays for public dissemination and the time delays for public

dissemination of large notional off-facility swaps and block trades;

and (8) interim notional cap sizes for all swaps that are publicly

disseminated.\37\ Based on commenters' recommendations, however, the

Commission did not adopt proposed Sec. 43.5 and stated its intent to

re-propose a calculation methodology for appropriate minimum block

sizes based on additional data and analysis in a separate

rulemaking.\38\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\34\ See 77 FR 1182.

\35\ The Real-Time Reporting Final Rule includes final

definitions for the following terms: (1) block trade; (2) large

notional off-facility swap; (3) appropriate minimum block size; and

(4) asset class. As noted above, the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule

did not define the term swap instrument. This final rule adopts a

new term, swap category, which groups swaps for the purpose of

determining whether a swap transaction qualifies as a large notional

off-facility swap or block trade. See note 17 supra.

\36\ See Sec. 43.2 of the Commission's regulations. 77 FR 1244.

The Real-Time Reporting Final Rule finalized the definition of

``reporting party'' as a ``party to a swap with the duty to report a

publicly reportable swap transaction in accordance with this part

[43] and section 2(a)(13)(F) of the [CEA].'' 77 FR 1244.

\37\ See 77 FR 1244.

\38\ See 77 FR 1185.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

D. Further Block Proposal

On March 15, 2012, the Commission issued for comment the Further

Block Proposal.\39\ Based on the public comments received in response

to the Initial Proposal, and in order to successfully implement the

real-time public reporting regulatory framework

[[Page 32870]]

established in the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule, the Commission

proposed provisions in the Further Block Proposal that: (1) Specify the

criteria for determining swap categories and methodologies for

determining the appropriate minimum block sizes for large notional off-

facility swaps and block trades; and (2) provide increased protections

to the identities of swap counterparties to large swap transactions and

certain other commodity swaps, which were not fully addressed in the

Real-Time Reporting Final Rule.\40\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\39\ See 77 FR 15460.

\40\ In several places in the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule,

the Commission stated that it planned to address these requirements

in a separate, forthcoming release. See, e.g., 77 FR 1185, 1191,

1193 and 1217. The Further Block Proposal was that release.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

1. Policy Goals

In section 2(a)(13) of the CEA, Congress intended that the

Commission consider both the benefits of enhanced market transparency

and the effects such transparency would have on market liquidity.\41\

Section 2(a)(13)(E)(iv) of the CEA places constraints on the

requirements for the real-time public reporting of swap transaction and

pricing data by mandating that the Commission shall ``take into account

whether the public disclosure [of swap transaction and pricing data]

will materially reduce market liquidity.''\42\ While the Commission

anticipates that the public dissemination of swap transaction and

pricing data will generally reduce costs associated with price

discovery and prevent information asymmetries between market makers and

end-users,\43\ it also believes that the benefits of enhanced market

transparency are not boundless, particularly in swap markets with

limited liquidity.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\41\ In considering the benefits and effects of enhanced market

transparency, the Commission notes that the ``guiding principle in

setting appropriate block trade levels [is that] the vast majority

of swap transactions should be exposed to the public market through

exchange trading.'' Congressional Record--Senate, S5902, S5922 (July

15, 2010).

\42\ CEA section 2(a)(13)(E)(iv). See also CEA section

5h(f)(2)(C) (concerning the treatment of block trades on SEFs for

trade execution purposes).

\43\ See e.g., CEA section 2(a)(13)(B) (``The purpose of this

section is to authorize the Commission to make swap transaction and

pricing data available to the public in such form and at such times

as the Commission determines appropriate to enhance price

discovery.'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission understands that the publication of detailed

information regarding ``outsize swap transactions'' \44\ could expose

swap counterparties to higher trading costs.\45\ In this regard, the

publication of detailed information about an outsize swap transaction

may alert the market to the possibility that the original liquidity

provider to the outsize swap transaction will be re-entering the market

to offset that transaction.\46\ Other market participants might be

alerted to the liquidity provider's need to offset risk and therefore

would have a strong incentive to exact a premium from the liquidity

provider. As a result, liquidity providers possibly could be deterred

from becoming counterparties to outsize swap transactions if swap

transaction and pricing data is publicly disseminated before liquidity

providers can offset their positions. The Commission anticipates that,

in turn, this result could negatively affect liquidity in the swaps

market.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\44\ As used in the Further Block Proposal and this final rule,

an ``outsize swap transaction'' is a transaction that, as a function

of its size and the depth of the liquidity of the relevant market

(and equivalent markets), leaves one or both parties to such

transaction unlikely to transact at a competitive price.

\45\ Consistent with this final rule, the Commission clarified

in the SEF final rule that a swap transaction qualifies as a block

trade based on the size of the swap transaction, not based on

whether the swap is subject to the trade execution requirement under

section 2(h)(8) of the CEA. See Core Principles and Other

Requirements for Swap Execution Facilities, p. 72 (May 16, 2013)].

In Sec. 37.200 of the Commission's regulations, the Commission has

codified the statutory text of SEF Core Principle 2 under section

5h(f)(2)(C) of the CEA, which requires a SEF to establish rules

governing the operation of its trading facility, including trading

procedures for block trades. 17 CFR 37.200(c). Similarly, the

Commission's proposed rulemaking regarding core principles and other

requirements for DCMs under Sec. 38.504 of the Commission's

regulations, the Commission requires DCMs to adopt rules that comply

with all of the provisions of part 43, including the block trade

provisions finalized herein. Core Principles and Other Requirements

for Designated Contract Markets, 75 FR 80572, 80617 (Dec. 22, 2010).

\46\ The price of such a transaction would reflect market

conditions for the underlying commodity or reference index and the

liquidity premium for executing the swap transaction. The time

delays in part 43 of the Commission's regulations will protect end-

users and liquidity providers from the expected price impact of the

disclosure of publicly reportable swap transactions. Trading that

exploits the need of traders to reduce or offset their positions has

been defined in financial economics literature as ``predatory

trading.'' See e.g., Markus Brunnermeier and Lasse Heje Pedersen,

Predatory Trading, Journal of Finance LX 4, Aug. 2005, available at

http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~lpederse/papers/predatory_trading.pdf.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In consideration of these potential outcomes, the Further Block

Proposal sought to provide maximum public transparency, while taking

into account the concerns of liquidity providers regarding possible

reductions in market liquidity. To do so, the Further Block Proposal

established the following more detailed criteria: (1) Swap categories

(relative to the definition of swap instrument in the Initial

Proposal); (2) a phased-in approach to determining appropriate minimum

block sizes for block trades and large notional off-facility swaps; and

(3) anonymity provisions for the public reporting of transaction data.

A summary of the Commission's proposed approach is provided below.

2. Summary of Proposed Approach

The Commission proposed a two-period, phased-in approach to

implement regulations for determining appropriate minimum block

sizes.\47\ Specifically, the Commission proposed phasing-in minimum

block sizes during an initial period and setting them thereafter on an

ongoing basis (i.e., the post-initial period) so that market

participants could better adjust their swap trading strategies to

manage risk, secure new technologies and make necessary arrangements in

order to comply with part 43 reporting requirements. The Commission

proposed two provisions relating to the Commission's determination of

appropriate minimum block sizes: (1) Initial appropriate minimum block

sizes under proposed Sec. 43.6(e); and (2) post-initial appropriate

minimum block sizes under proposed Sec. 43.6(f).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\47\ The Commission proposed the same phased-in approach for

determining cap sizes, which help to protect the anonymity of

counterparties' market positions and business transactions as

required in the CEA. For a more detailed discussion of the

Commission's proposed approach with respect to cap sizes, see

section III.B.

The two-period, phased-in approach would become effective after

the implementation of the part 43 provisions in the Real-Time

Reporting Final Rule. Until the date on which the proposed

provisions in the Further Block Proposal become effective, all swaps

would be subject to a time delay pursuant to the provisions in part

43.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In proposed Sec. 43.6(e), the Commission proposed establishing

initial appropriate minimum block sizes for each category of swaps

within the interest rate, credit, foreign exchange (``FX'') and other

commodity asset classes.\48\ The Commission listed the prescribed

initial appropriate minimum block sizes in proposed appendix F to part

43 based on these swap categories.\49\ For interest rate and credit

swaps, the Commission reviewed actual market data and prescribed

initial appropriate minimum block sizes for swap categories in these

asset classes

[[Page 32871]]

based on that data. For the other asset classes, the Commission did not

have access to relevant market data. As such, during the initial

period, the Commission proposed using a methodology based on whether a

swap or swap category is ``economically related'' to a futures

contract.\50\ Swaps and swap categories that are not economically

related to a futures contract would remain subject to a time delay

(i.e., treated as block trades or large notional off-facility swaps, as

applicable, regardless of notional amount) during the initial period.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\48\ The Commission proposed that swaps in the equity asset

class do not qualify as block trades and large notional off-facility

swaps. See proposed Sec. 43.6(d). Otherwise, the Commission

proposed prescribing swap categories for each asset class as set

forth in proposed Sec. 43.6(b). These swap categories would remain

the same during the initial and post-initial periods.

\49\ The Commission notes SEFs and DCMs would not be prohibited

under the Further Block Proposal from setting block sizes for swaps

at levels that are higher than the appropriate minimum block sizes

as determined by the Commission.

\50\ See infra notes 169-174 and accompanying text.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In proposed Sec. 43.6(f)(1), the Commission provided that the

duration of this initial period would be no less than one year after an

SDR started collecting reliable data for a particular asset class as

determined by the Commission. During the initial period, the Commission

would review reliable data for each asset class. For the purposes of

this proposed provision, reliable data would include all data collected

by an SDR for each asset class in accordance with the compliance chart

in the adopting release to part 45 of the Commission's regulations.\51\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\51\ See Swap Data Recordkeeping and Reporting Requirements, 77

FR 2136, 2196, Jan. 13, 2012.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission stated in the Further Block Proposal and is

currently of the view that data is per se reliable if it is collected

by an SDR for an asset class after the respective compliance date for

such asset class as set forth in part 45 of the Commission's

regulations or by other Commission action. The Commission notes that

SDRs have been collecting data pursuant to the compliance dates for

certain market participants and asset classes since December 2012. DCMs

and Swap Dealers (``SDs'') began reporting swap transactions in the

interest rate and credit default swap asset classes on December 31,

2012.\52\ DCMs and SDs began reporting swap transactions in the FX,

equity, and other commodity asset classes on February 28, 2013.\53\

Major Swap Participants (``MSPs'') began reporting swap transactions in

all five asset classes on February 28, 2013.\54\ Financial Entities

began reporting swap transactions in the interest rate and credit

default swap asset classes on April 10, 2013.\55\ Financial Entities

begin reporting swap transactions for swaps executed starting April 10,

2013, in the FX, equity, and other commodity asset classes on May 29,

2013.\56\ Non-SDs, non-MSPs, and non-Financial Entities begin reporting

swap transactions for swaps executed starting April 10, 2013, in the

interest rate and credit default swap asset classes on July 1,

2013.\57\ Non-SDs, non-MSPs, and non-Financial Entities begin reporting

swap transactions for swaps executed starting April 10, 2013, in the

FX, equity, and other commodity asset classes on August 19, 2013.\58\

Accordingly, the Commission and SDRs will have one year of reliable

data as of April 10, 2014.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\52\ See ``Commission Q & A--On the Start of Swap Data

Reporting'' (Oct. 9, 2012).

\53\ See ``No-Action Relief for Swap Dealers from Certain Swap

Data Reporting Requirements of Part 43, Part 45, and Part 46 of the

Commission's Regulations Due to Effects of Hurricane Sandy,''

Commission Letter No. 12-41 (Dec. 5, 2012).

\54\ See id.

\55\ See ``Time-Limited No-Action Relief for Swap Counterparties

that are not Swap Dealers or Major Swap Participants, from Certain

Swap Data Reporting Requirements of Parts 43, 45 and 46 of the

Commission's Regulations,'' Commission Letter No. 13-10 (Apr. 9,

2013).

\56\ See id.

\57\ See id.

\58\ See id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The proposed initial period would expire following the publication

of a Commission determination of post-initial appropriate minimum block

sizes in accordance with the publication process set forth in proposed

Sec. 43.6(f)(4) and (5). Thereafter, the Commission would set post-

initial appropriate minimum block sizes for swap categories no less

than once each calendar year using the calculation methodology set

forth in proposed Sec. 43.6(c)(1).\59\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\59\ In particular, the Commission proposed a 67-percent

notional amount calculation, which is discussed in more detail in

section II.B.3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also proposed special rules for determining

appropriate minimum block sizes in certain instances. In particular, in

proposed Sec. 43.6(d), the Commission prescribed special rules for

swaps in the equity asset class. In proposed Sec. 43.6(h), the

Commission proposed establishing special rules for determining

appropriate minimum block sizes in certain circumstances including, for

example, rules for converting currencies and rules for determining

whether a swap with optionality qualifies for block trade or large

notional off-facility swap treatment.\60\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\60\ See infra Section II.B.6. for a discussion of the special

rules.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the Further Block Proposal's proposed amendments to Sec.

43.4(h) and 43.4(d)(4), the Commission also prescribed measures to

fulfill the CEA's anonymity requirements in connection with the public

dissemination of publicly reportable swap transactions. The Commission

proposed adopting the practices used by most federal agencies when

releasing to the public company-specific information--by removing

obvious identifiers, limiting geographic detail (e.g., disclosing

general, non-specific geographical information about the delivery and

pricing points) and masking high-risk variables by truncating extreme

values for certain variables (e.g., capping notional values).\61\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\61\ The Commission proposed to follow the necessary procedures

for releasing microdata files as outlined by the Federal Committee

on Statistical Methodology: (i) Removal of all direct personal and

institutional identifiers, (ii) limiting geographic detail, and

(iii) top-coding high-risk variables which are continuous. See

Federal Committee on Statistical Methodology, Report on Statistical

Disclosure Limitation Methodology 94 (Statistical Policy Working

Paper 22, 2d ed. 2005), http://www.fcsm.gov/working-papers/totalreport.pdf. The report was originally prepared by the

Subcommittee on Disclosure Limitation Methodology in 1994 and was

revised by the Confidentiality and Data Access Committee in 2005.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. Overview of Comments Received

The Commission received comments from 35 interested parties

representing a broad range of interests including: financial end-users,

swap dealers, asset managers, industry groups/associations, potential

SEFs, and a DCM.\62\ Some commenters expressed general support for the

Further Block Proposal's provisions regarding minimum block sizes and

anonymity; others objected to particular aspects of the Further Block

Proposal and/or offered recommendations for clarification or

modification of specific proposed regulations.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\62\ A list of the full names and abbreviations of commenters

who responded to the Further Block Proposal is included in section

VIII below. As noted above, letters from these commenters and others

submitted in response to the Initial Proposal are available through

the Commission's Web site at http://comments.cftc.gov/PublicComments/CommentList.aspx?id=919.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition to a general solicitation for comment on all aspects of

the Further Block Proposal, the Commission requested comment on a

number of specific, focused questions related to particular provisions.

For example, commenters were asked to address issues related to: (i)

The appropriate criteria for determining swap categories in the five

asset classes; (ii) the appropriate methodology for determining

appropriate minimum block sizes for swaps in the five asset classes;

(iii) whether and how a phase-in of block thresholds should be

implemented; (iv) special rules with respect to swaps with optionality,

swaps with composite reference prices, physical commodity swaps,

currency conversions, and successor currencies; (v) the role of SEFs

and DCMs in

[[Page 32872]]

determining appropriate minimum block sizes for swaps that they list;

(vi) the process by which the Commission would notify the public of

appropriate minimum block sizes; (vii) the process through which a

qualifying swap transaction would be treated as a block trade or large

notional off-facility swap; (viii) the appropriate methodology for

determining the maximum limit of the principal, notional amount of a

swap that is publicly disseminated; (ix) appropriate anonymity

protections for the public dissemination of publicly reportable swap

transactions in the other commodity asset class.

The Commission also requested comment with respect to the cost-

benefit considerations in the Further Block Proposal and specifically

requested commenters to provide a feasible alternative approach to

establishing minimum block sizes that would impose less regulatory

burden on swap market participants and the general public. Commenters

also were expressly invited to provide data regarding the direct and

indirect quantifiable costs with the proposed criteria for establishing

minimum block thresholds.

4. Additional Proposal Regarding Aggregation of Blocks

Among the requirements contained in the Initial Proposal, proposed

Sec. 43.5(b)(1) provided that eligible parties to a block trade (or

large notional swap) must be Eligible Contract Participants (``ECPs''),

except that a DCM may allow a Commodity Trading Advisor (``CTA''),

investment advisor, or foreign person meeting certain criteria to

transact block trades for customers who are not ECPs. Further, proposed

Sec. 43.5(m) prohibited aggregation of orders for different trading

accounts in order to satisfy the appropriate minimum block size

requirement, except if done so on a DCM by a CTA, investment adviser,

or foreign person meeting certain criteria.

After it issued its Further Block Proposal, the Commission

determined that the aggregation provision and the provision that

specified the eligible parties to a block trade, including the proposed

requirement that persons transacting block trades on behalf of

customers must receive prior written consent to do so, were

inadvertently omitted from the Further Block Proposal. These provisions

were then the subject of a separate notice of proposed rulemaking

issued on June 27, 2012 (``Proposed Aggregation Rule'').\63\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\63\ Rules Prohibiting the Aggregation of Orders to Satisfy

Minimum Block Sizes or Cap Size Requirements, and Establishing

Eligibility Requirements for Parties to Block Trades, 77 FR 38229,

June 27, 2012.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission received a total of nine comment letters in response

to the proposed rules regarding eligible parties to a block trade and

aggregation of orders. Four of the letters responded to the Initial

Proposal and five letters responded to the Proposed Aggregation Rule.

Many of the comments received applied equally to the same provisions

contained in both proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(6) and 43.6(i), which address

the aggregation of orders and the eligible parties to a block trade.

II. Procedures To Establish Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes for Large

Notional Off-Facility Swaps and Block Trades--Final Rules

A. Criteria for Distinguishing Among Swap Categories in Each Asset

Class

In the Further Block Proposal, the Commission proposed to use the

term ``swap category'' to convey the concept of a grouping of swap

contracts that would be subject to a common appropriate minimum block

size.\64\ Specifically, the Commission proposed specific criteria for

defining swap categories in each asset class. As adopted in the Real-

Time Reporting Final Rule, Sec. 43.2 of the Commission's regulations

defines ``asset class'' as ``a broad category of commodities,

including, without limitation, any `excluded commodity' as defined in

section 1a(19) of the [CEA], with common characteristics underlying a

swap.'' \65\ Section 43.2 also identifies the following five swap asset

classes: Interest rates; \66\ equity; credit; FX; \67\ and other

commodities.\68\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\64\ Proposed Sec. 43.6(b) does not set out a definition for

the term ``swap category.'' Instead, proposed Sec. 43.6(b) sets out

the provisions that group swaps within each asset class with common

risk and liquidity profiles, as determined by the Commission.

\65\ See Sec. 43.2, 77 FR 1243.

\66\ In the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule, the Commission

determined that cross-currency swaps are a part of the interest rate

asset class. See 77 FR 1193. The Commission noted that this

determination is consistent with industry practice.

\67\ The U.S. Department of the Treasury (``Treasury'') has

issued a Final Determination, pursuant to sections 1a(47)(E)(i) and

1b of the CEA, that exempts FX swaps and FX forwards from the

definition of ``swap'' under the CEA. Therefore, the requirements of

section 2(a)(13) of the CEA would not apply to those transactions,

and such transactions would not be subject to part 43 of the

Commission's regulations. See Determination of Foreign Exchange

Swaps and Foreign Exchange Forwards under the Commodity Exchange

Act, 77 FR 69694, Nov. 20, 2012. Nevertheless, section

1a(47)(E)(iii) of the CEA provides that FX swaps and FX forwards

transactions still are not excluded from regulatory reporting

requirements to an SDR. Further, the Commission notes that

Treasury's final determination excludes FX swaps and FX forwards,

but does not apply to FX options or non-deliverable FX forwards. As

such, FX instruments that are not covered by Treasury's final

determination are subject to part 43 of the Commission's

regulations.

\68\ The Real-Time Reporting Final Rule defines the term ``other

commodity'' to mean any commodity that is not categorized in the

other asset classes as may be determined by the Commission. See 77

FR 1244. The definition of asset class in Sec. 43.2 also provides

that the Commission may later determine that there are other asset

classes not identified currently in that section. See 77 FR 1243.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The proposed swap category criteria are intended to address the

following two policy objectives: (1) Categorizing together swaps with

similar quantitative or qualitative characteristics that warrant being

subject to the same appropriate minimum block size; and (2) minimizing

the number of the swap categories within an asset class in order to

avoid unnecessary complexity in the determination process.\69\ In the

Commission's view, balancing these policy objectives and considering

the characteristics of different types of swaps within an asset class

are necessary in establishing appropriate criteria for determining swap

categories within each asset class. The five asset classes established

by the Commission in the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule are discussed

briefly in the paragraph below, followed by a discussion of the

proposed swap category criteria for each asset class.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\69\ These objectives are specific to the determination of

appropriate swap category criteria and are intended to promote the

general policy goals described above in section I.D.1.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the Further Block Proposal, the Commission proposed breaking

down each asset class into separate swap categories to determine

appropriate minimum block sizes for such categories. During the initial

and post-initial periods, the Commission would group swaps in the five

asset classes into the prescribed swap categories as set forth in

proposed Sec. 43.6(b).

[[Page 32873]]

Twenty-one commenters addressed the Further Block Proposal's use of

swap categories.\70\ The vast majority of the comments did not question

the use of swap categories generally, and focused on the specific

criteria proposed for determining swap categories within each asset

class instead. Better Markets and ICI expressly supported the

Commission's proposed use of swap categories.\71\ Better Markets stated

that ``the concept of a `swap category' is useful, in that it allows

greater granularity than the far broader notion of `asset class.' ''

\72\ ICI ``support[ed] the CFTC's proposal to establish categories of

swaps within different asset classes that would be subject to a common

appropriate minimum block size to better calibrate the block thresholds

to the relative liquidity of the swap categories in each asset class.''

\73\ ICAP, however, disagreed with the Commission's use of swap

categories and stated that ``the Commission's proposal is mistaken in

its use of `swap categories' . . . as opposed to using the standard

liquid tenors of swap contracts.'' \74\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\70\ See generally CL-AFR; CL-AII; CL-Barclays; CL-Better

Markets; CL-CME; CL-FIA; CL-GFMA; CL-ICAP; CL-ICAP Energy; CL-ICI;

CL-ISDA/SIFMA; CL-Kinetix; CL-MFA; CL-Morgan Stanley; CL-

Parascandola; CL-Parity; CL-Pierpont; CL-SDMA; CL-SIFMA; CL-WMBAA;

CL-Vanguard.

\71\ CL-Better Markets at 5; CL-ICI at 4.

\72\ CL-Better Markets at 5.

\73\ CL-ICI at 4.

\74\ CL-ICAP at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments related to the use of swap

categories, the Commission is adopting swap categories as proposed in

Sec. 43.6, with certain modifications based upon both general concerns

expressed by commenters in regard to the use of swap categories,

specific concerns raised in regard to the criteria for determining swap

categories within each asset class, and other relevant market

developments.\75\ The following sections address the comments regarding

specific asset classes and set out, where appropriate, the Commission's

responsive modifications of the swap categories approach.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\75\ The Commission is using the term ``swap category'' instead

of ``swap instrument'' in this final rule. Although the Commission

is not adopting a definition of ``swap category,'' the Commission

believes that this term groups swap contracts that would be subject

to the same appropriate minimum block size based on asset class with

common quantitative or qualitative characteristics, i.e., risk and

liquidity profiles.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

1. Interest Rate and Credit Asset Classes

a. Background

The Commission was able to obtain and review non-public swap data

to make inferences about patterns of trading activity, price impact and

liquidity in the markets for swaps in the interest rate and credit

asset classes. Based on that review, the Commission proposed criteria

for determining swap categories in these two asset classes.

Specifically, the Commission proposed defining swap categories for: (1)

Interest rate swaps based on unique combinations of tenor \76\ and

currency; and (2) credit default swaps (``CDS'') based on unique

combinations of tenor and conventional spread.\77\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\76\ As used in the Further Block Proposal, the tenor of a swap

refers to the amount of time from the effective or start date of a

swap to the end date of such swap. In circumstances where the

effective or start date of the swap was different from the trade

date of the swap, the Commission used the later occurring of the two

dates to determine tenor.

Two commenters addressed how the Commission should determine

tenor for backdated swaps. AFR stated that backdating a swap is the

equivalent of a swap with a date of its inception, but with a price

that includes an adjustment for the backdating feature of the

transaction; AFR wrote that tenor should be determined accordingly.

CL-AFR at 5-6. Similarly, ISDA/SIFMA requested that the Commission

determine the tenor of a back dated swap as the time from the date

of execution of the swap (as opposed to the start date) to the

maturity date of the swap. CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 10. After consideration

of these comments, the Commission maintains the same approach from

the Further Block Proposal.

\77\ As generally used in the industry, the term ``conventional

spread'' represents the equivalent of a swap dealer's quoted spread

(i.e., an upfront fee based on a fixed coupon and using standard

assumptions such as auctions and recovery rates). More information

regarding the use of this term can be found at Markit, The CDS Big

Bang: Understanding the Changes to the Global CDS Contract and North

American Conventions, at http://www.markit.com/cds/announcements/resource/cds_big_bang.pdf, (Mar. 2009), at 19.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission obtained transaction-level data for these asset

classes from two third-party service providers with the assistance of

the Over-the-Counter Derivatives Supervisors Group (``ODSG'').\78\

Established in 2005, the ODSG is chaired by the Federal Reserve Bank of

New York and is comprised of domestic and international supervisors of

representatives from major OTC derivatives market participants.\79\ In

particular, the ODSG coordinated with the ``G-14 banks'' in order to

gain written permission to access the non-public swap data.\80\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\78\ Section 8(a) of the CEA protects non-public, transaction-

level data from public disclosure. Section 8(a)(1) provides, in

relevant part, that ``the Commission may not publish data and

information that would separately disclose the business transactions

or market positions of any person and trade secrets or names of

customers . . . .'' To assist commenters, the Further Block Proposal

included various tables and summary statistics depicting the ODSG

data in aggregate forms. In the discussion that follows, the

Commission additionally has described the methodology it employed in

reviewing, analyzing and drawing conclusions based on the ODSG data.

\79\ See OTC Derivatives Supervisors Group--Federal Reserve Bank

of New York, http://www.ny.frb.org/markets/otc_derivatives_supervisors_group.html (last visited May 6, 2013). The ODSG was

formed ``in order to address the emerging risks of inadequate

infrastructure for the rapidly growing market in the credit

derivatives . . . .'' The ODSG works directly with market

participants to plan, monitor and coordinate industry progress

toward collective commitments made by firms.

\80\ The G-14 banks are Bank of America-Merrill Lynch; Barclays

Capital; BNP Paribas; Citigroup; Credit Suisse; Deutsche Bank AG;

Goldman Sachs & Co.; HSBC Group; J.P. Morgan; Morgan Stanley; The

Royal Bank of Scotland Group; Societe Generale; UBS AG; and Wells

Fargo Bank, N.A.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

MarkitSERV \81\ provided the interest rate swap data set. The

interest rate swap data set covered transactions confirmed on the

MarkitWire platform between June 1, 2010 and August 31, 2010 where at

least one party was a G-14 Bank.\82\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\81\ MarkitSERV is a post-trade processing company wholly owned

by Markit. From its formation in 2009 until April 2013, MarkitSERV

was jointly owned by Markit and The Depository Trust & Clearing

Corporation (``DTCC'').

\82\ The interest rate swap data was limited to transactions and

events submitted to the MarkitWire platform. MarkitWire is a trade

confirmation service offered by MarkitSERV.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Warehouse Trust Company LLC (``The Warehouse Trust'') provided

the CDS data set.\83\ The CDS data set covered CDS transactions for a

three-month period beginning on May 1, 2010 and ending on July 31,

2010.\84\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\83\ The Warehouse Trust, a subsidiary of DTCC DerivSERV LLC, is

regulated as a member of the U.S. Federal Reserve System and as a

limited purpose trust company by the New York State Banking

Department. The Warehouse Trust provides the market with a trade

database and centralized electronic infrastructure for post-trade

processing of OTC credit derivatives contracts over their entire

lifecycle. See DTCC, The Warehouse Trust Company, About the

Warehouse Trust Company, http://www.dtcc.com/about/subs/derivserv/warehousetrustco.php.

\84\ The Warehouse Trust data contained ``allocation-level

data,'' which refers to transactional data that does not distinguish

between isolated transactions and transactions that, although

documented separately, comprise part of a larger transaction.

The Commission notes the work of other regulators in aggregating

observations believed to be part of a single transaction. See

Kathryn Chen, et al., Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report,

An Analysis of CDS Transactions: Implications for Public Reporting,

(Sept. 2011), at 25, http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr517.html. The Commission notes that this allocation-level

information could produce a downward bias in the notional amounts of

the swap transactions in the data sets provided by the ODSG. In

turn, this downward bias would produce smaller appropriate minimum

block trade sizes relative to a data set that, if available with

appropriate execution time stamps, would reflect the aggregate

notional amount of swaps completed in a single transaction.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission filtered both data sets in order to analyze only

transaction-level data corresponding to ``publicly reportable swap

transactions,'' as defined in Sec. 43.2 of the Real-Time

[[Page 32874]]

Reporting Final Rule.\85\ As such, the Commission excluded from its

analysis duplicate and non-price forming transactions.\86\ The

Commission also converted the notional amount of each swap transaction

into a common currency denominator, the U.S. dollar.\87\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\85\ ``Publicly reportable swap transaction'' means, unless

otherwise provided in part 43: (1) Any executed swap that is an

arm's-length transaction between two parties that results in a

corresponding change in the market risk position between the two

parties; or (2) any termination, assignment, novation, exchange,

transfer, amendment, conveyance, or extinguishing of rights or

obligations of a swap that changes the pricing of the swap. Examples

of an executed swap that do not fall within the definition of

publicly reportable swap transaction may include: (1) Certain

internal swaps between 100-percent-owned subsidiaries of the same

parent entity; and (2) portfolio compression exercises. These

examples represent swaps that are not transacted at arm's length,

but that do result in a corresponding change in the market risk

position between two parties. See 77 FR 1244.

\86\ The excluded records represented activities such as option

exercises or assignments for physical, risk optimization or

compression transactions, and amendments or cancellations that were

assumed to be mis-confirmed. A transaction was assumed to be mis-

confirmed when it was canceled without a fee, which the Commission

has inferred was the result of a confirmation correction. The

Commission also excluded interest rate transactions that were

indicated as assignments, terminations, and structurally excluded

records since the Commission was unable to determine if these

records were price-forming. The Commission also excluded CDS

transactions that were notated as single name transactions. The data

sets also included transaction records created for workflow purposes

(and therefore redundant), duplicates and transaction records

resulting from name changes or mergers.

\87\ The Commission calculated the average daily exchange rates

between relevant currencies and the U.S. dollar for the three-month

period covered by the data. This average daily exchange rate was

then applied to the notional amounts for non-U.S. dollar denominated

swap transactions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Interest Rate Swap Categories

i. Interest Rate Swap Data Summary

The filtered transaction records in the interest rate swap data set

contained 166,847 transactions with a combined notional value of

approximately $45.4 trillion dollars.\88\ These transactions included

trades with a wide range of notional amounts, 28 different currencies,

eight product types, 57 different floating rate indexes and tenors

ranging from under one week to 55 years. Summary statistics of the

filtered interest rate swap data set are presented in Table 1.\89\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\88\ The Commission only reviewed relevant transaction records

in the interest rate swap data set. As noted above, the Commission

excluded duplicate and non-price forming transactions from its

review. See supra note 86 for a list of excluded transaction

records.

\89\ See the International Organization for Standardization

(ISO) standard ISO 4217 for information on the currency codes used

by the Commission. For information on floating rate indexes, see

also ISDA, 2006 Definitions (2006), and supplements.

[[Page 32875]]

Table 1--Summary Statistics for the Interest Rate Swap Data Set by Product Type, Currency, Floating Index and

Tenor

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Percentage of Notional

Number of total amount Percentage of

transactions transactions (billions of total notional

\90\ USD) amount (%)

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Product Type:

Single Currency Interest Rate Swap.......... 128,658 77 16,276 36

Over Night Index Swap (OIS)................. 12,816 8 16,878 37

Forward Rate Agreement (FRA)................ 5,936 4 7,071 16

Swaption.................................... 11,042 7 2,256 5

Other....................................... 8,395 5 2,909 6

Currency:

European Union Euro Area euro (EUR)......... 46,412 28 18,648 41

United States dollar (USD).................. 50,917 31 11,377 25

United Kingdom pound sterling (GBP)......... 16,715 10 7,560 17

Japan yen (JPY)............................. 19,502 12 4,253 9

Other....................................... 33,301 20 3,553 8

Floating Index:

USD-LIBOR-BBA............................... 48,651 29 9,411 21

EUR-EURIBOR-Reuters......................... 39,446 24 9,495 21

EUR-EONIA-OIS-COMPOUND...................... 6,517 4 9,122 20

JPY-LIBOR-BBA............................... 19,194 12 4,010 9

GBP-LIBOR-BBA............................... 12,835 8 2,419 5

GBP-WMBA-SONIA-COMPOUND..................... 2,014 1 5,123 11

Other....................................... 38,190 23 5,809 13

Tenor: \91\

1 Month..................................... 3,171 2 11,859 26

3 Month..................................... 10,229 6 11,660 26

6 Month..................................... 2,822 2 1,701 4

1 Year...................................... 9,522 6 3,484 8

2 Year...................................... 16,450 10 3,347 7

3 Year...................................... 9,628 6 1,488 3

5 Year...................................... 26,139 16 2,712 6

7 Year...................................... 6,599 4 661 1

10 Year..................................... 34,000 20 2,746 6

30 Year..................................... 9,616 6 448 1

Other....................................... 38,671 23 5,284 12

---------------------------------------------------------------

Sample Totals........................... 166,847 100 45,390 100

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\90\ The percentages were rounded to the nearest whole number.

Due to the rounding, the total percentages for the listed categories

do not add up to exactly 100%.

\91\ In producing Table 1, the Commission counted tenors for

swaps with an end date within four calendar days of a complete month

relative to the swap's start date as ending on the nearest complete

month.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table 2 below sets out the notional amounts of the interest rate

swap data set organized by product type, currency, floating index and

tenor. The table also includes the notional amounts in each percentile

of a distribution of the data set.

Table 2--Notional Amounts of Interest Rate Swap Data Set Organized by Product Type, Currency, Floating Index and Tenor

[In millions of USD]

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Mean Percentiles

notional ----------------------------------------------------------------------------

amount 5th 10th 25th 50th 75th 90th 95th

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Product Type:

Single Currency Interest Rate Swap.......................... 127 4 9 23 52 117 252 438

OIS......................................................... 1,293 6 13 63 341 1,261 3,784 5,282

FRA......................................................... 1,168 90 133 266 631 1,039 2,000 3,018

Swaption.................................................... 204 3 20 50 100 226 500 642

Other....................................................... 346 * 1 23 89 250 631 1,132

Currency:

EUR......................................................... 400 6 15 38 91 249 631 1,617

USD......................................................... 221 5 12 31 89 200 500 1,000

GBP......................................................... 435 1 1 15 57 167 755 1,698

JPY......................................................... 221 11 13 28 57 124 339 790

Other....................................................... 108 4 6 13 30 78 175 308

Floating Index:

USD-LIBOR-BBA............................................... 192 5 12 30 76 180 500 803

[[Page 32876]]

EUR-EURIBOR-Reuters......................................... 241 8 17 38 79 189 416 757

EUR-EONIA-OIS-COMPOUND...................................... 1,385 4 10 61 315 1,261 3,784 6,306

JPY-LIBOR-BBA............................................... 211 11 12 28 57 113 339 658

GBP-LIBOR-BBA............................................... 181 1 4 23 54 151 377 755

GBP-WMBA-SONIA-COMPOUND..................................... 2,450 75 113 283 1,509 3,018 6,037 9,055

Other....................................................... 152 2 4 12 31 88 264 500

Tenor: \92\

1 Month..................................................... 3,523 37 252 1,251 2,522 3,784 7,546 12,074

3 Month..................................................... 1,081 11 38 208 604 1,250 2,000 3,018

6 Month..................................................... 581 19 49 150 377 747 1,261 1,892

1 Year...................................................... 348 20 31 70 151 341 755 1,261

2 Year...................................................... 205 10 16 39 111 243 453 631

3 Year...................................................... 154 10 16 44 95 169 315 500

5 Year...................................................... 107 5 9 25 63 113 226 316

7 Year...................................................... 105 7 13 29 57 113 221 315

10 Year..................................................... 83 5 10 23 50 95 175 252

30 Year..................................................... 47 4 7 18 26 50 95 132

Other....................................................... 249 2 4 15 50 126 340 883

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\92\ In producing Table 2, the Commission counted tenors for

swaps with an end date within four calendar days of a complete month

relative to the swap's start date as ending on the nearest complete

month.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also analyzed the interest rate swap data set to

classify the counterparties into broad groups.\93\ The Commission's

analysis of the interest rate swap data set revealed that approximately

50 percent of the transactions were between buyers and sellers who were

both identified as G-14 banks and that these transactions represented a

combined notional amount of approximately $22.85 trillion, or 50

percent of the relevant IRS data set's total combined notional amount.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\93\ MarkitSERV anonymized the identities of the counterparties

and indicated whether a G-14 bank was a party to the swap

transaction. Summary statistics relating to these anonymous numbers

included the following: (1) The total count of unique counterparties

was approximately 300; (2) the average notional size of transactions

involving two G-14 banks was approximately $280 million; (3) the

average notional size of transactions involving both a G-14 bank and

a non G-14 bank (which traded at least 100 swap transactions) was

approximately $260 million.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Summary of Proposed Rule

Based upon the data described above, the Commission proposed Sec.

43.6(b)(1) establishing swap categories in the interest rate asset

class based on tenor and underlying currency.

The Commission proposed interest rate swap tenor groupings based on

two observations regarding the data in the interest rate swap data set.

First, the Commission observed that points of concentrated transaction

activity along the yield curve correspond with specific tenors (e.g.,

three months, six months, one year, two years, etc.). Second, the

Commission observed a tendency for the transacted notional amounts to

decrease as tenor increased (e.g., longer-dated tenors in the data set

generally had lower average notional sizes). Based on these

observations, table 3 below details the eight proposed tenor groups for

the interest rate asset class.

Table 3--Proposed Tenor Groups for Interest Rates Asset Class \94\

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Tenor group Tenor greater than And tenor less than or equal to

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

1.................................... ............................. Three months (107 days).

2.................................... Three months (107 days)...... Six months (198 days).

3.................................... Six months (198 days)........ One year (381 days).

4.................................... One year (381 days).......... Two years (746 days).

5.................................... Two years (746 days)......... Five years (1,842 days).

6.................................... Five years (1,842 days)...... Ten years (3,668 days).

7.................................... Ten years (3,668 days)....... 30 years (10,973 days).

8.................................... 30 years (10,973 days) ..........................................

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Similarly, through its analysis of the interest rate swap data set,

the Commission found that the currency referenced in a swap explains a

significant amount of variation in notional size and, hence, can be

used to categorize interest rate swaps \95\ The

[[Page 32877]]

Commission proposed currency groupings after considering: (1) The swap

transaction total notional amounts and transaction volumes of currency

groups based on the number of transactions; and (2) the average

transaction notional amounts and lack of evidence of large transacted

notional amounts or substantial volume of currency groups. After

considering these factors, the Commission proposed three currency

categories for the interest rate asset class: (1) Super-major

currencies, which are currencies with large volume and total notional

amounts; \96\ (2) major currencies, which generally exhibit moderate

volume and total notional amounts; \97\ and (3) non-major currencies,

which generally exhibit moderate to very low volume and total notional

amounts.\98\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\94\ The Commission chose to extend the tenor groups about one-

half month beyond the commonly observed tenors to group similar

tenors together and capture variations in day counts. The Commission

added an additional 15 days beyond a multiple of one year to the

number of days in each group to avoid ending each group on specific

years.

\95\ The Commission considered alternative approaches of using

the individual floating rate indexes or currencies to determine swap

categories in the interest rate asset class. These alternative

approaches would have the benefit of being more correlated to an

underlying curve than the adopted currency and tenor groupings. The

data contained 57 floating rate indexes and 28 currencies, which

would result in 456 and 224 categories respectively, after sorting

by the eight identified tenor groups. The Commission anticipates,

however, that grouping swaps using individual rates or currencies

would not substantially increase the explanation of variations in

notional amounts, while it could result in cells with relatively few

observations in some currency-tenor categories. Hence, the

Commission does not believe there would be a significant benefit to

offset the additional compliance burden that a more granular

approach would impose on market participants.

\96\ Super-major currencies represent over 92 percent of the

total notional amounts and 80 percent of the total transactions in

the data set. It is noteworthy that these currencies have well-

developed, i.e., liquid futures markets for general interest rates

and FX rates.

\97\ Major currencies represent about 6 percent of the total

notional amount and about 10 percent of the total transactions in

the data set. Some of these currencies host liquid futures markets

for interest rates, and all exhibit liquid FX markets.

\98\ Non-major currencies represent less than two percent of the

total notional amount and about 10 percent of the transactions in

the data set. These currencies typically do not have corresponding

interest rate and FX futures markets.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table 4 below summarizes the Commission's three proposed currency

swap categories.

Table 4--Proposed Currency Categories for Interest Rates Asset Class

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Currency category Component currencies

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Super-Major Currencies............ United States dollar (USD), European

Union Euro Area euro (EUR), United

Kingdom pound sterling (GBP), and

Japan yen (JPY).

Major Currencies \99\............. Australia dollar (AUD), Switzerland

franc (CHF), Canada dollar (CAD),

Republic of South Africa rand

(ZAR), Republic of Korea won (KRW),

Kingdom of Sweden krona (SEK), New

Zealand dollar (NZD), Kingdom of

Norway krone (NOK) and Denmark

krone (DKK).

Non-Major Currencies.............. All other currencies.

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table 5 below presents details on the sample characteristics of the

interest rate swap data set organized by currency and tenor swap

categories.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\99\ The Commission selected these currencies for inclusion in

the definition of major currencies based on the relative liquidity

of these currencies in the interest rate and FX futures markets. The

Commission is of the view that this list of currencies is

consistent, in part, with the Commission's existing regulations in

Sec. 15.03(a), which defines ``major foreign currency'' as ``the

currency, and the cross-rates between the currencies, of Japan, the

United Kingdom, Canada, Australia, Switzerland, Sweden and the

European Monetary Union.'' 17 CFR 15.03(a).

Table 5--Sample Characteristics of Proposed Interest Rate Swap Categories \100\

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Percent of Notional Percent of

Currency category Tenor group Number of transactions (billions of total notional

transactions (%) USD) (%)

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Super-major..................... 1 11,394 7 22,347 50

Super-major..................... 2 2,563 2 1,813 4

Super-major..................... 3 6,277 4 3,302 7

Super-major..................... 4 12,395 7 3,420 8

Super-major..................... 5 32,148 19 4,818 11

Super-major..................... 6 42,675 26 4,220 9

Super-major..................... 7 24,237 15 1,433 3

Super-major..................... 8 1,857 1 56 0

Major........................... 1 2,305 1 1,818 4

Major........................... 2 445 0 124 0

Major........................... 3 2,113 1 302 1

Major........................... 4 2,639 2 226 1

Major........................... 5 5,380 3 293 1

Major........................... 6 3,707 2 129 0

Major........................... 7 704 0 19 0

Major........................... 8 <200 .............. .............. ..............

Non-Major....................... 1 403 0 64 0

Non-Major....................... 2 247 0 26 0

Non-Major....................... 3 2,073 1 165 0

Non-Major....................... 4 3,354 2 256 1

Non-Major....................... 5 5,873 4 116 0

Non-Major....................... 6 3,935 2 41 0

Non-Major....................... 7 <200 .............. .............. ..............

Non-Major....................... 8 <200 .............. .............. ..............

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\100\ Tables 5 and 6 do not include sample characteristics for

swap categories with less than 200 transactions in order to preserve

the anonymity of the parties to these transactions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table 6 below sets out the notional amounts of the interest rate

swap data set organized by currency and tenor categories. The table

includes the mean notional amount of each currency and tenor category,

as well as the notional amounts in each percentile of a distribution of

the data set.

[[Page 32878]]

Table 6--Notional Amounts of Interest Rate Swap Data Set Organized by the Proposed Interest Rate Swap Categories

[In millions of USD]

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Transactions Percentiles

Currency group Tenor Mean --------------------------------------------------------------

group 5th 10th 25th 50th 75th 90th 95th

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Super-major.................... 1 1,961 10 36 500 1,000 2,260 4,000 6,306

Super-major.................... 2 708 13 41 200 500 883 1,500 2,260

Super-major.................... 3 526 47 75 150 272 565 1,179 1,809

Super-major.................... 4 276 19 43 100 176 304 565 848

Super-major.................... 5 150 9 21 50 100 158 301 482

Super-major.................... 6 99 6 12 30 54 100 204 305

Super-major.................... 7 59 1 5 14 31 63 126 200

Super-major.................... 8 30 0 0 1 13 37 65 118

Major.......................... 1 789 80 133 175 312 573 921 1,313

Major.......................... 2 279 50 70 120 210 350 480 921

Major.......................... 3 143 13 26 52 97 175 264 438

Major.......................... 4 86 9 16 33 66 104 184 240

Major.......................... 5 54 4 8 19 44 72 109 145

Major.......................... 6 35 4 7 13 23 46 72 96

Major.......................... 7 27 5 7 11 20 31 49 75

Major.......................... 8 <200 ....... ....... ....... ....... ....... ....... .......

Non-major...................... 1 160 19 37 64 129 225 315 450

Non-major...................... 2 106 16 23 39 72 145 233 311

Non-major...................... 3 79 8 22 31 56 102 157 224

Non-major...................... 4 76 6 9 16 27 50 78 108

Non-major...................... 5 20 2 4 8 14 23 39 54

Non-major...................... 6 10 2 2 4 8 13 21 29

Non-major...................... 7 <200 ....... ....... ....... ....... ....... ....... .......

Non-major...................... 8 <200 ....... ....... ....... ....... ....... ....... .......

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission received twelve comments regarding the use of tenor

to establish swap categories in the interest rate swap asset class.

Five commenters expressed support for the Further Block Proposal's

suggested tenor buckets.\101\ Five other commenters recommended nine

tenor buckets straddling the most liquid tenor points as follows: 0-3

months, 3-6 months, 6-18 months, 18 months-3 years, 3-7 years, 7-12

years, 12-20 years, 20-30 years, and more than 30 years.\102\ These

commenters suggested that these nine tenor groupings would provide

greater granularity and avoid grouping together swaps with different

levels of liquidity. Similarly, ICI suggested that narrower tenor

groupings would provide greater granularity.\103\ Kinetix also

expressed concern with the proposed tenor buckets, stating that they

grouped together products with sharply different trading volumes.\104\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\101\ CL-AFR at 5; CL-Better Markets at 5; CL-MFA at 4; CL-

Pierpont at 3; CL-SDMA at 8 (``The CFTC categories are . . .

appropriate and accurate in terms of currency, index, and tenor.'')

\102\ CL-AII at 8; CL-Barclays at 7; CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 10; CL-

SIFMA at 7; CL-Vanguard at 5.

\103\ See CL-ICI at 5.

\104\ Kinetix stated that ``[t]he major flaw comes from

including in a bucket products with sharply different trading

volumes.'' Kinetix recommended bucketing products by average trade

volume, product type, and tenor, but did not suggest specific tenor

buckets. CL-Kinetix at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition to the comments received regarding the Further Block

Proposal, the Commission also considered the research in the Federal

Reserve Bank of New York's March 2012 staff report entitled ``An

Analysis of OTC Interest Rate Derivatives Transactions: Implications

for Public Reporting'' (the ``Federal Reserve Staff Analysis''). In

that report, Federal Reserve staff tested for a relationship between

tenor and trade size. The Federal Reserve staff identified nine tenor

buckets, as opposed to the eight identified by the Commission. The

tenor buckets identified by the Federal Reserve staff were the same as

those proposed by the Commission in the Further Block Proposal, with a

further division of the Commission's 0-3 month bucket into a 0-1 month

bucket and a 1-3 month bucket.\105\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\105\ The Federal Reserve staff specifically found that ``when

[they] reduced the number of buckets at the short end of the trading

curve (by merging the 0-1 month and 1-3 month buckets into a 0-3

month bucket), the explanatory power of [their] regression declined

24%.'' Federal Reserve Staff Analysis at 16.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received and the Federal

Reserve Staff Analysis, the Commission is adopting Sec. 43.6(b)(1)

with one modification--the addition of another tenor grouping at the

shorter end of the interest rate yield curve. The Commission notes, as

an initial matter, that commenters generally supported the use of tenor

buckets to establish swap categories in the interest rate asset class.

Commenters, however, disagreed with the proposed tenor buckets.

In the Further Block Proposal, tenor buckets were proposed based on

observations of the distributions of notional sizes and volume with the

objectives of grouping swaps with similar characteristics while

maintaining a manageable number of swap categories. The tenor buckets

proposed by the Commission were associated with concentrations of

liquidity at commonly recognized points along the interest rate yield

curve. In general, the Commission observed that transactions in the

data set (and presumed market liquidity) tended to cluster at certain

tenors.

In establishing the categories, the Commission proposed groupings

that placed actively traded tenors at the upper boundary of the

category groupings because the calculation of the minimum block

threshold in a category will be most influenced by the notional amounts

of the most heavily traded swaps in a category, i.e., those at the

active tenor points. Hence, the minimum block thresholds for shorter

dated swaps in a category will tend to be set based on the typical

notional value of longer dated swaps. Since the longer dated swaps tend

to trade in smaller notional amounts, establishing

[[Page 32879]]

the categories in this manner will tend to result in a more

conservative (i.e., smaller) minimum block threshold for shorter

tenored swaps within the category. In addition, because the shorter-

dated swaps within an established swap category may experience less

liquidity, due to smaller trading volumes, these swaps may also benefit

from the setting of a lower minimum block threshold.

The narrower tenor buckets recommended by commenters, in contrast,

tend to straddle the liquid tenor points. If the Commission were to

establish tenor buckets straddling the liquid tenor points (rather than

having a liquid tenor point be the upper boundary of a tenor bucket),

then the minimum block threshold for swaps within a category would be

more heavily influenced by swaps centrally located in the category.

Thus, longer dated swaps in a category, which tend to trade in smaller

notional sizes, would be subject to higher minimum block thresholds,

meaning fewer would be eligible for the block trade exemption.

To illustrate the impact of placing the liquid tenor point at the

top of the category, consider the impact on a seven-year interest rate

swap that is proposed to be grouped in a tenor bucket with swaps having

a tenor greater than 5 years and less than or equal to 10 years. The

most liquid tenor point (i.e., the tenor point with the greatest number

of observations) within this bucket would be the 10-year interest rate

swap; thus, the 10-year interest rate swap would be the primary driver

in determining the minimum block threshold for swaps in the 5 to 10-

year tenor bucket. Table 7 is a subset of the information from Table 1

that illustrates this point. Specifically, there are 6,599 swaps with a

tenor of seven years, yielding an average notional amount of $100

million (USD) and 34,000 swaps with a tenor of ten years yielding an

average notional size of $81 million (USD). By combining these into the

same category, the Commission is adopting a conservative approach in

setting block sizes for the less liquid tenors.

Under the commenters' approach, however, the seven-year interest

rate swap is grouped in the same tenor bucket with the 5-year tenor

interest rate swaps. In this scenario, the liquid tenor point within

the bucket is the 5-year interest rate swap; thus, the 5-year interest

rate swap, with more than 26,000 transactions yielding an average

notional amount of $104 million (USD), is the primary driver in

determining the minimum block threshold for the tenor bucket and

results in a larger block size for the 7-year tenor interest rate swaps

than under the currently proposed swap category.

The Commission is of the view that the tenor with the most

transactions in the swap category, and thus having the most weight in

the block calculations, should be at the high end of the tenor grouping

for the swap category. Given the tendency for average notional size to

decrease as tenor increases as shown in Table 7 below, the Commission

views this as a more conservative approach to setting minimum block

thresholds, which results in lower block sizes for swap transactions at

tenors that may experience less liquidity.

Table 7--Summary Statistics for the Interest Rate Swap Data Set by Tenor \106\

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Average notional

Tenor \107\ Number of Notional amount amount (billions

transactions (billions of USD) of USD)

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

1 Month............................................. 3,171 11,859 3.740

3 Month............................................. 10,229 11,660 1.140

6 Month............................................. 2,822 1,701 0.603

1 Year.............................................. 9,522 3,484 0.366

2 Year.............................................. 16,450 3,347 0.203

3 Year.............................................. 9,628 1,488 0.155

5 Year.............................................. 26,139 2,712 0.104

7 Year.............................................. 6,599 661 0.100

10 Year............................................. 34,000 2,746 0.081

30 Year............................................. 9,616 448 0.047

Other............................................... 38,671 5,284 0.137

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\106\ In producing Table 7, the Commission counted tenors for

swaps with an end date within four calendar days of a complete month

relative to the swap's start date as ending on the nearest complete

month.

\107\ Tenor groups include swaps having tenors within 4 calendar

days of a complete month, plus or minus, of the stated tenor. All

other swaps are included in the ``Other'' category.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to comments generally calling for narrower tenor

buckets, the Commission is adopting an additional tenor bucket in order

to provide greater granularity as requested by commenters. The

Commission is splitting the first tenor group in the Further Block

Proposal (0-3 months) into two tenor groups (0-46 days, and greater

than 46 days to less than or equal to 3 months). While the Commission

did not receive any comments specifically discussing the less than 46

day tenor, the Commission received numerous comments recommending

greater granularity. Based upon the comments received requesting nine

tenor buckets and the Federal Reserve Staff Analysis identifying nine

tenor buckets, the Commission has determined to add a less than 46 day

tenor group. This would provide greater granularity and establish

notional swap groupings that account more precisely for the effects of

increased transparency on liquidity for swaps of a shorter tenor.

Accordingly, the Commission is adopting the following tenor

buckets:

[[Page 32880]]

Table 8--Tenor Groups for Interest Rates Asset Class \108\

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Tenor group Tenor greater than And tenor less than or equal to

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

1.................................... ............................. 46 days.

2.................................... 46 days...................... Three months (107 days).

3.................................... Three months (107 days)...... Six months (198 days).

4.................................... Six months (198 days)........ One year (381 days).

5.................................... One year (381 days).......... Two years (746 days).

6.................................... Two years (746 days)......... Five years (1,842 days).

7.................................... Five years (1,842 days)...... Ten years (3,668 days).

8.................................... Ten years (3,668 days)....... 30 years (10,973 days).

9.................................... 30 years (10,973 days)....... ..........................................

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\108\ As in the Further Block Proposal, the Commission chose to

extend the tenor groups about one-half month beyond the commonly

observed tenors to group similar tenors together and capture

variations in day counts. The Commission added an additional 15 days

beyond a multiple of one year to the number of days in each group to

avoid ending each group on specific months or years.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission received eleven comments regarding whether interest

rate swaps should be categorized into the super-major, major, and non-

major currency groupings as proposed. Five commenters supported the

currency groupings proposed in the Further Block Proposal.\109\ Four

commenters urged the Commission to establish a separate swap category

for each individual currency in determining block thresholds.\110\ Two

more commenters specifically recommended that each of the four super-

major currencies should be categorized separately, rather than as a

group, in determining block thresholds.\111\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\109\ CL-AFR at 5; CL-Better Markets at 5; CL-MFA at 4; CL-

Pierpont at 3; CL-SDMA at 8 (``The CFTC categories are . . .

appropriate and accurate in terms of currency, index, and tenor.'')

\110\ CL-AII at 8; CL-ICI at 5; CL-SIFMA at 8-9; CL-Vanguard at

6.

\111\ CL-Barclays at 7; CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 7-8. While ISDA/SIFMA

supported separate categories for super-major currencies, their

comment also suggests separate categorization for each individual

currency. Similarly, SIFMA's comment, while requesting separate

categorization generally, states that dividing the four proposed

super-major currencies is most important. CL-SIFMA at 8-9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.6(b)(1)(i) as proposed in regard to currency

categories. The currencies were grouped into the three categories in

the Further Block Proposal based upon the swap transaction total

notional amounts and transaction volumes of currency groups based on

the number of transactions, and the average transaction notional

amounts of currency groups. The commenters who requested that all

currencies be categorized by individual currency mainly focused on

differences in liquidity among the four super-major currencies,

particularly when comparing interest rate swaps in USD and EUR to those

in JPY and GBP. Similarly, the commenters who specifically requested

that the Commission establish separate swap categories for each of the

super-major currencies focused on perceived differences in liquidity.

While USD and EUR interest rate swaps feature the highest liquidity,

the Commission is of the view that, based upon all of the criteria

mentioned above, the super-major currencies are most similar to each

other (and different from major \112\ and non-major currencies) to

warrant treatment as a group, rather than separately.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\112\ The Commission notes that the difference between the total

notional and transactional volume of swaps referencing Japanese

yen--the lowest among those swaps in the super-major currency

category--and of swaps referencing the Australian Dollar--the

highest among those swaps in the major currency category--is

significantly larger than such differences between swaps within each

adopted currency category. This observation supports adopting the

Commission's approach in assigning certain swaps in the super-major

currency category against the major currency category.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission considered alternative approaches of using the

individual currencies to determine swap categories in the interest rate

asset class. While these alternative approaches would have provided

greater correlation to an underlying curve than the adopted groupings,

the Commission believes that this would not substantially increase the

explanation of variations in notional amounts, but rather would result

in categories with too few observations. Hence, the Commission does not

believe that there would be a significant benefit to offset the

additional compliance burden that a more granular approach would impose

on market participants. The Commission notes that adoption of the

proposed currency categories establishes 27 separate swap categories

for interest rate swaps. Separate categorization of all currencies

would result in nearly 200 separate swap categories. Separate

categorization of the super-major currencies alone would result in 54

swap categories. The Commission believes that the 27 separate swap

categories contained in the rule achieves the objectives of grouping

swaps with similar characteristics while maintaining a manageable

number of swap categories.

The Commission also received a number of comments recommending that

interest rate swaps should be categorized based on criteria other than

tenor and currency. Four commenters suggested a range of additional

interest rate swap categories for the purposes of establishing block

thresholds.\113\ Two other commenters suggested grouping swaps by

product type in addition to tenor and currency groupings.\114\ Another

commenter, Kinetix, recommended grouping products by average trade

volume, as well as by product type and tenor.\115\ Of the four

commenters who expressed support for the proposed tenor and currency

groupings,\116\ two of them argued that further granularity would cause

some swaps to be subject to lower block thresholds than are

appropriate.\117\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\113\ Barclays suggested unique block levels for each of the

following swap categories: each super major currency, swaps against

standard floating rate indices, basis swaps, inflation swaps,

swaptions, caps and floors, cross-currency swaps, and structured

swaps. CL-Barclays at 7-8. ISDA/SIFMA suggested the following

additional swap categories: fixed versus non-benchmark floating rate

indexes and basis swaps, inflation swaps (a specified inflation rate

index), options (swaption and cap/floor markets); cross-currency

swaps (each leg denominated by different currency), and exotics. CL-

ISDA/SIFMA at 9. SIFMA and Vanguard suggested swap categorization

based on optionality or other characteristics such as distinctions

between ``plain vanilla,'' ``interest rate options,'' and ``other,''

as well as separate categories for major floating rate indices. CL-

SIFMA at 8-9; CL-Vanguard at 5-6.

\114\ CL-ICI at 5; CL-MFA at 5.

\115\ CL-Kinetix at 2.

\116\ CL-AFR at 5; CL-Better Markets at 5; CL-Pierpont at 3; CL-

SDMA at 8 (``The CFTC categories are . . . appropriate and accurate

in terms of currency, index, and tenor.'')

\117\ CL-AFR at 5; CL-Better Markets at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.6(b)(1)(i) as proposed and Sec. 43. 6(b)(1)(ii) with

the modifications discussed above. Although some level of

[[Page 32881]]

categorization of swaps is useful to capture different levels of

trading activity and hedging potential, where a number of different

swaps could be used to hedge the same risk, the over-identification of

swap categories will eventually lead to a dilution of observations

within categories. Categories having small numbers of observations

could be subject to highly volatile minimum block sizes over time.

Over-identification also would be expected to lead to underestimations

of the ability to offset risks using related swap instruments. The

Commission believes that it has struck a balance between over- and

under-categorizing swaps that will result in more stable minimum block

sizes and allow for adequate risk offsets using instruments within a

category. The modification described above in regard to tenor will

provide some further granularity at the short end of the yield curve,

as suggested by commenters above, while still achieving the objectives

of grouping swaps with similar characteristics and reducing unnecessary

complexity for market participants in determining whether their swaps

are classified within a particular swap category.

c. Credit Swap Categories

i. Credit Swap Data Summary

The CDS data set contained 98,931 CDS index records that would fall

within the definition of publicly reportable swap transactions,\118\

with a combined notional value of approximately $4.6 trillion

dollars.\119\ The CDS data set contained transactions based on 26 broad

credit indexes.\120\ Of those indexes, both the iTraxx Europe Series

and the Dow Jones North America investment grade CDS indexes

(``CDX.NA.IG'') served as the basis for over 20 percent of the total

number of transactions and over 33 percent of the total notional value

in the relevant CDS data set. Table 9 sets out summary statistics of

the CDS data set for CDS indexes with greater than five transactions

per day on average.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\118\ See note 85 supra.

\119\ The CDS index transactions in the data set made up

approximately 33 percent of the total filtered records and 75

percent of the CDS markets' notional amount for the three months of

data provided. The data set contained over 250 different reference

indexes; 400 reference index and tenor combinations; and 450

reference index, tenor, and tranche combinations. The data set also

contained three different currencies: USD (53%), EUR (46%), and JPY

(1%). The Commission notes that in all but a handful of records,

each reference index transaction was denoted in a single currency.

\120\ Those indexes were: (1) ABX.HE; (2) CDX.EM; (3) CDX.NA.HY;

(4) CDX.NA.IG; (5) CDX.NA.IG.HVOL; (6) CDX.NA.XO; (7) CMBX.NA; (8)

IOS.FN30; (9) iTRAXX Asia ex-Japan HY; (10) iTRAXX Asia ex-Japan IG;

(11) iTRAXX Australia; (12) iTRAXX Europe Series; (13) iTRAXX Europe

Subs; (14) iTRAXX Japan 80; (15) iTRAXX Japan HiVol; (16) iTRAXX

Japan Series; (17) iTRAXX LEVX Senior; (18) iTRAXX SOVX Asia; (19)

iTRAXX SOVX CEEMA; (20) iTRAXX Western Europe; (21) LCDX.NA; (22)

MCDX.NA; (23) PO.FN30; (24) PRIMEX.ARM; (25) PRIMEX.FRM; and (26)

TRX.NA.

Table 9--Summary Statistics by CDS Index Name

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Percentage of Notional

Number of total amount (in Percentage of

Names transactions transactions millions of total notional

(%) USD) amount (%)

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

ITRAXX EUROPE SERIES 13 V1...................... 18,287 18.48 1,138,362 24.83

CDX.NA.IG.14.................................... 12,611 12.75 1,083,974 23.64

ITRAXX EUROPE XO SERIES 13 V1................... 8,713 8.81 153,365 3.34

CDX.NA.HY.14.................................... 7,984 8.07 172,599 3.76

ITRAXX EUROPE SENIOR FINANCIALS SERIES 13 V1.... 4,774 4.83 187,978 4.10

CDX.NA.IG.9..................................... 4,134 4.18 388,650 8.48

ITRAXX EUROPE XO SERIES 13 V2................... 3,959 4.00 66,894 1.46

CDX.NA.IG.9 TRANCHE............................. 3,357 3.39 112,411 2.45

ITRAXX SOVX CEEMEA SERIES 3 V1.................. 3,252 3.29 32,291 0.70

CDX.EM.13....................................... 3,052 3.08 34,952 0.76

ITRAXX SOVX WESTERN EUROPE SERIES 3 V1.......... 2,377 2.40 74,068 1.62

ITRAXX AUSTRALIA SERIES NUMBER 13 V1............ 2,138 2.16 31,540 0.69

ITRAXX EUROPE SERIES 9 V1....................... 1,893 1.91 188,364 4.11

ITRAXX EUROPE SUB FINANCIALS SERIES 13 V1....... 1,779 1.80 50,241 1.10

ITRAXX EUROPE SERIES 9 V1 TRANCHE............... 1,577 1.59 50,269 1.10

ITRAXX JAPAN SERIES NUMBER 13 V1................ 1,406 1.42 19,100 0.42

ITRAXX ASIA EX-JAPAN IG SERIES NUMBER 13 V1..... 1,319 1.33 15,856 0.35

ITRAXX SOVX ASIA PACIFIC SERIES 3 V1............ 1,001 1.01 11,666 0.25

ITRAXX EUROPE HIVOL SERIES 13 V1................ 788 0.80 30,585 0.67

CMBX.NA.AAA.1................................... 463 0.47 13,384 0.29

ITRAXX EUROPE SERIES 12 V1...................... 452 0.46 71,161 1.55

CMBX.NA.AJ.3.................................... 392 0.40 6,332 0.14

CMBX.NA.AAA.2................................... 381 0.39 8,433 0.18

LCDX.NA.14...................................... 380 0.38 7,063 0.15

MCDX.NA.14...................................... 350 0.35 2,798 0.06

CMBX.NA.AAA.4................................... 337 0.34 6,024 0.13

CMBX.NA.A.1..................................... 332 0.34 3,834 0.08

IOS.FN30.500.09................................. 317 0.32 7,836 0.17

---------------------------------------------------------------

Total....................................... 87,805 88.75 3,970,029 86.59

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Credit Swap Data Analysis

As noted above, the Commission proposed using tenor and

conventional spread criteria to define swap categories for CDS indexes.

The Commission proposed the following six broad tenor groups in the

credit asset class: (1) Zero to two years (0-746 days); (2) over two to

four years (747-1,476 days); (3) over four to six years (1,477-2,207

days) (which include the five-year tenor); (4) over six to eight-and-a-

half years (2,208-3,120 days); (5) over eight-and-a-half to

[[Page 32882]]

12.5 years (3,121-4,581 days) and (6) greater than 12.5 years (4,581

days).\121\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\121\ The Commission assessed the possibility of applying the

tenor categories proposed for swaps in the interest rate asset class

to the distribution of notional sizes in the CDS indexes and

anticipates the level of granularity proposed to categorize swaps in

the interest rate asset class by tenor would be inappropriate for

the CDS index market. The Commission anticipates that this level of

granularity would be inappropriate because the vast majority of CDS

index transactions in the data set had a tenor of five years (or

approximately 1,825 days). Based on the concentration of CDS index

transactions in five-year tenors, the Commission proposed six tenor

bands for CDS indexes.

The Commission chose to extend the tenor groups about one-half

month beyond the commonly observed tenors to group similar tenors

together and capture variations in day counts. The Commission added

an additional 15 days beyond a multiple of one year to the number of

days in each group to avoid ending each group on specific years.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With respect to the conventional spread criterion, the Commission

determined ranges of spread values based on a review of the

distribution of spreads in the entire CDS data set.\122\ In particular,

the Commission observed that the relevant CDS data set partitioned at

the 175 basis points (``bps'') and 350 bps levels.\123\ The Commission

found that significant differences existed in the CDS data set between

CDS indexes with spread values under 175 bps and those in the other two

CDS categories (spread values between 175 to 350 bps; spread values

above 350 bps). Accordingly, the Commission proposed three separate

conventional spread levels: (1) CDS indexes with spread values under

175 bps; (2) CDS indexes with spread values between 175 and 350 bps;

and (3) CDS indexes with spread values above 350 bps. Table 9 shows the

summary statistics of the proposed criteria to determine swap

categories for swaps in the credit asset class.\124\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\122\ See supra note 77 for a definition of ``conventional

spread.''

\123\ The Commission proposed partition levels by a qualitative

examination of multiple histogram distributions of the traded and

fixed spreads from the CDS data set. This qualitative examination

was confirmed through a partition test (using JMP software),

including both before and after controlling for the effects of tenor

on the distribution. The Commission observed that 175 bps explained

the greatest difference in means of the two data sets resulting from

a single partition of the data. The Commission also observed that

350 bps was an appropriate partition for CDS index transactions with

spreads over 175 bps.

\124\ The Commission found that these categories were good

predictors of notional size. This finding was based on an analysis

which used the tenor and spread categories in Table 9 as explanatory

variables in a least squares regression, where the logged value of

the notional amount of the swap was the dependent variable.

Table 9--CDS Index Sample Statistics by Proposed Swap Category Criteria

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sum of notional

Spread amounts (in Number of trades

billions of USD)

------------------------------------------------------------------------

<=175........................... 3,761 59,887

175-to-350...................... 233 11,045

350>............................ 577 27,998

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Sum of notional

Tenor (in calendar days) amounts Number of trades

------------------------------------------------------------------------

0-746........................... 146 1,421

747-1,476....................... 569 6,774

1,477-2,207..................... 3,490 79,357

2,208-3,120..................... 159 2,724

3,121-4,581..................... 18 497

4,582+.......................... 190 8,157

------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission sought comment on this proposed approach, a series

of alternative criteria to be used, and alternative categories. The

Commission received eight comments regarding the proposed swap

categories for CDS. Five of the comments focused on the proposed tenor

buckets in the Further Block Proposal. SIFMA and Vanguard suggested

that the 4-6 year tenor bucket be divided into four buckets: 4 to 4.5

years, 4.5 to 5 years, 5 to 5.5 years, and 5.5 to 6 years.\125\ AII and

ICI also recommended narrowing the tenor categories for CDS.\126\ MFA

generally supported the Commission's proposed grouping by tenor.\127\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\125\ CL-SIFMA at 7-8 (``We believe that such groupings would

better approximate sets of swaps with similar liquidity

characteristics''); CL-Vanguard at 5.

\126\ CL-AII at 8; CL-ICI at 5.

\127\ CL-MFA at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Two of the comments focused on the proposed conventional spread

criteria. ISDA/SIFMA expressed support for the proposed use of spread

criteria, but also suggested that the Commission should clarify that

the spread for a CDS transaction will be based on the traded spread,

rather than on the fixed coupon.\128\ Barclays, however, commented that

traded spreads should not be used for categorizing CDS because swaps

may move daily between threshold buckets as spreads can move

substantially over short periods, which would create an unacceptable

level of operational risk for market participants in trying to achieve

compliance.\129\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\128\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 6 (``swap categories should be based on

the current spread of a transaction in order to reflect . . .

changes in liquidity'').

\129\ CL-Barclays at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition to the comments regarding the tenor and conventional

spread criteria proposed, commenters also provided a number of

recommendations regarding other potential swap categories for CDS.

Three commenters suggested separate swap categories for individual CDX

index series.\130\ Better Markets, however, argued that using

individual CDX index series to create swap categories would be too

granular and recommended that CDS be divided into single-name and index

categories, with indexes further subdivided into five groups:

sovereign, corporate, municipal, mortgage-backed securities, and

other.\131\ Four commenters recommended that tranches of indices

receive their own unique swap category.\132\ Two commenters suggested

grouping CDS by different product type.\133\ MFA recommended separate

swap categories for indexes and options (as well as tranches).\134\

Finally, eight commenters suggested differentiating between on-the-run

and off-the-run CDS

[[Page 32883]]

indices.\135\ MFA specifically suggested separate minimum block sizes

for the current 5-year on-the-run CDS indices for CDX.NA.IG, CDX.NA.HY,

iTraxx Europe, and iTraxx Europe Crossover.\136\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\130\ CL-AII at 8; CL-Barclays at 8; CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 6.

\131\ CL-Better Markets at 6.

\132\ CL-AII at 8; CL-Barclays at 8; CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 6; MFA at

5.

\133\ CL-ICI at 5; CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 6.

\134\ CL-MFA at 5.

\135\ MFA specifically suggested separate minimum block sizes

for the current 5-year on-the-run CDS indices for CDX.NA.IG,

CDX.NA.HY, iTraxx Europe, and iTraxx Europe Crossover. CL-MFA at 5;

CL-AII at 8; CL-Barclays at 8; CL-ICAP at 7; CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 5-6;

CL-SIFMA at 8; CL-Vanguard at 5.

\136\ CL-MFA at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.6(b)(2) as proposed. In general, the Commission

believes that the proposed criteria--tenor and conventional spread--

provide an appropriate way to group swaps with economic similarities

and to reduce unnecessary complexity for market participants in

determining whether a particular swap is classified within a particular

swap category. In regard to ISDA/SIFMA's suggested clarification, the

Commission clarifies that the spread for a CDS transaction will be

based on the traded spread, rather than on the fixed coupon.

Specifically, the Commission believes that the proposed tenor and

conventional spread categories sufficiently capture the variation in

notional size that is necessary for setting appropriate minimum block

sizes and that refining these categories as suggested by commenters

will not improve the clustering of swaps in order to better set

appropriate minimum block sizes. For example, the Commission notes that

the tenor buckets contained in the adopted rule generally result in

separate categorization for on-the-run and off-the-run indexes for

swaps in the CDS data set. On-the-run indexes, for example, comprised

the vast majority of swaps in the 4-6 year tenor bucket, while off-the-

run indexes were the vast majority of swaps in the 0-2, 2-4, and 6-8.5

year tenor buckets.

The Commission determined these swap categories based on the way

activity in the CDS data set clustered towards the center of each tenor

band. While the majority of transactions in the CDS data set consisted

of on-the-run corporate credit default index swaps with a five-year

tenor, the Commission found that significant trading of corporate

credit default index swaps also occurred in other tenor ranges.\137\

The Commission believes that its approach is appropriate since CDS on

indexes other than corporate indexes (e.g., asset backed indexes,

municipal indexes, sovereign indexes) also trade at tenors other than

five years.\138\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\137\ For example, based on the observed CDS data set, corporate

CDS indexes traded in all but the longest of the tenor groups. The

vast majority of transactions outside of the 4-6 year tenor group

were off-the-run series.

\138\ For example, based on the observed CDS data set, the

majority of municipal credit default index swaps traded with tenors

of around 10 years.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission, however, decided not to use ``on-the-run'' or

``off-the-run'' designations for grouping CDS indexes into categories

for the following reasons: (i) The underlying components of swaps with

differing versions or series based on the same named index are broadly

similar, if not the same, and are indicative of economic

substitutability across versions or series; (ii) differences in the

average notional amount across differing versions or series were

explained by differences in tenor; and (iii) using versions or series

as the criterion for defining CDS swap categories may result in an

unnecessary level of complexity.\139\ Hence, the Commission believes

that while on-the-run and off-the-run indexes may differ in terms of

available liquidity, they nonetheless are economically related to each

other within the categories proposed by the Commission; therefore, on-

the-run indexes could be used to offset much of the risk associated

with off-the-run indices. Moreover, while the off-the-run swaps

generally had less trading activity, and presumably less liquidity,

than the on-the-run swaps, off-the-run index swaps had larger notional

sizes, on average, than on-the run swaps in the same category. Hence,

the more liquid, on-the-run swaps will drive the block size in a

category and will result in lower block sizes for the less liquid swaps

in the category.\140\ The Commission feels that this is a more

conservative approach to setting block sizes for less liquid swaps.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\139\ An on-the-run CDS index represents the most recently

issued version of an index. For example, every six months, Dow Jones

selects 125 investment grade entities domiciled in North America to

make up the Dow Jones North American investment grade index

(``CDX.NA.IG''). Each new CDX.NA.IG index is given a new series

number while market participants continue to trade the old or ``off-

the-run'' CDX.NA.IG series. The index provider determines the

composition of each index through a defined list of reference

entities. The index provider has discretion to change the

composition of the list of reference entities for each new version

or series of an index. In its analysis of the CDS data set, the

Commission generally observed either no change or a small change

(ranging from one percent to ten percent) of existing composition in

the reference entities underlying a new version or series of an

index. Because of these two dynamics (tenor and index composition),

the CDS data set contained transactions within a given index with

different versions and series that were, in some instances,

identical, and in others, not identical, across varying tenors.

\140\ This is similar to the example provided for the tenor

groupings in interest rate swaps in Section II.A.1.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to the commenters that specifically requested a

differentiation between on-the-run and off-the-run CDS indexes, the

Commission believes that while on-the-run and off-the-run indexes may

differ in terms of available liquidity, they nonetheless are

economically related to each other within the categories proposed by

the Commission such that on-the-run indexes could be used to offset

much of the risk associated with off-the-run indexes. The Commission

also notes that the tenor buckets contained in the adopted rule

generally result in separate categorization for on-the-run and off-the-

run indexes. For the CDS data set, the vast majority of swaps in the 4-

6 year tenor bucket were on-the-run indexes, while the vast majority of

swaps in the 0-2, 2-4, and 6-8.5 year tenor buckets were off-the-run.

In response to commenters that specifically recommended separate

swap categorization for tranches, the Commission believes that the

proposed swap categorization based upon conventional spread criteria

will result in separate categorizations related to tranches where

appropriate.\141\ For example, tranches having significantly different

levels of risk will potentially have spreads traded at levels that

differ enough from the underlying index so as to be placed in

categories that would receive a different block trade size. The

conventional spread reflects the risk of the underlying transaction and

the Commission believes that the risk associated with the transaction

will be the primary determinant of how difficult a transaction is to

hedge. Thus, the Commission believes that categorization of CDS by

conventional spread will capture differences related to tranches where

appropriate.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\141\ In the CDS market, a ``tranche'' means a particular

segment of the loss distribution of the underlying CDS index. For

example, tranches may be specified by the loss distribution for

equity, mezzanine (junior) debt, and senior debt on the referenced

entities. The Commission found that the tranche-level data was even

more granular than index-level data. Similarly, the Commission

anticipates that grouping the relevant CDS data set in tranche

criterion may not be practicable because it may produce too many

swap categories and as a result would impose unnecessary complexity

on market participants.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that the adopted Sec. 43.6(b)(2) establishes

18 separate swap categories for CDS swaps. While none of the commenters

provided suggestions as to precisely how to categorize CDS by tranche,

the Commission believes that creating additional swap categories for

tranches would result in swap categories totaling a multiple of the

proposed 18 swap categories, as each CDS index has multiple tranches.

Establishing swap categories based upon tenor and

[[Page 32884]]

conventional spread criterion as in adopted Sec. 43.6(b)(2) meets the

objectives of grouping swaps with economic similarity and reducing

confusion for market participants in determining whether their swaps

are classified within a particular swap category.

The Commission believes that this approach will mitigate the

administrative burden to both market participants and to the Commission

by limiting the number of swap categories for which appropriate minimum

block sizes need to be calculated. In regard to Barclay's concern that

swaps would move between categories, the Commission believes that

instances where a given swap will move daily between spread levels will

be limited given the small number of spread categories and the observed

distribution of trades. Additionally, the quantitative nature of the

block category calculation should limit the operational risk by

providing clarity and ease of notice to market participants as to what

the minimum block sizes are, even if they are subject to change.

If market participants reach the conclusion that the Commission has

determined specific swap categories in a way that will materially

reduce market liquidity, then those participants are encouraged to

submit data to support their conclusion. If, through its own

surveillance of swaps market activity, the Commission becomes aware

that a specific swap categorization for determination of appropriate

minimum block levels would reduce market liquidity, then the Commission

may exercise its legal authority to take action by rule or order to

mitigate the potential effects on market liquidity with respect to

swaps in that swap category.

2. Swap Category in the Equity Asset Class

The Commission proposed a single swap category for swaps in the

equity asset class. The Commission proposed this approach based on: (1)

The existence of a highly liquid underlying cash market for equities;

(2) the absence of time delays for reporting block trades in the

underlying equity cash market; (3) the small relative size of the

equity index swaps market relative to the futures, options, and cash

equity index markets; and (4) the Commission's goal to protect the

price discovery function of the underlying equity cash market and

futures market.

The Commission received six comments regarding swap categories in

the equity asset class. AFR supported the single swap category proposed

for the equity asset class.\142\ Five other commenters recommended that

the Commission treat equity swaps similarly to the other asset classes

and establish swap categories based upon a range of criteria.\143\ AII

recommended that equity swaps should be treated as blocks based on

liquidity, and urged the Commission to consider linking equity swap

categories to the liquidity of the underlying index.\144\ Barclays

recommended that swap categories should be established for equity swaps

taking into account transaction volume by index and equity asset class

type, and that broad-based indices should have separate block levels

based upon futures market levels.\145\ ICI recommended closer study of

data on equity swap transactions due to potential differences in

liquidity in the underlying equity cash market.\146\ ISDA/SIFMA

recommended categorizing equity swaps on the basis of underlying index

or basket, product type, notional size, and tenor.\147\ SIFMA stated

that the Commission should establish equity swap block categories based

upon liquidity of the underlying indices.\148\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\142\ CL-AFR at 6.

\143\ CL-AII at 9; CL-Barclays at 9; CL-ICI at; ISDA/SIFMA at

10-11; SIFMA at 5.

\144\ CL-AII at 9.

\145\ CL-Barclays at 9.

\146\ CL-ICI at 5.

\147\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 10-11.

\148\ CL-SIFMA at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.6(b)(3) as proposed. While a number of the commenters

point out differences in liquidity in the underlying equity indices to

support separate swap categories within the equity asset class and

establishment of block sizes in equities, these differences do not

undermine the premises underlying the Commission's proposal. Even

taking into account differences in liquidity, (1) there is still a

highly liquid underlying cash market for equities; and (2) the equity

index swaps market is small relative to the futures, options, and cash

equity index markets. These characteristics, combined with the fact

that there are no time delays for reporting block trades in the

underlying equity cash market, makes establishment of swap categories,

and therefore minimum block thresholds, for equity swaps

inappropriate.\149\ The Commission notes that establishing time delays

for reporting block trades in the swaps market when no time delays

exist could negatively impact the price discovery function of the

underlying equity cash market and futures market. Accordingly, the

Commission is adopting Sec. 43.6(b)(3) as proposed.\150\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\149\ See infra Section II.B(5)(b). In the event that time

delays are established for reporting block trades in the underlying

equity cash market, the Commission may consider establishing swap

categories and minimum block thresholds for equity swaps.

\150\ The Securities and Exchange Commission (``SEC'') has

proposed general criteria that it would consider to set appropriate

minimum block trade sizes for security-based swaps. The SEC,

however, has not proposed specific numerical thresholds at this

time, but rather intends to propose such thresholds upon the

adoption of Regulation SBSR--Reporting and Dissemination of

Security-Based Swap Information. 75 FR 75208, 75228 (Dec. 2, 2010).

On May 1, 2013, the SEC reopened the comment period regarding this

proposed rule. See Reopening of Comment Periods for Certain

Rulemaking Releases and Policy Statement Applicable to Security-

Based Swaps Proposed Pursuant to the Securities Exchange Act of 1934

and the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act

(May 1, 2013).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. Swap Categories in the FX Asset Class

The Commission proposed establishing swap categories for the FX

asset class based on unique currency combinations, with Sec.

43.6(b)(4)(i) distinguishing futures-related swaps \151\ from swaps

that are not futures-related (covered under proposed Sec.

43.6(b)(4)(ii)). Distinguishing futures-related swaps from other swaps

would allow the Commission to set initial appropriate minimum block

sizes for certain swaps based on DCM block sizes for FX futures

contracts.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\151\ Under Sec. 43.2, a futures-related swap is defined as a

swap (as defined in section 1a(47) of the Act and as further defined

by the Commission in implementing regulations) that is economically

related to a futures contract. See infra notes 169-174 and

accompanying text. Under Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i), a futures-related swap

is a swap where one of the underlying currencies of the swap is the

subject of a futures contract listed on a DCM.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission based its approach on the assumption that FX swaps

and futures contracts based upon the same currency draw upon the same

liquidity pools. The Commission proposed in Sec. Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i)

and (b)(4)(ii) to distinguish FX swaps and instruments based on the

existence of a related futures contract. Liquidity in the underlying

futures market for the currency combinations established in proposed

Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i) suggested sufficient liquidity in the swaps market

for these currency combinations.

The Commission proposed establishing swap categories for futures-

related swaps under proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i) based on the unique

currency combinations between the currency of each of the following:

the United States, European Union, United Kingdom, Japan, Australia,

Switzerland, Canada, Republic of South Africa, Republic of Korea,

Kingdom of Sweden, New Zealand, Kingdom of Norway, Denmark, Brazil,

China, Czech Republic, Hungary, Israel, Mexico, New

[[Page 32885]]

Zealand, Poland, Russia, and Turkey.\152\ Hence, proposed Sec.

43.6(b)(4)(i) would establish a separate swap category for each of the

231 unique currency combinations between these currencies. In proposed

Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(ii), the Commission would establish an additional swap

category based on unique currency combinations not included in proposed

Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i).\153\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\152\ For example, the euro (EUR) and the Canadian dollar (CAD)

combination would be one swap category; whereas, the Swedish krona

(SEK) and the Korean won (KRW) combination would be a separate swap

category.

\153\ Under proposed Sec. 43.6(e)(2), swaps having currency

combinations described in Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(ii) would all be eligible

to be treated as a block trade or large notional off-facility swap.

Only in the post-initial period would the proposed rules set an

appropriate minimum block size for this category of FX swaps. See

infra Section II.B(5)(c)(ii).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission received six comments regarding the proposed swap

categories for the FX asset class based on unique currency

combinations. Two commenters recommended additional swap categories for

the FX asset class.\154\ Barclays suggested that EUR- and USD-

denominated transactions should be categorized separately from less

liquid transactions and that distinct block levels should apply to the

following product categories: Forwards, non-deliverable forwards, non-

deliverable options, vanilla options, and other more complex

options.\155\ GFMA recommended more granular swap categories that would

group specific instruments according to similarity of liquidity

profile.\156\ AFR, however, commented that the governing principle in

establishing swap categories should be the reasonable relationship of

swaps within a category to a liquid class of swaps or futures that are

potential hedges for that category and expressed concern that adding

any additional granularity might violate this principle.\157\ AII and

ICI urged the Commission to remove block trading thresholds so that all

transactions would be treated as blocks for the FX asset class during

the initial period, and allow for collection and analysis of SDR data

during this period to determine appropriate swap categories for the

post-initial period.\158\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\154\ CL-Barclays at 10; CL-GFMA at 2-3.

\155\ CL-Barclays at 10.

\156\ CL-GFMA at 2-3. GFMA also suggested that (1) FX swaps

should be distinguished by tenor, and that (2) block size thresholds

should vary based on time of day, in order to take into account

liquidity across time zones.

\157\ CL-AFR at 6.

\158\ CL-AII at 3; CL-ICI at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that, since the Further Block Proposal,

Treasury has issued a Final Determination, pursuant to sections

1a(47)(E)(i) and 1b of the CEA, that exempts FX swaps and FX forwards

from the definition of ``swap'' under the CEA. Therefore, the

requirements of section 2(a)(13) of the CEA would not apply to those

transactions, and such transactions would not be subject to part 43 of

the Commission's regulations.\159\ Nevertheless, section 1a(47)(E)(iii)

of the CEA provides that FX swaps and FX forwards transactions still

are not excluded from regulatory reporting requirements to an SDR.

Further, the Commission notes that Treasury's final determination

excludes FX swaps and FX forwards, but does not apply to FX options or

non-deliverable FX forwards. As such, FX instruments that are not

covered by Treasury's final determination are subject to part 43 of the

Commission's regulations.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\159\ See Determination of Foreign Exchange Swaps and Foreign

Exchange Forwards under the Commodity Exchange Act, 77 FR 69,694,

Nov. 20, 2012.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received and the complexity of

the proposed approach, the Commission is adopting Sec. 43.6(b)(4) with

modifications. The Commission is modifying proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i)

to establish swap categories based on the unique currency combinations

between one super-major currency paired with one of the following: (1)

Another super major currency \160\; (2) a major currency \161\; or (3)

a currency of Brazil, China, Czech Republic, Hungary, Israel, Mexico,

New Zealand, Poland, Russia, or Turkey. This approach differs from the

proposal in that the adopted swap categories will not include the

unique currency combinations between major currencies and other major

currencies, between major currencies and each of the ten additional

enumerated non-major currencies, and between the ten additional

enumerated non-major currencies. Under Sec. 43.6(b)(4) as adopted, all

swap transactions subject to part 43 \162\ in these unique currency

combinations may be treated as blocks.\163\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\160\ As set out in Section II.A.1., the super-major currencies

are the United States dollar (USD), European Union Euro Area euro

(EUR), United Kingdom pound sterling (GBP), and Japan yen (JPY).

\161\ As set out in Section II.A.1., the major currencies are

the Australia dollar (AUD), Switzerland franc (CHF), Canada dollar

(CAD), Republic of South Africa rand (ZAR), Republic of Korea won

(KRW), Kingdom of Sweden krona (SEK), New Zealand dollar (NZD),

Kingdom of Norway krone (NOK) and Denmark krone (DKK).

\162\ As stated above, this section only applies to FX options

and non-deliverable FX forwards. Treasury has exempted FX swaps and

FX forwards from the definition of ``swap'' under the CEA. See

Determination of Foreign Exchange Swaps and Foreign Exchange

Forwards under the Commodity Exchange Act, 77 FR 69,694, Nov. 20,

2012.

\163\ See Table 10 for the enumerated swap categories

established by Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The changes to Sec. 43.6(b)(4) will significantly reduce the

number of swap categories, hence reducing complexity, but will still

ensure coverage of the most liquid currency combinations.\164\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\164\ According to the BIS Triennial Central Bank Survey:

Foreign Exchange and Derivatives Market Activity in April 2010

(preliminary results, dated September 2010), the currency

combinations enumerated under adopted Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i) comprise

more than 80% of global FX market turnover.

According to the Survey of North American Foreign Exchange

Volume in October 2012, the proposed categories established by Sec.

43.6(b)(4)(i) cover more than 86% of the notional value of total

monthly volume of FX swaps that are priced or facilitated by traders

in North America. The Survey of North American Foreign Exchange

Volume is conducted by the Foreign Exchange Committee, which

includes representatives of major financial institutions engaged in

foreign currency trading in the United States and is sponsored by

the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. The survey is designed to

measure the level of turnover in the foreign exchange market.

Turnover is defined as the gross value in U.S. dollar equivalents of

purchases and sales entered into during the reporting period. The

data covers a one-month period in order to reduce the likelihood

that very short-term variations in activity might distort the data

and include all transactions that are priced or facilitated by

traders in North America (United States, Canada, and Mexico).

Transactions concluded by dealers outside of North America are

excluded even if they are booked to an office within North America.

The survey also excludes transactions between branches,

subsidiaries, affiliates, and trading desks of the same firm. The

October 2012 data can be located at http://www.newyorkfed.org/fxc/2012/octfxsurvey2012.pdf.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

While not affording block treatment to all swaps in the FX asset

class subject to part 43, these modifications will increase the number

of currency combinations which will be eligible to be blocks, many of

which have limited liquidity.\165\ Yet, this modified approach still

allows the Commission to set initial appropriate minimum block sizes

for the most liquid categories based on the block trade size thresholds

set by DCMs for economically-related futures contracts, as enumerated

under adopted Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i). The Commission believes that the

categories established by proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i) and kept under

adopted Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i) provide the separate classification for

EUR- and USD-denominated transactions recommended by Barclays.\166\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\165\ For example, the unique currency combination of the

Australian Dollar (AUD) and the Canadian Dollar (CAD) had a minimum

block threshold of 10,000,000 CAD in the Further Block Proposal.

Under adopted Sec. 43.6(b)(4), all trades in this unique currency

combination will be eligible for block treatment.

\166\ The Commission emphasizes that the swap categories for the

FX asset class are unique currency combinations between each of the

super-major currencies, major currencies, and additional currencies

listed. The classification of EUR and USD as super-major currencies

simply means that both currencies are individually eligible for

inclusion among the unique currency combinations used for swap

categorization. In the FX asset class, there is no separate bucket

for super-major currencies (such as the buckets in the interest rate

swap asset class described above).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 32886]]

The Commission will also modify Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(ii) to establish

one swap category for the currency combinations not included in Sec.

43.6(b)(4)(i). This category will encompass the other currency

combinations proposed, but not adopted, by the Commission, as well as

other non-futures related currency swaps. With the modifications to

Sec. 43.6(b)(4), the euro (EUR) and the Canadian dollar (CAD)

combination will still be one swap category as in the original proposal

pursuant to Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i). However, the Swedish krona (SEK) and

the Korean won (KRW) combination will be grouped with all the other

swaps covered by Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(ii) into one swap category. As a

further example, a swap of the Czech koruna (CZK) and the Brazilian

real (BRL) will be in the same category as the SEK-KRW swap. While the

swaps grouped into one category by Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(ii) may have

different liquidity levels, these swaps will all be subject to the time

delays provided to block trades and large notional off-facility swaps

in both the initial and post-initial periods.

The Commission notes that the adopted Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i)

establishes 78 unique currency combinations, covering a vast majority

of the notional value of FX swaps concluded by traders in North

America. Creating additional swap categories, as suggested by Barclays

and GFMA,\167\ would result in swap categories totaling a multiple of

this already large number without drastically increasing the number of

swaps that will be subject to real-time reporting without a delay.

Establishing swap categories based upon unique currency combinations as

in adopted Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i) meets the objectives of grouping swaps

with economic similarity and reducing confusion for market participants

in determining whether their swaps are classified within a particular

swap category. The Commission believes that these changes will reduce

the administrative burden to both market participants and to the

Commission by reducing the number of swap categories for which

appropriate minimum block sizes need to be calculated.\168\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\167\ CL-Barclays at 10; CL-GFMA at 2-3.

\168\ In the Further Block Proposal, every unique currency

combination would be considered a unique swap category, which means

there would be hundreds of different swap categories for the FX

asset class. Proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i) alone established 231 swap

categories. Many additional categories would have been established

under proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(ii). The adopted Sec. 43.6(b)(4)

creates 78 categories requiring the calculation of appropriate

minimum block sizes in the post-initial period.

Table 10--Swap Categories Established Under Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i)

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Super-major currencies

-------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Euro (EUR) British pound (GBP) Japanese yen (JPY) U.S. dollar (USD)

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

British Pound (GBP)................. EUR-GBP ........................... ........................... ...........................

Japanese Yen (JPY).................. EUR-JPY GBP-JPY ........................... ...........................

U.S. Dollar (USD)................... EUR-USD GBP-USD JPY-USD ...........................

Australian Dollar (AUD)............. AUD-EUR AUD-GBP AUD-JPY AUD-USD

Canadian Dollar (CAD)............... CAD-EUR CAD-GBP CAD-JPY CAD-USD

Swiss Francs (CHF).................. CHF-EUR CHF-GBP CHF-JPY CHF-USD

Denmark Krone (DKK)................. DKK-EUR DKK-GBP DKK-JPY DKK-USD

Korean Won (KRW).................... KRW-EUR KRW-GBP KRW-JPY KRW-USD

Swedish Krona (SEK)................. SEK-EUR SEK-GBP SEK-JPY SEK-USD

Norwegian Krone (NOK)............... NOK-EUR NOK-GBP NOK-JPY NOK-USD

New Zealand Dollar (NZD)............ NZD-EUR NZD-GBP NZD-JPY NZD-USD

South African Rand (ZAR)............ ZAR-EUR ZAR-GBP ZAR-JPY ZAR-USD

Brazilian Real (BRL)................ BRL-EUR BRL-GBP BRL-JPY BRL-USD

Czech Koruna (CZK).................. CZK-EUR CZK-GBP CZK-JPY CZK-USD

Hungarian Forint (HUF).............. HUF-EUR HUF-GBP HUF-JPY HUF-USD

Israeli Shekel (ILS)................ ILS-EUR ILS-GBP ILS-JPY ILS-USD

Mexican Peso (MXN).................. MXN-EUR MXN-GBP MXN-JPY MXN-USD

Polish Zloty (PLN).................. PLN-EUR PLN-GBP PLN-JPY PLN-USD

Chinese Renminbi (RMB).............. RMB-EUR RMB-GBP RMB-JPY RMB-USD

Russian Ruble (RUB)................. RUB-EUR RUB-GBP RUB-JPY RUB-USD

Turkish Lira (TRY).................. TRY-EUR TRY-GBP TRY-JPY TRY-USD

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

4. Swap Categories in the Other Commodity Asset Class

The Commission proposed to determine swap categories in the other

commodity asset class based on three sets of groupings. The first two

sets of groupings create categories of swaps which are economically

related to specific futures contracts (i.e., futures-related swaps

\169\) or swap contracts under proposed Sec. Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(i) and

(ii). The third set of groupings creates categories based on swaps

sharing a common product type under proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(iii).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\169\ Proposed Sec. 43.2 defines a futures-related swap as a

swap (as defined in section 1a(47) of the Act and as further defined

by the Commission in implementing regulations) that is economically

related to a futures contract. The Commission is adopting this

definition as proposed.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission proposed defining ``economically related'' \170\ in

Sec. 43.2 as a direct or indirect reference to the same commodity at

the same delivery location or locations,\171\ or with the

[[Page 32887]]

same or substantially similar cash market price series.\172\ The

Commission noted that this definition would (1) ensure that swap

contracts with shared reference price characteristics indicating

economic substitutability (i.e., swaps in the category can be used to

offset some or all of the risks associated with positions in the

underlying commodity) are grouped together within a common swap

category; \173\ and (2) provide further clarity as to which swaps are

described in Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(ii)(B), which was previously finalized

under the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule.\174\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\170\ In the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule, the Commission

explained: ``For the purposes of part 43, swaps are economically

related, as described in Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(ii)(B), if such contract

utilizes as its sole floating reference price the prices generated

directly or indirectly from the price of a single contract described

in appendix B to part 43.'' 77 FR 1211. Further, the Commission

explained that ``an `indirect' price link to an Enumerated Physical

Commodity Contract or an Other Contract described in appendix B to

part 43 includes situations where the swap reference price is linked

to prices of a cash-settled contract described in appendix B to part

43 that itself is cash-settled based on a physical-delivery

settlement price to such contract.'' Id. at n.289.

\171\ For example, a swap utilizing the Platts Gas Daily/Platts

IFERC reference price is economically related to the Henry Hub

Natural Gas (NYMEX) (futures) contract because it is based on the

same commodity at the same delivery location as that underlying the

latter contract.

\172\ For example, a swap utilizing the Standard and Poor's

(``S&P'') 500 reference price is economically related to the S&P 500

Stock Index futures contract because it is based on the same cash

market price series.

\173\ The Commission proposed to amend Sec. 43.2 to define

``reference price'' as a floating price series (including

derivatives contract and cash market prices or price indices) used

by the parties to a swap or swaption to determine payments made,

exchanged or accrued under the terms of a swap contract. The

Commission proposed to use this term in connection with the

establishment of a method through which parties to a swap

transaction may elect to apply the lowest appropriate minimum block

size applicable to one component swap category of such swap

transaction. See infra Section II.B(6)(b). The Commission is

adopting this definition as proposed.

\174\ The Real-Time Reporting Final Rule previously finalized

Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(ii)(B), which requires a registered SDR to publicly

disseminate any publicly reportable swap transaction in the other

commodity asset class that is ``economically related'' to one of the

contracts described in appendix B to part 43, but did not define

``economically related.'' This definition, as proposed and to be

adopted here, would apply to the use of this term throughout all of

part 43 of the Commission's regulations.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The first set of swap categories, covered under proposed Sec.

43.6(b)(5)(i), would establish separate swap categories for swaps that

are economically related to one of the contracts listed in appendix B

to part 43. Therefore, proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(i) would establish one

swap category for each contract listed in appendix B to part 43. The

Real-Time Reporting Final Rule previously finalized appendix B to part

43, which lists 29 Enumerated Physical Commodity Contracts and Other

Contracts (i.e., Brent Crude Oil (ICE)).\175\ In the Further Block

Proposal, the Commission proposed to add 13 electricity and natural gas

swap contracts to appendix B to part 43.\176\ Therefore, proposed Sec.

43.6(b)(5)(i) would establish 42 swap categories such that each

contract would be the basis for its own other commodity swap category,

and all swaps that are economically related to that contract would be

included in that swap category.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\175\ As noted by the Commission in the Real-Time Reporting

Final Rule, the 28 Enumerated Physical Commodity Contracts are

traded on U.S. DCMs, while Brent Crude Oil (ICE) futures contracts

are primarily traded in Europe. 77 FR 1211 n. 288.

\176\ See infra Section II.B5(d)(i). The Commission had

previously issued orders deeming these contracts as ``significant

price discovery contracts'' in connection with trading on exempt

commercial markets (``ECMs''), based on, among other factors, their

material liquidity and price discovery function. See infra Section

III.C(4)(a). These contracts included: AECO Financial Basis Contract

(``AEC'') traded on the IntercontinentalExchange, Inc. (``ICE'')

(See 75 FR 23697); NWP Rockies Financial Basis Contract (``NWR'')

traded on ICE (See 75 FR 23704); PG&E Citygate Financial Basis

Contract (``PGE'') traded on ICE (See 75 FR 23710); Waha Financial

Basis Contract (``WAH'') traded on ICE (See 75 FR 24655); Socal

Border Financial Basis Contract (``SCL'') traded on ICE (See 75 FR

24648); HSC Financial Basis Contract (``HXS'') traded on ICE (See 75

FR 24641); ICE Chicago Financial Basis Contract (``DGD'') traded on

ICE (See 75 FR 24633); SP-15 Financial Day-Ahead LMP Peak Contract

(``SPM'') traded on ICE (See 75 FR 42380); SP-15 Financial Day-Ahead

LMP Off-Peak Contract (``OFP'') traded on ICE (See 75 FR 42380); PJM

WH Real Time Peak Contract (``PJM'') traded on ICE (See 75 FR

42390); PJM WH Real Time Off-Peak Contract (``OPJ'') traded on ICE

(See 75 FR 42390); Mid-C Financial Peak Contract (``MDC'') traded on

ICE (See 75 FR 38469); Mid-C Financial Off-Peak Contract (``OMC'')

traded on ICE (See 75 FR 38469).

As discussed further below, as of October 12, 2012, ICE withdrew

its listing of these contracts as a result of converting its cleared

OTC swap contracts and related options to futures listed at ICE

Futures U.S. and ICE Futures Europe. Accordingly, ICE converted

these contracts into economically equivalent futures contracts and

has listed them for trading. See ICE--Swaps to Futures Transition,

https://www.theice.com/S2F.jhtml (last visited May 7, 2013).

Therefore, as discussed further below, the Commission has determined

in this final rule to add the converted contracts to appendix B to

part 43, such that each contract will serve as a basis for an other

commodity swap category. See infra Section II.A(4).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission has separately enumerated these contracts since it

previously has identified these commodity contracts as: (1) Having high

levels of open interest and significant cash flow; and (2) serving as a

reference price for a significant number of cash market transactions.

Moreover, the Commission has also previously determined that any swap

that references or is economically related to these contracts (along

with the Brent Crude Oil (ICE) contract or any contract that is

economically related to it) has sufficient liquidity to ensure that the

public dissemination of swap transaction and pricing data for swaps

based on this reference asset poses little risk of disclosing

identities of parties, business transactions, or market positions.\177\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\177\ 77 FR 1211.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The second set of swap categories, covered under proposed Sec.

43.6(b)(5)(ii), would establish swap categories based on swaps in the

other commodity asset class that are: (1) Not economically related to

one of the futures or swap contracts listed in appendix B to part 43;

and (2) economically related to a relevant futures contract that is

subject to the block trade rules of a DCM. Proposed Sec.

43.6(b)(5)(ii) listed the 18 futures contracts to which these swaps are

economically related, and hence, establishes 18 swap categories.\178\

These swap categories would include any swap that is economically

related to such contracts. The swap categories established by proposed

Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(i) differ from the swap categories established by

proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(ii) in that the former may be economically

related to futures or swap contracts that are not subject to the block

trade rules of a DCM, whereas the latter are economically related to

futures contracts that are subject to the block trade rules of a

DCM.\179\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\178\ As proposed, these additional other commodity swap

categories would be based on the following futures contracts: CME

Cheese; CBOT Distillers' Dried Grain; CBOT Dow Jones-UBS Commodity

Index Excess Return; CBOT Ethanol; CME Frost Index; CME Goldman

Sachs Commodity Index (GSCI) (GSCI Excess Return Index); NYMEX Gulf

Coast Gasoline; NYMEX Gulf Coast Sour Crude Oil; NYMEX Gulf Coast

Ultra Low Sulfur Diesel; CME Hurricane Index; CME International

Skimmed Milk Powder; NYMEX New York Harbor Ultra Low Sulfur Diesel;

CBOT Nonfarm Payroll; CME Rainfall Index; CME Snowfall Index; CME

Temperature Index; CME U.S. Dollar Cash Settled Crude Palm Oil; and

CME Wood Pulp.

\179\ This distinction is noteworthy because proposed Sec.

43.6(e)(3) provides that ``[p]ublicly reportable swap transactions

described in Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(i) that are economically related to a

futures contract in appendix B to this part [43] shall not qualify

to be treated as block trades or large notional off-facility swaps

(as applicable) [during the initial period], if such futures

contract is not subject to a designated contract market's block

trading rules.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The third set of swap categories, covered under proposed Sec.

43.6(b)(5)(iii), would establish swap categories for all other

commodity swaps that are not categorized under proposed Sec.

43.6(b)(5)(i) or (ii). These swaps are not economically related to any

of the contracts listed in appendix B to part 43 or any of the

contracts listed in proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(ii). For these other

commodity swaps, the Commission would determine the appropriate swap

category based on the product types described in appendix D to part 43

to which the underlying asset(s) of the swap would apply or otherwise

relate. Proposed appendix D to part 43 establishes ``Other Commodity

Groups'' and certain ``Individual Other Commodities'' within those

groups. To the extent that there is an ``Individual Other Commodity''

listed, the Commission would deem the ``Individual Other Commodity'' as

a separate swap category. For example, regardless of whether the

underlying asset to an off-facility swap is ``Sugar No. 14'' or ``Sugar

No. 5,'' the underlying asset would be grouped as ``Sugar.'' The

Commission thereafter

[[Page 32888]]

would set the appropriate minimum block size for each of the swap

categories listed in appendix D to part 43.

In circumstances where a swap does not apply or otherwise relate to

a specific ``Individual Other Commodity'' listed under the ``Other

Commodity Group'' in appendix D to part 43, the Commission would

categorize such swap as falling under the respective ``Other'' swap

categories. For example, an emissions swap would be categorized as

``Emissions,'' while a swap in which the underlying asset is aluminum

would be categorized as ``Base Metals--Other.'' Additionally, in

circumstances where the underlying asset of swap does not apply or

otherwise relate to an ``Individual Other Commodity'' or an ``Other''

swap category, the Commission would categorize such swap as either

``Other Agricultural'' or ``Other Non-Agricultural.''

Comments on the proposed swap categories in the other commodity

asset class varied. CME Group agreed with the proposed approach to

establishing swap categories in the other commodity asset class in the

initial period because it would allow appropriate minimum block level

sizes to be set based on the minimum block sizes set by DCMs.\180\ ICI,

however, recommended that the Commission obtain and analyze trading

data from SDRs first before determining whether the proposed swap

categories are appropriate.\181\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\180\ CL-CME 3-4. Proposed Sec. 43.6(e)(1) established

appropriate minimum block sizes in the initial period for swap

categories in proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(i)-(ii) based on the block

sizes for related futures contracts set by DCMs, except for natural

gas and electricity swaps proposed to be added to appendix B of part

43.

\181\ CL-ICI at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters commented on the granularity of the proposed

swap categories. Some commenters recommended more granular categories

to account for the differences in liquidity and execution risk between

shorter- and longer-dated contracts.\182\ Similarly, Barclays also

commented that swap categories in the other commodity asset class

should consider that products typically experience a reduction in

liquidity beyond the first or second year.\183\ Other commenters,

however, opposed the proposed categories as too narrow and recommended

broadening the definition of ``economically related'' and reducing the

number of swap categories to reflect increasing price correlation

between different categories of commodities as well as existing hedging

practices by market participants.\184\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\182\ CL-ICAP Energy at 4; CL-fia at 3.

\183\ CL-Barclays at 9.

\184\ CL-Better Markets at 6-7; CL-AFR at 6-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Parity Energy requested that the Commission establish a separate

category for swaps that are economically related to crude oil options

because transactions in crude oil options are typically fewer and

larger in size than transactions in crude oil futures contracts.\185\

Parity Energy also agreed with the proposed distinction in swap

categories between swaps that are economically related to natural gas

swaps and swaps that are economically related to natural gas swap

options.\186\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\185\ CL-Parity at 4-5.

\186\ Id. As proposed, the initial minimum block size for swaps

that are economically related to Henry Hub Natural Gas futures was

set at 1,000,000 mmBtu; the initial minimum block size for Henry Hub

Natural Gas options was set at 5,500,000 mmBtu.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is adopting the definition of ``economically

related'' as proposed. The Commission believes that broadening the

definition, as suggested by some commenters, would reduce the precision

with which swaps in the other commodity asset class can be properly

categorized. As proposed, the definition of ``economically related'' is

sufficient in that it (1) ensures that swap contracts with shared

reference price characteristics (indicating economic substitutability)

are grouped together within a common swap category and (2) provides

further clarity as to which swaps are described in Sec.

43.4(d)(4)(ii)(B).

Furthermore, the Commission believes that its general approach to

establishing swap categories under Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(i)-(iii) is

appropriate and is adopting the text of Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(i)-(iii)

largely as proposed, with the exception of some proposed swap

categories in Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(ii).\187\ With the conversion of the 13

electricity and natural gas swap contracts proposed to be added to

appendix B to part 43 into DCM-listed, economically equivalent futures

contracts,\188\ the Commission is making one modification by

establishing swap categories and adopting initial appropriate minimum

block sizes corresponding to those set by a DCM for those futures

contracts. With respect to the swap categories established under Sec.

43.6(b)(5)(i), the Commission believes that establishing categories for

swaps that are economically related to one of the referenced futures

contracts is appropriate because these contracts have previously been

identified as (1) having high levels of open interest and significant

cash flow; and (2) serving as a reference price for a significant

number of cash market transactions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\187\ The Commission is not adopting separate swap categories

that it proposed in the Further Block Proposal for swaps that are

economically related to the following NYMEX futures contracts: Gulf

Coast Gasoline; Gulf Coast Ultra Low Sulfur Diesel; and New York

Harbor Ultra Low Sulfur Diesel. As of October 15, 2012, NYMEX

eliminated block trading in these contracts because they have no

open interest. The Commission is also removing the swap category for

swaps that reference or are economically related to Non-Farm Payroll

futures contract, the International Skimmed Milk Powder, and Wood

Pulp as these contracts are no longer listed for trading.

\188\ See supra note 176.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With respect to the swap categories established under Sec.

43.6(b)(5)(i)-(ii), the Commission is establishing swap categories and

adopting initial appropriate minimum block sizes which correspond with

those set by a DCM for economically related futures contracts in the

initial period.\189\ Hence, to the extent possible, the Commission is

relying upon the DCMs' knowledge of and experience with liquidity in

related futures markets until additional data becomes available. With

respect to the swap categories established under Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(iii),

the Commission believes that setting swap categories by product type

would allow the Commission to set appropriate minimum block sizes for

groups of transactions that have similar underlying physical commodity

market characteristics. Accordingly, the Commission does not believe

that establishing swap categories that are broader than proposed is

necessary to enhance market transparency.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\189\ See infra Section II.B(5)(d).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 32889]]

Furthermore, the Commission is not using additional criteria to

create more granular swap categories in the other commodity asset

class. While commodity swaps within a particular swap category may

feature different liquidity and risk profiles based on their tenor, the

Commission is not aware of any data that would warrant additional swap

categories. As swaps trading data becomes available, the Commission

will examine such data to determine whether establishing additional

swap categories would be appropriate.

The other main modification to the swap categories established

under Sec. 43.6(b)(5) is that the Commission is not adopting separate

swap categories for swaps that are economically related to the options

contracts listed in appendix F of the Further Block Proposal.\190\

Consistent with the Commission's definitions of ``economically-

related'' and ``futures-related swap,'' the Commission considers such

swaps, which feature an optionality component, to be economically

related to the corresponding futures contracts adopted in appendix F of

this final rule for purposes of determining swap categories. This

approach to categorizing such swaps is consistent with the Commission's

methodology to establish initial appropriate minimum block size for

swaps with optionality for all asset classes.\191\ Under this

methodology, the notional size of swaps with optionality in the initial

period will be equal to the notional size of the swap component without

the optional component. As discussed further below, the Commission is

adopting this methodology as proposed, and therefore will not consider

optionality in the determination of a swap contract's notional size--

allowing block sizes to be established based on the block sizes set by

DCMs for options contracts would contradict this approach.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\190\ These options contracts listed in proposed Appendix F,

which are subject to a minimum DCM block size rule, included Cocoa

(ICE); Coffee (ICE); Cotton No. 2 (ICE); Frozen Concentrated Orange

Juice (ICE); Gold (COMEX and NYSE Liffe); New York Harbor No. 2

Heating Oil (NYMEX); Silver (COMEX and NYSE Liffe); Sugar

11 (ICE); and Sugar 16 (ICE).

\191\ See infra Section II.C.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

5. Comments Regarding Swap Categories Across Asset Classes

The Commission received a number of comments suggesting that, for

all asset classes, the Commission establish separate swap categories,

with separate appropriate minimum block sizes, for infrequently traded

or illiquid swaps. Javelin and SDMA did not think infrequently-traded

swaps posed an obstacle and recommended swap categorization that would

account for hedging for illiquid swaps through synthetic/portfolio

hedging through liquidity of economically equivalent swaps.\192\

Barclays suggested that all swaps made available to trade that trade

less than three times a day should be treated as blocks, as market

makers otherwise will be reluctant to quote prices.\193\ Alternatively,

Barclays suggested removing such swaps from the ``available to trade''

category and thereby exempting them from post-trade reporting.\194\

ISDA/SIFMA requested block treatment for all infrequently traded swaps

and suggested a benchmark tied to precise daily trading frequency

including a time delay for illiquid products generally.\195\ To support

this approach, ISDA/SIFMA cited a Commission study showing that market

participants prefer off-exchange bilateral execution for illiquid

instruments because of liquidity concerns.\196\ ISDA/SIFMA suggested

that a single transaction, regardless of size, in such infrequently-

traded or illiquid swaps may move the market.\197\ GFMA suggested

treating all infrequently-traded swaps as blocks and defines such

transactions as exhibiting all or some of the following features: (1)

The constituent swap or swaps to which they are economically related

are not executed on, or pursuant to the rules of, a SEF or DCM; (2) few

market participants have transacted in these swaps or in economically-

related swaps; or (3) few swap transactions are executed during a

historic period in these swaps or in economically-related swaps.\198\

Parascandola recommended block treatment for small notional and odd-lot

trades, particularly in index products where the notional amount is

below $10 million.\199\ Kinetix suggested that transactions in any

product with fewer than 250 transactions annually should receive

treatment as block trades.\200\ Vanguard urged a more granular approach

to swap categories and thresholds to ``recognize distinct liquidity

pools.'' \201\ Vanguard and SIFMA suggested that swaps that trade fewer

than 14 trades per day should be blocks.\202\ AII suggested block

treatment for swaps that trade less than 5 times per day.\203\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\192\ CL-Javelin at 5-6; CL-SDMA at 6.

\193\ CL-Barclays at 4.

\194\ Id.

\195\ ISDA/SIFMA recommended that every transaction (regardless

of size) in a swap category for which there are no more than 14

swaps traded per business day receive block treatment for a period

of 1 year. CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 12.

\196\ According to ISDA/SIFMA, ``[f]orcing the same transparency

standards on market participants for both liquid and illiquid

products will be detrimental. Instantaneous trade disclosure for

highly illiquid products, combined with the potential for SEF or DCM

execution, is likely to erode their liquidity further and to do

severe damage to the safety and soundness of the system as a

whole.'' Id.

\197\ Id.

\198\ CL-GFMA at 3.

\199\ CL-Parascondola at 1.

\200\ CL-Kinetix at 1.

\201\ CL-Vanguard at 5.

\202\ CL-SIFMA at 10; CL-Vanguard at 7.

\203\ CL-AII at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting the swap categories described in the sections above. The

Commission believes that the trade frequency of a single instrument is

but one measure of liquidity for such a swap and does not factor in the

pool of instruments that are capable of providing an economically

equivalent position, either individually or on a portfolio basis.

B. Appropriate Minimum Block Size Methodologies for the Initial and

Post-Initial Periods

The Commission proposed a tailored approach for determining

appropriate minimum block sizes during the initial and post-initial

periods for each asset class. In the subsections below, the Commission

sets out a more detailed discussion of the appropriate minimum block

size methodologies for swaps within: (1) Swap categories in the

interest rate and credit asset classes; (2) the single swap category in

the equity asset class; (3) swap categories in the FX asset class; and

(4) swap categories in the other commodity asset class. Thereafter, the

Commission discusses special rules for determining the appropriate

minimum block sizes across asset classes.

[[Page 32890]]

1. Phase-In of Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes

As discussed in Section I.C.2. above, the Commission proposed a

phase-in of its regulations regarding appropriate minimum block size

methodologies so that market participants could better adjust their

swap trading strategies to manage risk, secure new technologies, and

make necessary arrangements to comply with part 43. Thus, the

Commission proposed two provisions relating to the Commission's

determination of appropriate minimum block sizes: (1) Initial

appropriate minimum block sizes under proposed Sec. 43.6(e); and (2)

post-initial appropriate minimum block sizes under proposed Sec.

43.6(f).

The Commission received ten comments regarding the proposed phase-

in of its appropriate minimum block size methodologies. Four

commenters, AII, EEI, SIFMA, and Vanguard, requested that the

Commission apply block status to all swaps during the initial

period.\204\ AII stated that removing (or lowering) block thresholds

would appropriately transition the market and avoid harming

liquidity.\205\ SIFMA recommended collecting SDR data during the

initial period and gradually and iteratively phasing in block

thresholds.\206\ Vanguard also expressed concern regarding the

liquidity impacts of setting block thresholds without more data.\207\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\204\ CL-AII at 3; CL-EEI at 5; CL-SIFMA at 3; CL-Vanguard at 7.

\205\ CL-AII at 3.

\206\ CL-SIFMA at 3.

\207\ CL-Vanguard at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Eight commenters suggested that the Commission establish a more

conservative threshold during the initial period. AII recommended that

the Commission either remove block trading thresholds during the

initial period or lower the thresholds below the proposed levels to

appropriately transition the market and avoid unnecessarily harming

liquidity.\208\ Barclays recommended introducing block levels that

allow for empirical analysis of the transaction data and sequentially

increasing block sizes until such point as the desired equilibrium

between transparency and liquidity is reached.\209\ GFMA stated that,

if the Commission used a percentage notional test, then it should

introduce it in a phased manner to assess the impact on the market over

time and ensure it has sufficient flexibility to amend the notional

percentage.\210\ ICAP Energy proposed specific initial block thresholds

for PJM at 50 MW/Hr and for SP-15 and Mid-C at 30 MW/Hr, and for

natural gas basis swaps at 2500 MMBTUs/day.\211\ ICI, while supporting

a 50 percent notional amount calculation, urged the Commission to

phase-in the calculation for very illiquid instruments (less than 3 or

4 trades per week) by first implementing a 25 percent notional amount

calculation, in order to alleviate potential harmful effects of

disclosure of large block sizes on liquidity, particularly in illiquid

swaps markets.\212\ ISDA/SIFMA stated that the Commission should phase

in the block threshold in order to allow trading on SEFs and DCMs to

develop and suggested setting the threshold based on a 25-percent

notional amount calculation.\213\ SIFMA proposed a multi-phase process

for establishing block levels, starting with a one-year data collection

phase, followed by an initial period with low block levels.\214\ The

block levels would then be decreased if the Commission found that

liquidity significantly decreased or bid-ask spreads significantly

increased over the quarter for swaps close to, but below, the block

threshold.\215\ WMBAA encouraged the Commission to implement lower

block trade thresholds while the post-trade reporting requirements are

implemented and market participants begin providing data to SDRs for

cleared and uncleared swaps.\216\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\208\ CL-AII at 3.

\209\ CL-Barclays at 11.

\210\ CL-GFMA at 3.

\211\ CL-ICAP Energy at 3.

\212\ CL-ICI at 7.

\213\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 13.

\214\ CL-SIFMA at 3.

\215\ Id.

\216\ CL-WMBAA at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments above, the Commission is

adopting a phased-in approach as proposed, but with modifications in

response to the comments above regarding phasing, as more fully

described below.

2. Overview of Proposed Approach

The chart below summarizes swap categories and calculation

methodologies that the Commission proposed for each asset class in both

the initial period and the post-initial period.

[[Page 32891]]

Proposed Approach

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Post-initial

Asset class Swap category criteria Initial implementation implementation period

period \217\

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Interest Rates................... By unique currency and 67-percent notional 67-percent notional

Credit........................... tenor grouping \218\ amount calculation by amount calculation by

By tenor and conventional swap category \219\ swap category \220\

spread grouping \221\.

FX............................... By numerated FX currency Based on DCM futures

combinations (i.e., block size by swap

futures related) \222\ category \223\

By non-enumerated FX All trades may be

currency combinations treated as block trades

(i.e., non-futures \225\

related) \224\

Other Commodity.................. By economically-related Based on DCM futures

Appendix B to part 43 block size by swap

contract if the swap is category \227\

(1) futures related and

(2) the relevant futures

contract is subject to

DCM block trade rules

\226\

By economically-related No trades may be treated

Appendix B to part 43 as blocks \229\

contract if the swap is:

(1) futures related and

(2) the relevant futures

contract is not subject

to DCM block trade rules

\228\

By economically-related Appropriate minimum

Appendix B to part 43 block size equal to $25

contract if the swap is million \231\

(1) a listed natural gas

or electricity swap

contract and (2) the

relevant Appendix B

contract is not futures

related \230\

By swaps that are Based on DCM futures

economically related to block size by swap

the list of 18 contracts category \233\

listed in Sec.

43.6(b)(5)(ii) \232\

By Appendix D to part 43 All trades may be

commodity group, for treated as block trades

swaps not economically \235\

related to a contract

listed in Appendix B to

part 43 or to the list

of 18 contracts listed

in Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(ii)

\234\

---------------------------------------------------

Equity........................... All equity swaps \236\... No trades may be treated as blocks \237\

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. The 67-Percent Notional Amount Calculation for Determination of

Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes

The Commission proposed using a 67-percent notional amount

calculation to determine initial and post-initial appropriate minimum

block sizes for swaps in the interest rate and credit asset classes

pursuant to proposed Sec. Sec. 43.6(c)(1), 43.6(e)(1), and

43.6(f)(1).\238\ The Commission also proposed using a 67-percent

notional amount calculation to determine post-initial appropriate

minimum block sizes for swaps in the FX and other commodity asset

classes pursuant to Sec. 43.6(f)(1).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\217\ This post-initial implementation period would commence

after an initial period, lasting at least one year. Thereafter, the

Commission would determine appropriate minimum block sizes a minimum

of once annually. See proposed Sec. 43.6(f)(1).

\218\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(1).

\219\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(c)(1).

\220\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(f)(2).

\221\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(2).

\222\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i).

\223\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(e)(1).

\224\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(ii).

\225\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(e)(2).

\226\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(i).

\227\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(e)(1).

\228\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(i).

\229\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(e)(3).

\230\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(i).

\231\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(e)(3).

\232\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(ii).

\233\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(e)(1).

\234\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(iii) and the product types

groupings listed in proposed appendix D to part 43.

\235\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(e)(2).

\236\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(3).

\237\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(d).

\238\ Proposed Sec. 43.6(c)(1) describes the 67-percent

notional amount calculation. Proposed Sec. 43.6(e)(1) provides the

provisions relating to the methodology for determining appropriate

minimum block sizes during the initial period for swaps in the

interest rate and credit asset classes, inter alia.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The 67-percent notional amount calculation as proposed is a

methodology under which the Commission would: (Step 1) select all of

the publicly reportable swap transactions within a specific swap

category using a rolling three-year window of data beginning with a

minimum of one year's worth of data and adding one year of data for

each calculation until a total of three years of data is accumulated;

\239\ (step 2) convert to the same currency or units and use a

``trimmed data set''; \240\ (step 3) determine the sum of the notional

amounts of swaps in the trimmed data set; (step 4) multiply the sum of

the notional amount by 67 percent; (step 5) rank order the observations

by notional amount from least to greatest; (step 6) calculate the

cumulative sum of the observations until the cumulative sum is equal to

or greater than the 67-percent notional amount calculated in step 4;

(step 7) select the notional amount associated with that observation;

(step 8) round the notional amount of that observation to two

significant digits, or if the notional amount associated with that

observation is already significant to two digits, increase that

notional amount to the next highest rounding

[[Page 32892]]

point of two significant digits; \241\ and (step 9) set the appropriate

minimum block size at the amount calculated in step 8. An example of

how the Commission would apply this proposed methodology is set forth

in section VII of this final rule.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\239\ See note 85 supra for the definition of publicly

reportable swap transaction. Since the Commission proposed to

determine all appropriate minimum block sizes based on reliable data

for all publicly reportable swap transactions within a specific swap

category, the Commission does not view the fact that more than one

SDR may collect such data as raising any material concerns.

\240\ See proposed amendment to Sec. 43.2 and the discussion

infra in this section.

\241\ For example, if the observed notional amount is

$1,250,000, the amount should be increased to $1,300,000. This

adjustment is made to assure that at least 67 percent of the total

notional amount of transactions in a trimmed data set are publicly

disseminated in real time.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Twenty-eight commenters provided general comments on the resulting

proposed block sizes or on the general approach of using a notional

amount calculation. Out of the 28 commenters, 14 opposed the 67 percent

notional amount calculation and/or supported lower appropriate minimum

block sizes,\242\ 12 supported the 67 percent notional amount

calculation and/or supported higher appropriate minimum block

sizes,\243\ 1 commenter felt unable to comment on the 67 percent

notional amount calculation without actual swap data,\244\ and 1

commenter opposed the 67 percent notional calculation for the other

commodity asset class, but also felt that the 50 percent notional

calculation was too low for interest rates.\245\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\242\ Commenters in this category include AII, Barclays, CME,

Freddie Mac, ICAP Energy, ICAP North America, ICI, ISDA/SIFMA, MFA,

Morgan Stanley, Pierpont, SIFMA, Vanguard, WMBAA.

\243\ Commenters in this category include Arbor, AFR, Barnard,

Better Markets, CRT, Currenex, Javelin, Jefferies, ODEX, RJ O'Brien,

SDMA, Spring Trading.

\244\ CL-GFMA at 3.

\245\ CL-FIA at 2-3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Of the 14 commenters who opposed the 67 percent notional amount

calculation and/or supported lower appropriate minimum block sizes, two

commenters, CME and Barclays, opposed the notional amount calculation

generally, but not necessarily the resulting block sizes.\246\ CME

stated that the rule is arbitrary and unrelated to the explicit goals

of Dodd-Frank with respect to setting appropriate minimum block

sizes.\247\ Barclays stated that the calculation is not based on any

analysis of the impact that these thresholds will have on liquidity or

on the corresponding costs to market participants.\248\ The other

commenters in this group generally expressed concern that the

appropriate minimum block sizes were too large and would reduce

liquidity and/or disrupt markets. For example, AII stated that ``we

believe that if the CFTC utilizes the 67 percent notional calculation

required under the Proposed Rules, the CFTC will sacrifice liquidity

for certain swap products and alter the proper functioning of the

marketplace in the name of transparency.'' \249\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\246\ CL-CME at 2; CL-Barclays at 10.

\247\ CL-CME at 2.

\248\ CL-Barclays at 10.

\249\ CL-AII at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several of the commenters who opposed the 67 percent notional

amount calculation and/or supported lower appropriate minimum block

sizes specifically discussed the 50 percent notional amount

calculation. These commenters generally expressed concern that the 67

percent notional amount calculation resulted in appropriate minimum

block sizes that are too high and would result in reduced liquidity in

these markets. Freddie Mac and ICI expressly supported a 50 percent

notional amount calculation.\250\ Pierpont and WMBAA recommended a

notional amount calculation of no greater than 50 percent.\251\ ICAP

Energy and SIFMA recommended a notional amount calculation below 50

percent, but preferred a 50 percent notional amount calculation to a 67

percent notional amount calculation.\252\ AII and ICAP recommended not

using a notional amount calculation at all, but preferred a 50 percent

notional amount calculation to a 67 percent notional amount

calculation.\253\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\250\ CL-Freddie at 2; CL-ICI at 6-7.

\251\ CL-Pierpont at 3; CL-WMBAA at 3.

\252\ CL-ICAP Energy at 3; CL-SIFMA at 10.

\253\ CL-AII at 6; CL-ICAP Energy at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some of the commenters who opposed the 67 percent notional amount

calculation and/or supported lower appropriate minimum block sizes did

so conditionally. MFA preferred the 50 percent notional amount

calculation over the 67 percent primarily in the initial period--``if

swap categories are not properly distinguished, and the Commission

cannot ensure a calibration of the initial minimum block sizes to

current market conditions, we hesitate to endorse the 67 percent

notional amount calculation in the final rulemaking and prefer instead

that the Commission use a 50 percent notional amount calculation,

particularly in the initial period, with a phase-in to a 67 percent

notional amount calculation over time.'' \254\ Two other commenters

supported the 50 percent notional amount calculation, but in the

context of specific asset classes--Freddie Mac for the interest rate

asset class and ICAP Energy for the other commodity asset class ``for

year two and beyond.'' \255\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\254\ CL-MFA at 3-4.

\255\ CL-Freddie at 2; CL-ICAP Energy at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Of the 12 commenters who supported the 67 percent notional amount

calculation and/or higher appropriate minimum block sizes, several

argued that lower appropriate minimum block sizes were inconsistent

with congressional intent. Barnard and SDMA specifically stated that a

50 percent notional amount calculation would not constitute a ``vast

majority'' of swap transactions as intended by Congress.\256\ Moreover,

commenters also suggested that the 67 percent notional amount

calculation supported the statutory requirements of section 2(a)(13) of

the CEA as well as congressional intent. For example, Arbor stated that

``the 67% rule and the Market Depth test are consistent with

[c]ongressional [i]ntent, promotes transparency and trading of SEFs,

provides better market data, and is a conservative approach given the

market's size.'' \257\ CRT and Currenex stated that the 67 percent

notional amount calculation would achieve a proper balance between

market transparency and market liquidity.\258\ Jefferies stated that

the 67 percent notional amount calculation was consistent with

congressional intent.\259\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\256\ The ``guiding principle in setting appropriate block trade

levels [is that] the vast majority of swap transactions should be

exposed to the public market through exchange trading.''

Congressional Record--Senate, S5902, S5922 (July 15, 2010); CL-

Barnard at 3; CL-SDMA at 2.

\257\ CL-Arbor at 1.

\258\ CL-CRT at 1-2; CL-Currenex at 2.

\259\ CL-Jefferies at 1-2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Seven commenters expressed a preference for the 67 percent notional

amount calculation, but also supported another alternative.\260\ ODEX,

RJ O'Brien, and Spring Trading expressed support for the 67 percent

notional amount calculation, but also suggested that a higher notional

amount calculation would be preferable, particularly in the post-

initial period.\261\ AFR, Better Markets, Javelin, and SDMA all

recommended a 75 percent or higher notional amount calculation and a

market depth and market breadth test.\262\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\260\ CL-AFR at 8-9; CL-Better Markets at 7-8; CL-Spring Trading

at 2; CL-ODEX at 1; CL-RJ O'Brien at 1; CL-AFR at 8-9; CL-Better

Markets at 7-8; CL-Javelin at 2; CL-SDMA at 2.

\261\ CL-ODEX at 1; CL-RJ O'Brien at 1; CL-Spring Trading at 2.

\262\ CL-AFR at 8-9; CL-Better Markets at 7-8; CL-Javelin at 2;

CL-SDMA at 2. For a discussion of market depth and market breadth,

see infra note 271 and accompanying text.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A number of commenters also expressed concern regarding imposing

the proposed 67 percent notional amount calculation prior to analysis

of swap data collected by SDRs. AII recommended lowering or eliminating

block thresholds until complete data has been reported to SDRs so as

not to

[[Page 32893]]

impair market liquidity.\263\ Barclays recommended introducing block

levels that allow for empirical analysis of the transaction data and

sequentially increasing block sizes until such point as the desired

equilibrium between transparency and liquidity is reached.\264\ Better

Markets suggested transitioning to a market depth and market breadth

test after the Commission has collected a year of SDR data.\265\ GFMA

could not comment on the 67 percent notional amount calculation in the

absence of swap data.\266\ ICAP Energy stated that once post-

implementation swap data is obtained, then the Commission and industry

will be in better position to assess liquidity and propose block

levels.\267\ ICI stated that, for those asset classes where no data is

available, it is impossible to determine whether the Commission has

identified the most relevant criteria for swap categories.\268\ ISDA/

SIFMA suggested that for new interest rate swap products the Commission

should allow for block treatment until sufficient data is

available.\269\ Vanguard stated that block thresholds cannot be

established absent an adequate data source and time for

assessment.\270\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\263\ CL-AII at 6.

\264\ CL-Barclays at 11.

\265\ CL-Better Markets at 9-10.

\266\ CL-GFMA at 3.

\267\ CL-ICAP Energy at 2.

\268\ CL-ICI at 4.

\269\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 14.

\270\ CL-Vanguard at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the Further Block Proposal, the Commission specifically

requested comment regarding other potential methods for determining

appropriate minimum block thresholds. While the Commission received

numerous comments regarding the efficacy of a notional amount

calculation and the appropriate percentage to use in making such a

calculation, the Commission only received significant comments

regarding one other method. The Commission received a number of

comments regarding whether the Commission should use a market depth and

market breadth test, instead of the 67 percent notional amount

calculation methodology, to calculate the relevant initial minimum

block sizes and the post-initial minimum block sizes.\271\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\271\ Market depth and market breadth was proposed to be

calculated as follows: (step 1) Identify swap contracts with pre-

trade price transparency within a swap category; (step 2) calculate

the total executed notional volumes for each swap contract in the

set from step 1 and calculate the sum total for the swap category

over the look back period; (step 3) collect a market depth snapshot

of all of the bids and offers once each minute for the pre-trade

price transparency set of contracts identified in step 1; (step 4)

identify the four 30-minute periods that contain the highest amount

of executed notional volume each day for each contract of the pre-

trade price transparency set identified in step 1 and retain 120

observations related to each 30-minute period for each day of the

look-back period; (step 5) determine the average bid-ask spread over

the look-back period of one year by averaging the spreads observed

between the largest bid and executed offer for all the observations

identified in step 3; (step 6) for each of the 120 observations

retained in step 4, calculate the sum of the notional amount of all

orders collected from step 3 that fall within a range, calculate the

average of all of these observations for the look-back period and

divide by two; (step 7) to determine the trimmed market depth,

calculate the sum of the market depth determined in step 6 for all

swap contracts within a swap category; (step 8) to determine the

average trimmed market depth, use the executed notional volumes

determined in step 2 and calculate a notional volume-weighted

average of the notional amounts determined in step 6; (step 9) using

the calculations in steps 7 and 8, calculate the market breadth

based on the following formula: market breadth = averaged trimmed

market depth + (trimmed market depth - average trimmed market depth)

x .75; (step 10) set the appropriate minimum block size equal to the

lesser of the values from steps 8 and 9. 77 FR 15,482.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Many commenters expressed support for adopting the market depth

test \272\ and other commenters additionally supported utilizing the

market breadth test.\273\ Several commenters stated that such tests

would provide a more accurate depiction of overall liquidity in

specific markets, and thus would produce more appropriate minimum block

sizes.\274\ Other commenters stated that employing the tests would be

consistent with congressional intent expressed in the Dodd-Frank

Act.\275\ MFA, however, cautioned that current market depth may be an

unreliable indicator because it may vary over time and be subject to

manipulation.\276\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\272\ CL-CME at 2; CL-ODEX at 2; CL-Spring Trading at 2; CL-MFA

at 7; CL-FIA at 2.

\273\ CL-Arbor at 1; CL-AFR at 8-9; CL-Jeffries at 2; CL-SDMA at

3-6; CL-Javelin at 4-6; CL-RJ O'Brien at 1; CL-Better Markets at 9-

10; CL-CRT at 2; CL-FIA at 2.

\274\ CL-AFR at 9; CL-Spring Trading at 2; CL-FIA at 2; CL-SDMA

at 8.

\275\ CL-Arbor at 1; CL-CME at 2; CL-AFR at 3.

\276\ CL-MFA at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters supported using the market depth and market

breadth test in conjunction with the proposed notional amount

calculation methodology and proposed different approaches. Some

commenters recommended using the market depth test during the initial

period as a cross-check against the Commission's notional amount

calculations.\277\ SDMA and Javelin argued that a market depth and

market breadth analysis would justify adoption of a 75-percent notional

amount threshold in the initial period; \278\ AFR suggested, however,

that such a threshold could be set as a floor, with higher thresholds

available based on liquidity levels.\279\ Spring Trading suggested

using the market depth test on a quarterly basis to refine the 67-

percent threshold during the initial period.\280\ Jefferies recommended

using the test in the post-initial period to complement the 67-percent

notional amount calculation in the initial period for interest rate and

credit swaps.\281\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\277\ CL-MFA at 7; CL-SDMA at 7; CL-Spring Trading at 2.

\278\ CL-SDMA at 5; CL-Javelin at 2.

\279\ CL-AFR at 9.

\280\ CL-Spring Trading at 2.

\281\ CL-Jefferies at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some commenters noted the need for available and sufficient data to

adopt the market depth and market breadth tests. AFR commented that

sufficient data was already available based on information provided on

trading screens of trading venues.\282\ Other commenters, however,

stated that additional market data would allow the tests to produce a

more adequate snapshot of liquidity.\283\ For example, SDMA recommended

adopting the tests after obtaining six months of data; Vanguard and

Better Markets recommended a year.\284\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\282\ CL-AFR at 9.

\283\ CL-Jefferies at 2; CL-Javelin at 6; CL-Arbor at 1; CL-RJ

O'Brien at 1; CL-CRT at 2.

\284\ CL-Better Markets at 10; CL-SDMA at 7; CL-Vanguard at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received in regard to phasing-

in the appropriate minimum block size and the 67-percent notional

amount calculation, the Commission is adopting Sec. 43.6(e)(1) with

the following modifications. For the initial period, the Commission is

adopting the 50 percent notional amount calculation to determine

appropriate minimum block sizes in the interest rate swaps and credit

asset classes. The Commission is of the view that this approach

provides for a more gradual phase-in of minimum block sizes as

recommended by numerous commenters. Moreover, this will allow SDRs to

collect at least one year of reliable data for each swap category prior

to the application of the higher 67-percent notional amount calculation

to determine appropriate minimum block sizes in the post initial

period, which the Commission is adopting as discussed below.

For the post-initial period, the Commission is adopting Sec.

43.6(f)(1) as proposed. The 67-percent notional amount calculation is

intended to ensure that within a swap category, approximately two-

thirds of the sum total of all notional amounts are reported on a real-

time basis. This approach would ensure that market participants have a

timely view of a substantial portion of swap transaction and pricing

data to assist them in determining, inter alia, the competitive

[[Page 32894]]

price for swaps within a relevant swap category. The Commission

anticipates that enhanced price transparency would encourage market

participants to provide liquidity (e.g., through the posting of bids

and offers), particularly when transaction prices move away from the

competitive price. The Commission also anticipates that enhanced price

transparency would improve market integrity and price discovery, while

reducing information asymmetries enjoyed by market makers in

predominately opaque swap markets.\285\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\285\ The proposed calculation stands in contrast to the

proposed 95th percentile-based distribution test set out in the

Initial Proposal. See the discussion in section I.B. of the Further

Block Proposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the Commission's view, using the 67-percent notional amount

calculation in the post-initial period also would minimize the

potential impact of real-time public reporting on liquidity risk. The

Commission views this calculation methodology as an incremental

approach to achieve real-time price transparency in swaps markets. The

Commission believes that its methodology, in conjunction with the 50-

percent notional amount calculation during the initial period,

represents a tailored approach towards achieving the goal of subjecting

``a vast majority'' of swap transactions to real-time public

reporting.\286\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\286\ See note 41 supra. This phased-in approach seeks to

improve transparency while not having a negative impact on market

liquidity.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As noted above, CEA section 2(a)(13)(E)(iv) directs the Commission

to take into account whether the public disclosure of swap transaction

and pricing data ``will materially reduce market liquidity.'' \287\ If

market participants conclude that the Commission has set appropriate

minimum block sizes for a specific swap category in a way that will

materially reduce market liquidity, then those participants are

encouraged to submit data to support their conclusion. In addition,

through its own surveillance of swaps market activity, the Commission

may become aware that an appropriate minimum block size would reduce

market liquidity for a specific swap category.\288\ In response to

either a submission or its own surveillance of swaps market activity

the Commission may exercise its legal authority to take action by rule

or order to mitigate the potential effects on market liquidity with

respect to swaps in a particular swap category.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\287\ 7 U.S.C. 2(a)(13)(E)(iv).

\288\ The Commission received two comments supporting the

Commission's authority to set appropriate minimum block sizes

outside of the proposed annual look-back period. MFA argued that the

Commission's goal to balance transparency and liquidity would be

better achieved with the flexibility to adjust minimum block sizes

quickly to respond to material market changes. CL-MFA at 8. MFA

recommended that the Commission should have the authority to update

post-initial minimum block sizes in extraordinary circumstances and

on a case-by-case basis, based on SDR data that it receives for

individual or across multiple swap categories. Id. GFMA stated that

if the Commission establishes a notional calculation test, then it

should ensure that it has sufficient flexibility to amend minimum

block sizes. CL-GFMA at 4. GFMA recommended that the Commission

should be able to ``swiftly alter'' block trade levels to enable

some trading to be conducted in a newly illiquid market, without the

benefit of reference to a data set. Id. The Commission notes that

Sec. 43.6(f)(1) provides that the Commission shall update post-

initial appropriate minimum block levels ``[n]o less than once each

calendar year.'' Accordingly, the Commission notes that it has the

ability to adjust post-initial minimum block sizes under the types

of extraordinary circumstances raised by commenters.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With respect to the market depth and market breadth test, the

Commission is declining to adopt this approach to determine appropriate

minimum block sizes at this time. The Commission considers the test a

viable alternative to the notional amount calculation methodology, but

also recognizes several prerequisites to implementing such a test. For

example, the Commission would need to determine which contracts within

a swap category offer pre-trade price transparency--electronically

displayed and executable bids and offers as well as displayed available

volumes for execution. As noted by commenters, adequate market trading

data also must be available to collect a market depth snapshot of all

of the bids and offers for the pre-trade price transparency set of

applicable contracts. The Commission is also cognizant of MFA's

concerns regarding the potential for manipulation of market depth.

Given the time needed for trading infrastructure to develop and the

significant time and cost considerations involved in collecting such

data from SEFs and DCMs, the Commission will continue to examine the

merits of adopting the market depth and market breadth test.

The Commission is currently of the view that data is per se

reliable if it is collected by an SDR for an asset class after the

respective compliance date for such asset class as set forth in part 45

of the Commission's regulations or by other Commission action. The

Commission notes that SDRs have been collecting data pursuant to the

compliance dates for certain market participants and asset classes

since December 2012. DCMs and Swap Dealers (``SDs'') began reporting

swap transactions in the interest rate and credit default swap asset

classes on December 31, 2012.\289\ DCMs and SDs began reporting swap

transactions in the FX, equity, and other commodity asset classes on

February 28, 2013.\290\ Major Swap Participants (``MSPs'') began

reporting swap transactions in all five asset classes on February 28,

2013.\291\ Financial Entities began reporting swap transactions in the

interest rate and credit default swap asset classes on April 10,

2013.\292\ Financial Entities begin reporting swap transactions for

swaps executed starting April 10, 2013, in the FX, equity, and other

commodity asset classes on May 29, 2013.\293\ Non-SDs, non-MSPs, and

non-Financial Entities begin reporting swap transactions for swaps

executed starting April 10, 2013, in the interest rate and credit

default swap asset classes on July 1, 2013.\294\ Non-SDs, non-MSPs, and

non-Financial Entities begin reporting swap transactions for swaps

executed starting April 10, 2013, in the FX, equity, and other

commodity asset classes on August 19, 2013.\295\ Accordingly, the

Commission and SDRs will have one year of reliable data as of April 10,

2014.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\289\ See ``Commission Q & A--On the Start of Swap Data

Reporting'' (Oct. 9, 2012).

\290\ See ``No-Action Relief for Swap Dealers from Certain Swap

Data Reporting Requirements of Part 43, Part 45, and Part 46 of the

Commission's Regulations Due to Effects of Hurricane Sandy,''

Commission Letter No. 12-41 (Dec. 5, 2012).

\291\ See id.

\292\ See ``Time-Limited No-Action Relief for Swap

Counterparties that are not Swap Dealers or Major Swap Participants,

from Certain Swap Data Reporting Requirements of Parts 43, 45 and 46

of the Commission's Regulations,'' Commission Letter No. 13-10 (Apr.

9, 2013).

\293\ See id.

\294\ See id.

\295\ See id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that in response to either a submission or its

own surveillance of swaps market activity, the Commission may exercise

its legal authority to take action by rule or order to delay the

imposition of post-initial appropriate minimum block sizes,

particularly with respect to swap categories in the other commodity

asset class.

4. Data for Determination of Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes in the

Post-Initial Period

As referenced above in Sec. 43.6(f)(2), the Commission proposed

determining post-initial appropriate minimum block sizes utilizing a

three-year rolling window (beginning with a minimum of one year and

adding one year of data for each calculation until a total of three

years of data is accumulated) of swap transaction and pricing data.

The Commission received eight comments regarding the use of a

three-

[[Page 32895]]

year rolling window of data. AII believed it would be more prudent for

the Commission to base block trading thresholds on a shorter time

frame, using newer data. AII recommended that the Commission should

only use the highest of the three-year, one-year, or one-quarter data

collected in the determinations.\296\ GFMA stated that the three-year

rolling data set is unlikely to be sensitive enough to shorter term

changes in market liquidity and therefore risks setting block sizes

that do not reflect current market conditions.\297\ ICI believed that a

three-year window may not provide an appropriate data set to calculate

the block threshold, and encouraged the Commission to look at a one-

year set of data and a one-quarter set of data to determine whether the

calculation would produce more accurate results.\298\ ISDA/SIFMA

recommended a 6-month window for determining appropriate minimum block

sizes, as a three-year rolling window is over-inclusive, particularly

in CDS.\299\ Kinetix expressed concern that historical data may not be

indicative of current market conditions.\300\ MFA was concerned that

the three-year window would constrain the ability to shorten the look-

back period if material changes in market conditions warranted a

smaller data set, and recommended retaining the option to shorten the

look-back window for the observed data set.\301\ SIFMA believed that

block reassessments should look to data on swaps executed since the

previous reassessment, rather than from a three-year data window as

proposed by the Commission.\302\ Vanguard believed the assessment

should be made on the basis of data recorded over a rolling three-month

period for each swaps category.\303\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\296\ CL-AII at 11.

\297\ CL-GFMA at 4.

\298\ CL-ICI at 7-8.

\299\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 14.

\300\ CL-Kinetix at 1.

\301\ CL-MFA at 8.

\302\ CL-SIFMA at 6-7.

\303\ CL-Vanguard at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.6(f)(2) with modifications. Based upon the numerous

comments recommending a data set covering a shorter time frame, the

Commission will determine post-initial appropriate minimum block sizes

under Sec. 43.6(f)(2) utilizing a one-year window of swap transaction

and pricing data. This approach will allow the Commission to better

calibrate block thresholds to changes in market liquidity, while at the

same time providing enough data to smooth out fluctuations in data such

as those that may result from, for example, seasonality.

As referenced above, the Commission proposed to amend Sec. 43.2 of

the Commission's regulations to define the term ``trimmed data set'' as

a data set that has had extraordinarily large notional transactions

removed by transforming the data into a logarithm with a base of ten

(Log10), computing the mean, and excluding transactions that

are beyond four standard deviations above the mean. Proposed Sec.

43.6(c) uses this term in connection with the calculations that the

Commission would undertake in determining appropriate minimum block

sizes and cap sizes.

The Commission received five comments regarding the proposed use of

a trimmed data set. Three commenters supported the use of a trimmed

data set, but suggested alternative approaches. ISDA/SIFMA opposed the

proposed methodology and believed that it would establish a threshold

that is too high to exclude large transactions.\304\ Therefore, ISDA/

SIFMA recommended that the Commission look instead at the raw block

size (calculated based on all transactions in the relevant swap

category) and eliminate any trades more than five times larger than the

block threshold.\305\ ISDA/SIFMA alternatively recommended that the

Commission only exclude transactions that are three standard deviations

beyond the mean because the proposed methodology (excluding

transactions that are four standard deviations beyond the mean) would

capture large transactions that would otherwise skew the data.\306\ For

purposes of applying a market depth and market breadth test, Javelin

and SDMA recommended trimming each data set to focus only on bids or

offers at the ``current price''--the Commission would (1) determine the

mid-point of the bid-offer spread; (2) capture orders between the bid

and this value; and (3) capture orders between the offer and this

value.\307\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\304\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 14.

\305\ Id.

\306\ Id.

\307\ CL-Javelin at 5; CL-SDMA at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Two commenters opposed data trimming on the grounds that it is

irrelevant to the purpose of determining minimum block trade sizes. AFR

and Better Markets believed that trimming the data set would ultimately

skew minimum block size calculations, such that certain-sized trades

would be classified as block trades.\308\ Better Markets stated that

the Commission should disclose the discrepancies between using a

trimmed data set versus an unfiltered data set to calculate the block

size threshold because the public lacks the data to make this

determination on its own.\309\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\308\ CL-AFR at 7; CL-Better Markets at 9.

\309\ CL-Better Markets at 9.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.2 as proposed and applying the concept of a trimmed

data set in Sec. 43.6(c) as proposed. The Commission believes that

removing the largest transactions, but not the smallest transactions,

may provide a better data set for establishing the appropriate minimum

block size, given that the smallest transactions may reflect liquidity

available to offset large transactions. Moreover, in the context of

setting a block trade level (or large notional off-facility swap

level), a method to determine relatively large swap transactions should

be distinguished from a method to determine extraordinarily large

transactions; the latter may skew measures of the central tendency of

transaction size (i.e., transactions of usual size) away from a more

representative value of the center.\310\ Therefore, trimming the data

set increases the power of these statistical measures. In response to

the commenters who oppose data trimming, the Commission emphasizes that

trimming the data set is necessary to avoid the skewing of these

measures, which could lead to the establishment of inappropriately high

minimum block sizes.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\310\ A measure of central tendency, also known as a measure of

location, in a distribution is a single value that represents the

typical transaction size. Two such measures are the mean and the

median. For a general discussion of statistical methods, see e.g.,

Wilcox, R. R., Fundamentals of Modern Statistical Methods (Springer

2d ed. 2010), (2010).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

5. Methodology for Determining the Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes by

Asset Class

a. Interest Rate and Credit Default Swaps

As described above, the Commission proposed using a 67-percent

notional amount calculation to determine appropriate minimum block

sizes for swaps in the interest rate and credit asset classes in both

the initial and post-initial periods pursuant to Sec. Sec. 43.6(c)(1),

43.6(e)(1), and 43.6(f)(1). There was an exception to the use of the

67-percent notional amount calculation for the initial period in three

swap categories in the interest rate and credit asset classes which

contained less than 30 transactions that would meet the definition of

publicly reportable swap transaction: (1) Interest rate swap

[[Page 32896]]

category--major currency/30 years +; (2) interest rate swap category--

non-major currency/30 years +; and (3) CDScategory--350 bps +/6 to 8.5

years. If the Commission were to use the proposed 67 percent notional

calculation method, then two of the three swap categories would have

resulted in appropriate minimum block sizes higher than those proposed.

The remaining swap category contained no data. Accordingly, for these

three swap categories in the initial period, the Commission proposed

using the lowest appropriate minimum block size for their respective

asset classes based on the respective data set.\311\ In the interest

rate asset class, the swap category with the lowest block size was the

non-major currency/5 to 10 years, with an appropriate minimum block

size of $22 million (USD). In the credit asset class, the swap category

with the lowest block size was the category 350 bps +/8.5 to 12.5

years, with an appropriate minimum block size of $21 million (USD).

Hence, the appropriate minimum block size was proposed to be set at $22

million (USD) for the two interest rate swap categories with

insufficient data and at $21 million (USD) for the corresponding CDS

category.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\311\ 77 FR at 15480.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For interest rate swaps specifically, the Commission received eight

comments regarding the application of the 67 percent notional amount

calculation to determine initial and post-initial minimum block sizes.

Jefferies supported the Commission's proposal, stating that the 67

percent notional amount calculation was consistent with congressional

intent and observed liquidity.\312\ FIA did not explicitly support the

67 percent notional amount calculation, but stated that a 50 percent

notional amount calculation for interest rate swaps would be

significantly too low.\313\ Javelin, ODEX, SDMA, and Spring Trading all

recommended that the Commission maintain the proposed 67 percent

notional amount calculation or raise the threshold higher.\314\ Javelin

and SDMA both suggested a 75 percent notional amount calculation in

conjunction with a market breadth and market depth approach.\315\ Other

commenters, however, suggested lower values for the notional amount

calculation--Freddie recommended a 50 percent notional calculation in

the absence of more comprehensive data about liquidity and depth of

swaps markets.\316\ Pierpont commented that, for instances where one

counterparty to a swap is not a registered swap dealer, the Commission

should determine block levels based on a 25 percent notional amount

calculation.\317\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\312\ CL-Javelin at 1-2.

\313\ CL-FIA at 2.

\314\ CL-Javelin at 2; CL-ODEX at 1; CL-SDMA at 2; CL-Spring

Trading at 2.

\315\ CL-Javelin at 2; CL-SDMA at 2.

\316\ CL-Freddie at 2.

\317\ CL-Pierpont at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For credit default swaps, the Commission received four comments

regarding the application of the 67 percent notional amount calculation

to determine initial and post-initial minimum block sizes. Jefferies

supported the Commission's proposal, stating that the 67 percent

notional amount calculation was consistent with congressional intent

and observed liquidity.\318\ Javelin recommended that the Commission

maintain the proposed 67 percent notional amount calculation or raise

the threshold higher, to a 75 percent notional amount calculation.\319\

Four commenters supported a market depth and market breadth test for

CDS.\320\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\318\ CL-Javelin at 1-2.

\319\ CL-Javelin at 2.

\320\ CL-CRT at 1-2; CL-Javelin at 5-6; CL-Jefferies at 2; CL-

SDMA at 2-7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also received seven comments specifically regarding

the interest rate swaps and CDS data sets used for determining swap

categories and establishing appropriate minimum block thresholds in the

initial period. AII commented that the data for interest rate swaps and

CDS is no longer reflective of the market, nor is it reflective of the

market that will result once the Commission's regulations are

implemented in full, and urged the Commission not to rely on minimal

and outdated data.\321\ ICI stated that the historical data on which

the Commission relies may not be reflective of the swaps market once

the Dodd-Frank Act requirements are fully implemented.\322\ Freddie

stated that the interest rate data set may not be comprehensive enough

to form the basis of the proposed minimum block sizes, particularly

where the proposed post-initial appropriate minimum block sizes are

determined after transaction and pricing data has been collected for a

year.\323\ ICAP recommended that, if the Commission relies on

historical market data, then it should use data that is more current

and demonstrated to be representative of the market.\324\ MFA stated

that, given limitations related to the size, composition, and

timeliness of the data set that the Commission used for the initial

period, the Commission should calibrate initial minimum block sizes

against current market conditions.\325\ Vanguard stated that block

thresholds cannot be established absent an adequate data source and

time for assessment.\326\ WMBAA believed that, in basing rules on three

months of data from over two years ago, the Commission has failed to

``examine the relevant data and articulate a satisfactory explanation

for its action including a rational connection between the facts found

and the choices made'' as well as ``determine as best it can the

economic implications of the rule.'' \327\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\321\ CL-AII at 7.

\322\ CL-ICI at 5.

\323\ CL-Freddie at 2.

\324\ CL-ICAP at 8.

\325\ CL-MFA at 6-7.

\326\ CL-Vanguard at 7.

\327\ CL-WMBAA at 4-5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As described more fully above, in response to comments regarding

the data sets used for interest rate and credit default swaps, the use

of an incremental approach, and the comments regarding phasing and the

67-percent notional amount calculation regardless of asset class, the

Commission is adopting a phased-in approach to notional amount

calculation. The Commission is adopting Sec. 43.6(e)(1) and (f)(1) as

proposed, with modifications. In the initial period, the Commission is

adopting the 50-percent notional amount calculation to determine

appropriate minimum block sizes in the interest rate and credit asset

classes. The Commission believes that this approach provides for a more

gradual phase-in of minimum block sizes, as explained more fully

above.\328\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\328\ See supra Section II.B(3).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission did not receive any comments regarding the exception

to the 67 percent notional amount calculation for swap categories

containing fewer than 30 transactions. Accordingly, the Commission will

continue to apply this exception in instances where the a Interest Rate

or Credit swap category contains fewer than 30 transactions in

calculating appropriate minimum block thresholds for the initial

period.

b. Equity

The Commission proposed under Sec. 43.6(d) that all swaps in the

equity asset class would not qualify for treatment as a block trade or

large notional off-facility swap (i.e., these swaps would not be

subject to a reporting time delay under part 43). As noted above, the

Commission proposed this approach based on (1) the existence of a

highly liquid underlying cash market; (2) the absence of time delays

for reporting block trades in the underlying equity cash market; (3)

the

[[Page 32897]]

small relative size of the equity swaps market relative to the futures,

options and cash equity index markets; and (4) the Commission's goal to

protect the price discovery function of the underlying equity cash

market and futures market.

The Commission received six comments regarding swap categories in

the equity asset class. One commenter, AFR, felt that no block trade

treatment is appropriate as proposed for the equity asset class.\329\

Five other commenters recommended that the Commission treat equity

swaps similarly to the other asset classes and establish swap

categories based upon a range of criteria.\330\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\329\ CL-AFR at 6.

\330\ CL-AII at 9; CL-Barclays at 9; CL-ICI at; ISDA/SIFMA at

10-11; SIFMA at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

AII disagreed with the Commission's proposal that no equity swaps

should be treated as blocks and suggested harmonization with the SEC's

approach for large equity trades.\331\ Barclays also disagreed with

disallowing block levels for all equity swaps and recommended that the

equity asset class should be treated similarly to the other asset

classes, such that broad based indices should have separate block

levels based upon futures market levels.\332\ Barclays also suggested

that the Commission coordinate with the SEC in setting minimum block

levels.\333\ ICI recommended interim time delays for all equity swaps

until a closer study of data on equity swap transactions is completed,

due to potential differences in liquidity in the underlying equity cash

market.\334\ ISDA/SIFMA requested that the Commission reconsider its

proposal and suggested that the Commission establish block sizes based

on the consideration of total trading volume of swaps linked to the

relevant underlying index or basket of equity securities.\335\ SIFMA

stated that the Commission should establish appropriate minimum block

sizes for equity swaps based upon liquidity of the underlying

indices.\336\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\331\ CL-AII at 9.

\332\ CL-Barclays at 9.

\333\ Id.

\334\ CL-ICI at 5.

\335\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 10-11.

\336\ CL-SIFMA at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.6(d) as proposed. While a number of the commenters

pointed out differences in liquidity in the underlying equity indices

as a justification for swap categorization, these differences do not

alter the premises underlying the Commission's proposal. Even taking

these differences into account, there is still (1) a highly liquid

underlying cash market; and (2) a small equity swaps market relative to

the futures, options, and cash equity index markets. These

characteristics, combined with the fact that there are no time delays

for reporting block trades in the underlying equity cash market, makes

establishment of swap categories and block thresholds for equity swaps

inappropriate.\337\ Accordingly, the Commission is adopting Sec.

43.6(d) as proposed.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\337\ In the event that time delays are established for

reporting block trades in the underlying equity cash market, the

Commission may consider establishing swap categories and block

thresholds for equity swaps.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

c. FX

The Commission proposed to use different methodologies for the

initial and post-initial periods to determine appropriate minimum block

sizes for swaps categories in the FX asset class. The Commission's

proposed approach is premised on the absence of actual market data on

which to determine appropriate minimum block sizes in the initial

period. Subsection a. below includes a discussion of the initial period

methodology. Subsection ii. below includes a discussion of the post-

initial period methodology.

i. Initial Period Methodology

The Commission proposed under Sec. 43.6(e)(1) to set the

appropriate minimum block sizes for swaps in the FX asset class during

the initial period based on whether such swap is economically related

to a futures contract, i.e., a futures-related swap.\338\ For futures-

related swaps in the FX asset class, proposed Sec. 43.6(e)(1) provides

that the Commission would establish the appropriate minimum block sizes

based on the block trade size thresholds set by DCMs for economically-

related futures contracts.\339\ The Commission set forth the initial

appropriate minimum block sizes in proposed appendix F to part 43 of

the Commission's regulations.\340\ For non-futures related swaps in the

FX asset class in the initial period, the Commission proposed under

Sec. 43.6(e)(2) that all such swaps would qualify to be treated as

block trades or large notional off-facility swaps (i.e., these swaps

would be subject to a time delay under part 43 of the Commission's

regulations). The Commission expected that this provision, as provided,

only would apply to the most illiquid swaps.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\338\ See supra note 169.

\339\ For example, if swap A is economically related to futures

F, and futures F is subject to the block trade rules of a DCM that

applies at a notional amount of $1 million, then swap A would

qualify for treatment as a block trade or large notional off-

facility swap if the notional amount of swap A exceeds $1 million.

\340\ In situations when two or more DCMs offer for trading

futures contracts that are economically related, the Commission has

selected the lowest applicable non-zero futures block size as the

initial appropriate minimum block size. The Commission believes that

this approach would reduce the chance that the appropriate minimum

block size established by the Commission in the initial period would

have an unintended adverse effect on market liquidity for the

relevant swap category.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission received three comments specifically related to the

proposed methodology for determining appropriate minimum block sizes

for swap categories in the FX asset class during the initial period.

SDMA supported the Commission's proposed block trade thresholds for the

FX asset class.\341\ AII, however, urged the Commission to consider

removing the block trading threshold during the initial period for the

FX asset class, so as to allow the Commission to use SDR data to

properly evaluate the market.\342\ ICAP recommended an initial block

level of $10 million in the 1-month contract on a variety of FX non-

deliverable forward contracts.\343\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\341\ CL-SDMA at 2.

\342\ CL-AII at 3 n.10.

\343\ CL-ICAP at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission notes that, since the Further Block Proposal,

Treasury has issued a Final Determination, pursuant to sections

1a(47)(E)(i) and 1b of the CEA, that exempts FX swaps and FX forwards

from the definition of ``swap'' under the CEA. Therefore, the

requirements of section 2(a)(13) of the CEA would not apply to those

transactions, and such transactions would not be subject to part 43 of

the Commission's regulations.\344\ Nevertheless, section 1a(47)(E)(iii)

of the CEA provides that FX swaps and FX forwards transactions still

are not excluded from regulatory reporting requirements to an SDR.

Further, the Commission notes that Treasury's final determination

excludes FX swaps and FX forwards, but does not apply to FX options or

non-deliverable FX forwards. As such, FX instruments that are not

covered by Treasury's final determination are subject to part 43 of the

Commission's regulations.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\344\ See Determination of Foreign Exchange Swaps and Foreign

Exchange Forwards under the Commodity Exchange Act, 77 FR 69694,

Nov. 20, 2012.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.6(e)(1) and (2) as proposed. However, given the

changes to proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i), which significantly reduce the

number of swap categories, the Commission believes that this approach

encompasses the most liquid FX swaps and instruments, including all

[[Page 32898]]

super-major currency combinations, as well as all super-major and major

currency combinations. This approach further encompasses many important

super-major and non-major currency combinations, many of which already

have block trade size thresholds set by DCMs for economically-related

futures contracts.\345\ The Commission believes that this approach is

appropriate during the initial period in the absence of actual swap

data. The approach during the initial period would draw upon the

experience of DCMs in considering the potential impacts on liquidity

risk that enhanced transparency may cause in connection with futures

contract execution.\346\ The Commission understands that DCMs have set

block sizes primarily in consideration of the objectives of enhancing

pre-trade transparency and reducing liquidity risk.\347\ The Commission

notes that DCMs are required to set block sizes for futures in

compliance with relevant core principles (including Core Principle 9)

\348\ and Commission regulations.\349\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\345\ See Q18 of the Further Block Proposal, which sets forth an

alternative approach to proposed swap categories based on unique

currency combinations. 77 FR 15476.

\346\ The Commission notes further that DCMs historically have

had the appropriate incentive to balance these considerations

because they benefit from liquidity generally (i.e., commissions

from transaction volume in block and non-block trades provides DCMs

with their primary source of revenue).

\347\ The Commission is of the view that the pre-trade and post-

trade contexts are sufficiently similar such that policies directed

at balancing transparency and liquidity concerns in a pre-trade

context are relevant in considering what an appropriate balance is

in the post-trade context. In the pre-trade context, block sizes are

set near or at the point where a trader would be able to offset the

risk of an equally large transaction without bearing liquidity risk.

\348\ Core Principle 9 of section 5(d) of the CEA provides that

a DCM ``shall provide a competitive, open, and efficient market and

mechanism for executing transactions. . . . '' 7 U.S.C. 7(d)(9).

Current appendix B to part 38 of the Commission's regulations

provides that in order to maintain compliance with Core Principle 9,

DCMs allowing block trading ``should ensure that the block trading

does not operate in a manner that compromises the integrity of

prices or price discovery on the relevant market.'' See 17 CFR 38

app. B.

\349\ For example, section 40.6 of the Commission's regulations

include a process by which registered entities may certify rules or

rule amendments that establish or change block trade sizes for

futures contracts. See 17 CFR 40.6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Post-Initial Period Methodology

In the post-initial period, the Commission proposed under Sec.

43.6(f)(2) to utilize the 67 percent notional amount calculation to

determine appropriate minimum block sizes for swap categories in the FX

asset class. The Commission would group all publicly reportable swap

transactions in the FX asset class into their respective swap

categories and then apply the 67 percent notional amount calculation to

determine the appropriate minimum block sizes.

The Commission received three comments specific to the proposed

methodology for determining appropriate minimum block sizes for swap

categories in the FX asset class during the post-initial period. SDMA

supported the Commission's proposed block trade thresholds for the FX

asset class.\350\ Barclays and GFMA, however, expressed concern that

the 67 percent notional amount calculation was proposed without actual

swap data regarding the FX asset class.\351\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\350\ CL-SDMA at 2.

\351\ CL-Barclays at 10; CL-GFMA at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.6(f)(2) with the modification that only those swap

categories established in Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(i) will have minimum block

sizes set using this methodology in the post-initial period, while the

remainder of the swaps covered by Sec. 43.6(b)(4)(ii) will continue to

be treated as blocks. The Commission believes that applying the 67

percent notional amount calculation will ensure that the vast majority

of swap transactions are subject to real-time reporting.\352\ In

addition, applying the 67 percent notional amount calculation to all

five asset classes in the post-initial period provides a consistent,

bright-line rule regarding how appropriate minimum block thresholds

will be calculated, thus providing clarity to market participants

engaging in swap transactions. By allowing all swaps covered by Sec.

43.6(b)(4)(ii) to be treated as blocks, the Commission is being

conservative in its approach in potentially less liquid markets where

the impacts to market participants of inappropriate block trades could

be substantial. The Commission believes that this approach provides

additional time to analyze data in order to establish improved swap

categories as suggested by commenters.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\352\ See supra note 256.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

d. Other Commodity

The Commission proposed using different methodologies for the

initial and post-initial periods to determine appropriate minimum block

sizes for swaps categories in the other commodity asset class. The

proposed methodology for determining the appropriate minimum block

sizes in the initial period differs based on the three types of other

commodity swap categories: (1) Those swaps based on contracts listed in

appendix B to part 43 of the Commission's regulations; \353\ (2) swaps

that are economically related to certain futures contracts; \354\ and

(3) other swaps.\355\ With regards to (1), the Commission proposed

setting initial appropriate minimum block sizes for publicly reportable

swap transactions in which the underlying asset directly references or

is economically related to the natural gas or electricity swap

contracts listed in appendix B to part 43 of the Commission's

regulations.\356\ The proposed methodology for determining the

appropriate minimum block sizes for other commodity swaps in the post-

initial period follows the same methodology--the 67 percent notional

amount methodology--used for determining the post-initial appropriate

minimum block sizes in the interest rate, credit and FX asset classes.

A more detailed description of the methodologies during the initial and

post-initial periods, as well as the rules for the special treatment of

listed natural gas and electricity swaps are presented in the

subsections below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\353\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(i). The Commission is

adopting most of the proposed categories in this final rule, subject

to some modifications. See supra note 190 and accompanying text.

\354\ As proposed under Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(ii), these futures

contracts were: CME Cheese; CBOT Distillers' Dried Grain; CBOT Dow

Jones-UBS Commodity Index Excess Return; CBOT Ethanol; CME Frost

Index; CME Goldman Sachs Commodity Index (GSCI) (GSCI Excess Return

Index); NYMEX Gulf Coast Gasoline; Gulf Coast Sour Crude Oil; NYMEX

Gulf Coast Ultra Low Sulfur Diesel; CME Hurricane Index; CME

International Skimmed Milk Powder; NYMEX New York Harbor Ultra Low

Sulfur Diesel; CBOT Nonfarm Payroll; CME Rainfall Index; CME

Snowfall Index; CME Temperature Index; CME U.S. Dollar Cash Settled

Crude Palm Oil; and CME Wood Pulp. The Commission is adopting most

of the proposed categories in this final rule, subject to some

modifications. See supra note 187.

\355\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(iii).

\356\ The Commission notes that pursuant to proposed Sec.

43.6(b)(5)(i), each of the listed natural gas and electricity swap

contracts proposed to be listed in appendix B to part 43 would be

considered its own swap category. As discussed further above, the

Commission is adopting these categories in this final rule. See

supra Section II.A(4).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

i. Initial Period Methodology

With respect to swaps that reference or are economically related to

one of the futures contracts listed in appendix B to part 43 \357\ or

in Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(ii), the Commission proposed to set the appropriate

minimum block size based on the block sizes for related futures

[[Page 32899]]

contracts set by DCMs.\358\ Similar to its rationale with respect to

setting initial appropriate minimum block sizes for swaps in the FX

asset class, the Commission believed that this approach would utilize

the experience of DCMs in considering liquidity effects of enhancing

pre-trade transparency in setting block sizes for these contracts. For

swaps that reference or are economically related to a futures contract

listed in appendix B to part 43 that is not subject to a DCM block

trade rule, the Commission proposed in Sec. 43.6(e)(3) to disallow

treatment as a block trade or large notional off-facility swap. The

Commission based this approach on an inference that DCMs have not set

block trade rules for certain futures contracts because of the degree

of liquidity in those futures markets.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\357\ The futures contracts that are currently listed on

appendix B to part 43 are the 28 Enumerated Reference Contracts plus

Brent Crude Oil (ICE). The 13 electricity and natural gas swap

contracts that the Commission had proposed to add to appendix B to

part 43 of the Commission's regulations were not futures contracts.

As noted above, however, these contracts have been converted into

economically equivalent futures contracts that are listed on a DCM.

See supra note 176.

\358\ In situations when two or more DCMs offer for trading

futures contracts that are economically related, the Commission has

selected the lowest applicable non-zero futures block size among the

DCMs as the initial appropriate minimum block size. The Commission

believes that this approach would reduce the chance that the

appropriate minimum block size established by the Commission in the

initial period would have an unintended adverse effect on market

liquidity for the relevant swap category.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the initial period, the Commission proposed in Sec. 43.6(e)(2)

to treat all non-futures-related swaps \359\ in the other commodity

asset class as block trades or large notional off-facility swaps (i.e.,

these swaps would be subject to a reporting time delay under part 43,

irrespective of notional amount). The Commission believed that non-

futures-related swaps in the other commodity asset class generally have

lower liquidity in contrast to the more liquid interest rate, credit

and equity asset classes, as well as other commodity swaps that are

economically related to liquid futures contracts (i.e., those futures

contracts listed in appendix B to part 43).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\359\ These non-futures related swaps are not economically

related to one of the futures contracts listed in proposed appendix

B to part 43 or in proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(ii). See proposed Sec.

43.6(b)(5)(iii).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also proposed to amend appendix B to part 43 of the

Commission's regulations to add 13 natural gas and electricity swap

contracts, which the Commission previously has determined to be liquid

contracts serving a price discovery function,\360\ with each contract

serving as the basis for a swap category in the other commodity asset

class. The Commission further proposed to set the initial appropriate

minimum block size for each of these categories to $25 million (USD),

which would apply to natural gas and electricity swaps that reference

or are economically related to these natural gas and electricity swap

contracts.\361\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\360\ See supra Section II.A(4).

\361\ For swaps in which the underlying asset references or is

economically related to one of the natural gas or electricity swaps,

the Commission proposed to treat such natural gas and electricity

swaps differently than other publicly reportable swap transactions

in the other commodity asset class when setting the initial

appropriate minimum block sizes. The Commission recognized that

traders typically offset their positions in the natural gas and

electricity markets through trading OTC forward contracts, swaps,

plain vanilla options, non-standard options and other customized

arrangements since existing futures contracts listed on DCMs only

cover a limited number of electricity delivery points. The proposed

$25 million initial minimum block level corresponded to the level of

the interim and initial cap sizes. For a discussion of interim and

initial cap sizes, see supra section III.A of the Further Block

Proposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

SDMA expressed support for the proposed methodology for swaps in

the other commodity asset class.\362\ With respect to the swaps in

which the underlying asset references or is economically related to one

of the natural gas or electricity swaps listed in appendix B to part

43, EEI also expressed support for denominating the minimum block size

in U.S. dollars, rather than by a quantity such as Mwh.\363\ EEI argued

that denominating minimum block sizes in U.S. dollars would promote

standardization across the various trading hubs in the electricity and

natural gas markets.\364\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\362\ CL-SDMA at 2 n.1.

\363\ CL-EEI at 11 n. 29.

\364\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters, however, objected to certain aspects of the

proposed $25 million (USD) initial appropriate minimum block size. Two

commenters recommended setting the block sizes based on mmBtu/day and

MW/hr for natural gas and electricity swaps, respectively, rather than

setting the block sizes based on notional amount.\365\ ICAP Energy

commented in particular that adopting the latter approach would be

inappropriate, given that prices for such commodities fluctuate due to

peak season usage or delivery location.\366\ ICAP Energy also commented

that it was not clear as to how the notional value of swaps with

optionality would be calculated; calculating notional value based on

the premium of the option, for example, would adversely affect low-

premium options such as out-of-the-money calls and puts.\367\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\365\ CL-ICAP Energy at 4; CL-Barclays at 9.

\366\ CL-ICAP Energy at 4.

\367\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Two commenters opposed the proposed $25 million (USD) initial

minimum block size with respect to the swap categories for the

electricity swaps added to appendix B to part 43. ICAP Energy and EEI

argued that the proposed limits were too high given the relative

illiquidity of these markets.\368\ ICAP Energy recommended the

following minimum block sizes: PJM WH (on-peak and off-peak)--50 MW/hr;

SP-15 Financial Day-Ahead LMP (on-peak and off-peak)--30/MW/hr; Mid-C

Financial (on-peak and off-peak--30 MW/hr).\369\ EEI requested that the

Commission treat all electricity swaps transactions as block trades

during the initial period or, in the alternative, set the initial

minimum block size at no higher than $3 million.\370\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\368\ CL-ICAP Energy at 5; CL-EEI at 5.

\369\ CL-ICAP Energy at 5.

\370\ CL-EEI at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ICAP Energy and EEI also opposed the proposed $25 million initial

minimum block size with respect to the swap categories for the natural

gas swaps proposed to be added to appendix B to part 43. EEI requested

that the Commission treat all natural gas swaps transactions as block

trades during the initial period because of their relatively illiquid

markets.\371\ In the alternative, EEI recommended setting the initial

minimum block size at no higher than $3 million, which would

approximately equate the proposed initial block size for the Henry Hub

Natural Gas futures contract.\372\ ICAP Energy recommended setting the

initial minimum block size at 2500 mmBtu.\373\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\371\ CL-EEI at 8.

\372\ According to EEI, the proposed initial minimum block size

of 1,000,000 mmBtu for the Henry Hub Natural Gas futures contract is

approximately equal to a minimum block size of $3 million. EEI

Comment Letter at 8-9.

\373\ CL-ICAP Energy at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Parity Energy commented on the ambiguity of the term ``economically

related'' and requested clarification that natural gas swaps with

optionality that reference or are economically related to the Henry Hub

Natural Gas options would be subject to the initial minimum block size

proposed for that particular swap category (5,500,000 mmBtu), rather

than the block size for Henry Hub Natural Gas futures (1,000,000

mmBtu).\374\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\374\ CL-Parity at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Parity Energy opposed the proposed initial minimum block size of

100,000 bbl. to crude oil swaps with optionality as too low and

recommended that the Commission establish a separate initial minimum

block size for such swaps at 1,000,000 bbl., which would be consistent

with CME's minimum block size for Light Sweet Crude Oil options.\375\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\375\ Id. at 4-5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ICAP Energy commented that swaps that reference or are economically

[[Page 32900]]

related to the NYMEX New York Harbor RBOB Gasoline futures contract,

for which the Commission has not set an initial minimum block size

under proposed appendix F, should be subject to a block size that is

consistent with the one set by DCMs for the related futures

contract.\376\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\376\ CL-ICAP Energy at 1-2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission has considered the comments above regarding the

appropriate unit of measurement and initial appropriate minimum block

size for the natural gas and electricity swap categories in the other

commodity asset class. Based on those comments and the other commodity

swap categories adopted by the Commission in this final rule that are

based on the converted natural gas and electricity futures

contracts,\377\ the Commission is setting the appropriate minimum block

sizes for these categories in the initial period based on the block

sizes set by DCMs for these futures contracts. The Commission is

adopting this approach for several reasons. This approach is consistent

with the Commission's approach for swaps that reference or are

economically related to one of the futures contracts previously listed

in appendix B to part 43 or adopted Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(ii), which

utilizes the experience of DCMs in setting block sizes for these

contracts. The Commission also believes this approach is more

conservative than the proposed $25 million initial minimum block size,

which might adversely affect market liquidity for the electricity and

natural gas swaps markets. Further, this approach responds to comments

by setting the initial minimum block sizes based on underlying units,

rather than notional amount, and would be more appropriate to avoid

price fluctuations and to establish consistency with post-initial

calculation methodology.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\377\ See supra note 176.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to Parity Energy and consistent with the Commission's

adopted approach to swaps categories in the other commodity asset class

under Sec. 43.6(b)(5)(i)-(ii), the Commission is not establishing

initial appropriate minimum block sizes based on DCM block sizes for

swaps that reference or are economically related to the options

contracts listed in proposed appendix F.\378\ The Commission is

establishing initial appropriate minimum block size for such swaps

based on the adopted methodology for swaps with optionality, as

discussed further below.\379\ The notional size of swaps with

optionality in the initial period will be equal to the notional size of

the swap component without the optional component; accordingly, the

appropriate minimum block size will be based on the block sizes for

economically related futures contracts set by DCMs.\380\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\378\ See supra note 187 and accompanying text.

\379\ See infra Section II.C.

\380\ See infra Section II.B.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is otherwise adopting the rule generally as proposed

under Sec. 43.6(e) with respect to swaps in the other commodity asset

class, but also is updating initial appropriate minimum block sizes

proposed in appendix F, consistent with block sizes set by DCMs for the

relevant related futures contract.\381\ In response to ICAP Energy's

request, the Commission is also setting an initial minimum block size

for swaps that reference or are economically related to the NYMEX New

York Harbor RBOB Gasoline futures contract that is based on the DCM

block size set for that contract.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\381\ The Commission is also amending the initial minimum block

size for swaps that reference or are economically related to the

GSCI Excess Return Index, Dow Jones-UBS Commodity Index, Gulf Coast

Sour Crude Oil, and Palladium futures contract. The Commission is

also removing the initial minimum block size for swaps that

reference or are economically related to the Non-Farm Payroll,

International Skimmed Milk Powder, and Wood Pulp futures contracts,

as these contracts are no longer listed for trading. See supra note

187.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Post-Initial Period Methodology

In the post-initial period, the Commission provided in proposed

Sec. 43.6(f)(3) to determine appropriate minimum block sizes for swaps

in the other commodity asset class by using the 67-percent notional

amount calculation set forth in proposed Sec. 43.6(c)(1). The 67-

percent notional amount calculation would be applied to publicly

reportable swap transactions in each swap category observed during the

appropriate time period.

Several commenters opposed the 67-percent notional amount

calculation methodology for swaps in the other commodity asset class in

the post-initial period.\382\ CME and WMBAA characterized the proposed

methodology as overbroad and recommended a more tailored approach based

on the trading profiles of each particular market.\383\ Barclays

commented that the Commission has no data or evidence demonstrating

that such a notional amount would properly balance liquidity and

transparency considerations.\384\ ICAP Energy recommended a lower post-

initial notional amount--either 33 or 50 percent--that would account

for the illiquid nature of the electricity and natural gas basis swaps

market.\385\ Based on the non-standardized and bespoke nature of many

electricity and natural gas swap transactions, EEI recommended that the

Commission eliminate post-initial minimum block sizes for the

electricity and natural gas swap categories for the swaps added to

appendix B to part 43.\386\ EEI also recommended that the Commission

eliminate minimum post-initial block sizes for the electricity swap

category under appendix D.\387\ In the alternative, EEI recommended

that the Commission set the minimum block sizes for each of these

categories at no greater than $3 million.\388\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\382\ CL-Barclays at 10; CL-CME at 2, 4; CL-WMBAA at 2-3.

\383\ CL-CME at 4; CL-WMBAA at 2-3.

\384\ CL-Barclays at 10.

\385\ CL-ICAP Energy at 3.

\386\ CL-EEI at 8-9.

\387\ Id. at 9.

\388\ EEI requested that the Commission delay the adoption of

minimum block sizes for the swaps in these categories for at least

one year until it has obtained at least one year of data from an

SDR; in the interim, all relevant transactions would be eligible for

block trade treatment. CL-EEI at 11.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.6(f)(1) as proposed for swap categories in the other

commodity asset class for the post-initial period. The reasons stated

by the Commission above in support of this methodology in the post-

initial period also apply to swaps in this asset class. The Commission

believes that this methodology will ensure that the vast majority of

swap transactions are subject to real-time reporting.\389\ In addition,

applying the same post-initial notional amount calculation to the other

commodity asset class provides a consistent, bright-line rule regarding

how appropriate minimum block thresholds will be calculated, thus

providing clarity to market participants engaging in swap transactions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\389\ See note 41 supra.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

6. Special Provisions for the Determination of Appropriate Minimum

Block Sizes for Certain Types of Swaps

The Commission recognizes the complexity of the swaps market may

make it difficult to determine appropriate minimum block sizes for

particular types of swaps under the methodologies discussed above. For

that reason, the Commission proposed Sec. 43.6(h), which sets out a

series of special rules that apply to the determination of the

appropriate minimum block sizes for particular types of swaps. The

Commission proposed special rules with respect to: (a) Swaps with

optionality; (b) swaps with composite reference prices \390\; (c)

[[Page 32901]]

``physical commodity swaps'' \391\; (d) currency conversions; and (e)

successor currencies. Each of these special rules is discussed in the

subsections below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\390\ In the Further Block Proposal, the Commission proposed

amending Sec. 43.2 to define ``swaps with composite reference

prices'' as swaps based on reference prices composed of more than

one reference price that are in differing swap categories. The

Commission proposed to use this term in connection with the

establishment of a method through which parties to a swap

transaction can determine whether a component to their swap would

qualify the entire swap as a block trade or large notional off-

facility swap. The Commission is adopting this definition as

proposed.

\391\ In the Further Block Proposal, the Commission proposed to

amend Sec. 43.2 of the Commission's regulations by defining the

term ``physical commodity swap'' as a swap in the other commodity

asset class that is based on a tangible commodity. The Commission is

adopting this definition as proposed.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. Swaps With Optionality

A swap with optionality highlights special concerns in terms of

determining whether the notional size of such swap would be treated as

a block trade or large notional off-facility swap. Proposed Sec.

43.6(h)(1) addressed these concerns by providing that the notional size

of swaps with optionality would equal the notional size of the swap

component without the optional component. For example, a LIBOR 3-month

call swaption with a calculated notional size of $9 billion for the

swap component--regardless of option component, strike price, or the

appropriate delta factor--would have a notional size of $9 billion for

the purpose of determining whether the swap would qualify as a block

trade or large notional off-facility swap.\392\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\392\ In essence, this approach would assume a delta factor of

one with respect to the underlying swap for swaptions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission received two comments regarding proposed Sec.

43.6(h)(1). FIA stated that the approach failed to recognize potential

differences in liquidity between the swap and an underlying

swaption.\393\ FIA also pointed out that the Further Block Proposal did

not explicitly address how to handle combinations of options.\394\ With

respect to options transactions involving swaps in the electricity,

natural gas, and crude oil swap categories that are used to carry out

complex strategies, ICAP Energy recommended treating all such

transactions, as well as related swap hedges, as block trades.\395\

ICAP Energy cited the complex nature of these transactions and the

common involvement of an intermediary in carrying them out as reasons

for across-the-board treatment as block trades.\396\ ICAP Energy,

however, supported the proposed approach of adopting the block sizes

set by DCMs for natural gas and electricity outright options.\397\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\393\ CL-FIA at 3.

\394\ Id.

\395\ CL-ICAP Energy at 6.

\396\ Id.

\397\ CL-ICAP Energy at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.6(h)(1) as proposed. In response to ICAP Energy, the

Commission believes that the proposed approach provides an easily

calculable method for market participants to ascertain whether their

swaps with optionality features would qualify as a block trade or large

notional off-facility swap. The Commission is aware that this approach

does not take into account the risk profile of a swap with optionality

compared to that of a ``plain-vanilla swap,'' but believes that this

approach is reasonable to minimize complexity.

b. Swaps With Composite Reference Prices

Swaps with two or more reference prices (i.e., composite reference

prices) raise concerns as to which reference price market participants

should use to determine whether such swap qualifies as a block trade or

large notional off-facility swap.\398\ Proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(2)

provides that the parties to a swap transaction with composite

reference prices (i.e., two or more reference prices) may elect to

apply the lowest appropriate minimum block size applicable to any

component swap category. This provision also would apply to: (1)

Locational or grade-basis swaps that reflect differences between two or

more reference prices; and (2) swaps utilizing a reference price based

on weighted averages of component reference prices.\399\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\398\ Swaps with composite reference prices are composed of

reference prices that relate to one another based on the difference

between two or more underlying reference prices--for example, a

locational basis swap (e.g., a natural gas Rockies Basis swap) that

utilizes a reference price based on the difference between a price

of a commodity at one location (e.g., a Henry Hub index price) and a

price at another location (e.g., a Rock Mountains index price).

\399\ In other words, swaps with a composite reference price

composed of reference prices that relate to one another based on an

additive relationship. This term would include swaps that are priced

based on a weighted index of reference prices.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Under proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(2), market participants would need to

decompose their composite reference price swap transaction in order to

determine whether their swap would qualify as a block trade or large

notional off-facility swap. For example, assume that the appropriate

minimum block size for futures A-related swaps is $3 million, for

futures B-related swaps is $800,000, for futures C-related swaps is

$1.2 million and for futures D-related swaps is $1 million. If a swap

is based on a composite reference price that itself is based on the

weighted average of futures price A, futures price B, futures price C,

and futures price D (25% equal weightings for each), and the notional

size of the swap is $4 million (i.e., $1 million for each component

swap), then the swap would qualify as a block trade or large notional

off-facility swap based on the futures B-related swap appropriate

minimum block size.

The Commission received one comment regarding proposed Sec.

43.6(h)(2). AFR recommended that transactions that are composites of

swaps that are economically equivalents of futures contracts should be

disaggregated and separately priced for the purpose of determining

applicability of the block rules. AFR also recommended that the

Commission be vigilant of the use of composite swaps by counterparties

in order to ``evade the purpose of Section 727 and the Proposed

Rules.'' \400\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\400\ CL-AFR at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With respect to spread transactions, ICAP Energy recommended that

the minimum block size limit be based upon the lowest limit leg of the

transaction, in a manner consistent with the proposed approach to

setting minimum block size limits for the mixed asset swap class.\401\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\401\ CL-ICAP Energy at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Based upon the comments received, the Commission is adopting Sec.

43.6(h)(2) with certain clarifications based upon general concerns

expressed by commenters regarding the use of composite swaps to evade

minimum block sizes. The Commission is of the view that this rule

provides market participants with a straightforward and uncomplicated

way in which to determine whether such swap would qualify as a block

trade or large notional off-facility swap, but that a clarification is

needed to avoid the risk of evasion raised by commenters. In response

to ICAP Energy's comments, the Commission highlights to provide clarity

that ``any component swap category'' as used above in the methodology

applies to swaps with a single Unique Swap Identifier (``USI'') for the

combination of swaps identified with a single Unique Product Identifier

(``UPI'') and not to groups of different swaps each with separate USIs

transacted on or near the same time.\402\ Further, the reference to

``any component swap category'' does not

[[Page 32902]]

limit the application of this standard to those composite reference

swaps comprised of only multiple asset classes and instead should be

understood to apply more broadly to composite swaps of multiple asset

classes (i.e., a mixed asset swap), intra asset classes, and intra swap

category composite reference prices.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\402\ The real-time public reporting rules would apply to each

of the separate USIs as previously finalized in part 43. 17 CFR

45.5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

To provide further clarity and clarification in response to AFR's

comment, the Commission provides the following additional example of

determining whether a composite reference price swap transaction would

qualify as a block trade or large notional off-facility swap. For

example, assume that the appropriate minimum block size for swap

category E is $50 million and for swap category F is $200 million. If a

single swap transaction with a corresponding singular reporting

obligation is based on a composite reference price that itself is based

on the weighted average of (1) one component in swap category E; (2) a

second component in swap category E; and (3) a component in swap

category F (33% equal weightings for each), and the notional size of

the swap is $75 million (i.e., $25 million for each component swap),

then the swap would not qualify as a block trade or large notional off-

facility swap based on either the swap category E or the swap category

F appropriate minimum block size.

c. Physical Commodity Swaps

Block trade sizes for physical commodities are generally expressed

in terms of notional quantities (e.g., barrels, bushels, gallons,

metric tons, troy ounces, etc.). The Commission proposed a similar

convention for determining the appropriate minimum block sizes for

block trades and large notional off-facility swaps. In particular,

proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(3) provides that notional sizes for physical

commodity swaps shall be expressed in terms of notional quantities

using the notional unit measure utilized in the related futures

contract market or the predominant notional unit measure used to

determine notional quantities in the cash market for the relevant,

underlying physical commodity. This approach ensures that appropriate

minimum block size thresholds for physical commodities are not subject

to volatility introduced by fluctuating prices. This approach also

eliminates complications arising from converting a physical commodity

transaction in one currency into another currency to determine

qualification for treatment as a block trade or large notional off-

facility swap.

The Commission received no comments regarding proposed Sec.

43.6(h)(3). The Commission is adopting Sec. 43.6(h)(3) as proposed.

d. Currency Conversion

Under proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(4), the Commission provided that when

determining whether a swap transaction denominated in a currency other

than U.S. dollars qualifies as a block trade or large notional off-

facility swap, swap counterparties and registered entities may use a

currency exchange rate that is widely published within the preceding

two business days from the date of execution of the swap transaction in

order to determine such qualification. This proposed approach would

enable market participants to use a currency exchange rate that they

deem to be the most appropriate or easiest to obtain.

The Commission received no comments regarding proposed Sec.

43.6(h)(4). The Commission is adopting Sec. 43.6(h)(4) as proposed.

e. Successor Currencies

As noted above, the Commission proposed using currency as a

criterion to determine swap categories in the interest rate asset

class.\403\ The Commission also proposed to classify the euro (EUR) as

a super-major currency, among other currencies.\404\ Proposed Sec.

43.6(h)(5) provides that for currencies that succeed a super-major

currency, the appropriate currency classification for such currency

would be based on the corresponding nominal gross domestic product

(``GDP'') classification (in U.S. dollars) as determined in the most

recent World Bank World Development Indicator at the time of

succession. This proposed provision is intended to address the possible

removal of one or more of the 17 EU member states that use the

euro.\405\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\403\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(b)(1)(i) and the related

discussion in section II.B.1. of the Further Block Proposal.

\404\ See the proposed amendment to Sec. 43.2, defining

``super-major currencies.''

\405\ The 17 European Union member states that use the euro are:

Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece,

Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Malta, the Netherlands, Portugal,

Slovakia, Slovenia and Spain.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(5)(i)-(iii) further specifies the manner in

which the Commission would classify a successor currency for each

country that was once a part of the predecessor currency. Specifically,

the Commission proposes to use GDP to determine how to classify a

successor currency. For countries with a GDP greater than $2 trillion,

the Commission would classify the successor currency to be a super-

major currency.\406\ For countries with a GDP greater than $500 billion

but less than $2 trillion, the Commission would classify the successor

currency as a major currency.\407\ For nations with a GDP less than

$500 billion, the Commission would classify the successor currency as a

non-major currency.\408\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\406\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(6)(i).

\407\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(6)(ii).

\408\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(6)(iii).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission received no comments regarding proposed Sec.

43.6(h)(5). The Commission is adopting Sec. 43.6(h)(5) as proposed.

C. Procedural Provisions

1. Sec. 43.6(a) Commission Determination

The Commission proposed that it determine the appropriate minimum

block size for any swap listed on a SEF or DCM, and for large notional

off-facility swaps. Proposed Sec. 43.6(a) specifically provides that

the Commission would establish the appropriate minimum block sizes for

publicly reportable swap transactions based on the swap categories set

forth in proposed Sec. 43.6(b) in accordance with the provisions set

forth in proposed Sec. Sec. 43.6(c), (d), (e), (f) and (h), as

applicable.

The Commission received eight comments regarding determination of

appropriate minimum block sizes for swaps listed on a SEF or DCM. Four

commenters favored allowing SEFs and DCMs to set appropriate minimum

block sizes for the swaps they list. CME stated that the Commission

would be better served by retaining the ability to set block levels in

the private, bilateral swaps market and deferring to the expertise of

SEFs and DCMs to set the levels in their markets.\409\ ICAP suggested

that the Commission utilize the same approach as for the futures

markets, where futures exchanges set their own block sizes, and allow

SEFs to set block sizes since they have an incentive to provide as much

information about trading interest as possible without hurting

liquidity.\410\ Morgan Stanley suggested that the Commission could

allow DCMs and SEFs to set appropriate block sizes, subject to

Commission approval, as DCMs and SEFs would benefit from setting block

sizes in a way that maximizes liquidity.\411\ WMBAA stated that the

Commission should authorize SEFs to analyze ongoing swaps market

[[Page 32903]]

trading activity and trade data to determine uniform thresholds that

distinguish transactions that move markets from those that do not, and

work to ensure that block trade regimes for swaps executed on SEFs and

DCMs are as consistent as possible to avoid arbitrage.\412\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\409\ CL-CME at 3.

\410\ CL-ICAP at 5-6.

\411\ CL-Morgan Stanley at 3.

\412\ CL-WMBAA at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Four commenters supported the Commission's proposal that the

Commission set minimum block levels. Three of those commenters

recommended that SEFs and DCMs should not be able to set minimum block

thresholds above the level mandated by the Commission. Javelin asserted

that the CFTC should set block trade rules and not SEFs, so as to avoid

a race to the bottom that would harm transparency and threaten

competition.\413\ SIFMA stated that the Commission should set minimum

block trade size thresholds and argued that allowing SEFs and DCMs to

set a block size threshold above the minimum level mandated by the

Commission without guidance is inconsistent with the Commission's

statutory duty ``to specify the criteria for determining what

constitutes a large notional swap transaction (block trade) for

particular markets and contracts.'' \414\ AII also stated that SEFs or

DCMs should not have the ability to set block sizes for swaps at higher

levels than the appropriate minimum block sizes determined by the

Commission, as SEFs in particular have interests that may not be

aligned with buy-side firms and may not be incentivized to ensure that

market disruption is minimal.\415\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\413\ CL-Javelin at 6.

\414\ CL-SIFMA at 11-12.

\415\ CL-AII at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition, ICAP Energy stated that SEF block limits for futures

equivalent swap contracts should adjust automatically to meet DCM

contract limits adjustments between annual revisions of SEF block

limits, so that the Commission does not set SEF block levels at levels

higher than the block levels set by DCMs.

Based upon the comments received, the Commission is adopting Sec.

43.6(a) as proposed. The Commission agrees with the commenters who

recommended that appropriate minimum block thresholds for swaps be set

by the Commission, rather than SEFs or DCMs. The Commission concurs

with SIFMA that it has a statutory duty ``to specify the criteria for

determining what constitutes a large notional swap transaction (block

trade) for particular markets and contracts.'' \416\ The Commission

also agrees with Javelin that allowing SEFs and DCMs to set appropriate

minimum block thresholds could lead to a race to the bottom that would

harm transparency and reduce competition. In the Commission's view, the

Commission's approach is also the least burdensome from a cost-benefit

perspective because it significantly reduces the direct costs imposed

on registered entities. Moreover, while Sec. 43.6(a) states that the

Commission will determine minimum block sizes, as recommended by some

of the commenters, the Commission notes that SEFs and DCMs nonetheless

will have the discretion to set block sizes for swaps at levels that

are higher than the appropriate minimum block sizes determined by the

Commission.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\416\ CL-SIFMA at 11-12; 7 U.S.C. 2(a)(13)(E)(ii).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. 43.6(f)(4) and (5) Publication and Effective Date of Post-Initial

Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes

Proposed Sec. 43.6(f)(3) provided that the Commission would

publish the post-initial appropriate minimum block sizes on its Web

site. Proposed Sec. 43.6(f)(4) provided that these sizes would become

effective on the first day of the second month following the date of

publication. Per proposed Sec. 43.6(f)(1), the Commission would

publish updated post-initial appropriate minimum block sizes in the

same manner no less than once each calendar year.

Several commenters recommended that post-initial appropriate

minimum block sizes should be updated more frequently than on an annual

basis.\417\ ICI, AII and SIFMA recommended a quarterly or at least a

semi-annual calculation in order to account for changes in liquidity in

the market.\418\ Spring Trading and Vanguard recommended a quarterly

calculation that would allow block levels to be more responsive to the

market.\419\ Kinetix, however, recommended that calculations should be

carried out on a monthly basis.\420\ MFA suggested that the Commission

maintain the optional ability to update the minimum block size on a

more frequent basis as well as shorten the look-back window for the

relevant data set.\421\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\417\ CL-GFMA at 3.

\418\ CL-ICI at 7; CL-AII at 11; CL-SIFMA at 6-7.

\419\ CL-TeraExchange at 2; CL-Vanguard at 7.

\420\ CL-Kinetix at 2.

\421\ CL-MFA at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Some commenters asserted that the Commission should have the

authority to update appropriate minimum block sizes outside of the

proposed 1-year set look-back period. GFMA believed that the Commission

should have this authority, without reference to a data set, to respond

to a market that quickly becomes illiquid.\422\ MFA also supported

providing this authority, but believed that the Commission should

exercise this authority based on SDR data received for individual or

multiple swap categories.\423\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\422\ CL-GFMA at 4.

\423\ CL-MFA at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Based on its argument that block levels set by SEFs should not be

higher than those set by DCMs, ICAP Energy recommended allowing for

automatic adjustment to occur during the course of the year.\424\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\424\ CL-ICAP Energy at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is adopting the rule as proposed, with the one

modification that proposed Sec. 43.6(f)(3) and (4) will be adopted as

Sec. 43.6(f)(4) and (5). The rule as adopted only requires that the

Commission to update post-initial minimum block sizes at least once a

year and therefore does not preclude the Commission from doing so on a

more frequent basis. The Commission anticipates that it will examine

and re-calculate such block sizes at regular intervals, but also

acknowledges that the liquidity of a swap market may change

significantly outside of such intervals. Therefore, the Commission

reserves the authority to update minimum block sizes when warranted and

as necessary to respond to such circumstances. In response to GFMA and

MFA, the Commission agrees with MFA and emphasizes that in all

circumstances, minimum block sizes will be updated based on the

relevant market data received.

In response to ICAP Energy's recommendation, the Commission notes

that adopting such a requirement would potentially create minimum block

size re-alignment issues for SEFs, particularly during the initial

period for swaps in the other commodity class. Under this requirement,

SEFs would be de facto subject to a DCM's own business decisions, i.e.,

block trade size calculations that are based on trading that does not

occur on their own facility or platform. Further, the Commission has

noted that SEFs and DCMs may set minimum block sizes that are higher

than those prescribed by the Commission; this recommended requirement

would otherwise preclude such an ability in certain cases. Accordingly,

the Commission declines to adopt this requirement.

3. Sec. 43.6(g) Notification of Election

Proposed Sec. 43.6(g) set forth the election process through which

a qualifying swap transaction would be treated as a block trade or

large notional

[[Page 32904]]

off-facility swap, as applicable. Proposed Sec. 43.6(g)(1) would

establish a two-step notification process relating to block trades.

Proposed Sec. 43.6(g)(2) would establish the notification process

relating to large notional off-facility swaps.

Proposed Sec. 43.6(g)(1)(i) contained the first step in the two-

step notification process relating to block trades. In particular, the

parties to a publicly reportable swap transaction that has a notional

amount at or above the appropriate minimum block size would be required

to notify the SEF or DCM (pursuant to the rules of such SEF or DCM) of

their election to have their qualifying publicly reportable swap

transaction treated as a block trade.\425\ With respect to the second

step, proposed Sec. 43.6(g)(1)(ii) provided that the SEF or DCM that

receives an election notification would be required to notify the

relevant SDR of such block trade election when transmitting swap

transaction and pricing data to the SDR for public dissemination.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\425\ In order to qualify as a block trade, a swap must (1) be

listed on a registered SEF or DCM; (2) occur away from the

registered SEF's or DCM's trading system or platform and is executed

pursuant to its rules and procedures; and (3) have a notional or

principal amount at or above the appropriate minimum block size

applicable to such swap. See Sec. 43.2. By definition, a block

trade must occur away from the SEF or DCM's trading system or

platform and thus cannot be transacted on the SEF or DCM's trading

system or platform. Moreover, the swap must be at or above the

appropriate minimum block size at the time that it becomes a

publicly reportable swap transaction. Any swap that is executed on a

SEF or DCM's trading system or platform, regardless of whether it is

for a size at or above the appropriate minimum block size for such

swap, is not a block trade under this definition, and, thus, is

required to be publicly disseminated in real-time pursuant to Sec.

43.4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Similar to the first step set forth in proposed Sec. 43.6(g)(1),

proposed Sec. 43.6(g)(2) would provide, in part, that a reporting

party who executes an off-facility swap with a notional amount at or

above the applicable appropriate minimum block size would be required

to notify the relevant SDR of its election to treat such swap as a

large notional off-facility swap. This section provided further that

the reporting party would be required to notify the relevant SDR in

connection with the reporting party's transmission of swap transaction

and pricing data to the SDR pursuant to Sec. 43.3 of the Commission's

regulations.

The Commission received no comments regarding proposed Sec.

43.6(g). The Commission is adopting Sec. 43.6(g) as proposed.

4. Sec. 43.7 Delegation of Authority

Under proposed Sec. 43.7(a), the Commission would delegate the

authority to undertake certain Commission actions to the Director of

the Division of Market Oversight (``Director'') and to other employees

as designated by the Director from time to time. In particular, this

proposed delegation would grant to the Director the authority to

determine: (1) New swap categories as described in proposed Sec.

43.6(b); (2) post-initial appropriate minimum block sizes as described

in proposed Sec. 43.6(f); and (3) post-initial cap sizes as described

in the proposed amendments to Sec. 43.4(h)(2) of the Commission's

regulations.\426\ The purpose of the proposed delegation provision

would be to facilitate the Commission's ability to respond

expeditiously to ever-changing swap market and technological

conditions. The Commission is of the view that this delegation would

help ensure timely and accurate real-time public reporting of swap

transaction and pricing data and further ensure anonymity in connection

with the public reporting of such data. Proposed Sec. 43.7(b) provided

that the Director may submit to the Commission for its consideration

any matter that has been delegated pursuant to this authority. Proposed

Sec. 43.7(c) provided that the delegation to the Director would not

prevent the Commission, at its election, from exercising the delegated

authority.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\426\ See the discussion of post-initial cap sizes in section

III.B. infra. As noted above, the Commission proposed an amendment

to Sec. 43.2 to define the term ``cap size'' as the maximum limit

of the principal, notional amount of a swap that is publicly

disseminated. This term applies to the cap sizes determined in

accordance with the proposed amendments to Sec. 43.4(h) of the

Commission's regulations.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission received no comments regarding proposed Sec.

43.7(a) and therefore is adopting Sec. 43.7(a) as proposed.

5. Section 43.6(h)(6) Aggregation

Proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(6) would prohibit the aggregation of orders

for different trading accounts in order to satisfy the minimum block

size or cap size requirements, except that aggregation would be

permissible if done on a DCM or SEF by a person who: (i)(A) Is a CTA

registered pursuant to Section 4n of the CEA or exempt from such

registration under the Act, or a principal thereof, and who has

discretionary trading authority or directs client accounts, (B) is an

investment adviser who has discretionary trading authority or directs

client accounts and satisfies the criteria of Sec. 4.7(a)(2)(v) of

this chapter, or (C) is a foreign person who performs a similar role or

function as the persons described in (A) or (B) and is subject as such

to foreign regulation, and (ii) has more than $25 million in total

assets under management. In the Commission's view, such a prohibition

would be integral to ensuring the integrity of block trade principles

and preserving the basis for the anonymity associated with establishing

cap sizes.

The Commission received a number of comments on the proposed

aggregation rule, particularly as to the enumerated persons who would

otherwise be allowed to aggregate orders from different trading

accounts. Barnard supported the rule, noting that it would help ensure

that non-block transactions comply with the exchange trading

requirements and real-time reporting obligations, thereby increasing

transparency and price discovery, promoting market integrity, improving

efficiency and competitiveness in the swap markets, and ultimately

providing timely information to enable market participants to improve

their risk management practices.\427\ Barnard suggested that the

Commission add an additional requirement--that the ``block trade is

suitable for customers of such persons''--on the basis that such a

requirement would improve consistency in the rules applicable to swap

and futures markets.\428\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\427\ CL-Barnard at 2.

\428\ CL-Barnard at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ABC and CIEBA stated that qualified investment advisers who are not

CTAs should be able to aggregate block trade orders for different

trading accounts.\429\ Tradeweb commented that CTAs who trade on a SEF

should also be permitted to aggregate trades on behalf of their

customers for purposes of block trades.\430\ JP Morgan commented that

this rule appears to reflect a concern that private negotiation affords

less protection to unsophisticated investors than trading through the

central markets, and that since all entities that transact in the OTC

market already must be ECPs, the analogous concern about customer

protection in the swaps market is already addressed.\431\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\429\ CL-ABC/CIEBA at 3.

\430\ CL-Tradeweb at 5. Tradeweb's comment was received in

response to the Initial Proposal and not the Aggregation Proposed

Rule, the latter which allowed for CTAs to aggregate on SEFs. 75 FR

at 76174.

\431\ CL-JPM at 9, n.13.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ICI opposed the minimum assets under management requirement in

proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(6)(ii) and argued that the Commission did not

articulate a rationale or policy reason for this requirement.\432\ ICI

stated that while advisers to registered funds would typically meet the

asset requirement, advisers with less than the proposed

[[Page 32905]]

minimum would also have a valid need to engage in block trades on

behalf of the funds they manage.\433\ ICI further stated that no

relationship exists between the amount of assets managed and the

legitimacy of aggregating client orders. ICI also disagreed that an

investment adviser seeking to aggregate orders must satisfy the

criteria of Sec. 4.7(a)(2)(v) of the Commission's regulations.\434\

ICI suggested that the Commission only require an investment adviser to

be registered under Sec. 203 of the Investment Advisers Act of 1940 or

pursuant to the laws of any state without specifying a minimum

registration length or location for deposit of client assets.\435\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\432\ CL-ICI at 3.

\433\ Id.

\434\ Id. at 4. An investment adviser satisfies the criteria of

Sec. 4.7(a)(2)(v) if the investment adviser registers pursuant to

Sec. 203 of the Investment Advisers Act of 1940, or pursuant to the

laws of any state, and the investment adviser has been registered

and active for two years or provides security investment advice to

securities accounts which, in the aggregate, have total assets in

excess of $5,000,000 deposited at one or more registered securities

brokers. 17 CFR 4.7(a)(2)(v).

\435\ CL-ICI at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Two comments requested clarifications to the proposed rule. WMBAA

sought clarification that the Commission did not intend for the

Proposed Rule to prevent the use of ``work up'' in over-the-counter

swaps.\436\ WMBAA stated that a block size calculation should not be

performed until the work up period ends, but expressed concern that the

work up trades could be considered aggregation.\437\ SIFMA noted that

proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(6) does not restrict the aggregation prohibition

to ``block trades'' and, as a result, ``large notional off-exchange

swaps'' could be subject to the aggregation prohibition.\438\ SIFMA

requested that the Commission add language to clarify that the

aggregation prohibition does not apply to large notional off-exchange

swaps.\439\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\436\ CL-WMBAA at 2. During a work up transaction, a swap price

is agreed upon for trading and the trade is then reported to market

participants, who then have the opportunity to ``join the trade'' by

placing a firm bid or offer to buy or sell a particular quantity.

Id.

\437\ Id. at 2-3.

\438\ Id. at 3.

\439\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(6) as proposed. In response to the

comment by ABC and CIEBA, the Commission notes that qualified

investment advisers, who are not CTAs, are able to aggregate block

trade orders from different trading accounts. Under Sec.

43.6(h)(6)(i)(B) and (ii), investment advisers that satisfy the

criteria under Sec. 4.7(a)(2)(v) and have more than $25 million in

total assets under management are able to aggregate orders from

different accounts. The Commission also agrees that CTAs who trade on a

SEF should be permitted to aggregate customer trades, which would be

allowed under the rule as adopted, subject to the enumerated

conditions.

With respect to JP Morgan's comment, the Commission notes that

customers trading swaps on DCMs do not have to be ECPs. As discussed

further below, adopted Sec. 43.6(i)(1) allows non-ECP customers to be

parties to block trades through a qualifying CTA, investment adviser,

or similar foreign person.\440\ It is possible, therefore, that those

non-ECP DCM customers may not be aware if they received the best terms

for their individual swap transactions that are aggregated with other

transactions. Protection for such customers is therefore necessary, as

it is for unsophisticated customers in other markets.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\440\ See infra Section II.C(6).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to Barnard's suggested additional requirement,\441\ the

Commission acknowledges that the same or similar phrase appears in the

rules of many exchanges.\442\ The Commission, however, does not believe

that it is necessary to incorporate such specific language to the rule

because persons such as CTAs and investment advisers are already

subject to broad anti-fraud prohibitions under their governing

statutes.\443\ Moreover, adopted Sec. 43.6(i)(2), discussed further

below, also requires that any person transacting a block trade on

behalf of a customer receive prior written instruction or consent from

the customer.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\441\ CL-Barnard at 2.

\442\ See, e.g., Chicago Mercantile Exchange Rule 526(I). See

also Chicago Board of Trade Rule 526(I); Eris Exchange, LLC Rule

601(b)(10); and New York Mercantile Exchange, Inc. Rule 526(I).

\443\ See CEA section 4o (CTAs); Investment Advisors Act of 1940

section 206.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to ICI's opposition to the minimum asset threshold

under Sec. 43.6(h)(6)(ii), the Commission notes that this threshold

reflects common industry practice.\444\ CME, for example, has enforced

the $25 million threshold in its rules since September 2000.\445\ CME

has stated that the threshold ``is an effort to establish the

professionalism and sophistication of the registrant'' \446\ while also

expanding the number of CTAs and investment advisers eligible to

aggregate trades.\447\ The Commission believes that the $25 million

threshold is an appropriate requirement to ensure that persons allowed

to aggregate trades are appropriately sophisticated with these

transactions, while at the same time not excluding an unreasonable

number of CTAs, investment advisers, and similar foreign persons.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\444\ See, e.g., CME Rule 526. See also CBOE Futures Exchange

LLC Rule 415(a)(i); Chicago Board of Trade Rule 526; Eris Exchange,

LLC Rule 601(b)(10); ICE Futures U.S. Rule 4.07; NASDAQ OMX Futures

Exchange, Inc. Rule E23; New York Mercantile Exchange, Inc. Rule

526(I); NYSE Liffe US, LLC Rule 423; and OneChicago LLC Rule 417.

\445\ See CME Submission 00-99 (Sept. 21, 2000) (modifying CME

Rule 526 to reduce the threshold from $50,000,000 to $25,000,000).

CME originally planned to lower the threshold from $50,000,000 to

$5,000,000, but withdrew the submission and instead proposed to

lower the threshold to $25,000,000, based on customer suggestions.

See CME Submission 00-93 (Sept. 1, 2000); CME Submission 00-99 at 5-

6.

\446\ Id. at 6 (quoting letter addressed to Jean A. Webb,

Secretary of the Commission from John G. Gaine, President, Managed

Funds Association dated April 24, 2000 regarding ``Chicago

Mercantile Exchange new Proposed Rule 526'').

\447\ Id. at 4, 6-7. CME also stated in the filing that it

planned to readdress the threshold amount as it gained experience

with block trades, but has declined to modify the amount.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also disagrees with ICI's contention that investment

advisers should not be required to satisfy the criteria under Sec.

4.7(a)(2)(v), which requires an investment adviser to (1) be registered

and active as an investment adviser for two years or (2) provide

securities investment advice to securities accounts which, in the

aggregate, have total assets in excess of $5 million deposited at one

or more registered securities brokers.\448\ The Commission first

adopted provisions similar to current Sec. 4.7(a)(2)(v) in 1992 \449\

as objective indications that a person had the investment

sophistication and experience needed to evaluate the risks and benefits

of investing in commodity pools or a portfolio large enough to indicate

the same, along with the financial resources to withstand the

investment risks.\450\ In 2000,\451\ the Commission extended the same

criteria in current Sec. 4.7(a)(2)(v) to registered investment

advisers for the same reasons.\452\ The Commission believes that these

objective criteria, which demonstrate that an investment adviser

possesses the necessary investment expertise, should also apply with

respect to allowing such persons to aggregate client orders.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\448\ 17 CFR 4.7(a)(2)(v).

\449\ 57 FR 34853, 34854-55 (Aug. 7, 1992). The final rule

reduced the amount on deposit threshold to $5 million from the $10

million required by the proposed rule. See 57 FR 3148, 3152 (Jan.

28, 1992).

\450\ See 57 FR at 34854 (quoting 57 FR at 3152).

\451\ 65 FR 11253, 11257-58 (Mar. 2, 2000).

\452\ Id. at 11257 (quoting 57 FR at 3152).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to WMBAA, the Commission clarifies that the aggregation

prohibition will not affect the work up process. By definition, a block

trade occurs away from a DCM or

[[Page 32906]]

SEF.\453\ The trades that are part of the work up process will occur on

a DCM or SEF, and therefore are not block trades and are not subject to

the aggregation prohibition.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\453\ Section 43.2 defines a ``block trade'' as a publicly

reportable swap transaction that ``occurs away from the registered

swap execution facility's or designated contract market's trading

system or platform and is executed pursuant to the registered swap

execution facility's or designated contract market's rules and

procedures.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Finally, as to SIFMA's requested clarification, the Commission

notes that that it does intend to include large notional off-facility

swaps in the aggregation prohibition under Sec. 43.6(h)(6). The

appropriate minimum block size applies to both block trades and large

notional off-facility swaps,\454\ and thus the aggregation prohibition

should be applied to both types of transactions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\454\ Section 43.2 defines a ``large notional off facility

swap'' as having ``notional or principal amount at or above the

appropriate minimum block size.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

6. Section 43.6(i) Eligible Block Trade Participants

Proposed Sec. 43.6(i)(1) provided that parties to a block trade

must be ECPs, as defined under Section 1a(18) of the CEA and the

Commission's regulations. The proposed rule includes an exception to

the ECP requirement by providing that a DCM may allow (i) A CTA

registered pursuant to Section 4n of the CEA, or exempt from

registration under the CEA, or a principal thereof, who has

discretionary trading authority or directs client accounts, (ii) an

investment adviser who has discretionary trading authority or directs

client accounts and satisfies the criteria the criteria of 4.7(a)(2)(v0

of the Commission's regulations, or (iii) a foreign person who performs

a similar role or function to the persons described in (i) or (ii) and

is subject as such to foreign regulation, to transact block trades for

customers who are not ECPs, if such CTA, investment adviser or foreign

person has more than $25 million in total assets under management.

Proposed Sec. 43.6(i)(2) further provided that a person transacting a

block trade on behalf of a customer must receive prior written

instruction or consent from the customer to do so. Such instruction or

consent may be provided in a power of attorney or similar document, by

which the customer provides the person with discretionary trading

authority or the authority to direct the trading in the customer's

account.

As discussed above, similar comments regarding the exceptions to

the prohibitions against aggregation for certain persons were submitted

with respect to the exception to certain persons transacting blocks on

a DCM on behalf of non-ECPs. For example, ICI opposed the minimum

assets under management requirement in proposed Sec. Sec. 43.6(i)(1)

and similarly argued that the Commission did not articulate a rationale

or policy reason for this requirement.\455\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\455\ CL-ICI at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Specific comments were also received on proposed Sec.

43.6(i)(2).\456\ ICI requested a clarification that only a person

transacting a block trade on behalf of a customer who is not an ECP

must receive prior written instruction or consent.\457\ ICI argued that

written instruction or consent from an ECP is not necessary because

these customers can engage in block trades and that investment advisers

with discretionary trading authority registered with the SEC already

have the ability to aggregate orders on behalf of clients without

obtaining separate consent.\458\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\456\ CL-ICI at 5; CL-SIFMA at 1-2.

\457\ CL-ICI at 5.

\458\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

SIFMA commented that proposed Sec. 43.6(i)(2) may require asset

managers to obtain consent from each client for whom they will engage

in block trades.\459\ SIFMA contended that this requirement would be

costly and unnecessary, and that notice to the customers \460\ or a

general grant of investment discretion in the investment management

agreement, power of attorney, or similar document should be

sufficient.\461\ SIFMA further commented that proposed Sec. 43.6(i)(2)

is unlike rules governing DCMs in the futures context.\462\ SIFMA also

argued that DCM rules requiring consent for block trades only require

the direct members of the DCM to obtain consent from the members'

direct customers, not from the customers' customers. Additionally,

SIFMA contended that a client consent requirement does not apply to

advisers with respect to futures trades and should not apply to

advisers with respect to swaps trades.\463\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\459\ CL-SIFMA at 1.

\460\ Id. at 2.

\461\ Id.

\462\ Id. at 1 n.4.

\463\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.6(i) as proposed. The Commission declines to adopt

ICI's clarification and notes that Sec. 43.6(i)(2) is intended to

ensure that all customers of CTAs, investment advisers, and similar

foreign persons, whether the customers are ECPs or not, are fully

informed of the use of block trades on their behalf.

The Commission also disagrees with SIFMA's contention regarding the

burdens of obtaining consent. This burden consent will be minimal

because Sec. 43.6(i)(2) states that the instruction or consent may be

provided through a power of attorney or similar document that provides

discretionary trading authority or the authority to direct trading in

the account. The consent may therefore be included in existing and

future customer agreements. The Commission further disagrees that a

general grant of investment discretion or notice to the customer should

satisfy Sec. 43.6(i)(2). A customer's written instruction or consent

is necessary because a customer potentially may not receive the best

terms for an individual swap transaction that is part of an

aggregation. The written instruction or consent makes the customer

aware that block trades may be used on its behalf, allowing the

customer to decide whether to allow these transactions.

The Commission notes that a similar consent requirement was

included in the Commission's proposed DCM rule.\464\ The Commission

believes that the customer protection functions of the consent

requirement apply, regardless of the degree of separation between the

customer and the DCM or SEF. As discussed above, the consent

requirement ensures that customers are informed of the use of block

trades for their accounts. If a CTA, an investment adviser, or a

similar foreign person plans to aggregate customer orders for block

trades, then the customers must have the opportunity to evaluate

whether the customer agrees to the use of aggregation, as evidenced by

the written instruction or consent, regardless of whether the CTA,

investment adviser, or similar foreign person is a direct member of a

DCM or SEF.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\464\ Core Principles and Other Requirements for Designated

Contract Markets. 75 FR 80572, Dec. 22, 2010. The final DCM rule,

however, did not include this proposed regulation which was

promulgated, along with various other regulations, to implement Core

Principle 9. As noted in the final rule, given the number of

comments received under Core Principle 9, the Commission believed

that additional time was appropriate before finalizing the proposed

rules for Core Principle 9; it expects to consider the proposed

rules at a future date. 77 FR 36643, June 19, 2012.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

III. Anonymity Protections for the Public Dissemination of Swap

Transaction and Pricing Data

A. Policy Goals

Section 2(a)(13)(E)(i) of the CEA directs the Commission to protect

the identities of counterparties to swaps subject to the mandatory

clearing requirement, swaps excepted from the

[[Page 32907]]

mandatory clearing requirement, and voluntarily cleared swaps.

Similarly, section 2(a)(13)(C)(iii) of the CEA requires that the

Commission prescribe rules that maintain the anonymity of business

transactions and market positions of the counterparties to an uncleared

swap.\465\ In proposed amendments to Sec. 43.4(h) and 43.4(d)(4), as

described further below, the Commission proposed measures to protect

the identities of counterparties and to maintain the anonymity of their

business transactions and market positions in connection with the

public dissemination of publicly reportable swap transactions. The

Commission proposed to follow the practices used by most federal

agencies when releasing to the public company-specific information--by

removing obvious identifiers, limiting geographic detail (e.g.,

disclosing general, non-specific geographical information about the

delivery and pricing points) and masking high-risk variables by

truncating extreme values for certain variables (e.g., capping notional

values).\466\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\465\ This provision does not cover swaps that are ``determined

to be required to be cleared but are not cleared.'' See 7 U.S.C.

2(a)(13)(C)(iv).

\466\ The Commission is following the necessary procedures for

releasing microdata files as outlined by the Federal Committee on

Statistical Methodology: (i) Removal of all direct personal and

institutional identifiers, (ii) limiting geographic detail, and

(iii) top-coding high-risk variables which are continuous. See

Federal Committee on Statistical Methodology, Report on Statistical

Disclosure Limitation Methodology 94 (Statistical Policy Working

Paper 22, 2d ed. 2005), http://www.fcsm.gov/working-papers/totalreport.pdf. The report was originally prepared by the

Subcommittee on Disclosure Limitation Methodology in 1994 and was

revised by the Confidentiality and Data Access Committee in 2005.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

B. Establishing Notional Cap Sizes for Swap Transaction and Pricing

Data to Be Publicly Disseminated in Real-Time

1. Policy Goals for Establishing Notional Cap Sizes

In addition to establishing appropriate minimum block sizes, the

Commission also proposed to amend Sec. 43.4(h) to establish cap sizes

for notional and principal amounts that would mask the total size of a

swap transaction if it equals or exceeds the appropriate minimum block

size for a given swap category. For example, if the block size for a

category of interest rate swaps was $1 billion, the cap size was $1.5

billion, and the actual transaction had a notional value of $2 billion,

then this swap transaction would be publicly reported with a delay and

with a notional value of $1.5+ billion.

The proposed cap size provisions are consistent with the two

relevant statutory requirements in section 2(a)(13) of the CEA. First,

the cap size provisions would help protect the anonymity of

counterparties' market positions and business transactions as required

in section 2(a)(13)(C)(iii) of the CEA.\467\ Second, the masking of

extraordinarily large positions also takes into consideration the

requirement under section 2(a)(13)(E)(iv) that the Commission take into

account the impact that real-time public reporting could have in

reducing market liquidity.\468\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\467\ See 7 U.S.C. 2(a)(13)(C)(iii).

\468\ See 7 U.S.C. 2(a)(13)(E)(iv).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. Proposed Amendments Related to Cap Sizes--Sec. 43.2 Definitions and

Sec. 43.4 Swap Transaction and Pricing Data To Be Publicly

Disseminated in Real-Time

The Commission proposed an amendment to Sec. 43.2 to define the

term ``cap size'' as the maximum limit of the principal, notional

amount of a swap that is publicly disseminated. This term applies to

the cap sizes determined in accordance with the proposed amendments to

Sec. 43.4(h) of the Commission's regulations.

Section 43.4(h) of the Commission's regulations currently

establishes interim cap sizes for rounded notional or principal amounts

for all publicly reportable swap transactions. In the Real-Time

Reporting Final Rule, the Commission finalized Sec. 43.4(h) to provide

that the notional or principal amounts shall be capped in a manner that

adjusts in accordance with the appropriate minimum block size that

corresponds to a publicly reportable swap transaction.\469\ Section

43.4(h) further provides that if no appropriate minimum block size

exists, then the cap size on the notional or principal amount shall

correspond to the interim cap sizes that the Commission has established

for the five asset classes.\470\ In Sec. 43.4(h) and as described in

the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule, the Commission notes that SDRs will

apply interim cap sizes until such time as appropriate minimum block

sizes are established.\471\ The Commission continues to believe that

the interim cap sizes for each swap category should correspond with the

applicable appropriate minimum block size, to the extent that an

appropriate minimum block size exists.\472\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\469\ See 77 FR 1247.

\470\ Sections 43.4(h)(1)-(5) established the following interim

cap sizes for the corresponding asset classes: (1) Interest rate

swaps at $250 million for tenors greater than zero up to and

including two years, $100 million for tenors greater than two years

up to and including 10 years, and $75 million for tenors greater

than 10 years; (2) credit swaps at $100 million; (3) equity swaps at

$250 million; (4) foreign exchange swaps at $250 million; and (5)

other commodity swaps at $25 million.

\471\ See 77 FR 1215.

\472\ Leading industry trade associations agree that cap sizes

are an appropriate mechanism to ensure that price discovery remains

intact for block trades, while also protecting post-block trade risk

management needs from being anticipated by other market

participants. See ISDA and SIFMA, Block Trade Reporting for Over-

the-Counter Derivatives Market, Jan. 18, 2011.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission proposed to amend Sec. 43.4(h) both to establish

initial cap sizes for each swap category within the five asset classes

and also to delineate a process for the post-initial period through

which the Commission would establish post-initial cap sizes for each

swap category.\473\ The Commission also proposed changing the term

``interim'' as it is used in Sec. 43.4(h) in the Real-Time Reporting

Rule to ``initial'' in order to correspond with the description of the

initial period in proposed Sec. 43.6(e).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\473\ The Commission does not intend the provisions in this

final rule to prevent a SEF or DCM from sharing the exact notional

amounts of a swaps transaction on or pursuant to the rules of its

platform with market participants on such platform irrespective of

the cap sizes set by the Commission. To share the exact notional

amounts of swaps, the SEF or DCM must comply with Sec.

43.3(b)(3)(i) of the Commission's regulations. See 77 FR 1245.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. Initial Cap Sizes

In the initial period,\474\ proposed Sec. 43.4(h)(1) would set the

cap size for each swap category as the greater of the interim cap sizes

in all five asset classes set forth in the Real-Time Reporting Final

Rule (Sec. 43.4(h)(1)-(5)) or the appropriate minimum block size for

the respective swap category.\475\ If such appropriate minimum block

size does not exist, then the cap sizes shall be set at the interim cap

sizes set forth in the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule (Sec.

43.4(h)(1)-(5)).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\474\ The initial period is the period prior to the effective

date of a Commission determination to establish applicable post-

initial cap sizes. See proposed Sec. 43.4(h)(1).

\475\ See 77 FR 1249.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For the initial period, AII and ISDA/SIFMA argued that the cap size

should be the lower of block size and the interim cap size in Sec.

43.4(h)(1).\476\ EEI stated that the cap size of $25 million for both

the electricity swap contracts proposed to be added to appendix B and

the electricity swaps in the other commodity swap categories in

appendix D, which would be based on the interim cap sizes established

by the Commission in the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule, is too high.

EEI instead recommended both a fixed cap size and a minimum block size

of $3 million.\477\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\476\ CL-AII at 12; CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 15.

\477\ CL-EEI at 11-12.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting

[[Page 32908]]

Sec. 43.4(h)(1) as proposed. EEI recommends a lower cap size for

specific swap categories--particularly electricity swaps--but it does

not recommend any change to the proposed interplay between cap size and

appropriate minimum block size during the interim period. The cap size

for the interim period was established by the Real-Time Reporting Final

Rule, and the Commission considered the appropriate level for these cap

sizes at that time. The Commission did not propose altering the interim

cap size in the Further Block Proposal, and thus did not receive

comments regarding altering the interim cap size beyond that of EEI.

The Commission does not believe that altering the interim cap size

would be appropriate under such circumstances.

AII and ISDA/SIFMA recommended that the cap size be set as the

lower of the appropriate minimum block size and the interim cap sizes

set forth in the Real-Time Reporting Rule. The Commission, however,

disagrees with this view of the relationship between block thresholds

and cap sizes. All of the information regarding a block trade is

reported to the market at the end of the block time delay. Cap sizes,

on the other hand, are never expressed to the market. Because this

information is not reported to the market in real-time, nor reported to

the market at all, the Commission believes that cap sizes should be set

at a higher level than block sizes, in order to minimize the amount of

information that is never publicly disseminated. Accordingly, the

Commission is adopting Sec. 43.4(h)(1) as proposed.

b. Post-Initial Cap Sizes and the 75-Percent Notional Amount

Calculation

Pursuant to proposed Sec. 43.4(h)(2)(ii), the Commission would use

a 75 percent notional amount calculation, as proposed in Sec.

43.6(c)(2), to determine the appropriate post-initial cap sizes for all

swap categories for the purpose of reporting block trades or large

notional off-facility swaps of significant size.\478\ This calculation

methodology would be different from the 67 percent notional amount

calculation methodology that the Commission proposed in Sec.

43.6(c)(1), which would be used to determine appropriate minimum block

sizes.\479\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\478\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(c)(2).

\479\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(c)(2).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For the 75 percent notional amount calculation, the Commission

would determine the appropriate cap size through the following process,

pursuant to proposed Sec. 43.6(c)(2): (step 1) select all of the

publicly reportable swap transactions within a specific swap category

using a rolling three-year window of data beginning with a minimum of

one year's worth of data and adding one year of data for each

calculation until a total of three years of data is accumulated; (step

2) convert to the same currency or units and use a trimmed data set;

(step 3) determine the sum of the notional amounts of swaps in the

trimmed data set; (step 4) multiply the sum of the notional amount by

75 percent; (step 5) rank order the observations by notional amount

from least to greatest; (step 6) calculate the cumulative sum of the

observations until the cumulative sum is equal to or greater than the

75 percent notional amount calculated in step 4; (step 7) select the

notional amount associated with that observation; (step 8) round the

notional amount of that observation to two significant digits, or if

the notional amount associated with that observation is already

significant to two digits, increase that notional amount to the next

highest rounding point of two significant digits; and (step 9) set the

appropriate minimum block size at the amount calculated in step 8.

Consistent with the Commission's proposed process to determine the

appropriate post-initial minimum block sizes, proposed Sec. 43.4(h)(3)

provided that the Commission would publish post-initial cap sizes on

its Web site. Proposed Sec. 43.4(h)(4) provided that unless otherwise

indicated on the Commission's Web site, the post-initial cap sizes

would become effective on the first day of the second month following

the date of publication.

The Commission received 10 comments regarding the 75 percent

notional amount calculation for determining post-initial cap sizes. One

commenter, Javelin, supported the 75 percent notional amount

calculation and stated that it was consistent with the minimum block

size threshold established by the Commission.\480\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\480\ CL-Javelin at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Seven commenters, however, recommended that the Commission set

post-initial cap sizes matching the post-initial minimum block size

thresholds established by the Commission. AII recommended setting the

post-initial cap size for each swap category at the same level as the

post-initial block size threshold and states that the 75 percent

notional amount calculation is far too high.\481\ GFMA similarly stated

that the same rationale should apply to cap and block sizes, as both

have potential negative impacts on liquidity.\482\ ICI stated that the

75 percent notional amount would be too high for determining cap size

because the lack of depth and liquidity in the swaps market could cause

public reporting of block sizes to reveal identities, business

transactions, and market positions of participants, and recommended a

67 percent notional amount calculation for determining cap size in the

post-initial period.\483\ ISDA/SIFMA also stated that the added

transparency from reporting transaction sizes between 67 percent and 75

percent would not outweigh the harm to liquidity from additional

disclosure, and urges the Commission to ensure that the post-initial

cap size is always equal to the relevant block size.\484\ MFA commented

that it is unnecessary for the Commission to establish cap sizes that

differ from minimum block sizes as there is not a meaningful

transparency benefit that would outweigh the resource burdens on the

Commission, SDRs, SEFs, and other market participants.\485\ SIFMA

recommended that the Commission should set the notional cap size at the

block threshold, as the added public dissemination could harm liquidity

in the same manner that a higher block trade size threshold might.\486\

Vanguard believes that it is essential that the cap match the block

trade threshold, as to do otherwise would compromise the liquidity

protections afforded by the nuanced assessment of block trade

thresholds.\487\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\481\ CL-AII at 12.

\482\ CL-GFMA at 5.

\483\ CL-ICI at 8.

\484\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 15.

\485\ CL-MFA at 8-9.

\486\ CL-SIFMA at 12.

\487\ CL-Vanguard at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Two other commenters suggested alterations of the Commission's

proposed cap sizes. Barclays recommended that the post-initial period

cap sizes be introduced at more nuanced levels that reflect the

differences between product's traded volumes.\488\ EEI recommended a

much lower fixed cap size for Electricity Swap Contracts and the Other

Commodity Electricity Swap Category.\489\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\488\ CL-Barclays at 6.

\489\ CL-EEI at 11-12.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments above, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.4(h)(2)(ii) as proposed. The Commission is of the

view that setting post-initial cap sizes above appropriate minimum

block sizes would provide additional pricing information with respect

to large swap transactions, which are large enough to be treated as

block trades (or large notional off-facility swaps), but small enough

that they do not exceed the applicable post-

[[Page 32909]]

initial cap size. This additional information may enhance price

discovery by publicly disseminating more information relating to market

depth and the notional sizes of publicly reportable swap transactions,

while still protecting the anonymity of swap counterparties and their

ability to lay off risk when executing extraordinarily large swap

transactions.

The Commission notes that Section 2(a)(13) tasks the Commission

with bringing real-time public reporting to the swaps market. Section

2(a)(13)(E) expressly provides that the Commission determine

appropriate time delays for block trades and large notional off-

facility swaps. However, these provisions only call for a time delay--

they do not provide for information to be kept from the market in

perpetuity. All of the information regarding a block trade is reported

to the market at the end of the block time delay. Cap sizes, on the

other hand, are never expressed to the market. Because this information

is not reported to the market in real-time, nor reported to the market

at all, the Commission believes that cap sizes should be set at a

higher level than block sizes. The 75 percent notional test balances

the competing interests of providing meaningful real-time public

reporting to the swaps market and protecting the anonymity of swap

market participants, while taking into account potential impacts on

market liquidity.

If market participants conclude that the Commission has set cap

sizes for a specific swap category in a way that will materially reduce

market liquidity, then those participants are encouraged to submit data

to support their conclusion. In addition, through its own surveillance

of swaps market activity, the Commission may become aware that a cap

size would reduce market liquidity for a specific swap category. In

response to either a submission or its own surveillance of swaps market

activity, the Commission has the legal authority to take action by rule

or order to mitigate the potential effects on market liquidity of cap

sizes with respect to swaps in a particular swap category.

C. Masking the Geographic Detail of Swaps in the Other Commodity Asset

Class

1. Policy Goals for Masking the Geographic Detail for Swaps in the

Other Commodity Asset Class

In the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule, the Commission sets forth

general protections for the identities, market positions and business

transactions of swap counterparties in Sec. 43.4(d). Section 43.4(d)

generally prohibits an SDR from publicly disseminating swap transaction

and pricing data in a manner that discloses or otherwise facilitates

the identification of a swap counterparty.\490\ Notwithstanding that

prohibition, Sec. 43.4(d)(3) provides that SDRs are required to

publicly disseminate data that discloses the underlying asset(s) of

publicly reportable swap transactions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\490\ See Sec. 43.4(d)(1) of the Commission's regulations.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Section 43.4(d)(4) contains special provisions for swaps in the

other commodity asset class. These swaps raise special concerns because

the public disclosure of the underlying asset(s) may in turn reveal the

identities, market positions and business transactions of the swap

counterparties. To address these concerns, Sec. 43.4(d)(4) limits the

types of swaps in the other commodity asset class that are subject to

public dissemination. Specifically, Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(ii) of the

Commission's regulations provides that, for publicly reportable swap

transactions in the other commodity asset class, SDRs must publicly

disseminate the actual underlying assets only for: (1) those swaps

executed on or pursuant to the rules of a SEF or DCM; (2) those swaps

referencing one of the contracts described in appendix B to part 43;

and (3) those swaps that are economically related to one of the

contracts described in appendix B to part 43.\491\ Essentially, the

Commission has determined that these three categories of swap have

sufficient liquidity such that the disclosure of the underlying asset

would not reveal the identities, market positions and business

transactions of the swap counterparties.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\491\ Appendix B to part 43 provides a list of 28 ``Enumerated

Physical Commodity Contracts'' as well as 1 contract under the

``Other Contracts'' heading. See 77 FR 1182 app. B.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In its Real-Time Reporting Final Rule, the Commission included in

appendix B to part 43 a list of contracts that, if referenced as an

underlying asset, should be publicly disseminated in full without

limiting the commodity or geographic detail of the asset. In the

Further Block Proposal, the Commission proposed adding 13 contracts to

appendix B to part 43 under the ``Other Contracts'' heading.\492\ The

Commission believes that since it previously has determined that these

13 contracts have material liquidity and price references, among other

things, the public dissemination of the full underlying asset for

publicly reportable swap transactions that reference such contracts

(and any underlying assets that are economically related thereto) would

not disclose the identities, market positions and business transactions

of swap counterparties.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\492\ Appendix B to part 43 currently lists only Brent Crude Oil

(ICE) under the ``Other Contracts'' heading.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Pursuant to the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule, any publicly

reportable swap transaction in the other commodity asset class that is

excluded under Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(ii) would not be subject to the

reporting and public dissemination requirements for part 43 upon the

effective date of the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule. The Commission

noted in the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule that it planned to address

the group of other commodity swaps that were not subject to the rules

of part 43 in a forthcoming release.\493\ Accordingly, the Commission

proposed in the Further Block Proposal to address the public

dissemination of swap transaction and pricing data for the group of

other commodity swaps that are not covered currently by Sec.

43.4(d)(4)(ii).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\493\ See 77 FR 1211.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is of the view that given the lack of data on the

liquidity for certain swaps in the other commodity asset class, the

lack of data on the number of market participants in these other

commodity swaps markets, and the statutory requirement to protect the

anonymity of market participants,\494\ the public dissemination of less

specific information for swaps with specific geographic or pricing

detail may be appropriate. The Commission believes that the public

dissemination of the exact underlying assets for swaps in this group of

the other commodity asset class may subject the identities, market

positions and business transactions of market participants to

unwarranted public disclosure if additional protections are not

established with respect to the geographic detail of the underlying

asset. For that reason, the Commission proposed that SDRs mask or

otherwise disguise the geographic details related to the underlying

assets of a swap in connection with the public dissemination of such

swap transaction and pricing data.\495\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\494\ See sections 2(a)(13)(E)(i) and 2(a)(13)(C)(iii) of the

CEA. 7 U.S.C. 2(a)(13)(C)(iii), (E)(i).

\495\ Limiting the geographical detail is a typical statistical

disclosure control used by other federal agencies as described in

the Report on Statistical Disclosure Limitation Methodology. See

supra note 61.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. Proposed Amendments to Sec. 43.4

In order to accommodate the policy goals described above, the

Commission proposed adding Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) to part 43 to

establish rules regarding the

[[Page 32910]]

public dissemination of the remaining group of swaps in the other

commodity asset class (i.e., those not described in Sec.

43.4(d)(4)(ii)). In the Commission's view, proposed Sec.

43.4(d)(4)(iii) would ensure that the public dissemination of swap

transaction and pricing data would not unintentionally disclose the

identities, market positions and business transactions of any swap

counterparty to a publicly reportable swap transaction in the other

commodity asset class. In particular, proposed Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii)

provides that SDRs must publicly disseminate the details about the

geographic location of the underlying assets of the other commodity

swaps not described in Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(ii) (i.e., other commodity

swaps that have a specific delivery or pricing point) pursuant to

proposed appendix E to part 43. Proposed appendix E to part 43 is

discussed in the next subsection.

The Commission recognizes that requiring the public dissemination

of less specific geographic detail for an other commodity swap may, to

some extent, diminish the price discovery value of swap transaction and

pricing data for such swap. The Commission believes, however, that the

public dissemination of such data will still provide the market with

useful information relating to market depth, trading activity and

pricing information for similar types of swaps.

The Commission also proposed making conforming amendments to Sec.

43.4(d). Specifically, the Commission proposed amending the

introductory language to Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(i) by deleting ``Sec.

43.4(d)(4)(ii)'' and adding in its place ``Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(ii) and

(iii)'' to make clear that SDRs have to publicly disseminate swaps data

under Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) in accordance with part 43.\496\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\496\ In addition to proposing limitations on the geographic

detail for public dissemination of underlying assets for certain

swaps in the other commodity asset class, the Commission also

proposed amending Sec. 43.4(g) and (h) to make conforming changes.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission received no comments regarding Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(i)

and (ii). The Commission is adopting Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(i) and (ii) as

proposed.

3. Application of Proposed Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) and Proposed Appendix

E to Part 43--Geographic Detail for Delivery or Pricing Points

Proposed appendix E to part 43 includes the system that SDRs would

be required to use to mask the specific delivery or pricing points that

are a part of an underlying asset in connection with the public

dissemination of swap transaction and pricing data for certain swaps in

the other commodity asset class. To the extent that the underlying

asset of a publicly reportable swap transaction described in proposed

Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) does not have a specific delivery or pricing

point, the provisions of proposed Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) and proposed

appendix E to part 43 would not apply. Specifically, proposed appendix

E to part 43 provides top-coding for various geographic regions, both

in the United States and internationally.

Subsection (a) below includes a description of the top-coding U.S.

regions. Subsection (b) below includes a description of the top-coding

non-U.S. regions. Finally, subsection (c) below outlines the proposed

system for SDRs to publicly disseminate ``basis swaps.''\497\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\497\ For the purposes of the Further Block Proposal and this

final rule, basis swaps are defined as swap transactions in which

one leg of the swap references a contract described in appendix B to

part 43 (or is economically related thereto) and the other leg of

the swap does not.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. U.S. Delivery or Pricing Points

Table E1 in proposed appendix E to part 43 lists the geographic

regions that an SDR would publicly disseminate for an off-facility swap

in the other commodity asset class that is described in proposed Sec.

43.4(d)(4)(iii). The Commission proposed that an SDR publicly

disseminate swap transaction and pricing data for certain energy and

power swaps in the other commodity asset class, as described in more

detail below, in a different manner than the remaining other

commodities. In order to mask the specific delivery or pricing detail

of these energy and power swaps, the Commission proposed using

established regions or markets that are associated with these

underlying assets.

i. Natural Gas and Related Products

In proposed Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) and proposed appendix E to part

43, the Commission set forth a method to describe the publicly

reportable swap transactions that have natural gas or related products

as an underlying asset and have a specific delivery or pricing point in

the United States. In particular, the proposal required SDRs to

publicly disseminate a description of the specific delivery or pricing

point based on one of the five industry specific natural gas markets

set forth by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (``FERC'').\498\

The FERC Natural Gas Markets reflect natural deviations found in the

spot prices in different markets.\499\ The Commission anticipates that

a distinction for natural gas is necessary to enhance price discovery

while protecting the identities of the parties, business transactions

and market positions of market participants.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\498\ See FERC, National Gas Markets--Overview, http://www.ferc.gov/market-oversight/mkt-gas/overview.asp (last viewed May

6, 2013).

\499\ See FERC, Natural Gas Market Overview: Spot Gas Prices,

http://www.ferc.gov/market-oversight/mkt-gas/overview/ngas-ovr-avg-spt-ng-pr.pdf (updated Jan.10, 2013). In addition, there is evidence

that the spot prices in these markets and the corresponding futures

prices are highly correlated. D. Murray, Z. Zhu, ``Asymmetric price

responses, market integration and market power: A study of the U.S.

natural gas market,'' Energy Economics, 30 (2008) 748-65.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The proposed five markets for public dissemination of delivery or

pricing points for natural gas swaps are as follows: (i) Midwest

(including North Dakota, South Dakota, Minnesota, Wisconsin, Michigan,

Indiana, Illinois, Iowa, Nebraska, Kansas, Oklahoma, Missouri and

Arkansas); (ii) Northeast (including Maine, New Hampshire, Vermont,

Massachusetts, Rhode Island, Vermont, Connecticut, New York,

Pennsylvania, Kentucky, Ohio, West Virginia, New Jersey, Delaware,

Maryland and Virginia); \500\ (iii) Gulf (including Louisiana and

Texas); (iv) Southeast (including Tennessee, North Carolina, South

Carolina, Georgia, Florida, Alabama and Mississippi); and (v) Western

(including Montana, Wyoming, Colorado, New Mexico, Idaho, Utah,

Washington, Oregon, California, Nevada and Arizona). For any other

pricing points in the United States, SDRs would publicly disseminate

``Other U.S.'' in place of the actual pricing or delivery point for

such natural gas swaps.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\500\ The District of Columbia would be included in this region,

if any specific delivery or pricing points existed at the time of

the Further Block Proposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ii. Petroleum and Related Products

In proposed Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) and proposed appendix E to part

43, the Commission set forth a method to describe the publicly

reportable swap transactions that have petroleum or related products as

an underlying asset and have a specific delivery or pricing point in

the United States. In particular, the proposal would require SDRs to

publicly disseminate a description of the specific delivery or pricing

point based on one of the seven Petroleum Administration for Defense

Districts (``PADD'') regions.\501\ The PADD regions indicate

economically and geographically distinct regions for the purposes of

administering oil allocation.

[[Page 32911]]

The Department of Energy's Energy Information Administration (``EIA'')

collects and publishes oil supply and demand data with respect to the

PADD regions.\502\ Accordingly, to provide consistency with EIA

publications and information regarding regional patterns, the

Commission proposed that specific delivery or pricing points with

respect to such petroleum product swaps are publicly disseminated based

on PADD regions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\501\ See PADD Map, Appendix A, Petroleum Administration for

Defense Districts, http://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.cfm?id=4890, (last viewed May 6, 2013).

\502\ See U.S. Energy Information Administration (EIA)--

Petroleum & Other Liquids, http://www.eia.gov/petroleum/data.cfm

(last viewed May 6, 2013).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The PADD regions for public dissemination of delivery or pricing

points for such petroleum product swaps are as follows: (i) PADD 1A

(New England); (ii) PADD 1B (Central Atlantic); (iii) PADD 1C (Lower

Atlantic); (iv) PADD 2 (Midwest); (v) PADD 3 (Gulf Coast); (vi) PADD 4

(Rocky Mountains); and (vii) PADD 5 (West Coast).\503\ For any other

pricing points in the United States, SDRs would publicly disseminate

the term ``Other U.S.'' in place of the actual pricing or delivery

point for such petroleum product swaps.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\503\ Alternatively, the Commission is considering combining the

East Coast PADD into one category, such that any oil swap with a

specific delivery or pricing point as PADD 1A (New England), PADD 1B

(Central Atlantic) or PADD 1C (Lower Atlantic) would be publicly

disseminated as PADD 1 (East Coast).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

iii. Electricity and Sources

In proposed Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii), the Commission also set forth a

method to describe publicly reportable swap transactions that have

electricity and sources as an underlying asset and have a specific

delivery or pricing point in the United States. In particular, the

proposal would require SDRs to publicly disseminate the specific

delivery or pricing point based on a description of one of the FERC

Electric Power Markets.\504\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\504\ See FERC, Electric Power Markets--Overview, http://www.ferc.gov/market-oversight/mkt-electric/overview.asp (last viewed

May 6, 2013).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The markets for public dissemination of delivery or pricing points

for such electricity swaps are as follows: (i) California (CAISO); (ii)

Midwest (MISO); (iii) New England (ISO-NE); (iv) New York (NYISO); (v)

Northwest; (vi) Pennsylvania-New Jersey-Maryland (PJM); (vii)

Southeast; (viii) Southwest; (ix) Southwest Power Pool (SPP); and (x)

Texas (ERCOT). For any other pricing points in the United States, SDRs

would publicly disseminate the term ``Other U.S.'' in place of the

actual pricing or delivery point for such electricity and sources

swaps.

iv. All Remaining Other Commodities

In proposed Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) and proposed appendix E to part

43, the Commission set forth a method to describe any swaps in the

other commodity asset class that do not have oil, natural gas,

electricity, or petroleum as an underlying asset, but have specific

delivery or pricing points in the United States. In particular, the

Commission proposed that SDRs publicly disseminate information with

respect to these swaps based on the 10 federal regions established by

the U.S. Energy Information Administration (``EIA''). The Commission

believed that the use of the 10 federal regions would provide

consistency among different types of underlying assets in the other

commodity asset class with respect to delivery and pricing point

descriptions.

The 10 federal regions that SDRs would use for public dissemination

under the proposal for all remaining other commodity swaps are as

follows: (i) Region I (including Connecticut, Maine, Massachusetts, New

Hampshire, Rhode Island and Vermont); (ii) Region II (including New

Jersey and New York); (iii) Region III (including Delaware, District of

Columbia, Maryland, Pennsylvania, Virginia and West Virginia); (iv)

Region IV (including Alabama, Florida, Georgia, Kentucky, Mississippi,

North Carolina, South Carolina and Tennessee); (v) Region V (including

Illinois, Indiana, Michigan, Minnesota, Ohio and Wisconsin); (vi)

Region VI (including Arkansas, Louisiana, New Mexico, Oklahoma and

Texas); (vii) Region VII (including Iowa, Kansas, Missouri and

Nebraska); (viii) Region VIII (including Colorado, Montana, North

Dakota, South Dakota, Utah and Wyoming); (ix) Region IX (including

Arizona, California, Hawaii and Nevada); and (x) Region X (including

Alaska, Idaho, Oregon and Washington).\505\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\505\ See U.S. Energy Information Administration, U.S. Federal

Region Map, http://www.eia.gov/electricity/regionsmap/fedregstates.html (last visited May 6, 2013).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Non-U.S. Delivery or Pricing Points

Table E2 in proposed appendix E to part 43 provided the appropriate

manner for SDRs to publicly disseminate non-U.S. delivery or pricing

points for all publicly reportable swap transactions described in the

proposed Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii). The Commission is of the view that SDRs

should not publicly disseminate the actual location for these

international delivery or pricing points since the public disclosure of

such information may disclose the identities of parties, business

transactions and market positions of market participants. In Table E2,

the Commission proposed the countries and regions that an SDR must

publicly disseminate. In proposing the use of these geographic

breakdowns for the public reporting of international delivery or

pricing points, the Commission considered world regions that have

significant energy consumption, whether ISDA-specific documentation

exists for a particular country, and whether public disclosure would

compromise the anonymity of the swap counterparties.

The Commission proposed the following international regions for

publicly disseminating specific delivery or pricing points of publicly

reportable swap transactions described in Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii): (i)

North America (publicly disseminate ``Canada'' or ``Mexico''); (ii)

Central America (publicly disseminate ``Central America''); (iii) South

America (publicly disseminate ``Brazil'' or ``Other South America'');

(iv) Europe (publicly disseminate ``Western Europe,'' ``Northern

Europe,'' ``Southern Europe,'' or ``Eastern Europe''); (v) Russia

(publicly disseminate ``Russia''); \506\ (vi) Africa (publicly

disseminate ``Northern Africa,'' ``Western Africa,'' ``Eastern

Africa,'' ``Central Africa,'' or ``Southern Africa''); (vii) Asia-

Pacific (publicly disseminate ``Northern Asia,'' ``Central Asia,''

``Eastern Asia,'' ``Western Asia,'' ``Southeast Asia,'' or ``Australia/

New Zealand/Pacific Islands''). The Commission considered whether a

more granular approach is necessary for certain regions in order to

enhance price discovery while still protecting anonymity. For example,

Mexico, Canada and Russia may benefit from a more granular public

dissemination of delivery or pricing points given the amount of energy

production in those regions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\506\ Note that Russia is not included in ``Eastern Europe'' or

in ``Northern Asia'' and instead should be publicly disseminated as

``Russia.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

To the extent that a publicly reportable swap transaction described

in proposed Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) references the United States as a

whole and not a specific delivery or pricing point, proposed appendix E

would require an SDR to publicly disseminate that reference. For

example, an SDR would publicly disseminate a weather swap that

references ``U.S. Heating Monthly'' as ``U.S. Heating Monthly.''

c. Basis Swaps

The Commission proposed requiring SDRs to ensure that specific

underlying assets are publicly disseminated for basis swaps that

qualify as publicly

[[Page 32912]]

reportable swap transactions. The Commission recognizes that basis

swaps exist in which one leg of the swap references a contract

described in appendix B to part 43 (or is economically related to one

such contract) and the other leg of the swap references an asset or

pricing point not listed in appendix B to part 43. Currently, Sec.

43.4(d)(4)(ii)(A)-(B) requires an SDR to publicly disseminate the

actual underlying asset of the leg of the basis swap that references or

is economically related to a contract listed in appendix B to part 43.

To the extent that a basis swap is executed on or pursuant to the rules

of a SEF or DCM, an SDR would also publicly disseminate the specific

underlying asset. With respect to the leg of a basis swap that does not

reference a contract in appendix B to part 43, however, the Commission

proposed to require SDRs to publicly disseminate the underlying asset

of that leg pursuant to proposed Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) and proposed

appendix E to part 43, i.e., with top-coding provisions.

d. Comments Received and Commission Determination

The Commission received three comments regarding the masking of

specific delivery or pricing detail of energy and power swaps. EEI

recommended that the Commission mask data regarding Other Commodity

Electricity Swaps according to the North American Electric Reliability

Corporation eight regions rather than the FERC regions proposed.\507\

Barclays recommended that the Commission use wider geographic regions

when publicly disseminating data for commodity swaps with very specific

underlying assets and/or delivery points and develop an appropriate

process to avoid identifying issuers of debt.\508\ Spring Trading

supported further measures to prevent public disclosure of identities,

business transactions, and market positions of swap market

participants, and recommended disclosing a subset of data on a

collective basis at a later date.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\507\ CL-EEI at 12-13.

\508\ CL-Barclays at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the comments received, the Commission is

adopting Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) with the following modification. For

publicly reportable swap transactions that have electricity and sources

as an underlying asset and have a specific delivery or pricing point in

the United States, the Commission is requiring SDRs to publicly

disseminate the specific delivery or pricing point based on a

description of one of the North American Electric Reliability

Corporation (``NERC'') regions for publicly disseminating delivery or

pricing points for electricity swaps described in proposed Sec.

43.4(d)(4)(iii). The NERC regions are broader than the FERC regions and

include much of Canada. Specifically, the NERC regions are as follows:

(i) Florida Reliability Coordinating Council (FRCC); (ii) Midwest

Reliability Organization (MRO); (iii) Northeast Power Coordinating

Council (NPCC); (iv) ReliabilityFirst Corporation (RFC); (v) SERC

Reliability Corporation (SERC); (vi) Southwest Power Pool, RE (SPP);

(vii) Texas Regional Entity (TRE); (viii) Western Electricity

Coordinating Council (WECC).\509\ The Commission is of the view that

using these regions as suggested by EEI will provide further masking of

specific delivery details and thus further protection against public

disclosure of identities, business transactions, and market positions

of swap market participants, as recommended by Barclays and Spring

Trading.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\509\ See NERC, Key Players: Regional Entities, http://www.nerc.com/page.php?cid=1%7C9%7C119 (last visited May 6, 2013).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

4. Further Revisions to Part 43

a. Additional Contracts Added to Appendix B to Part 43

Appendix B to part 43 currently lists contracts that, if referenced

as an underlying asset, would require SDRs to publicly disseminate the

full geographic detail of the asset. In the Real-Time Reporting Final

Rule, the Commission provided that SDRs were required to publicly

disseminate any underlying asset of a publicly reportable swap

transaction that references or is economically related to any contract

or contracts listed in appendix B to part 43 in the same manner.

As noted above, the Commission proposed adding 13 natural gas and

electricity contracts under the ``Other Commodity'' heading in appendix

B to part 43 that have been de-listed and converted into futures

contracts listed on a DCM.\510\ Nevertheless, the addition of these 13

contracts to appendix B effectively would require SDRs to publicly

disseminate these contracts the same way as the other contracts that

are currently listed in appendix B to part 43. That is, an SDR would

publicly disseminate the actual underlying asset (and any underlying

asset(s) that are economically related) without any limitation of the

geographic detail.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\510\ See supra note 176.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission had previously determined that these 13 contracts--

as swaps--were significant price discovery contracts (``SPDCs'') in

connection with trading on exempt commercial markets (``ECMs'').\511\

Each of the 13 contracts had undergone an analysis in which the

Commission considered the following five criteria: (i) Price linkage

(the extent to which the contract uses or otherwise relies on a daily

or final settlement price of a contract listed for trade on or subject

to the rules of a DCM); (ii) arbitrage (the extent to which the price

of the contract is sufficiently related to the price of a contract

listed on a DCM to permit market participants to effectively arbitrage

between the two markets); (iii) material price reference (the extent to

which, on a frequent and recurring basis, bids, offers or transactions

in a commodity are directly based on, or are determined by referencing,

the prices generated by contracts being traded or executed on the ECM);

(iv) material liquidity (the extent to which volume of the contract is

sufficient to have a material effect on other contracts listed for

trading); and (v) other material factors.\512\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\511\ Id.

\512\ The Dodd-Frank Act deleted and replaced CEA section

2(h)(7), which contained the five criteria for determining a SPDC.

The Dodd-Frank Act amended CEA section 4a(a) to include CEA section

4a(a)(4), which contains a similar version of the five criteria for

determining a SPDC in the context of excessive speculation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

To the extent that the SPDC contracts have been de-listed and

replaced by listed futures contracts, the Commission believes that the

latter contracts have similar material liquidity and material price

reference, among other things. Therefore, the Commission anticipates

that, the public dissemination of the full underlying asset for

publicly reportable swap transactions that reference such futures

contracts (and any underlying assets that are economically related

thereto) would not disclose the identities, market positions and

business transactions of market participants and would enhance price

discovery in the related markets.\513\ The Commission did not receive

any other comments, and accordingly, is adopting these additions to

appendix B.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\513\ The Commission notes that it is not adding ``Henry

Financial LD1 Fixed Price,'' a listed futures contract that was

converted from ``Henry Financial LD1 Fixed Price Swap'' (which was

previously deemed by the Commission to be a SPDC), to appendix B to

part 43. This contract is economically related to the ``New York

Mercantile Exchange Henry Hub Natural Gas,'' which is listed under

``Enumerated Physical Commodity Contracts'' in appendix B to part

43. Therefore, listing this contract again would be redundant.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Technical Revisions to Part 43

In the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule, the Commission states that

the

[[Page 32913]]

transactions described Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(ii)(A)-(C), i.e., the instances

in which the actual underlying asset for a publicly reportable swap

transaction in the other commodity asset class is to be publicly

disseminated, are meant to be exclusive of one another. Under these

sections, an SDR is required to publicly disseminate the actual

underlying asset(s) of a swap in the other commodity asset class, where

the swap (1) is executed on or pursuant to the rules of a SEF or DCM;

(2) references a contract listed on appendix B to part 43; or (3) is

economically related to a contract on appendix B. Accordingly, the

Commission proposed a technical clarification to Sec.

43.4(d)(4)(ii)(B) to clarify the intent that these elements are

exclusive of one another, as articulated in the preamble to the Real-

Time Reporting Final Rule.

The Commission did not receive any comments regarding the technical

clarification to Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(ii)(B). Accordingly, the Commission

is adopting Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(ii)(B) as proposed.

IV. Paperwork Reduction Act

A. Background

The purposes of the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995, 44 U.S.C. 3501

et seq. (``PRA'') are, among other things, to minimize the paperwork

burden to the private sector, ensure that any collection of information

by a government agency is put to the greatest possible uses, and

minimize duplicative information collections across the

government.\514\ The PRA applies with extraordinary breadth to all

information, ``regardless of form or format,'' whenever the government

is ``obtaining, causing to be obtained [or] soliciting'' information,

and includes required ``disclosure to third parties or the public, of

facts or opinions,'' when the information collection calls for

``answers to identical questions posed to, or identical reporting or

recordkeeping requirements imposed on, ten or more persons.'' \515\ The

PRA requirements have been determined to include not only mandatory but

also voluntary information collections, and include both written and

oral communications.\516\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\514\ See 44 U.S.C. 3501.

\515\ See 44 U.S.C. 3502.

\516\ See 5 CFR 1320.3(c)(1).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

To effectuate the purposes of the PRA, Congress requires all

agencies to quantify and justify the burden of any information

collection it imposes.\517\ This requirement includes submitting each

collection, whether or not it is contained in a rulemaking, to the

Office of Management and Budget (``OMB'') for review. The OMB

submission process included completing a supporting statement with the

agency's burden estimate and justification for the collection. The

information collection established within this rulemaking, which

included the agency's burden estimate and justification, was subjected

to the rulemaking's public comment process. No public comments were

received affecting the information burden and justification.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\517\ See 44 U.S.C. 3506.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Section 43.6 and amendments to Sec. 43.4 amend an existing

collection of information within the meaning of the PRA in two

respects. Accordingly, the Commission submitted the Further Block

Proposal to the OMB for review pursuant to 44 U.S.C. 3507(d) and 5

CFR1320.11. OMB has assigned control number 3038-0070 to the existing

collection of information, which is titled ``Part 43--Real-Time Public

Reporting.'' The Commission invited the public to comment on any aspect

of the proposed amendments to existing collections of information. The

responses to this amended collection of information are mandatory. The

Commission did not receive any comments regarding the proposed

amendments. Accordingly, the Commission is not revising the estimates

contained in the Further Block Proposal, which are described in the

following sections.

B. Description of the Collection

On January 9, 2012, the Commission issued the Real-Time Reporting

Final Rule, which includes three collections of information

requirements within the meaning of the PRA. The first collection of

information requirement under Part 43 imposed a reporting requirement

on a SEF or DCM when a swap is executed on a trading facility or on the

parties to a swap transaction when the swap is executed bilaterally.

The second collection of information requirement under Part 43 created

a public dissemination requirement on SDRs. The third collection of

information requirement created a recordkeeping requirement for SEFs,

DCMs, SDRs and any reporting party (as such term is defined in part 43

of the Commission's regulations).

Sections 43.4 and 43.6 amend the first and second collections of

information within the meaning of the PRA as described below. The

analysis with respect to the amended collections as a result of Sec.

43.6 is set out in section 1 below. The analysis with respect to the

amended collections as a result of amendments to Sec. 43.4 is set out

in section 2 below.

1. Sec. 43.6(g)--Notification of Election

Section 43.6(g) amends the first and second collections of

information within the meaning of the PRA. In particular, Sec. 43.6(g)

contains the provisions regarding the election to have a swap

transaction treated as a block trade or large notional off-facility

swap, as applicable. Section 43.6(g)(1) establishes a two-step

notification process relating to block trades. Section 43.6(g)(2)

establishes the notification process relating to large notional off-

facility swaps. Section 43.6(g) is an essential part of this rulemaking

because it provides the mechanism through which market participants

will be able to elect to treat their qualifying swap transaction as a

block trade or large notional off-facility swap.

Section 43.6(g)(1)(i) contains the first step in the two-step

notification process relating to block trades. In particular, this

section provides that the parties to a swap that are executed at or

above the appropriate minimum block size for the applicable swap

category are required to notify the SEF or DCM (as applicable) of their

election to have their qualifying swap transaction treated as a block

trade. The Commission understands that SEFs and DCMs use automated,

electronic, and in some cases, voice processes to execute swap

transactions; therefore, the transmission of the notification of a

block trade election also would either be automated, electronic or

communicated through voice.

The Commission estimates that there are 125 SDs and MSPs, and 1,000

other non-financial end-user parties.\518\ The Commission estimates

that, on average, SD/MSP reporting parties would likely notify a SEF or

DCM of a block trade election approximately 1,000 times per year while

non-SD/MSP reporting parties likely would notify a SEF or DCM of a

block trade election approximately five times per year.\519\ Thus, the

Commission estimates that there would be 130,000 notifications of a

block trade election by reporting parties under Sec. 43.6(g) each

year.\520\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\518\ The Commission has previously estimated that 125 SDs and

MSPs will register with the Commission and 1,000 non-financial end-

users (i.e., non-SD/non-MSPs) will be required to report swap

transactions annually. 77 FR 1229-30.

\519\ The Commission anticipates that these figures will change

as a function of changes in the market structure and practices in

the U.S. swaps markets.

\520\ The Commission estimates the total number of notifications

as follows: 125 SDs/MSPs x 1,000 notifications = 125,000

notifications per year; 1,000 non-SDs/non-MSPs x 5 notifications =

5,000 notifications per year; therefore, the total across all types

of entities would be 130,000 notifications per year.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 32914]]

The Commission estimates that the burden hours associated with

Sec. 43.6(g)(1)(i) would include: (i) 30 seconds on average for

parties to a swap to determine whether a particular swap transaction

qualifies as a block trade based on the appropriate minimum block size

of the applicable swap category; and (ii) 30 seconds on average for the

parties to electronically transmit or otherwise communicate their

notice of election. SDs, MSPs and reporting parties would use existing

traders (or other professionals earning similar salaries) to

electronically transmit or otherwise communicate their notice of

election. Based on the Securities Industry and Financial Market

Association's 2011 Securities Industry Salary Survey, the Commission

estimates that these block traders would earn approximately $184.90 per

hour in total compensation.\521\ Accordingly, the Commission estimates

that the total annual burden hour costs associated with the first step

in proposed Sec. 43.6(g)(1)(i) would be 2,167 hours \522\ or $400,678

in total annual burden hours costs \523\ and $11.8 million in total

start-up capital costs.\524\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\521\ The Commission previously has utilized wage rate estimates

based on average salary and average prior year bonus information for

the securities industry compiled by SIFMA. These wage estimates are

derived from an industry-wide survey of participants and thus

reflect an average across entities; the Commission notes that the

actual costs for any individual company or sector may vary from the

average.

The Commission estimated the dollar costs of hourly burdens for

different types of relevant professionals using the following

calculations:

(1) [(2010 salary + bonus) * (salary growth per professional

type, 2010-2011)] = Estimated 2010 total annual compensation. The

most recent data provided by the SIFMA report describe the 2010

total compensation (salary + bonus) by professional type, the growth

in base salary from 2010 to 2011 for each professional type, and the

2011 base salary for each professional type; therefore, the

Commission estimated the 2011 total compensation for each

professional type, but, in the absence of similarly granular data on

salary growth or compensation from 2011 to 2012 and beyond, did not

estimate dollar costs beyond 2011. [(Estimated 2011 total annual

compensation)/(1,800 annual work hours)] = Hourly wage per

professional type.]

(2) [(Hourly wage) * (Adjustment factor for overhead and other

benefits, which the Commission has estimated to be 1.3)] = Adjusted

hourly wage per professional type.]

(3) [(Adjusted hourly wage) * (Estimated hour burden for

compliance)] = Dollar cost of compliance for each hour burden

estimate per professional type.]

The sum of each of these calculations for all professional types

involved in compliance with a given element of the Further Block

Proposal represents the total cost for each counterparty, reporting

party, swap dealer, major swap participant, SEF, DCM, or SDR, as

applicable to that element of the proposal.

\522\ To comply with the election process in proposed Sec.

43.6(g), a market participant likely would need to provide training

to its existing personnel and update its written policies and

procedures to account for this new process. The total annual burden

hours equals the total hours for swap dealers and major swap

participants plus the total hours for non-swap dealers and non-major

swap participants.

\523\ The underlying adjusted labor cost estimate of $184.90 per

hour used in this estimate is calculated based on the adjusted wages

of swap traders. See note 521 supra.

\524\ The estimated costs are based on the Commission's estimate

of the incremental, non-recurring expenditures to reporting

entities, including non-SD/non-MSPs (i.e., non-financial end-users)

to: (1) update existing technology, including updating its OMS

system ($7,170); and (2) provide training to existing personnel and

update written policies and procedures ($3,360). See section V.D.1.

infra. The Commission believes that SDs/MSPs would incur similar

non-recurring start-up costs. The Commission has previously

estimated that 125 SDs and MSPs will register with the Commission

and 1,000 non-financial end-users (i.e., non-SD/non-MSPs) will be

required to report in a year. See 77 FR 1229-30.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With respect to the second step, proposed Sec. 43.6(g)(1)(ii)

provides that the SEF or DCM, as applicable, that receives an election

notification is required to notify an SDR of a block trade election

when transmitting swap transaction and pricing data to such SDR for

public dissemination. As noted above, the Commission anticipates that

SEFs and DCMs would use automated, electronic and, in some cases, voice

processes to execute swap transactions. The Commission estimates that

there will be approximately 58 SEFs and DCMs. Accordingly, the

Commission estimates that the total annual burden associated with the

second step in Sec. 43.6(g)(1)(ii) would be approximately $610,740 in

non-recurring annualized capital and start-up costs.\525\ The Real-Time

Reporting Final Rule already has addressed the recurring annualized

costs for the hour burden.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\525\ The Commission bases this estimate on 58 projected SEFs

and DCMs, each of which will incur costs of investing in update

technology, including updating its OMS system ($6,761.20); and

training existing personnel and updating written policies and

procedures ($3,195.00). See section V.D.1. infra.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Section 43.6(g)(2) is similar to the first step set forth in Sec.

43.6(g)(1). That is, Sec. 43.6(g)(2) provides, in part, that a

reporting party who executes a bilateral swap transaction that is at or

above the appropriate minimum block size is required to notify the SDR

of its election to treat such swap as a large notional off-facility

swap. This section provides further that the reporting party is

required to notify the SDR in connection with the reporting party's

transmission of swap transaction and pricing data to the SDR for public

dissemination. The Commission anticipates that reporting parties may

have various methods through which they will transmit information to

SDRs, which would include a large notional off-facility swap election.

Most reporting parties would use automated and electronic methods to

transmit this information; other reporting parties, because of the

expense associated with building an electronic infrastructure, may

contract with third parties (including their swap counterparty) to

transmit the notification of a large notional off-facility swap

election.

The Commission estimates that the incremental time and cost burden

associated with the Sec. 43.6(g)(2) would include: (i) One minute for

a reporting party to determine whether a particular swap transaction

qualifies as a large notional off-facility swap based on the

appropriate minimum block size of the applicable swap category; and

(ii) one minute for the reporting party (or its designee) to

electronically transmit or communicate through voice processes its

notice of election. The Commission estimates that, of the approximately

2,250 hours incurred by 125 SDs/MSPs and 1,000 non-SD/MSPs, all of

those hours would be spent by traders and market analysts (or

designee).\526\ SIFMA's report states that traders and market analysts

make $184.90 per hour in total compensation.\527\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\526\ The economic costs associated with entering into a third

party service arrangement to transmit an electronic notice to an SDR

are difficult to determine. There are too many variables that are

involved in determining those costs. Notwithstanding this

difficulty, the Commission foresees that, for many reporting parties

that infrequently trade swaps, the annualized cost of entering into

a third-party service arrangement of this type would likely be less

than the total annual cost of building an electronic infrastructure

to transmit electronic notices directly to an SDR.

\527\ See note 521 supra.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission estimates that, on average, each of the estimated

125 SD/MSP counterparties would likely notify an SDR of a large

notional off-facility swap election approximately 500 times per year

while each of the estimated 1,000 non-SD/MSP counterparties would

notify an SDR approximately five times per year. Accordingly, the

Commission estimates that there are, on average, approximately 67,500

notifications large notional off-facility swaps under Sec. 43.6 each

year. Accordingly, the Commission estimates that the total annual

burden associated with Sec. 43.6(g)(2) would be approximately 2,250

annual labor hours or $416,025 in annual labor costs.\528\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\528\ The labor hour estimate is calculated as follows: (125

SDs/MSPs x 500 notifications) + (1,000 non-SDs/non-MSPs x 5

notifications) = 67,500 notifications x 2 minutes/notification =

135,000 minutes/60 minutes/hour = 2,250 hours. The labor cost

estimate is calculated as follows: 2,250 labor hours x $140.93 per

hour total compensation = $317,092. The Commission notes that the

calculation in the Further Block Proposal incorrectly listed the

labor hour estimate as 2,255 hours (rather than 2,250). The labor

cost estimate was then incorrectly listed as $317,797 (rather than

$317,092) due to the incorrect labor hour estimate.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 32915]]

In addition, the Commission estimates that Sec. 43.6(g)(2) results

in $11.8 million in non-recurring annualized capital and start-up

costs.\529\ The Real-Time Reporting Final Rule addressed all ongoing

operational and maintenance costs.\530\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\529\ The estimated costs are based on the Commission's estimate

of the incremental, non-recurring expenditures to reporting

entities, including non-SD/non-MSPs (i.e., non-financial end-users)

to (1) update existing technology, including updating its OMS system

($6,761.20); and (2) provide training to existing personnel and

update written policies and procedures ($3,195.00). See section

V.D.1. infra. The Commission believes that SDs/MSPs would incur

similar non-recurring start-up costs. The Commission has previously

estimated that 125 SDs and MSPs will register with the Commission

and 1,000 non-financial end-users (i.e., non-SD/non-MSPs) will be

required to report in a year. 77 FR 1229-30.

\530\ See 77 FR at 1232.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. Amendments to Sec. 43.4(d)(4) and 43.4(h)

The Commission addresses the public dissemination of certain swaps

in the other commodity asset class in Sec. 43.4(d)(4). Section

43.4(d)(4)(ii) provides that for publicly reportable swaps in the other

commodity asset class, the actual underlying assets must be publicly

disseminated for: (1) Those swaps executed on or pursuant to the rules

of a SEF or DCM; (2) those swaps referencing one of the contracts

described in appendix B to part 43; and (3) any publicly reportable

swap transaction that is economically related to one of the contracts

described in appendix B to part 43. Pursuant to the Real-Time Reporting

Final Rule, any swap that is in the other commodity asset class that

does not fall under Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(ii) would not be subject to

reporting and public dissemination requirements upon the effective date

of the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule.

In this final rule, the Commission is promulgating a new provision

(Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii)), which would develop a system for the public

dissemination of exact underlying assets in the other commodity asset

class with a ``mask'' based on geographic detail. The Commission is

adopting a new appendix to part 43, which contains the geographical

top-codes that SDRs would use in masking certain other commodity swaps

in connection with such swaps public dissemination of swap transaction

and pricing data under part 43. The Commission anticipates that there

will be approximately 50,000 additional swaps reported to an SDR each

year in the other commodity asset class, which the Commission estimates

would be $154,021 in annualized hour burden costs.\531\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\531\ The Commission estimates that there will be 5 SDRs, which

will collect swaps data in the other commodity asset class. Each SDR

would collect swaps data on approximately 10,000 swap transactions

in the other commodity asset class. The commission estimates that it

will take each SDR on average approximately 1 minute to publicly

disseminate swaps data related to these new swap transactions. The

number of burden hours for these SDRs would be 833 hours. As

referenced in note 523 supra, the total labor costs for a swap

trader is $140.93. Thus, the total number of burden hour costs equal

the total number of burden hours (833 burden hours) x $140.93.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission's regulations currently provide a system

establishing cap sizes. Section 43.4(h) of the Commission's regulations

provides that cap sizes for swaps in each asset class shall equal the

appropriate minimum block size corresponding to such publicly

reportable swap transaction. If no appropriate minimum block size

exists, then Sec. 43.4(h) sets out specific interim cap sizes for each

asset class.\532\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\532\ The Real-Time Reporting Final Rule calculated and

addressed the total ongoing burden hours and burden hour costs. See

77 FR 11232.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

This final rule amends Sec. 43.4(h) to establish new cap sizes in

the post-initial period using a 75-percent notional amount calculation.

Under this amendment, the Commission will perform the calculation;

however, SDRs will update their technology and other systems at a

minimum of once per year to publicly disseminate swap transaction and

pricing data with the cap sizes issued by the Commission.

The Commission estimates that the incremental start-up costs

associated with the amendment to Sec. Sec. 43.4(d)(4) and 43.4(h) for

an SDR would include: (1) Reprograming its technology infrastructure to

accommodate the masking system and post-initial cap sizes methodology;

(2) updating its written policies and procedures to ensure compliance

with Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) and the amendment to Sec. 43.4(h); and (3)

training staff on the new policies and procedures.\533\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\533\ The economic costs associated with entering into a third

party service arrangement to transmit an electronic notice to an SDR

are difficult to determine because of too many variables involved in

determining those costs. Notwithstanding this difficulty, the

Commission believes that, for many reporting parties that

infrequently trade swaps, the annualized cost of entering into a

third-party service arrangement of this type would likely be less

than the total annual cost of building an electronic infrastructure

to transmit electronic notices directly to an SDR.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

V. Cost-Benefit Considerations

A. Background

Section 15(a) of the Commodity Exchange Act \534\ (``CEA'')

mandates that the Commission consider the costs and benefits of this

rulemaking, which amends portions of part 43 (the Real-Time Reporting

Final Rule).\535\ Part 43 implements section 727 of the Dodd-Frank

Act.\536\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\534\ 7 U.S.C. 19(a).

\535\ Real-Time Public Reporting of Swap Transaction Data, 77 FR

1182, Jan. 9, 2012.

\536\ Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act

section 727, Public Law 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010) (``Dodd-Frank

Act'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Enacted in the wake of the 2008 financial crisis with the aim of

preventing a repeat of the severe harm that crisis caused, Title VII of

the Dodd-Frank Act establishes a comprehensive new regulatory framework

for swaps and security-based swaps.\537\ Among other things, the

legislation seeks to promote market integrity, reduce risk, and

increase transparency within the financial system as a whole and swaps

markets in particular. Consistent with the view that the financial

crisis was not attributable to a single weakness, but a combination of

several,\538\ Title VII does not provide for a single-dimensional fix.

Rather, it weaves together a multidimensional regulatory construct

designed to ``mitigate costs and risks to taxpayers and the financial

system.'' \539\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\537\ Dodd-Frank Act section 701, et seq.

\538\ See, e.g., Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, ``The

Financial Crisis Inquiry Report: Final Report of the National

Commission on the Causes of the Financial and Economic Crisis in the

United States,'' Jan. 2011, at xxiv, available at http://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/GPO-FCIC/pdf/GPO-FCIC.pdf (listing

uncontrolled leverage; lack of transparency, capital and collateral

requirements; speculation; interconnection among firms; and

concentrations of risk in the market as contributing factors).

\539\ S. Rep. No. 111-176, at 92 (2010).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Section 727 concerns a fundamental component in the Dodd-Frank Act

construct: public swap transaction reporting. This provision adds

section 2(a)(13) to the CEA ``to authorize the Commission to make swap

transaction and pricing data available to the public in such form and

at such times as the Commission determines appropriate to enhance price

discovery.'' \540\ In addition, the section directs the Commission to

promulgate certain rules, including rules that:

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\540\ CEA section 2(a)(13)(B).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Require ``real-time public reporting''--i.e., ``reporting

data related to a swap transaction, including price and volume, as soon

as technologically practicable after the time at which the swap

transaction has been executed'' \541\--of swap transactions \542\;

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\541\ CEA section 2(a)(13)(A).

\542\ CEA section 2(a)(13)(C).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

specify ``the criteria for determining what constitutes a

large notional swap transaction (block trade) for particular markets

and contracts'' and ``the appropriate time delay for reporting

[[Page 32916]]

large notional swap transactions (block trades) to the public;'' \543\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\543\ See CEA sections 2(a)(13)(E)(ii) and (iii). Section

2(a)(13)(E) explicitly refers to the swaps described only in

sections 2(a)(13)(C)(i) and 2(a)(13)(C)(ii) of the CEA (i.e.,

clearable swaps, including swaps that are exempt from clearing). The

Commission, in exercising its authority under CEA section

2(a)(13)(B) to ``make swap transaction and pricing data available to

the public in such form and at such times as the Commission

determines appropriate to enhance price discovery,'' is authorized

to prescribe rules similar to those provisions in section

2(a)(13)(E) to uncleared swaps described in section 2(a)(13)(C)(iii)

and (iv) of the CEA. Thus, the Commission is establishing block

thresholds for the swaps described in Sections 2(a)(13)(C)(i) and

2(a)(13)(C)(ii) of the CEA as required by Section 2(a)(13)(E). The

Commission is establishing large notional off-facility swap

thresholds for swaps described in Sections 2(a)(13)(C)(iii) and

2(a)(13)(C)(iv) pursuant to its authority under Section 2(a)(13)(B).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

take into account whether public disclosure of swap

transaction and pricing data ``will materially reduce market

liquidity'' \544\;

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\544\ CEA section 2(a)(13)(E)(iv).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

protect the identities of counterparties to swaps and

maintain the anonymity of business transactions and market positions of

swap counterparties.\545\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\545\ See CEA sections 2(a)(13)(E)(i) and 2(a)(13)(C)(iii).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In January 2012, the Commission adopted the part 43 Real-Time

Reporting Final Rule implementing section 2(a)(13)of the CEA.\546\

Generally summarized, the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule defined the

terms ``block trade'' and ``large notional off-facility swap,'' \547\

and established the: (1) Responsibilities of the parties to each swap

to report swap transaction and pricing data to a swap data repository

(``SDR'') and the types of data they must report \548\; (2)

requirements for SDRs to publicly disseminate such data in real-time

or, in the case of block trades and large-notional off-facility swaps,

subject to a time delay \549\; (3) applicable time delays for public

dissemination of block trades and large-notional off-facility swaps

data according to asset class \550\; and (4) a system to protect the

anonymity of parties to a swap, including interim notional cap sizes

for all swaps that are publicly disseminated and the creation of an

exception from the real-time public reporting requirement for certain

swaps in the ``other commodity'' asset class.\551\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\546\ Real-Time Public Reporting of Swap Transaction Data, 77 FR

1182, Jan. 9, 2012.

\547\ The Real-Time Reporting Final Rule defines the term

``Block trade'' as a publicly reportable swap transaction that:

``(1) [i]nvolves a swap that is listed on a SEF or DCM; (2) [o]ccurs

away from the [SEF's or DCM's] trading system or platform and is

executed pursuant to the [SEF's or DCM's] rules and procedures; (3)

has a notional or principal amount at or above the appropriate

minimum block applicable to such swap ; and (4) [i]s reported

subject to the rules and procedures of the [SEF or DCM] and the

rules described in [part 43], including the appropriate time delay

requirements set forth in Sec. 43.5.'' See Sec. 43.2, 77 FR 1243.

The Real-Time Reporting Final Rule defined the term ``Large

notional off-facility swap as an ``off-facility swap that has a

notional or principal amount at or above the appropriate minimum

block size applicable to such publicly reportable swap transaction

and is not a block trade as defined in Sec. 43.2 of the

Commission's regulations.'' Id.

\548\ See Sec. 43.3, 77 FR 1244.

\549\ See Sec. 43.4, 77 FR 1246.

\550\ See Sec. 43.5, 77 FR 1247.

\551\ See Sec. 43.4 (d) and (h), 77 FR 1,246. Section 43.4(h)

states that ``[t]he rounded notional or principal amount that is

publicly disseminated for a publicly reportable swap transaction

shall be capped. . . . '' If the notional or principal amount of a

publicly reportable swap transaction is greater than the cap size,

the publicly reported size for the trade will be ``[cap size]+.''

For example, if the relevant cap size is 250 million, the publicly

reported size will be ``250+.''

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Real-Time Public Reporting Final Rule as adopted in January

2012, however, deferred its responsibility to promulgate rules that

``specify the criteria for determining what constitutes a large

notional [off-facility] swap transaction [or block trade] for

particular markets and contracts'' as CEA section 2(a)(13)(E)(ii)

requires. Pending the adoption of such supplemental part 43 rules, the

Commission adopted ``interim time delays for all swaps.'' \552\

Accordingly, at present no swap transaction data is publicly

disseminated in real-time; interim time delays are in place for all

swaps.\553\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\552\ 77 FR 1217; see also Sec. 43.5(c).

\553\ See Sec. 43.5(c)(1).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The final rules adopted in this release amend part 43 to establish

appropriate minimum block sizes, lift the blanket interim time-delay

for all swaps from real-time public reporting, and provide further

anonymity provisions to protect the identities of swap counterparties

and transactions. More specifically, and as discussed in more detail

above, these rules do so by:

creating ``swap categories'' (i.e., groupings of swaps

within the same asset class based on underlying characteristics) to

which a common appropriate minimum block size applies \554\;

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\554\ See Sec. 43.6(b), which defines swap category by asset

class.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

prescribing a two-period, phased in approach to implement

regulations, comprised of an initial period and an on-going (post-

initial) period to allow market participants sufficient time for

compliance \555\;

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\555\ See Sec. 43.6(e) and (f).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

establishing initial appropriate minimum block sizes based

on the Commission's review and analysis of swap market data across

certain asset classes \556\;

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\556\ See Sec. 43.6(e) and appendix F to part 43.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

obligating set forth a methodology for calculating post-

initial appropriate minimum block sizes \557\;

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\557\ See Sec. 43.6(c) and (f).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

providing a procedure that allows parties to a swap to

elect block trade or large notional off-facility swap treatment for a

swap transaction; \558\ and

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\558\ See Sec. 43.6(g).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

establishing a system to ensure the anonymity of certain

swaps in the other commodity asset class,\559\ including a methodology

for the calculation of initial or post-initial cap sizes.\560\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\559\ See amendments to Sec. 43.4(d)(4).

\560\ See Sec. Sec. 43.4(h) and 43.6(c).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The rules do not, however, amend part 43 in a manner that alters the

appropriate time delays for block trades and large notional off-

facility swaps, nor do they require investment in a completely new

information infrastructure beyond what is necessary to comply with the

existing provisions of part 43.\561\ With this release, in conjunction

with the separate SEF core principles rulemaking \562\ and the made

available to trade rulemaking,\563\ the Commission is implementing the

trade execution mandate of CEA Section 2(h)(8). Due to the clearing

mandate, the Final Rule at this time mainly will affect pre-trade

transparency only in the interest rate and credit default asset

classes. In regard to the foreign exchange and other commodity asset

classes, the Commission notes that there is no clearing mandate for

foreign exchange swaps and other commodity swaps at this time. Thus,

the swaps block rule does not currently affect pre-trade transparency

for these asset classes. As these markets evolve, the Commission will

continue to monitor developments within each asset class and may

exercise its legal authority to take action by rule or order if

necessary to address changes in the markets.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\561\ The costs and benefits attendant to the time delay and

development of an infrastructure for block trades and large notional

off-facility swaps are discussed in Real-Time Public Reporting of

Swap Transaction Data, 77 FR 1182, 1232, Jan. 9, 2012.

\562\ See, the Core Principles and Other Requirements for Swap

Execution Facilities notice of proposed rulemaking, 76 FR 1214 (Jan.

7, 2011).

\563\ The Commission separately proposed rules to determine

whether a swap is ``made available to trade'' for purposes of the

trade execution requirement in CEA section 2(h)(8). Process for a

Designated Contract Market or Swap Execution Facility To Make a Swap

Available to Trade, 76 FR 77728 (proposed Dec. 14, 2011).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

This rulemaking requires the Commission to carefully navigate a

tension that CEA section 2(a)(13) recognizes: while section 2(a)(13)(C)

requires the Commission to promulgate rules to bring real-time public

reporting to the swaps market, section 2(a)(13)(E)(iv) requires that in

doing so

[[Page 32917]]

the Commission ``take into account whether the public disclosure will

materially reduce market liquidity.'' The Commission has followed both

directives. Accordingly, a central focus of the Commission's

consideration of costs and benefits of this rulemaking is the interplay

between the important benefits of enhanced swap transaction

transparency that real-time public dissemination affords \564\ and the

potential that, in certain circumstances, transparency could reduce

swap market liquidity. As evident by commenters' divergent opinions,

the optimal point in this interplay, and how to set it, defies

precision.\565\ Given this fact, these rules reflect the Commission's

reasoned judgment of how best to meaningfully effectuate real-time

public reporting of swap transactions--and the transparency Congress

intended--in a manner that takes into account the impact on market

liquidity. Briefly, the Commission will use a 67% percent notional

calculation to determine the threshold over which block trades and

large notional off-facility swaps will be eligible for block trade

treatment, meaning that most swaps will be reported in real-time.\566\

At the same time, a phased implementation schedule assures that

transparency is introduced incrementally, taking into account whether

public disclosure will ``materially reduce market liquidity.'' For

example, to cushion potential liquidity impact, the thresholds for

swaps in the interest rate and credit assets classes will initially

rest conservatively at 50 percent, thus allowing transactions above 50

percent of the notional amount to remain shielded from real-time public

reporting, before transitioning to 67 percent in the post-initial

period. While this departure from the proposal means that fewer swaps

will be subject to real-time transparency during the initial period, it

affords the Commission the opportunity to collect and analyze data on

the use of block thresholds and to apply that data to its evaluation of

the risks attendant to a less transparent market. Simultaneously

introducing a conservative, 50 percent threshold also allows the

Commission to assess whether there are material reductions in the

liquidity for some swaps and take any measures to stave off those

reductions, as the rules allow the Commission to review and refine the

thresholds as liquidity and transparency needs may warrant in the

future.\567\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\564\ The benefits of public dissemination of swap transaction

and pricing data are detailed in Real-Time Public Reporting of Swap

Transaction Data, 77 FR at 1234. As the Commission explained in that

release and reaffirms here, swap transaction reporting and public

dissemination benefits market participants and the public in a

number of respects. Among others discussed in that earlier release,

and considered by reference herein, these include enhanced: price

discovery, ability to manage risk as a result of improved visibility

into swap market risk pricing, and improved swap market price

competition. Additionally, the transparency afforded through public

dissemination of swap transaction and pricing data ``will enhance

the Commission's ability to detect anomalies in the market . . . and

provide a check against a reoccurrence of the type of systemic risk

build-up that occurred in 2008 when `the market permitted enormous

exposure to risk to grow out of the sight of regulators and other

traders [and d]erivatives exposures that could not be readily

quantified exacerbated panic and uncertainty about the true

financial condition of other market participants, contributing to

the freezing of credit markets.' '' Id. (quoting Congressional

Research Service Report for Congress, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street

Reform and Consumer Protection Act: Title VII, Derivatives, by Mark

Jickling and Kathleen Ann Ruane (August 30, 2010).

\565\ Indeed, CEA section 2(a)(13)(E)(iv), in simply requiring

that the Commission ``take into account whether public disclosure

will materially reduce market liquidity,'' does not require that the

Commission attempt to determine the precise optimal relationship

between transparency and liquidity or assure no liquidity loss.

\566\ Using the Over-the-Counter Derivatives Supervisors Group

(``ODSG'') data for interest rate swaps, the Commission notes that

the 67 percent notional amount calculation would result in 94

percent of trades being reported in real-time. A discussion of the

ODSG and the data set is set forth in section II.C.1 of this final

rule.

\567\ See Sec. 43.6(f).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

B. The Statutory Mandate To Consider the Costs and Benefits of the

Commission's Action: Section 15(a) of the CEA

Section 15(a) of the CEA \568\ requires the Commission to consider

the costs and benefits of its actions before promulgating a regulation

under the CEA or issuing certain orders. Section 15(a) further

specifies that the costs and benefits shall be evaluated in light of

the following five broad areas of market and public concern: (1)

Protection of market participants and the public; (2) efficiency,

competitiveness, and financial integrity of futures markets; (3) price

discovery; (4) sound risk management practices; and (5) other public

interest considerations. The Commission considers the costs and

benefits resulting from its discretionary determinations with respect

to the section 15(a) factors.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\568\ 7 U.S.C. 19(a).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

These amending rules become effective in--and their costs and

benefits are considered relative to--the context of the conditions now

in place under part 43. That is: all publicly reportable swap

transactions are currently subject to a time delay and are not publicly

reported in real-time.569 570 Unless otherwise indicated,

the Commission has looked to a non-financial end-user that already has

developed the technical capability and infrastructure necessary to

comply with the requirements set forth in part 43 as a reference entity

for estimating this rulemaking's direct costs under the assumption that

the costs for this particular market participant would represent the

maximum degree of compliance costs.\571\ The Commission anticipates,

however, that in many cases the actual costs to established market

participants (including swap counterparties, SDRs and other registered

entities) would be lower than for the reference entity--perhaps

significantly so, depending on the type, flexibility, and scalability

of systems already in place.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\569\ See Sec. 43.5(c).

\570\ Currently, the part 43 requirements are not applicable to

swaps in the other commodities asset class that reference underlying

assets not included in Appendix B to Part 43. The Real-Time

Reporting Rule provides notice that, until such time as the

anonymity provisions of this final rule are finalized, those off-

facility swaps not listed in appendix B to part 43 are not be

required to comply with the real-time reporting and public

dissemination requirements under part 43. However, such swaps are

subject to the regulatory reporting requirements, described in

proposed part 45. According to the BIS report http://bis.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qs1209.pdf, commodities (as a whole and not just the

subset identified above) only represent slightly more than one third

of one percent (0.36%) of the notional amounts outstanding as a

percentage of the global OTC derivatives market for the end of

December 2011. For this small subset of other commodity swaps, the

starting point for the purposes of the Commission's consideration of

the costs and benefits is the same as the starting point for the

Commission's consideration of costs and benefits of the Real-Time

Reporting Rule. A detailed discussion of the Commission's

consideration of those costs and benefits is contained in the Real-

Time Reporting Rule. See 77 FR at 1232-1240.

\571\ A non-financial end-user is a new market entrant with no

prior swaps market participation or infrastructure. This reference

point is different from the reference point(s) used in the PRA

analysis in section V above for the following two reasons: (1) the

burdens in the PRA are narrower than the costs discussed in this

section (i.e., the PRA analysis solely discusses costs relating to

collections of information, whereas this cost-benefit analysis

considers all costs relating to the proposed rules); and (2) as

discussed above, the cost-benefit analysis determines costs relative

to one market participant that presumably would bear the highest

burdens in implementing the proposed rules, whereas the PRA analysis

seeks to estimate the costs of the proposed rules on all market

participants.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Wherever reasonably feasible, the Commission has endeavored to

quantify the costs and benefits of this rulemaking. In a number of

instances, the Commission lacks the data and information required to

precisely estimate costs, owing to the fact that these markets do not

yet exist or are not yet fully developed. The Commission requested that

commenters provide any data or other information that would be useful

in the estimation of the

[[Page 32918]]

quantifiable costs and benefits of this rulemaking \572\; no commenters

supplied such data or other information. Where it was not feasible to

quantify (e.g., because of the lack of accurate data or appropriate

metrics), the Commission has considered the costs and benefits of these

rules in qualitative terms.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\572\ Further Block Proposal Q93(a)-(e), 77 FR at 15507.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For purposes of considering their costs and benefits, the

Commission has organized these rules in three groups: (1) Block trade

rules concerning the criteria for determining swap categories and the

methodologies to be used to determine the initial and post-initial

appropriate minimum block sizes for large notional off-facility swaps

and block trades; (2) block trade rules concerning the method by which

swap counterparties may elect to treat a qualifying swap transaction as

a block trade or a large notional off-facility swap, as applicable, and

SEFs and DCMs notify an SDR of a block trade election; and (3) rules

concerning anonymity protections. Each group is discussed below.

C. Rules Establishing Determination Criteria and Methodology (Sec.

43.6(a)-(f) and (h))

Rules 43.6(a)-(f) and (h) specify the Commission's criteria for

establishing swap categories and methodology for determining

appropriate minimum block sizes. The subsections that follow provide a

brief contextual summary description of the rules; identify and discuss

the costs and benefits attributable to the rules in light of comments;

consider alternatives; and consider costs and benefits relative to

factors specified in CEA section 15(a).

1. Rule Summary

Rules 43.6(a)-(f) and (h) are described previously in this

release.\573\ A summary of each follows:

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\573\ See section II, supra.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. Rule 43.6(a) Commission Determination

Rule 43.6(a) provides that the Commission will determine the

appropriate minimum block size for any swap on a SEF or DCM, and for

large notional off-facility swaps. The rule also sets forth a schedule

whereby the Commission will calculate and publish all appropriate

minimum block sizes across all asset classes no less than once each

calendar year, following an initial period (as described below).

b. Rule 43.6(b) Swap Category

Rule 43.6(b) specifies the Commission's approach for grouping swaps

by asset class based on existing liquidity in underlying cash markets,

relevant economic indicators, the underlying asset class, and the

Commission's analysis of relevant swap market data supplied to the

Commission.\574\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\574\ Data was supplied to the Commission by MarkitSERV and The

Warehouse Trust Company LLC. The data is more fully described in

Section II.A.1.a. of this release.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

c. Rules 43.6(c)-(f) and (h) Methods for Determining Appropriate

Minimum Block Sizes

Rules 43.6(c)-(f) and (h) prescribe a phased-in approach, with an

initial period and a post-initial period for determining appropriate

minimum block sizes for each swap category. Appendix F to part 43

contains a schedule of appropriate minimum block sizes effective during

the initial period. The schedule reflects a different appropriate

minimum block size methodology for the interest rate and credit asset

classes than for the equity, FX and other commodity asset classes. The

initial appropriate minimum block sizes for the interest rate and

credit asset class are derived from data supplied by the ODSG.\575\ As

set forth in Appendix F to this Final Rule, the Commission is

calculating the appropriate minimum block sizes in interest rate and

credit asset classes based upon the 50-percent notional amount

calculation set forth in Sec. 43.6(c)(1) in the initial period.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\575\ A discussion of the ODSG and the data set is set forth in

section II.C.1 of this final rule.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Rule 43.6(d) states that swaps in the equity asset class shall not

be treated as block trades or large notional off-facility swaps (i.e.,

equity swaps would not be subject to a time delay as provided in part

43).

With respect to the FX and other commodity asset classes, the

appropriate minimum block sizes for swaps during the initial period is

divided primarily between swaps that are futures-related swaps and

those that are not futures-related.\576\ Appendix F to part 43 lists

the proposed initial appropriate minimum block sizes for swap

categories in the FX and other commodity asset classes. For swaps in

the FX and other commodity asset classes that are not listed in

appendix F to part 43, Sec. 43.6(e)(2) generally provides that these

swaps will be considered block trades or large notional off-facility

swaps.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\576\ As explained above in section II.C., the Commission

believes that the difference in methodology for determining initial

appropriate minimum block sizes for swaps in the FX and other

commodity asset classes is warranted because: (1) Swaps in these

asset classes are closely linked to futures markets; and (2) DCMs

have experience in setting block sizes for futures.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After an SDR has collected reliable data for a particular asset

class, Sec. 43.6(f)(1) provides that the Commission shall determine

post-initial appropriate minimum block sizes for all swaps in the

interest rate, credit, FX and other commodity asset classes based on

the 67-percent notional amount calculation. The Commission is also

adopting special rules for the determination of appropriate minimum

block sizes that would apply to all asset classes, including rules

applicable to swaps with optionality, swaps with composite reference

prices, physical commodity swaps, currency conversion, and successor

currencies.\577\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\577\ See proposed rule Sec. 43.6(h).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. Overview of Comments Received

The Commission received numerous comments regarding the potential

costs and benefits to market participants and the public in response to

the rules establishing the criteria and methodology for determining

block thresholds. Commenters were divided on whether the Commission

properly considered costs or misstated or ignored the benefits of the

rules. Some commenters touched on the cost benefit considerations

directly by promoting various alternatives to the proposed rules.\578\

Comments relating to the Commission's consideration of costs and

benefits are discussed specifically in the sections below.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\578\ E.g., CL-AII at 6; CL-SIFMA at 10; CL-WMBAA at 8; CL-CME

at 2; CL-Vanguard at 3; CL-Morgan Stanley at 3; CL-ICAP Energy at 3;

CL-Barnard at 1; CL-Freddie at 2; CL-Barclays at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. Costs

a. Direct Costs

Rules 43.6(a)-(f) and (h) will impose recurring costs on swap

market participants and registered entities (i.e., SEFs, DCMs, or SDRs)

to accommodate the Commission's publication of post-initial appropriate

minimum block sizes at least once each calendar year following the

initial period. In the Further Block Proposal, the Commission

anticipated that in order for registered entities to comply with the

rule, they would need to update their existing data systems and that

process would entail approximately 40 initial, non-recurring personnel

hours at an approximate cost of $2,728 for each registered entity.\579\

This estimate included the potential number of burden hours required to

[[Page 32919]]

make a one-time adjustment to internal procedures, reprogram systems

and implement processes to segregate the data by swap categories and

incorporate data on appropriate minimum block sizes as published by the

Commission at least once each calendar year.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\579\ The estimate is calculated as follows: (Senior Programmer

at 20 hours) + (Systems Analyst at 20 hours). A senior programmer's

adjusted hourly wage is $81.52. A systems analyst's adjusted hourly

wage is $54.89. See note 521 supra.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Market participants other than registered entities, and

specifically non-financial end users, expectedly will need to train

their existing personnel and update their written policies and

procedures to comply with Sec. 43.6(a)-(f) and (h). The Commission

estimated that the training and updating of policies and procedures

will impose an initial non-recurring burden of approximately 15

personnel hours at an approximate cost of $1,430 for each non-financial

end-user.\580\ This cost estimate included the number of potential

burden hours required to produce and design training materials, conduct

training with existing personnel, and revise and circulate written

policies and procedures in compliance with the proposed requirements.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\580\ This estimate is calculated as follows: (Compliance

Manager at 10 hours) + (Director of Compliance at 3 hours) +

(Compliance Attorney at 2 hours) = 15 hours per non-financial end-

user who is a reporting party. A compliance manager's adjusted

hourly wage is $77.77. A director of compliance's hourly wage is

$158.21. A compliance attorney's hourly wage is $89.43. See note 521

supra.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission received one comment specifically addressing direct

costs. WMBAA disagreed with the Further Block Proposal's projected cost

estimates and contended that the Commission's approach ``is overly

simplistic and does not contemplate the actual efforts a SEF will have

to undertake to implement the block trade regime, including the two-

step notification process, the technology upgrades, providing training

to existing personnel and updating written policies and procedures,

among other necessary actions to comply with the CFTC's proposed

rule.'' \581\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\581\ CL-WMBAA at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Because WMBAA did not provide data to support or monetize its cost

concern, the Commission has considered them qualitatively. Further,

WMBAA's disagreement with the Further Block Proposal's cost estimates

does not concern the incremental cost to augment and maintain systems

and processes that the Commission believes entities need have in place

to comply with the real time reporting requirement of Section 2(a)(13)

of the CEA; rather it concerns the cost to comply with that statutory

requirement as prescribed by the existing part 43 implementation

regulations. SEFs and DCMs would incur these costs regardless of how

the Commission determines block thresholds. Accordingly, the Commission

considers WMBAA's criticism of the cost estimates in this rulemaking

misplaced. Moreover, the Commission has intentionally structured the

requirements of Sec. 43.6(a) to mitigate these costs; this rule's

approach seeks to leverage the existing connectivity, infrastructure

and arrangements that market participants and registered entities will

have already established to comply with the part 43 regulations.

The Commission did not find, nor was it provided, additional

information that was sufficient to change the cost basis. Therefore,

the Commission is maintaining the Further Block Proposal's approach to

calculating the direct costs resulting from the methodology for

determining block thresholds. However, the Commission is revising its

estimates to reflect wage rate data updated since the Further Block

Proposal was published. The Commission estimates that for registered

entities to update existing technology as necessary will entail

approximately 40 initial, non-recurring personnel hours at an

approximate cost of $2,874 for each registered entity.\582\ The

Commission estimates that training for existing personnel and updating

written policies and procedures will impose an initial non-recurring

burden of approximately 15 personnel hours at an approximate cost of

$1,456 for each non-financial end-user.\583\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\582\ The estimate is calculated as follows: (Senior Programmer

at 20 hours) + (Systems Analyst at 20 hours). A senior programmer's

adjusted hourly wage is $86.89. A systems analyst's adjusted hourly

wage is $56.79. See note 521 supra.

\583\ This estimate is calculated as follows: (Compliance

Manager at 10 hours) + (Director of Compliance at 3 hours) +

(Compliance Attorney at 2 hours) = 15 hours per non-financial end-

user who is a reporting party. A compliance manager's adjusted

hourly wage is $74.17. A director of compliance's hourly wage is

$169.16. A compliance attorney's hourly wage is $103.18. See note

521 supra.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Indirect Costs

The Commission received numerous comments regarding indirect costs

that could result from the establishment of criteria and methodology

for setting appropriate minimum block thresholds. The majority of these

comments focused on the issue of market liquidity; and many of the

comments provided alternatives for either lower notional amount

calculation thresholds, and extended phase-in or restricting the asset

classes to which thresholds would apply. Eleven commenters suggested

that the 67 percent notional amount calculation set forth in proposed

Sec. 43.6(c)(1) would have a negative impact on market liquidity.\584\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\584\ CL-AII at 6; CL-SIFMA at 10; CL-WMBAA at 8; CL-CME at 2;

CL-Vanguard at 3; CL-Morgan Stanley at 3; CL-ICAP Energy at 3; CL-

Barnard at 1; CL-Freddie at 2; CL-Barclays at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

SIFMA and AII asserted that the 67 percent notional amount

calculation is under inclusive for most swap categories and that the

Commission should start with low block sizes (or classify all swaps as

block trades) until data can be accumulated.\585\ Consequences of a

high threshold, they maintain, would be reduced liquidity,

fragmentation of trading, higher transaction costs and higher swap

pricing costs to end users.\586\ AII stated that high block sizes would

permit front running of swap dealers' hedging activities.\587\ SIFMA

suggested that the Commission identify minimum liquidity thresholds for

certain swaps in each swap category below which all swaps should be

treated as blocks.\588\ SIFMA stated that 67 percent is too high to

prevent liquidity impact; that 20-33 percent of trades should be

blocks; and that 50 percent is better than 67 percent.\589\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\585\ CL-AII at 6; CL-SIFMA at 10.

\586\ CL-AII at 6; CL-SIFMA at 10.

\587\ CL-AII at 6.

\588\ CL-SIFMA at 10.

\589\ CL-SIFMA at 10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

WMBAA advocated using a 50 percent or lower block level and that

the Commission rely on more timely and complete data to avoid impairing

liquidity.\590\ CME asserted that 67 percent is arbitrary, has no

relationship to the explicit goals of Dodd-Frank with respect to block

trading of swaps, and would materially reduce market liquidity.\591\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\590\ CL-WMBAA at 8.

\591\ CL-CME at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Vanguard commented that block rules bringing transparency may

ultimately increase liquidity, but an abrupt change could decrease

liquidity.\592\ Vanguard instead favored a lower, 25 percent initial

notional calculation methodology or perhaps providing block treatment

to all swaps for one-year before phasing in notional amount calculation

thresholds, maintaining that a lack of data compromises the setting of

blocks and risks a negative liquidity impact.\593\ Vanguard further

urged more swap category granularity by identifying discrete

``liquidity pools'', and asserted that the lack of a sufficient time

delay would hamper liquidity providers' ability to enter into off-

setting trades.\594\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\592\ CL-Vanguard at 3.

\593\ CL-Vanguard at 3.

\594\ CL-Vanguard at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 32920]]

Morgan Stanley, AII, and CME all stated that the approach in the

Further Block Proposal would sacrifice liquidity in the name of

transparency in contravention of the statute.\595\ Specifically, Morgan

Stanley commented that the proposed rules would diminish liquidity

because the market would know details of transactions that are about to

take place; Morgan Stanley also provided examples of IRS swaps under

the proposed threshold that might move the market and, without

providing further support, stated that application of the 67 percent

notional amount calculation in CDS would result in too few trades

receiving treatment as blocks and reduce liquidity.\596\ Morgan Stanley

urged the Commission to lower block thresholds and apply them only to

vanilla structures with standard maturities; Morgan Stanley further

advocated for DCM/SEFs to set block sizes because they would maximize

liquidity.\597\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\595\ CL-Morgan Stanley at 3; CL-AII at 6; CL-CME at 2.

\596\ CL-Morgan Stanley at 3.

\597\ CL-Morgan Stanley at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ICAP and Barnard asserted that the Further Block Proposal fails to

evaluate the effect of the block thresholds on liquidity.\598\ ICAP

stated that the Commission misconstrued the legislative intent of Dodd-

Frank Act because the Further Block Proposal 1) proposes a ``results-

oriented'' approach; 2) does not determine if the 67 percent

methodology would minimize impact on market liquidity; and 3)

establishes block size thresholds based on notional size rather than

number of transactions.\599\ In addition, ICAP stated that the Further

Block Proposal failed to identify a ``market moving'' transaction for

certain swaps, as intended by Congress and does not propose a

methodology.\600\ Freddie stated that, in the absence of data, minimum

block sizes for Interest Rate swaps are too high and will materially

reduce market liquidity.\601\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\598\ CL-ICAP Energy at 3; CL-Barnard at 1.

\599\ CL-ICAP Energy at 3.

\600\ CL-ICAP at Energy at 3.

\601\ CL-Freddie at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also received comments raising potential indirect

costs besides market liquidity impact. Barclays stated that mandatory

clearing and uncleared margin requirements may compound the costs of

increased transparency created by high block trade thresholds.\602\

SIFMA stated that the Commission's cost-benefit consideration is

insufficient and incorrect in the context of mandatory execution under

the proposed SEF rules.\603\ SIFMA expressed the concern that

``liquidity seekers' [sic] could provide other market participants with

the information needed to front run the successful dealer in the hedge

market.'' \604\ SIFMA concluded that ``the Commission should implement

lower block trade size thresholds to avoid significant decreases in

liquidity or increases in bid-ask spreads.'' \605\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\602\ CL-Barclays at 10.

\603\ CL-SIFMA at 4.

\604\ CL-SIFMA at 4.

\605\ CL-SIFMA at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters objected to the Commission's use of data in the

Further Block Proposal. Five commenters \606\ asserted that the Further

Block Proposal fails to adequately consider costs and benefits and

relies upon obsolete data. AII \607\ stated that the Commission relies

upon inadequate and outdated data, that the rules will impede

competition and increase costs, and that the Commission should look to

TRACE as a model for more deliberate disclosure implementation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\606\ CL-Vanguard at 3; CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 11-13; CL-SIFMA at 10;

CL-WMBAA at 8; and CL-AII at 6.

\607\ CL-AII at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Vanguard \608\ suggested phasing in the requirements because the

new rules are a ``paradigm shift,'' and issuing final rules on block

trades requires more data collection before implementation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\608\ CL-Vanguard at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Several commenters suggest the Commission collect more and better

data before setting block levels. They criticize not only the dearth of

relevant data but how the Commission has interpolated the data through

trimming mechanism. SIFMA suggests that all swaps should be treated as

blocks for first year of compliance during which data is collected,

then the Commission should take a conservative approach to establish

and iteratively modify thresholds based on liquidity and bid-ask spread

of swaps that near the established block size threshold.\609\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\609\ CL-SIFMA at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also received comments suggesting costs in terms of

market liquidity or other factors in setting the appropriate minimum

block thresholds too low (or benefits in setting the appropriate

minimum block thresholds at 67 percent of notional or higher).

Conversely, four commenters expressed support for the Further Block

Proposal's 67 percent notional amount calculation methodology or

suggested that a lower threshold would result in a decrease in

liquidity.\610\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\610\ CL-ODEX at 2; CL-SDMA at 3-6; CL-Javelin at 4-6; CL-Arbor

at 1.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Specifically, Javelin stated that the Commission should set a

higher block threshold than the 67 percent notional amount calculation

``where the market is protected from disruption and where greater

transparency, competition and liquidity are ensured.'' \611\ SDMA

commented that ``[t]oo low a block threshold and fewer trades will be

executed on SEFs as little structural change in swaps execution occurs,

increased competition fails to manifest itself and more diverse

liquidity is impaired.'' \612\ AFR asserted that some drop in liquidity

was assumed by Congress when it enacted the provision and that ``there

is no authoritative study supporting the concept that immediate

disclosure would distort prices because of market liquidity.'' \613\

Similarly, Better Markets argued that any information embargo should be

eliminated, stating that ``there is no authoritative study validating

the notion that market liquidity would be adversely affected if Block

Trade data were fully disclosed.'' \614\ Better Markets also stated

that the public benefits of swap data transparency under the Further

Block Proposal greatly outweigh the private costs to the disclosing

entities and to the swaps market participants; Better Markets argued

that Congress' ultimate objective in the Dodd-Frank Act was to prevent

another crisis and avert the massive costs it would inflict upon the

public (including all market participants), and that the consideration

of costs and benefits should focus on this overriding public

interest.\615\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\611\ CL-Javelin at 2.

\612\ CL-SDMA at 1.

\613\ CL-AFR at 4.

\614\ CL-Better Markets at 4.

\615\ CL-Better Markets at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to comments advocating for a more gradual phase in of

appropriate minimum block thresholds, the Commission is adopting rules

establishing a more conservative 50 percent notional amount calculation

for determining block thresholds in the Interest Rate Swap and Credit

Default Swap categories during the initial period. This will allow for

a more gradual phase-in of the 67 percent notional amount calculation

for determining block thresholds in the post-initial period than what

was proposed. The block trade methodology that will be implemented by

the Commission also allows minimum appropriate block trade amounts to

change periodically in response to the new data collected in the

market.

The Commission believes that this implements the congressional

directive

[[Page 32921]]

for transparency while accounting for possible material reductions in

liquidity through the phasing-in of real-time reporting of a portion of

the swaps market. In contrast, SIFMA's suggestion of treating all swaps

as blocks while the Commission collects data inverts the public policy

rationale underlying congressional requirements for transparency

through real-time public reporting. The most useful data for

determining at what levels blocks would be appropriate is data

collected for swaps reported in real-time when market participants have

the ability to execute block trades above minimum block thresholds.

Data collected prior to the point where real-time reporting and block

levels are functioning together is useful (and has been used by the

Commission in fashioning block thresholds in the initial period for

swaps in the interest rate and credit asset classes), but provides an

incomplete picture absent implementation of the real-time reporting

regime. The Commission's 67 percent notional amount calculation in the

post-initial period is designed to adjust appropriate minimum block

levels once this data becomes available.

Notwithstanding the fact that the commenters did not provide data

to support or monetize their cost concerns, the Commission has

considered their qualitative comments regarding the potential costs

that the Commission's appropriate minimum block threshold methodology

may have on market liquidity.

The Commission agrees with Vanguard that transparency ultimately

promotes increased market liquidity. Transparency afforded through the

publication of swap transaction and pricing data is likely to attract

more market participants to the market place, thereby increasing market

liquidity depth. However, the Commission also understands the tension

between achieving greater swap transaction transparency and liquidity:

required reporting of large transactions without a time delay (i.e., as

soon as technologically practicable) presents potential for downside

cost to certain market participants, most particularly market makers

providing liquidity. The immediate reporting of swaps that approach,

but fall shy of the appropriate minimum block size threshold, may in

certain circumstances increase the difficulty, and thus cost, for

liquidity providers to lay off attendant price risks in the market. As

the commenters suggest, market makers ultimately could pass these costs

on to their end-user clients.

Recognizing the potential for such indirect costs, the Commission

believes it has designed the criteria and methodology outlined in the

rule in a manner that strikes an appropriate balance between the

importance of price discovery and transparency, and concerns about

potential costs to market participants. By establishing a 67 percent

notional amount calculation for appropriate minimum block thresholds in

the post initial period, the Commission will bring transparency through

real-time reporting to the vast majority of transactions in the swap

market.

The Commission believes that the phase-in approach provides swap

market participants with adequate time to incrementally adjust their

trading practices, technology infrastructure and business arrangements

to comply with the new block trade regime. As a result, the rule's

approach promotes liquidity since the Commission believes that a

transparent market with improved pre-trade price transparency is likely

to attract customers. The Commission expects that indirect costs

described above will be mitigated through improved price discovery and

a decrease in the cost of hedging practices for end users due to

improved transparency and competition in the marketplace.

The Commission also considered the potential that different swaps

and futures block criteria and methodology might competitively

disadvantage SEFs to the extent certain market participants consider

swaps and futures products competitive substitutes; thus, in turn,

frustrating public interests that Congress, in authorizing SEFs in the

Dodd-Frank Act, intended to further. For several reasons, the

Commission does not believe this will occur. First, as discussed in the

SEF Rulemaking, the Commission has provided SEFs with various

functionalities designed to provide flexibility that will promote the

trading of swaps on SEFs.\616\ Second, by using futures block

thresholds as a reference for initially setting the criteria for

economically related swaps, the rule, at a minimum, substantially

mitigates any such theoretical costs. Further, the Commission has, and

will use, corrective tools if experience in these newly-regulated

markets indicates potential for differences in swaps and futures block

criteria and methodology to harm market users through hindered product

competition. These tools include periodical recalibration of swap

criteria as anticipated under this rule as well as the Commission's

ability to exercise its legal authority to take action by rule or order

to mitigate any potential harm due to hindered competition.\617\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\616\ See, the Core Principles and Other Requirements for Swap

Execution Facilities notice of proposed rulemaking, 76 FR 1214 (Jan.

7, 2011), for details of functionalities that provide flexibility to

promote trading of swaps on SEFs.

\617\ Historically (and under a rule proposed in a pending

rulemaking concerning Core Principle 9 for Designated Contract

Markets (``DCMs'')), DCMs have discretion to set minimum block

thresholds for futures trading, the Dodd-Frank Act amended the CEA

to require that the Commission specify criteria to determine swap

block trades without imposing an equivalent requirement for

Commission specification of futures block criteria. See Core

Principles and Other Requirements for Designated Contract Markets,

75 FR 80572, 80616-17 (Dec. 22, 2010) (Notice of Proposed

Rulemaking; proposed Sec. 38.503(a) would require that a board of

trade that permits block trade transactions on futures contracts

have rules governing such transactions, including rules limiting

block trades to large transactions and imposing minimum size

requirements, and that block trade size be certified or approved by

the Commission); Core Principles and Other Requirements for

Designated Contract Markets, 77 FR 36612, 36643 (Final Rule;

announces Commission intent to take additional time to consider the

proposed rules for block transactions and other aspects of proposed

rules under Core Principle 9).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

4. Benefits

The Commission believes that Sec. 43.6(a)-(f) and (h) will

generate several overarching benefits to swap market participants,

registered entities and the general public. Most notably, the

Commission expects that the criteria and methodologies for setting

appropriate minimum block sizes will provide greater price transparency

for a substantial portion of swap transactions in a manner carefully

calibrated to preserve and promote swaps market liquidity. More

specifically, the regulations will provide price transparency by

lifting the current part 43 real-time reporting time delay \618\ in a

measured manner for swap transactions with notional values under

specified threshold levels.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\618\ See 77 FR 1240.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

At the same time, the Commission's criteria and methodology--

including carefully crafted block trade and large-notional off-facility

swap categories--are designed to retain time-delay status for those

high-notional-value transactions, where doing otherwise could

negatively impact market liquidity. In addition to avoiding potential

negative market liquidity impact associated with transactions that

remain eligible for a reporting time-delay, the Commission also expects

the liquidity in the market to increase since a more transparent market

is likely to attract more customers. The Commission expects improved

transparency and liquidity to have a positive effect on the prices

market participants will pay for their swaps as

[[Page 32922]]

well as to cause a decrease in the cost of hedging due to improved

transparency and competition in the market. The Commission also expects

that lower hedging costs and improved transparency will reduce systemic

risk potential. A swaps market that is transparent to regulators and

the public in real-time, without the interim delays for all

transactions imposed in Part 43, provides for a system that will assist

the Commission's oversight ability. Finally, the Commission believes

that this added transparency will ultimately strengthen the swaps

market by affording academics, the media, public and market

participants the opportunity to monitor, study, and analyze these

previously opaque segments of the economy.

The rules' phased-in implementation will introduce greater

transparency in an incremental, measured and flexible manner so that

appropriate minimum block sizes can respond to changing markets.

Section 43.6(f)(2) permits the Commission to set appropriate minimum

block sizes no less than once annually during the post-initial period.

If swap market conditions were to change significantly after the

implementation of the provisions of this final rule, there is nothing

that prevents the Commission from reacting to take action further

improving price transparency or mitigating adverse effects on market

liquidity. In an effort to add more flexibility to respond to

continuing swaps market evolution, the methodology in Sec. 43.6(c)-(f)

and (h) will recalibrate appropriate minimum block sizes regularly to

ensure that those sizes remain appropriate for, and responsive to,

these changing markets.

5. Alternatives

The Commission considered alternatives to the determination

criteria and methodology adopted in this rulemaking. The chief

alternatives raised by commenters or otherwise considered by the

Commission concerned three topics--Commission's determination of

minimum block sizes, swap categories, and block methodology--as

discussed below.

a. Commission Determination of Minimum Block Sizes

Under Sec. 43.6(a) the Commission will determine minimum block

sizes; this approach limits the direct burden on market participants

and registered entities relative to an alternative that would require

them to engage a quantitative analysis to ascertain appropriate minimum

block sizes for themselves. Such an alternative approach is

inconsistent with the statutory requirement of CEA section

2(a)(13)(E)(ii) that the Commission ``specify the criteria for

determining what constitutes a large notional swap transaction (block

trade) for particular markets and contracts.'' \619\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\619\ See also 111 Cong. Rec. S. 5921 (daily ed., July 15, 2010)

(Statement of Sen Lincoln) (the regulators are given authority to

establish what constitutes a `block trade' or `large notional' swap

transaction for particular contracts as well as appropriate time

delay in reporting transactions to the public'').

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Swap Category Alternatives

Commenters \620\ noted what they described as a lack of granularity

in the Commission's choice of swaps categories, which they cautioned

would result in the grouping of liquid swaps together with illiquid

swaps in the same swap category. Vanguard \621\ suggested a more

granular approach to setting swap categories and block sizes according

to ``distinct liquidity pools.'' ISDA/SIFMA \622\ suggested subjecting

a swap to block thresholds as long as the swap has sufficient trading

frequency and trades in such volume that allows full hedging in a short

period of time and also prevents widening of the spread as a result of

public reporting. In support of such a test, the comment cited research

and data to suggest that disclosure does not necessarily lead to

increased transparency and swaps with varying levels of liquidity will

be subject to the same block size. Many commenters expressed that the

Commission's determination of swap categories would result in block

levels that are insufficiently granular to account for differences

between swap asset classes and within swap categories, including the

differences in transaction frequency and volume.\623\ Some commenters

suggested that all infrequently traded swaps, under a specified level,

should be treated as block trades.\624\ The various swap category

alternatives suggested by commenters are more fully discussed and

considered in Sections II.A.1-5 of this final rule.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\620\ CL-Vanguard at 7; CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 14; CL-SIFMA at 10; and

CL-Better Markets at 4.

\621\ CL-Vanguard at 7.

\622\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 14; and CL-SIFMA at 10.

\623\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 14; CL-Vanguard at 7.

\624\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 14.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission believes that its approach of establishing specific

criteria for grouping swaps into a finite set of defined swap

categories is preferable to the alternatives noted; it provides (1)

appropriate granularity that mitigates the potential for like risks to

trade differently; and (2) a clear organizational framework that avoids

administrative burdens for market participants that otherwise could

arise from more numerous and/or non-uniform swap categories. The

Commission made use of swaps market data, as well as market convention,

in making its determination of how best to form swap categories and

asset classes as well as buckets within each asset class. Ultimately,

the Commission determined that that the best approach was to allow for

products with similar characteristics and risk structures to be grouped

together, given that in certain circumstances market participants view

similar financial products as close substitutes and use them as such

for risk mitigating purposes. The Commission has fashioned its swaps

categories to, where possible, group together swaps that could be used

to hedge the same risk or otherwise establish an equivalent position.

Grouping economically-substitutable swaps together makes the

setting of appropriate minimum block sizes on an individual product

basis unnecessary and potentially dangerous in that it would allow for

like risks to trade differently.

c. Block Methodology Alternatives

The Commission also considered various alternatives to its proposed

methodologies for determining appropriate minimum block thresholds in

both the initial and the post initial periods. As discussed more fully

in Section II.B., the Commission received various comments suggesting

alternatives to the phased-in approach contained in the Further Block

Proposal. Many commenters compared the 67 percent notional amount

calculation to a 50 percent notional amount calculation, as

specifically requested by the Commission in Question 33 of the Further

Block Proposal. Twelve commenters preferred the 67 percent notional

amount calculation to a 50 percent notional amount calculation;

whereas, nine commenters preferred the 50 percent notional amount

calculation to the 67 percent notional amount calculation. ODEX, RJ

O'Brien, and Spring Trading expressed support for the 67 percent

notional amount calculation, but also suggested that a higher notional

amount calculation would be preferable, particularly in the post-

initial period.\625\ AFR, Better Markets, Javelin, and SDMA all

recommended a 75 percent or higher notional amount calculation and a

market depth and market breadth test.\626\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\625\ CL-ODEX at 1; CL-RJ O'Brien at 1.

\626\ CL-AFR at 8-9; CL-Better Markets at 7-8; CL-Javelin at 2;

CL-SDMA at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 32923]]

Nine commenters preferred the 50 percent notional amount

calculation to the 67 percent notional amount calculation.

Freddie Mac and ICI expressly supported a 50 percent notional

amount calculation.\627\ Pierpont and WMBAA recommended a notional

amount calculation of no greater than 50 percent.\628\ ICAP Energy and

SIFMA recommended a notional amount calculation below 50 percent, but

preferred a 50 percent notional amount calculation to a 67 percent

notional amount calculation.\629\ AII and ICAP recommended not using a

notional amount calculation at all, but preferred a 50 percent notional

amount calculation to a 67 percent notional amount calculation.\630\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\627\ CL-Freddie at 2; CL-ICI at 6-7.

\628\ CL-Pierpont at 3; CL-WMBAA at 3.

\629\ CL-ICAP Energy at 3; CL-SIFMA at 10.

\630\ CL-AII at 6; CL-ICAP Energy at 4.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

AII recommended lowering or eliminating block thresholds until

complete data has been reported to SDRs so as not to impair market

liquidity.\631\ Barclays recommended introducing block levels that

allow for empirical analysis of the transaction data and sequentially

increasing block sizes until such point as the desired equilibrium

between transparency and liquidity is reached.\632\ Better Markets

suggested transitioning to a market depth/market breadth test after the

Commission has collected a year of SDR data.\633\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\631\ CL-AII at 6.

\632\ CL-Barclays at 11.

\633\ CL-Better Markets at 9-10.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also specifically requested comments regarding other

potential methods for determining appropriate minimum block

thresholds.\634\ While numerous comments addressed the efficacy of a

notional amount calculation and the appropriate percentage to use in

making such a calculation, the comments reveal only one significant

alternative methodology to calculating relevant initial and post-

initial minimum block thresholds in place of a notional amount

calculation: block thresholds based on market depth and market

breadth.\635\ The Commission received a number of comments regarding

whether the Commission should use either market depth or market breadth

criteria, instead of the 67-percent notional amount calculation

methodology, to calculate the relevant initial minimum block sizes and

the post-initial minimum block sizes.\636\ Many commenters expressed

support for adopting the market depth test \637\ and other commenters

additionally supported utilizing the market breadth test.\638\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\634\ See Further Block Proposal, Q32-54.

\635\ See Note 262 for an in depth description of the market

depth and market breadth test.

\636\ Market depth and market breadth was proposed to be

calculated as follows: (step 1) Identify swap contracts with pre-

trade price transparency within a swap category; (step 2) calculate

the total executed notional volumes for each swap contract in the

set from step 1 and calculate the sum total for the swap category

over the look back period of one year; (step 3) collect a market

depth snapshot of all of the bids and offers once each minute for

the pre-trade price transparency set of contracts identified in step

1; (step 4) identify the four 30-minute periods that contain the

highest amount of executed notional volume each day for each

contract of the pre-trade price transparency set identified in step

1 and retain 120 observations related to each 30-minute period for

each day of the look-back period; (step 5) determine the average

bid-ask spread over the look-back period of one year by averaging

the spreads observed between the largest bid and executed offer for

all the observations identified in step 3; (step 6) for each of the

120 observations retained in step 4, calculate the sum of the

notional amount of all orders collected from step 3 that fall within

a range, calculate the average of all of these observations for the

look-back period and divide by two; (step 7) to determine the

trimmed market depth, calculate the sum of the market depth

determined in step 6 for all swap contracts within a swap category;

(step 8) to determine the average trimmed market depth, use the

executed notional volumes determined in step 2 and calculate a

notional volume weighted average of the notional amounts determined

in step 6; (step 9) using the calculations in steps 7 and 8,

calculate the market breadth based on the following formula: market

breadth = averaged trimmed market depth + (trimmed market depth -

average trimmed market depth) x .75; (step 10) set the appropriate

minimum block size equal to the lesser of the values from steps 8

and 9. 77 FR 15482.

\637\ CME-CL at 2; ODEX-CLetter at 2; Spring Trading-CL at 2;

MFA-CL at 7; FIA-CL at 2.

\638\ Arbor-CL at 1; AFR-CL at 8-9; Jeffries-CL at 2; SDMA-CL at

3-6; Javelin-CL at 4-6; RJ O'Brien-CL at 1; Better Markets-CL at 9-

10; CRT-CL at 2; FIA-CL at 2.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As discussed more fully in Section II.B., for the initial period

the Commission is adopting the 50 percent notional amount calculation

to determine appropriate minimum block sizes in the interest rate and

credit asset classes. This approach provides for a more gradual phase-

in of minimum block sizes, as recommended by numerous commenters. The

Commission believes that the phase-in approach should provide swap

market participants with an adequate amount of time to incrementally

adjust their trading practices, technology infrastructure and business

arrangements to comply with the new block trade regime.

For the post-initial period, the Commission is adopting Sec.

43.6(f)(1) as proposed. The 67-percent notional amount calculation

means that, within a swap category, approximately two-thirds of the sum

total of all notional amounts will be reported on a real-time basis.

This approach will afford market participants a timely view of a

substantial portion of swap transaction and pricing data to assist them

in determining the competitive price for swaps within a relevant swap

category. The Commission anticipates that this enhanced price

transparency will encourage market participants to provide liquidity

(e.g., through the posting of bids and offers), particularly when

transaction prices move away from the competitive price. The Commission

also anticipates that enhanced price transparency thereby will improve

market integrity and price discovery, while also reducing information

asymmetries enjoyed by market makers in predominately opaque swap

markets.\639\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\639\ The proposed calculation stands in contrast to another

alternative--the proposed 95th percentile-based distribution test

set out in the Initial Proposal. See the discussion in section I.B.

of the Further Block Proposal. No commenters suggested or supported

the distribution test in response to the Further Block Proposal.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the Commission's view, using the 67-percent notional amount

calculation also would minimize the potential impact of real-time

public reporting on liquidity risk compared to other alternatives. The

67 percent notional amount calculation represents a middle ground

between the many commenters who supported higher block thresholds and

the many commenters who preferred much more conservative thresholds.

The Commission believes that its methodology, in conjunction with the

50-percent notional amount calculation during the initial period,

represents a tailored and incremental approach for achieving the goal

of ``a vast majority'' of swap transactions becoming subject to real-

time public reporting.\640\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\640\ The ``guiding principle in setting appropriate block trade

levels [is that] the vast majority of swap transactions should be

exposed to the public market through exchange trading.''

Congressional Record--Senate, S5902, S5922 (July 15, 2010). As

discussed above, this phased-in approach seeks to improve

transparency while not having a negative impact on market liquidity.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As noted above, CEA section 2(a)(13)(E)(iv) directs the Commission

to take into account whether the public disclosure of swap transaction

and pricing data ``will materially reduce market liquidity.'' \641\ If

market participants reach the conclusion that the Commission has set

appropriate minimum block sizes for a specific swap category in a way

that will materially reduce market liquidity, then those participants

are encouraged to submit data to support their conclusion. In addition,

the Commission will conduct its own surveillance of swaps market

[[Page 32924]]

activity and how block sizes affect market liquidity in each of the

specified swap categories.\642\ In response to either a submission or

its own surveillance of swaps market activity the Commission may

exercise its legal authority to take action by rule or order to

mitigate the potential effects on market liquidity with respect to

swaps in a particular swap category.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\641\ 7 U.S.C. 2(a)(13)(E)(iv).

\642\ The Commission received two comments supporting the

Commission's authority to set appropriate minimum block sizes

outside of the proposed annual look-back period. MFA argued that the

Commission's goal to balance transparency and liquidity would be

better achieved with the flexibility to adjust minimum block sizes

quickly to respond to material market changes. MFA recommended that

the Commission should have the authority to update post-initial

minimum block sizes in extraordinary circumstances and on a case-by-

case basis, based on SDR data that it receives for individual or

across multiple swap categories. GFMA stated that if the Commission

establishes a notional calculation test, then it should ensure that

it has sufficient flexibility to amend minimum block sizes. GFMA

recommended that the Commission should be able to ``swiftly alter''

block trade levels to enable some trading to be conducted in a newly

illiquid market, without the benefit of reference to a data set. The

Commission notes that Sec. 43.6(f)(1) provides that the Commission

shall update post-initial appropriate minimum block levels ``[n]o

less than once each calendar year.'' Accordingly, the Commission

notes that it has the ability to adjust post-initial minimum block

sizes under the types of extraordinary circumstances raised by

commenters.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission acknowledges that the market depth and market

breadth test is a viable alternative to the notional amount calculation

methodology. However, it has several prerequisite conditions that

complicate the ability to implement it. For example, the Commission

would need to determine which contracts within a swap category offer

pre-trade price transparency--electronically displayed and executable

bids and offers as well as displayed available volumes for execution.

As noted by commenters, adequate market trading data also must be

available to collect a market depth snapshot of all of the bids and

offers for the pre-trade price transparency set of applicable

contracts. The Commission is also cognizant of MFA's concerns regarding

the potential for manipulation of market depth. Given the time needed

for trading infrastructure to develop and the significant time and cost

considerations involved in collecting such data from SEFs and DCMs, the

Commission deems it unfeasible to implement at this time; the

Commission will continue to examine the merits of doing so in the

future.

6. CEA Section 15(a) Factors

a. Protection of Market Participants and the Public

The Commission believes that the criteria and methodology in Sec.

43.6(a)-(f) and (h) will protect swap market participants by extending

the delay for reporting for publicly reportable swap transactions, as

appropriate, while also accommodating the market participant and public

interest with enhanced transparency. By setting appropriate minimum

block sizes in a thoughtful and measured manner as contemplated in the

final rule, the Commission believes that it has properly balanced the

tradeoff between transparency and liquidity interests. As a result,

swap market participants will retain a means to offset risk exposures

related to their swap transactions at competitive prices. In addition,

the phased-in implementation scheme outlined in this rulemaking will

introduce greater transparency in an incremental, measured and flexible

manner so that appropriate minimum block sizes are responsive to

changing markets. Specifically, the Commission expects that the

availability of real-time pricing information for carefully enumerated

categories of swap transactions will draw increased swap market

liquidity through the competitive appeal of improved pricing efficiency

that greater transparency affords. More liquid, competitive swap

markets, in turn, allow businesses to offset costs more efficiently

than in completely opaque markets, thus serving the interests of both

market participants and the public who should benefit through lower

costs of goods and services.

Another benefit of increasing swaps market transparency to

regulators and the public in real-time, without the interim delays for

all transactions imposed in Part 43, is better protection of market

participants and the public by improving the Commission's oversight

ability and by giving academics, the media, public and market

participants the opportunity to monitor, study, and analyze these

previously opaque segments of the economy.

b. Efficiency, Competitiveness and Financial Integrity of Markets \643\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\643\ The Commission sees no potential impact to the financial

integrity of futures markets from the criteria and methodology in

its consideration of section 15(a)(2)(B) of the CEA. Although by its

terms, section 15(a)(2)(B) applies to futures, the Commission finds

this factor useful in analyzing the costs and benefits of swaps

regulation, as well.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The criteria and methodology set out in the rules will promote

market efficiency, competitiveness and financial integrity of markets

in several ways. The Commission acknowledges that because

responsibility for specifying swap categories and determining

appropriate minimum block sizes is with the Commission rather than

registered entities, the administrative burden on swap market

participants is minimized. Further, the rules afford flexibility to

respond to continuing swaps market evolution, including but not limited

to changing industry practices and activities that the Commission

foresees occurring as market participants comply with regulations,

including part 43, implementing the Dodd-Frank Act regulatory regime.

More specifically, the methodology in Sec. 43.6(c)-(f) and (h) will

recalibrate appropriate minimum block sizes regularly to ensure that

those sizes remain appropriate for, and responsive to, these changing

markets. This ability, coupled with the potential for the Commission to

adjust futures block requirements in pending and future rulemakings

(among other tools) also helps assure that competitive implications

that could arise between substitutable swaps and futures as markets

evolve are appropriately addressed. The Commission believes that the

rules will introduce increased market transparency for swaps in a

careful, measured manner that the Commission believes will optimize the

balance between liquidity and transparency concerns.\644\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\644\ As noted above, under part 43 of the Commission's

regulations (as now promulgated in the Real-Time Reporting Final

Rule), all publicly reportable swap transactions are subject to a

time delay pending further amending regulation to establish the

criteria and methodology to distinguish block trades and large

notional off-facility swaps from those swaps that do not meet those

definitions. See 77 FR 1217. As a result, SDRs as of now are not

required to publicly disseminate publicly reportable swap

transactions as soon as technologically practicable.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

c. Price Discovery

The criteria and methodology set out in the rules will enhance swap

market price discovery by eliminating, to the extent appropriate, the

time delays for the real-time public reporting. The methodology of this

final rule will ensure that an SDR will be able to publicly disseminate

data for certain swaps as soon as technologically practicable and the

majority of the transactions in the market will be visible to traders

as well as the public. Since the majority of trades will be published

and visible in real-time, reported prices are likely to be better

indicators of competitive pricing. As such, the rules promote improved

price discovery.

[[Page 32925]]

d. Sound Risk Management Practices

As discussed above, the Commission believes that the criteria and

methodology set forth in the rules will enhance price discovery since

SDRs will publicly disseminate price and other data relevant to

valuation as soon as technologically practicable for the swaps for

which the time-delay is lifted. This better and more accurate data will

enable swap market participants, generally, to better measure risk. An

ability to better manage risk at an entity level should translate to

improved market participant risk management generally. Improved risk

measurement and management potential, in turn, mitigates the risk of

another financial crisis by better equipping market participants to

value their swap contracts and other assets during times of market

instability.

e. Other Public Interest Considerations

The Commission believes that the criteria and methodology in Sec.

43.6(a)-(f) and (h) will allow the majority of swap transactions and

prices to be publicly disseminated, giving academics, the media, public

and market participants the opportunity to monitor, study, and analyze

these previously opaque segments of the economy. This would allow the

public to be better informed about swaps markets and analyze publicly

available market data disseminated in real-time.

D. Cost-Benefit Considerations Relevant to the Block Trade/Large

Notional Off-Facility Swap Election Process (Sec. 43.6(g))

Section 43.6(g) specifies the process for a market participant to

elect that a swap transaction be treated as a block trade or large

notional off-facility swap (``the election process''). Section

43.6(g)(1) establishes a two-step notification process relating to

block trades. Section 43.6(g)(2) establishes the notification process

relating to large notional off-facility swaps.

Section 43.6(g)(1)(i) sets out the first step in the block trade

notification process: parties to a swap executed at or above the

appropriate minimum block size for the applicable swap category are

required to notify the SEF or DCM, as applicable, of their election to

have their qualifying swap transaction treated as a block trade.

Section 43.6(g)(1)(ii) sets out the second step: the SEF or DCM, as

applicable, that receives an election notification is required to

notify an SDR of a block trade election when transmitting swap

transaction and pricing data to such SDR for public dissemination. The

Commission expects SEFs and DCMs to use automated, electronic--and in

some cases voice--processes to execute swap transactions; the

transmission of the notification of a block trade election, which may

occur separately from the execution process, also will be either

automated, electronic or communicated through voice processes.

Section 43.6(g)(1)(ii) sets out the second step: the SEF or DCM, as

applicable, that receives an election notification is required to

notify an SDR of a block trade election when transmitting swap

transaction and pricing data to such SDR for public dissemination.

1. Costs Relevant to the Election Process (Sec. 43.6(g))

Non-financial end-users who are reporting parties, as well as SEFs,

DCMs, and SDRs will likely bear the costs of complying with the

election process in Sec. 43.6(g). To comply with the real-time

reporting requirements of part 43 already in place, these entities will

have already invested in technology and personnel as well as

established programs for continued systems maintenance, support and

compliance; the Commission has previously described and considered

these costs in the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule.\645\ The Commission

specifically designed the election process so that non-financial end-

users, SEFs, DCMs, and SDRs would be able to leverage any investments

made for compliance with part 43 to also comply with Sec. 43.6(g).

Accordingly, the Commission expects non-financial end-users, SEFs, DCMs

and SDRs to have the following direct, quantifiable costs: (a) An

incremental, non-recurring expenditure to update existing technology to

comply with Sec. 43.6(g); (b) an incremental non-recurring expenditure

for training existing personnel and updating written policies and

procedures for compliance with amendments to part 43; (c) incremental

recurring expenses associated with compliance, maintenance and

operational support in connection with the election process; and (d)

additional incremental, non-recurring expenditures to update existing

technology exclusive to SDRs. SDRs also would have incremental, non-

recurring expenditures to update existing technology.\646\ The

Commission also recognizes that the election process in Sec. 43.6(g)

is voluntary and that eligible entities would not elect block trade

treatment for a swap transaction in circumstances in which they did not

perceive a net benefit in doing so. In the paragraphs that follow, the

Commission discusses each of these costs.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\645\ See 77 FR 1237. As noted in the Real-Time Reporting Final

Rule, non-financial end-users (that do not contract with a third

party) will have initial costs consisting of: (i) Developing an

internal order management system capable of capturing all relevant

data ($26,689 per non-financial end-user) and a recurring annual

burden of ($27,943 per non-financial end-user); (ii) establishing

connectivity with an SDR that accepts data ($12,824 per non-

financial end-user); (iii) developing written policies and

procedures to ensure compliance with part 43 ($14,793 per non-

financial end-user); and (iv) compliance with error correction

procedures ($2,063 per non-financial end-user). See id. With respect

to recurring costs, a non-financial end-user will have: (i)

Recurring costs for compliance, maintenance and operational support

($13,747 per non-financial end-user); (ii) recurring costs to

maintain connectivity to an SDR ($100,000 per non-financial end-

user); and (iii) recurring costs to maintain systems for purposes of

reporting errors or omissions ($1,366 per non-financial end user).

See id.

SDRs (that do not enter into contracts with a third party) would

have incremental costs related to compliance with part 43 beyond

those costs identified in the release adopting part 49 of the

Commission's regulations. See Swap Data Repositories: Registration

Standards, Duties and Core Principles, 76 FR 54538 (Sept. 1, 2011).

In the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule, the Commission stated that

each SDR would have: (i) A recurring burden of approximately

$856,666 and an annual burden of $666,666 for system maintenance per

SDR; (ii) non-recurring costs to publicly disseminate ($601,003 per

SDR); and (iii) recurring cots to publicly disseminate ($360,602 per

SDR). See id.

In the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule, the Commission assumed

that SEFs and DCMs will experience the same or lower costs as a non-

financial end-user. See id.

\646\ SDRs that do not enter into contracts with a third party

would have incremental costs related to compliance with part 43 of

the Commission's regulations beyond those cost identified in the

release adopting part 49 of the Commission's regulations. See Swap

Data Repositories: Registration Standards, Duties and Core

Principles, 76 FR 54538 (Sept. 1, 2011). In the Real-Time Reporting

Final Rule, the Commission stated that each SDR would have: (1) A

recurring burden of approximately $856,666 and an annual burden of

$666,666 for system maintenance per SDR; (2) non-recurring costs to

publicly disseminate ($601,003 per SDR); and (3) recurring costs to

publicly disseminate ($360,602 per SDR). See id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

a. Incremental, Non-Recurring Expenditure to a Non-Financial End-User,

SEF or DCM to Update Existing Technology \647\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\647\ For the same reasons stated in the Real-Time Reporting

Final Rule, the Commission assumes that SEFs and DCMs would

experience the same or less costs as a non-financial end-user. See

77 FR 1236. Under Sec. 43.6(g)(1), SEFs or DCMs would be required

to transmit a block trade election to an SDR only when the SEF or

DCM receives notice of a block trade election from a reporting

party.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

To comply with the election process in Sec. 43.6(g), a non-

financial end-user, SEF, or DCM likely would need to: (1) Update its

Order Management System (``OMS'') to capture the election to treat a

qualifying publicly reportable swap transaction as a block trade or

large notional off-facility swap. In the Further Block Proposal, the

Commission

[[Page 32926]]

estimated that updating an OMS system to permit notification to an SDR

of a block trade or large notional off-facility swap election would

impose an initial non-recurring burden of approximately 80 personnel

hours at an approximate cost of $6,761 for each non-financial end-user,

SEF or DCM.\648\ This cost estimate included an estimate of the number

of potential burden hours required to amend internal procedures,

reprogram systems and implement processes to permit a non-financial

end-user to elect to treat their qualifying swap transaction as a block

trade or large notional off-facility swap in compliance with the

requirements set forth in Sec. 43.6(g). The Commission is revising its

estimates based on updated wage rate data. The Commission estimates

that updating an OMS system to permit notification to an SDR of a block

trade or large notional off-facility swap election would impose an

initial non-recurring burden of approximately 80 personnel hours at an

approximate cost of $7,171 for each non-financial end-user, SEF or

DCM.\649\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\648\ This estimate was calculated as follows: (Compliance

Manager at 15 hours) + (Director of Compliance at 10 hours) +

(Compliance Attorney at 5 hours) + (Senior Systems Analyst at 30) +

(Senior Programmer at 20) = 80 hours per non-financial end-user who

is a reporting party. A compliance manager has adjusted hourly wages

of $77.77. A director of compliance has adjusted hourly wages of

$158.21. A compliance attorney has adjusted hourly wages of $89.43.

A senior systems analyst has adjusted hourly wages of $64.50. A

senior programmer has adjusted hourly wages of $81.52.

\649\ This estimate was calculated as follows: (Compliance

Manager at 15 hours) + (Director of Compliance at 10 hours) +

(Compliance Attorney at 5 hours) + (Senior Systems Analyst at 30) +

(Senior Programmer at 20) = 80 hours per non-financial end-user who

is a reporting party. A compliance manager has adjusted hourly wages

of $74.16. A director of compliance adjusted hourly wages of

$169.16. A compliance attorney has adjusted hourly wages of $103.17.

A senior systems analyst has adjusted hourly wages of $70.45. A

senior programmer has adjusted hourly wages of $86.89.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Incremental, Non-Recurring Expenditure to a Non-Financial End-User

to Provide Training To Existing Personnel and Update Written Policies

and Procedures

To comply with the election process in Sec. 43.6(g), a non-

financial end-user likely would need to provide training to its

existing personnel and update its written policies and procedures to

account for this new process. In the Further Block Proposal, the

Commission estimated that providing training to existing personnel and

updating written policies and procedures would impose an initial non-

recurring burden of approximately 39 personnel hours at an approximate

cost of $3,200 for each non-financial end-user.\650\ This cost estimate

included the number of potential burden hours required to produce

design training materials, conduct training with existing personnel,

and revise and circulate written policies and procedures in compliance

with the requirements set forth in Sec. 43.6(g). The Commission is

revising its estimates based on updated wage rate data. The Commission

estimates that providing training to existing personnel and updating

written policies and procedures would impose an initial non-recurring

burden of approximately 39 personnel hours at an approximate cost of

$3,360 for each non-financial end-user.\651\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\650\ This estimate is calculated as follows: (Compliance

Manager at 5 hours) + (Director of Compliance at 2 hours) +

(Compliance Attorney at 2 hours) + (Senior Systems Analyst at 10) +

(Senior Programmer at 20) = 39 hours per non-financial end-user who

is a reporting party. A compliance manager has adjusted hourly wages

of $77.77.

\651\ This estimate was calculated as follows: (Compliance

Manager at 5 hours) + (Director of Compliance at 2 hours) +

(Compliance Attorney at 2 hours) + (Senior Systems Analyst at 10) +

(Senior Programmer at 20) = 39 hours per non-financial end-user who

is a reporting party. A compliance manager has adjusted hourly wages

of $74.16. A director of compliance adjusted hourly wages of

$169.16. A compliance attorney has adjusted hourly wages of $103.17.

A senior systems analyst has adjusted hourly wages of $70.45. A

senior programmer has adjusted hourly wages of $86.89.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

c. Incremental, Recurring Expenses to a Non-Financial End-User, DCM or

SEF Associated With Incremental Compliance, Maintenance and Operational

Support in Connection With the Election Process

A non-financial end-user, DCM or SEF likely would incur costs on an

annual basis in order to comply with the election process in Sec.

43.6(g). In the Further Block Proposal, the Commission estimated that

annual compliance; maintenance and operation support would impose an

incremental, recurring burden of approximately five personnel hours at

an approximate cost of $340 for each non-financial end-user, DCM or

SEF.\652\ This cost estimate included the number of potential burden

hours required to design training materials, conduct training with

existing personnel, and revise and circulate written policies and

procedures in compliance with the requirements set forth in Sec.

43.6(g). The Commission is revising its estimates based on updated wage

rate data. The Commission estimates the updated approximate cost of

designing training materials, conducting training with existing

personnel, and revising and circulating written policies and procedures

in compliance with the requirements set forth in Sec. 43.6(g) to be

$370 for each non-financial end-user, DCM, or SEF.\653\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\652\ This estimate is calculated as follows: (Director of

Compliance at 1 hour) + (Compliance Clerk at 3 hours) + (Compliance

Attorney at 1 hour) = 5 hours per year per non-financial end-user

who is a reporting party. A director of compliance has adjusted

hourly wages of $158.21. A compliance clerk (junior compliance

advisor) has adjusted hourly wages of $31.22. A compliance attorney

has adjusted hourly wages of 89.43.

\653\ This estimate is calculated as follows: (Director of

Compliance at 1 hour) + (Compliance Clerk at 3 hours) + (Compliance

Attorney at 1 hour) = 5 hours per year per non-financial end-user

who is a reporting party. A director of compliance's adjusted hourly

wage is $169.16. A compliance clerk (junior compliance advisor) has

adjusted hourly wages of $33.52. A compliance attorney's adjusted

hourly wage is $103.17.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

d. Incremental, Non-Recurring Expenditure to an SDR To Update Existing

Technology To Capture and Publicly Disseminate Swap Data for Block

Trades and Large Notional Off-Facility Swaps

To comply with the election process in Sec. 43.6(g), an SDR likely

would need to update its existing technology to capture elections and

disseminate qualifying publicly reportable swap transactions as block

trades or large notional off-facility swaps. In the Further Block

Proposal, the Commission estimated that updating existing technology to

capture elections would impose an initial non-recurring burden of

approximately 15 personnel hours at an approximate cost of $1,310 for

each SDR.\654\ This cost estimate included the number of potential

burden hours required to amend internal procedures, reprogram systems,

and implement processes to capture and publicly disseminate swap

transaction and pricing data for block trades and large notional off-

facility swaps in compliance with the requirements set forth in Sec.

43.6(g). The Commission is revising its estimates based on updated wage

rate data. The Commission estimates the updated approximate cost

required to amend internal procedures, reprogram systems, and implement

processes to capture and publicly disseminate swap transaction and

pricing data for block trades and large notional off-facility swaps in

compliance with the requirements set forth in Sec. 43.6(g) to be

$1,390 for each SDR.\655\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\654\ This estimate is calculated as follows: (Sr. Programmer at

8 hours) + (Sr. Systems Analyst at 3 hours) + (Compliance Manager at

2 hours) + (Director of Compliance at 2 hours) = 15 hours per SDR. A

senior programmer has adjusted hourly wages of $81.52. A senior

systems analyst has adjusted hourly wages of $64.50. A compliance

manager has adjusted hourly wages of $77.77. A director of

compliance has adjusted hourly wages of $158.21.

\655\ This estimate is calculated as follows: (Senior Programmer

at 8 hours) + (Senior Systems Analyst at 3 hours) + (Compliance

Manager at 2 hours) + (Director of Compliance at 2 hours) = 15 hours

per SDR. A senior programmer has adjusted hourly wages of $86.89. A

senior systems analyst has adjusted hourly wages of $70.45. A

compliance manager has adjusted hourly wages of $74.16. A director

of compliance has adjusted hourly wages of $169.16.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 32927]]

2. Comments Received

The Commission received one comment directly related to the costs

of the election process. As discussed more fully above, WMBAA disagreed

with the Further Block Proposal projected cost estimates generally and

contended that the Commission failed to contemplate the actual efforts

a SEF will have to undertake to implement the block trade regime,

including the two-step notification process.\656\ In addition to the

fact that WMBAA did not provide data to support or monetize its

position, WMBAA's disagreement with the Further Block Proposal's

election process cost estimates does not concern the incremental cost

to augment and maintain systems and processes that the Commission

believes entities need have in place to comply with the real time

reporting requirement of Section 2(a)(13) of the CEA; rather it

concerns the cost to comply with that statutory requirement as

prescribed by the existing part 43 implementation regulations. SEFs and

DCMs would incur these costs regardless of how the Commission

determines block thresholds. Accordingly, the Commission considers

WMBAA's criticism of the cost estimates in this rulemaking misplaced.

Therefore, the Commission is maintaining the Further Block Proposal's

approach to calculating the direct costs resulting from the methodology

for determining block thresholds, but is revising its estimates based

on updated wage rate data.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\656\ CL-WMBAA at 8.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. Benefits Relevant to the Election Process (Sec. 43.6(g))

The Commission has identified two overarching benefits that the

election process in Sec. 43.6(g) would confer on swap market

participants, registered entities and the general public. First,

although Sec. 43.6(g) sets out a purely administrative process with

which market participants and registered entities must comply, the

Commission views this process as an integral component of the block

trade framework in this rulemaking and in part 43. Consequently, this

election process will benefit market participants, registered entities

and the general public by providing greater price transparency in swaps

markets than currently exists under part 43.\657\ Since this election

process is optional, entities need avail themselves of the process only

in circumstances where the attendant benefits warrant.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\657\ See the discussion of benefits in section VI.E.1.e above

with respect to Sec. 43.6(a)-(f) and (h).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Second, the Commission believes that the election process will

promote market efficiency by creating a standardized process in Sec.

43.6(g) for market participants to designate publicly reportable swap

transactions that are eligible for block trade or large notional off-

facility swap treatment. In addition, this standardized process will

further promote efficiency by allowing market participants and

registered entities to leverage their existing technology

infrastructure, connectivity, personnel and other resources required

under parts 43 and 49 of the Commission's regulations. The Commission

believes the final rule avoids imposing duplicative or conflicting

obligations on market participants and registered entities.

4. Alternatives

The Commission specifically asked commenters whether there were

alternative methods through which a reporting party could elect to

treat its qualifying swap transaction as a block trade or large

notional off-facility swap. In addition, the Commission asked whether

it should require a variation on the proposed election process where

SEFs, DCMs, and reporting parties would be required to indicate under

which swap category they were claiming block or large notional off-

facility swap treatment. Finally, the Commission asked whether it

should establish an alternative approach for small end-users when such

an end-user is the reporting party to a qualified swap transaction.

No comments were received either proposing or otherwise supporting

an alternative approach and as such, the Commission is adopting in

Sec. 43.6(g) relative to possible alternatives.

5. Application of the Section 15(a) Factors to Sec. 43.6(g)

a. Protection of Market Participants and the Public

Section 43.6(g) is an essential part of this rulemaking because it

provides the mechanism through which market participants will be able

to elect to treat their qualifying swap transaction as a block trade or

large notional off-facility swap. Consequently, this process

contributes to providing greater swap market transparency than what

currently exists under part 43 of the Commission's regulations. Market

participants, registered entities and the general public benefit from

this enhanced swap market price transparency.

b. Efficiency, Competitiveness and Financial Integrity.\658\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\658\ Although by its terms, section 15(a)(2)(B) of the CEA

applies to futures and not swaps, the Commission finds this factor

useful in analyzing the costs and benefits of regulating swaps, as

well. See 7 U.S.C. 19(a)(2)(B).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

As noted above, the election process will promote efficiency by

providing market participants and registered entities with a

standardized process to delineate which publicly reportable swap

transactions are block trades or large notional off-facility swaps. The

voluntary nature of this election process will also add to the

efficiency of the swaps market since eligible entities will only choose

to elect if it is financially beneficial for them to do so. In

addition, the proposed election process will promote efficiency by

allowing non-financial end-users, SEFs, DCMs and SDRs to leverage their

existing technology infrastructure, connectivity, personnel and other

resources required under part 43 and part 49 of the Commission's

regulations. The use of existing technologies, connectivity, personnel

and other resources will create efficiencies for these entities and

mitigate the cost to comply Sec. 43.6(g).

The Commission has identified no potential impact on

competitiveness and financial integrity that would result from the

implementation of the proposed election process.

c. Price Discovery

The Commission has identified no potential material impact to price

discovery that would result from the implementation of the election

process outside of those discussed in section b. above.

d. Sound Risk Management Practices

The Commission has identified no potential impact on sound risk

management practices that would result from the implementation of the

election process outside of those discussed in section b. above.

e. Other Public Interest Considerations

The Commission has identified no potential impact on other public

interest considerations (other than those identified above) that would

result from the implementation of the election process.

[[Page 32928]]

E. Costs and Benefits Relevant to Anonymity Protections (Amendments to

Sec. 43.4(d)(4) and (h))

This section discusses the two amendments to Sec. 43.4. Section

43.4 as now promulgated prescribes the manner in which SDRs must

publicly disseminate swap transaction and pricing data. One amendment

adds a system for masking the geographical data for certain swaps in

the other commodity asset class not currently subject to public

dissemination, which provides limited, but not detailed information on

the geographic location of the underlying assets of those swaps. The

other amendment establishes a methodology to establish cap sizes that

masks the size of swap transactions above a certain threshold, which is

different from the methodology for determining appropriate minimum

block sizes. Both amendments seek to protect the anonymity of the

parties and certain identifying information for swaps while also

providing increased transparency in swaps markets.

1. Amendments to Sec. 43.4(d)(4)

The Commission addresses the public dissemination of information

regarding certain swaps in the other commodity asset class in Sec.

43.4(d)(4). Section 43.4(d)(4)(ii) currently provides that for publicly

reportable swaps in this commodity asset class, information identifying

the underlying assets of the swap must be publicly disseminated for:

(a) those swaps executed on or pursuant to the rules of a SEF or DCM;

(b) those swaps referencing one of the contracts described in appendix

B to part 43; and (c) any publicly reportable swap transaction that is

economically related to one of the contracts described in appendix B to

part 43. Pursuant to the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule, any swap that

is in the other commodity asset class that falls under Sec.

43.4(d)(4)(ii) will be subject to reporting and public dissemination

requirements.

In this final rule, the Commission is adopting a new provision,

Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii), that prescribes a system for the public

dissemination of exact underlying assets in the other commodity asset

class with a ``mask'' for sensitive and potentially revealing

geographic detail. The Commission also is adopting guidance in the form

of a new appendix to part 43 that contains the geographical details

that SDRs will be able to use in masking eligible other commodity swaps

while maintaining compliance with public dissemination of swap

transaction and pricing data.

2. Amendments to Sec. 43.4(h)

Section 43.4(h) establishes cap sizes for ``rounded notional or

principal swap amounts'' above which information on swaps transactions

is publicly reportable, for the purpose of providing anonymity for

transactions where information on the notional or principal amounts

alone would likely reveal the identity of the parties to the swap or

sensitive business information. In doing so, the Commission notes that

the objective of establishing cap sizes differs from that of

establishing appropriate minimum block sizes.\659\ With respect to the

latter, the objective is to ensure that a block trade or large notional

off-facility swap can be sufficiently offset during a relatively short

reporting delay. The former is strictly for the protection of the

counterparties' identity and sensitive business information.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\659\ The Commission received numerous comments suggesting that

the block thresholds and cap sizes established by the Commission

should be the same. However, block thresholds and cap sizes have

different statutory mandates and serve different purposes.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Section 43.4(h) currently requires SDRs to publicly disseminate the

notional or principal amounts of a publicly reportable swap transaction

represented by a cap size (i.e., $XX+) that adjusts in accordance with

the respective appropriate minimum block size for the relevant swap

category. Section 43.4(h) further provides that if no appropriate

minimum block size exists with respect to a swap category, then the cap

size on the notional or principal amount will correspond with interim

cap sizes that the Commission has established for the five asset

classes.\660\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\660\ See note 470 supra, which lists the interim cap sizes set

forth in Sec. 43.4(h)(1)-(5).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The amendment to Sec. 43.4(h) will require SDRs to continue to

publicly disseminate cap sizes that correspond to their respective

appropriate minimum block sizes during the initial period. However,

when the Commission publishes the post-initial appropriate minimum

block sizes in accordance with Sec. 43.6(f), it will also publish

post-initial cap sizes for each swap category by applying a 75-percent

notional amount calculation on data collected by SDRs. The Commission

will apply the 75-percent notional amount calculation to a one-year

rolling window of such data corresponding to each relevant swap

category for each calendar year.

3. Costs Relevant to the Amendments to Sec. 43.4(d)(4) and (h)

SDRs will bear some costs of complying with the amendments to Sec.

43.4(d)(4) and (h).\661\ The Commission set forth the potential costs

of these provisions in the Further Block Proposal and requested

comments regarding its estimates. The Commission did not receive any

comments regarding its estimates.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\661\ The Commission anticipates that reporting parties, SEFs

and DCMs would not incur any new costs related to the amendments to

Sec. 43.4 because this section relates to the data that an SDR must

publicly disseminate. Section 43.3 of the Commission's regulations

sets out the requirements for reporting parties, SEFs and DCMs in

terms of what is transmitted to an SDR.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission anticipates that these entities already will have

made non-recurring expenditures in technology and personnel in

connection with the requirements set forth in part 43 and part 49

(which contain rules regarding the registration and regulation of

SDRs). As such, SDRs already will be required to pay recurring expenses

associated with systems maintenance, support and compliance as

described in the cost-benefit discussion in the Real-Time Reporting

Final Rule.\662\ Notwithstanding these recurring expenses, an SDR will

have additional non-recurring expenditures associated with the

amendments to Sec. 43.4. Specifically, the Commission estimated that

updating existing technology will impose an initial non-recurring

burden of approximately 34 personnel hours at an approximate cost of

$3,190 for each SDR.\663\ This cost estimate included an estimate of

the number of potential burden hours required to amend internal

procedures, reprogram systems and implement processes to capture and

publicly disseminate swap transaction and pricing data for block trades

and large notional off-facility swaps in

[[Page 32929]]

compliance with the requirements set forth in Sec. 43.4(d).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\662\ See 76 FR 54572-75. As noted in SDR final rule, SDRs (that

do not enter into contracts with a third party) would have

incremental costs related to compliance with part 43 beyond those

costs identified in the release adopting part 49 of the Commission's

regulations. See 76 FR 54573. In the Real-Time Reporting Final Rule,

the Commission stated that each SDR would have: (i) A recurring

burden of approximately $856,666 and an annual burden of $666,666

for system maintenance per SDR; (ii) non-recurring costs to publicly

disseminate ($601,003 per SDR); and (iii) recurring cots to publicly

disseminate ($360,602 per SDR). See 77 FR 1238.

\663\ This estimate is calculated as follows: (Sr. Programmer at

20 hours) + (Sr. Systems Analyst at 10 hours) + (Compliance Manager

at 2 hours) + (Director of Compliance at 2 hours) = 34 hours per

SDR. A senior programmer has adjusted hourly wages of $81.52. A

senior systems analyst has adjusted hourly wages of $64.50. A

compliance manager has adjusted hourly wages of $77.77. A director

of compliance has adjusted hourly wages of $158.21. The total number

was calculated incorrectly in the Further Block Proposal. The

initial cost to an SDR should have been $2,747, rather than $3,190.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission is revising its estimates based on updated wage rate

data. The Commission estimates the updated approximate cost required to

amend internal procedures, reprogram systems and implement processes to

capture and publicly disseminate swap transaction and pricing data for

block trades and large notional off-facility swaps in compliance with

the requirements set forth in Sec. 43.4(d) to be $2,930 for each

SDR.\664\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\664\ This estimate is calculated as follows: (Sr. Programmer at

20 hours) + (Sr. Systems Analyst at 10 hours) + (Compliance Manager

at 2 hours) + (Director of Compliance at 2 hours) = 34 hours per

SDR. A senior programmer has adjusted hourly wages of $86.89. A

senior systems analyst has adjusted hourly wages of $70.45. A

compliance manager has adjusted hourly wages of $74.16. A director

of compliance has adjusted hourly wages of $169.16.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In addition, the Commission believes that Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii)

will result in some incremental, recurring costs for SDRs because they

will be required to publicly disseminate other commodity swaps data

that were not previously within the scope of the public dissemination

requirement in Sec. 43.4. The Commission estimates that there will be

approximately 50,000 additional swaps reported to an SDR each year in

the other commodity asset class, which the Commission estimates will be

$154,021 in annualized costs.\665\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\665\ The Commission estimates that there will be 5 SDRs, which

will collect swaps data in the other commodity asset class. Each SDR

would collect swaps data on approximately 10,000 swap transactions

in the other commodity asset class. The commission estimates that it

will take each SDR on average approximately 1 minute to publicly

disseminate swaps data related to these new swap transactions. The

number of burden hours for these SDRs would be 833 hours. As

referenced in note 523 supra, the total labor costs for a swap

trader is $184.90. Thus, the total number of burden hour costs equal

the total number of burden hours (833 burden hours) x $184.90.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also anticipates that Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) will

result in some indirect costs to the market through reduced

information, since notional values of transactions beyond the cap size

limits will not be revealed to the public. The Commission lacks data to

quantify the costs associated with the reduction of information.

However, given the statutory mandate to protect market participant

identities, the Commission believes such costs are warranted and

contemplated by Congress.

The Commission also received a number of comments regarding

potential costs arising from the established level for cap size. GFMA

stated that the same rationale should apply to cap and block sizes, as

both have potential negative impacts on liquidity.\666\ ICI stated that

the 75 percent notional amount would be too high for determining cap

size because the lack of depth and liquidity in the swaps market could

cause public reporting of block sizes to reveal identities, business

transactions, and market positions of participants, and recommends a 67

percent notional amount calculation for determining cap size in the

post-initial period.\667\ ISDA/SIFMA stated that the added transparency

from reporting transaction sizes between 67 percent and 75 percent

would be outweighed by the harm to liquidity from additional

disclosure, and urges the Commission to ensure that the post-initial

cap size is always equal to the relevant block size.\668\ MFA stated

that it is unnecessary for the Commission to establish cap sizes that

differ from minimum block sizes as there is not a meaningful

transparency benefit that would outweigh the resource burdens on the

Commission, SDRs, SEFs, and other market participants.\669\ SIFMA

stated that the Commission should set the notional cap size at the

block threshold, as the added public dissemination could harm liquidity

in the same manner that a higher block trade size threshold might.\670\

Vanguard stated that it is essential that the cap match the block trade

threshold, as to do otherwise would compromise the liquidity

protections afforded by the nuanced assessment of block trade

thresholds.\671\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\666\ CL-GFMA at 5.

\667\ CL-ICI at 8.

\668\ CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 15.

\669\ CL-MFA at 8-9.

\670\ CL-SIFMA at 12.

\671\ CL-Vanguard at 7.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The additional information provided to the market regarding the

size of block trades that are below the cap size may enhance price

discovery by publicly disseminating more information relating to market

depth and the notional sizes of publicly reportable swap transactions.

This, in turn, promotes increased market liquidity.

In addition, the rule incorporates flexibility to adjust post-

initial cap sizes in response to changing markets. Section 43.4(h) will

permit the Commission to set cap sizes no less than once annually

during the post-initial period. If swap market conditions change

significantly after the implementation of the provisions of this

rulemaking, then the Commission can react in a timely manner to further

improve price transparency or to mitigate adverse effects on market

liquidity.\672\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\672\ This benefit is consistent with one of the considerations

for implementation identified by ISDA and SIFMA in their January 18,

2011 report. See Block trade reporting for over-the-counter

derivatives markets, note 32 supra.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

4. Benefits Relevant to the Amendments to Sec. 43.4

The Commission anticipates that the anonymity provisions of Sec.

43.4 will generate several overarching benefits to swap market

participants, registered entities and the general public. In the first

instance, the Commission anticipates that the cap size amendments to

Sec. 43.4(h) will benefit market participants, registered entities and

the general public by providing greater price transparency with respect

to swaps with notional amounts that fall between the post-initial

appropriate minimum block size and post-initial cap size for a

particular swap category. During the post-initial period, the

Commission will set appropriate minimum block sizes based on the 67

percent notional amount calculation \673\ and cap sizes based on the

75-percent notional amount calculation.\674\ Although swaps with

notional amounts that fall between these two sizes will be subject to a

time delay, the exact notional amounts of these swaps eventually will

be publicly disclosed. The delayed public disclosure of the notional

amount of these swaps will provide market participants, registered

entities and the general public with meaningful price transparency.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\673\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(c)(1).

\674\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(c)(2).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The masking provisions in the amendment to Sec. 43.4(d)(4) and

appendix D to part 43 will further benefit market participants,

registered entities and the general public by enhancing price discovery

with respect to swaps that currently are not required to be publicly

disclosed under part 43. Section 43.4(d)(4) currently requires SDRs to

publicly disseminate swap transaction and pricing data for publicly

reportable swap transactions that reference or are economically related

to the 29 contracts identified in appendix B to part 43. However, the

Commission believes there are a significant number of swaps in the

other commodity asset class that are not economically related to the 29

contracts identified on this appendix to part 43. The amendment

creating new Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) will require the public

dissemination of data on these swaps. The real-time public reporting of

these swaps will enhance price discovery in the other commodity asset

class.

[[Page 32930]]

In addition, the rule incorporates flexibility to adjust post-

initial cap sizes in response to changing markets. Section 43.4(h) will

permit the Commission to set cap sizes no less than once annually

during the post-initial period. If swap market conditions change

significantly after the implementation of the provisions of this

rulemaking, then the Commission can react in a timely manner to further

improve price transparency or to mitigate adverse effects on market

liquidity.\675\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\675\ This benefit is consistent with one of the considerations

for implementation identified by ISDA and SIFMA in their January 18,

2011 report. See Block trade reporting for over-the-counter

derivatives markets, note 32 supra.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

5. Alternatives

The Commission received numerous comments supporting alternatives

to the proposed anonymity provisions in Sec. 43.4(d)(4) and (h). These

alternatives fall into two basic categories: (1) Post-initial cap size

level; and (2) preventing public disclosure of swap market participant

identity. In regard to cap size, seven commenters recommended that the

Commission set post-initial cap sizes matching the minimum block size

thresholds established by the Commission. AII supported setting the

post-initial cap size for each swap category at the same level as the

block size threshold and states that the 75 percent notional amount

calculation is far too high.\676\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\676\ CL-AII at 12.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

For the initial period, AII and ISDA/SIFMA argued that the cap size

should be the lower of block size and the interim cap size in Sec.

43.4(h)(1).\677\ Barclays recommended that the post initial period cap

sizes be introduced at more nuanced levels that reflect the differences

between product's traded volumes.\678\ EEI stated that the initial cap

size of $25 million for both the Electricity Swap Contracts and the

Other Commodity Electricity Swap Category is too high, as is the 75

percent notional amount for the post-initial period. EEI recommended

that the Commission adopt a fixed cap size of $3 million for both

periods.\679\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\677\ CL-AII at 12; CL-ISDA/SIFMA at 15.

\678\ CL-Barclays at 6.

\679\ CL-EEI at 5.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission has evaluated these various alternatives concerning

post-initial cap size levels against the statutory requirements imposed

upon it by Section 2(a)(13): bring real-time public reporting to the

swaps market subject to time delays for block trades and large notional

off-facility swaps that it determines appropriate.\680\ However, the

statute only calls for a time delay--it does not provide for

information to be kept from the market in perpetuity. All of the

information regarding a block trade is reported to the market at the

end of the block time delay. Notional or principal amount information

above cap sizes, on the other hand, is never expressed to the market.

Because the notional amount of the trade is neither reported to the

market in real-time, nor reported to the market at all, the Commission

believes that cap sizes should be set at a higher level than block

sizes. The 75 percent notional test balances the competing interests of

providing meaningful real-time public reporting to the swaps market and

protecting the anonymity of swap market participants, while taking into

account potential impacts on market liquidity.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\680\ Section 2(a)(13)(E) of the CEA.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The additional information provided to the market regarding the

size of block trades that are below the cap size may enhance price

discovery by publicly disseminating more information relating to market

depth and the notional sizes of publicly reportable swap transactions.

This, in turn, promotes increased market liquidity.

In regard to alternatives for preventing the public disclosure of

the identities of swap market participants, the Commission received

three comments regarding the masking of specific delivery or pricing

detail of energy and power swaps. EEI recommended that the Commission

mask data regarding Other Commodity Electricity Swaps according to the

North American Electric Reliability Corporation eight regions rather

than the FERC regions proposed.\681\ Barclays recommended that the

Commission use wider geographic regions when publicly disseminating

data for commodity swaps with very specific underlying assets and/or

delivery points and develop an appropriate process to avoid identifying

issuers of debt.\682\ Spring Trading supported further measures to

prevent public disclosure of identities, business transactions, and

market positions of swap market participants, and recommended

disclosing a subset of data on a collective basis at a later date.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\681\ CL-EEI at 12-13.

\682\ CL-Barclays at 6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

After consideration of the alternatives suggested by commenters,

the Commission is adopting Sec. 43.4(d)(iii) with the following

modification that it believes affords greater anonymity protection

relative to the Further Block Proposal, without adversely impacting

transparency. The modification is: For publicly reportable swap

transactions that have electricity and sources as an underlying asset

and have a specific delivery or pricing point in the United States, the

Commission is requiring SDRs to public disseminate the specific

delivery or pricing point based on a description of one of the North

American Electric Reliability Corporation (``NERC'') regions for

publicly disseminating delivery or pricing points for electricity swaps

described in proposed Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii). Using the regions

suggested by EEI further masks specific delivery details and thus

provides additional protection against public disclosure of identities,

business transactions, and market positions of swap market

participants, as recommended by Barclays and Spring Trading.

The Commission also considered the alternative of having DCMs and

SEFs set cap sizes. The Commission ultimately chose to determine cap

sizes itself for the reason that doing so limits the direct burden on

registered entities to determine and implement appropriate cap sizes

themselves. As such, the chosen approach will promote market efficiency

for market participants and registered entities.

6. Application of the Section 15(a) Factors to the Amendments to Sec.

43.4

a. Protection of Market Participants and the Public

The amendments to Sec. 43.4 protect swap counterparty anonymity on

an ongoing basis. While cap sizes for some transactions can exceed

appropriate minimum block sizes in certain circumstances (resulting in

the public dissemination of notional/principal-amount information after

a time delay), the Commission believes that for the vast majority of

impacted swap transactions, the cap-size process and methodology is

sufficient to distinguish correctly between those for which masking of

notional or principal amount is required to maintain anonymity and

those for which it is not.\683\ The Commission believes that setting

post-initial cap sizes above appropriate minimum block sizes will

provide additional pricing information with respect to large swap

transactions, which are large enough to be treated as block trades (or

large notional off-facility swaps), but small enough that they do not

exceed the applicable post-

[[Page 32931]]

initial cap size. This additional information may enhance price

discovery by publicly disseminating more information relating to market

depth and the notional sizes of publicly reportable swap transactions,

while still protecting the anonymity of swap counterparties and their

ability to lay off risk when executing extraordinarily large swap

transactions.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\683\ The Commission recognizes that adoption of rules that

delineate cap sizes insufficient to provide anonymity could cause

prospective counterparties to forego swap transactions, thus

adversely impacting market liquidity.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Efficiency, Competitiveness and Financial Integrity \684\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\684\ Although by its terms, section 15(a)(2)(B) applies to

futures and not swaps, the Commission finds this factor useful in

analyzing the costs and benefits of swaps regulation, as well. 7

U.S.C. 19(a)(2)(B).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission believes that amendments to Sec. 43.4(h) promote

market efficiencies and competitiveness since the approach will provide

market participants with the ability to continue transacting swaps with

the protection of anonymity, while promoting greater price

transparency.

The Commission does not believe that the implementation of the

anonymity protections established in Sec. 43.4(h) will adversely

impact the financial integrity of swap markets. The Commission has

considered the comments provided regarding impacts on liquidity arising

out of the 75 percent notional cap size. The Commission does not agree

that the cap size will have a substantial negative impact on market

liquidity. As stated above, the additional pricing information

available to the market as a result of the 75 percent notional cap size

promotes enhanced price discovery by publicly disseminating more

information relating to market depth and the notional sizes of publicly

reportable swap transactions, while still protecting the anonymity of

swap counterparties and their ability to lay off risk when executing

extraordinarily large swap transactions. This, in turn, promotes market

liquidity.

c. Price Discovery

The cap size amendments to Sec. 43.4(h) should benefit market

participants, registered entities and the general public by providing

greater price transparency with respect to swaps with notional amounts

that fall between the post-initial appropriate minimum block size and

post-initial cap size for a particular swap category. During the post-

initial period, the Commission will set appropriate minimum block sizes

based on the 67 percent notional amount calculation \685\ and cap sizes

based on the 75-percent notional amount calculation.\686\ Although

swaps with notional amounts that fall between these two sizes will be

subject to a time delay, the exact notional amounts of these swaps will

be publicly disclosed after the established time delay for blocks and

large notional off-facility swaps.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\685\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(c)(1).

\686\ See proposed Sec. 43.6(c)(2).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The masking provisions in the amendment to Sec. 43.4(d)(4) and

appendix D to part 43 further benefit market participants, registered

entities and the general public by enhancing price discovery with

respect to swaps that currently are not required to be publicly

disclosed under part 43. The amendment creating new Sec.

43.4(d)(4)(iii) will require the public dissemination of data on these

swaps. The Commission expects that the real-time public reporting of

these swaps will enhance price discovery in the other commodity asset

class.

d. Sound Risk Management Practices

To the extent that the amendments to Sec. 43.4 mask the identity,

business transactions and market positions of swap counterparties, the

Commission expects that the amendments to Sec. 43.4 provide those

traders with the anonymity and time delay they require to manage their

market risk efficiently.

e. Other Public Interest Considerations

The Commission does not anticipate that the amendment to Sec.

43.4(h) will have a material effect on public interest considerations

other than those identified above.

F. Costs and Benefits Relevant to Sec. 43.6(h)(6)--Aggregation

Section 43.6(h)(6) specifies that, except as otherwise provided, it

is impermissible to aggregate orders for different accounts in order to

satisfy minimum block trade or cap size requirements. The rule further

provides that aggregation may be permitted on a DCM or SEF if done by a

person who: (i)(A) is a CTA who is registered pursuant to Section 4n of

the Act or is exempt from registration under the Act, or a principal

thereof, and has discretionary trading authority or directs client

accounts, (B) is an investment adviser who has discretionary trading

authority or directs client accounts and satisfies the criteria of

Sec. 4.7(a)(2)(v) of the Commission's regulations, or (C) is a foreign

person who performs a role or function similar to the persons described

in (A) or (B) and is subject as such to foreign regulation, and (ii)

has more than $25,000,000 in total AUM.

1. Overview of Comments Received

The Commission received a number of comments with the proposed

aggregation rule but none directly addressing the costs and benefits

considerations of the rule.

JP Morgan commented that the rule appears to reflect a concern that

private negotiation affords less protection to unsophisticated

investors than trading through the central markets, and that since all

entities that transact in the OTC market already must be ECPs, the

analogous concern about customer protection in the swaps market is

already addressed.\687\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\687\ CL-JPM at 9, n.13.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

ICI opposed the minimum assets under management requirement in

proposed Sec. 43.6(h)(6)(ii) and argued that the Commission did not

articulate a rationale or policy reason for this requirement.\688\ ICI

also disagreed that an investment adviser seeking to aggregate orders

must satisfy the criteria of Sec. 4.7(a)(2)(v) of the Commission's

regulations.\689\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\688\ CL-ICI at 3.

\689\ Id. at 4. An investment adviser satisfies the criteria of

Sec. 4.7(a)(2)(v) if the investment adviser registers pursuant to

Sec. 203 of the Investment Advisers Act of 1940, or pursuant to the

laws of any state, and the investment adviser has been registered

and active for two years or provides security investment advice to

securities accounts which, in the aggregate, have total assets in

excess of $5,000,000 deposited at one or more registered securities

brokers. 17 CFR 4.7(a)(2)(v).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

With respect to JP Morgan's comment, the Commission notes that

customers trading swaps on DCMs do not have to be ECPs. As discussed

further below, adopted Sec. 43.6(i)(1) allows non-ECP customers to be

parties to block trades through a qualifying CTA, investment adviser,

or similar foreign person.\690\ It is possible, therefore, that those

non-ECP DCM customers may not be aware if they received the best terms

for their individual swap transactions that are aggregated with other

transactions. Protection for such customers is therefore necessary, as

it is for unsophisticated customers in other markets.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\690\ See infra Section II.C.6.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In response to ICI's opposition to the minimum asset threshold

under Sec. 43.6(h)(6)(ii), the Commission notes that this threshold

reflects common industry practice.\691\ CME, for example, has enforced

the $25 million threshold

[[Page 32932]]

in its rules since September 2000.\692\ CME has stated that the

threshold ``is an effort to establish the professionalism and

sophistication of the registrant'' \693\ while also expanding the

number of CTAs and investment advisers eligible to aggregate

trades.\694\ The Commission believes that the $25 million threshold is

an appropriate requirement to ensure that persons allowed to aggregate

trades are appropriately sophisticated with these transactions, while

at the same time not excluding an unreasonable number of CTAs,

investment advisers, and similar foreign persons.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\691\ See, e.g., CME Rule 526. See also CBOE Futures Exchange

LLC Rule 415(a)(i); Chicago Board of Trade Rule 526; Eris Exchange,

LLC Rule 601(b)(10); ICE Futures U.S. Rule 4.07; NASDAQ OMX Futures

Exchange, Inc. Rule E23; New York Mercantile Exchange, Inc. Rule

526(I); NYSE Liffe US, LLC Rule 423; and OneChicago LLC Rule 417.

\692\ See CME Submission 00-99 (Sept. 21, 2000) (modifying CME

Rule 526 to reduce the threshold from $50,000,000 to $25,000,000).

CME originally planned to lower the threshold from $50,000,000 to

$5,000,000, but withdrew the submission and instead proposed to

lower the threshold to $25,000,000, based on customer suggestions.

See CME Submission 00-93 (Sept. 1, 2000); CME Submission 00-99 at 5-

6.

\693\ Id. at 6 (quoting letter addressed to Jean A. Webb,

Secretary of the Commission from John G. Gaine, President, Managed

Funds Association dated April 24, 2000 regarding ``Chicago

Mercantile Exchange new Proposed Rule 526'').

\694\ Id. at 4, 6-7. CME also stated in the filing that it

planned to readdress the threshold amount as it gained experience

with block trades, but has declined to modify the amount.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission also disagrees with ICI's contention that investment

advisers should not be required to satisfy the criteria under Sec.

4.7(a)(2)(v), which requires an investment adviser to (1) be registered

and active as an investment adviser for two years or (2) provide

securities investment advice to securities accounts which, in the

aggregate, have total assets in excess of $5 million deposited at one

or more registered securities brokers.\695\ The Commission first

adopted provisions similar to current Sec. 4.7(a)(2)(v) in 1992 \696\

as objective indications that a person had the investment

sophistication and experience needed to evaluate the risks and benefits

of investing in commodity pools or a portfolio large enough to indicate

the same, along with the financial resources to withstand the

investment risks.\697\ In 2000,\698\ the Commission extended the same

criteria in current Sec. 4.7(a)(2)(v) to registered investment

advisers for the same reasons.\699\ The Commission believes that these

objective criteria, which demonstrate that an investment adviser

possesses the necessary investment expertise, should also apply with

respect to allowing such persons to aggregate client orders.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\695\ 17 CFR 4.7(a)(2)(v).

\696\ 57 FR 34853, 34854-55 (Aug. 7, 1992). The final rule

reduced the amount on deposit threshold to $5 million from the $10

million required by the proposed rule. See 57 FR 3148, 3152 (Jan.

28, 1992).

\697\ See 57 FR at 34854 (quoting 57 FR at 3152).

\698\ 65 FR 11253, 11257-58 (Mar. 2, 2000).

\699\ Id. at 11257 (quoting 57 FR at 3152).

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission believes that the $25 million threshold, as well as

requiring investment advisers to satisfy the criteria under Sec.

4.7(a)(2)(v), are both important for certifying that persons allowed to

aggregate trades are appropriately sophisticated and important for

protection of market participants and public.

2. Costs

The Commission expects that there will be some incremental cost

attendant to compliance with Sec. 43.6(h)(6). The Commission believes

that the overall benefits to the market of allowing for the aggregation

of orders under certain circumstances (i.e., if done on a designated

contract market or a swap execution facility by certain CTAs,

investment advisers or foreign persons) will mitigate costs of reduced

market liquidity that could result from execution of such transactions

away from the centralized marketplace. The Commission also expects

there to be some advisors who will be prohibited from aggregating

orders for different trading accounts in order to satisfy the minimum

block size, or cap size requirements. The Commission also believes that

as a result of some advisers not being allowed to aggregate, there

might be some minimal unquantifiable cost associated with a decrease in

competition among such traders in the market.

3. Benefits

The rule is designed, in large part, to prevent circumvention of

the exchange trading requirements and of the real-time reporting

obligations associated with non-block transactions. Absent this

prohibition, the goals of the Commission's regulations regarding block

trading, namely increased transaction transparency, better price

discovery and improved competitiveness in the markets as well as better

risk management, could be frustrated by those whose trades individually

fail to meet the minimum block trade threshold (and cap size threshold

as a result), but nevertheless achieve the benefits intended for

extraordinarily large positions by aggregating those individual trades.

In other words, such entities would be able to evade the exchange-

trading and reporting obligations that are integral to price

transparency.

4. Section 15(a) Factors

a. Protection of Market Participants and the Public

The Commission believes that the rule will protect market

participants from unfair practices by preventing trades that do not

meet the minimum block trade threshold from enjoying extended reporting

times. This means that trades that are not extraordinarily large, and

hence, that do not need extra reporting time will not qualify as block

trades and will be made public as soon as technologically practicable.

Hence, the rule will increase transparency of non-block transactions,

and thus, would protect market participants by informing their trading

determinations through increased transparency and price discovery.

b. Efficiency, Competitiveness, and Financial Integrity of the Futures

Markets

The Commission expects the prohibition of aggregation of trades to

improve efficiency and competitiveness in the markets by allowing more

trades to be reported without the time delay that is applied to

qualifying block trades. This means that a higher number of trades will

be eligible for real time reporting, and that will increase market

transparency as well as promote competition in the swap markets. The

rule also will protect the integrity of the derivatives market by

ensuring that smaller trades, which do not qualify as block

transactions, are executed on the trading system where there is pre-

trade and post-trade transparency.

The Commission also recognizes that advisors who are prohibited

from aggregating orders in order to satisfy the minimum block size or

cap size requirements might not trade at the most favorable prices in

the market, which might have a negative effect on the number of such

traders in the market. While the Commission expects that competition in

the market may be negatively affected as a result of prohibiting

aggregation, the Commission anticipates that the positive effects of

the rule on competition outweigh its negative effects.

c. Price Discovery

The Commission expects the rule to improve price discovery in the

swap markets by preventing aggregation of trades and as a result

promoting more trades to be publicly reported as soon as

technologically practicable. This will result in enhanced swap market

price discovery, since market participants and the public will be able

to observe real-time pricing information for a higher

[[Page 32933]]

percentage of transactions in the market. In addition, the Commission

expects that the rule will enhance price discovery by ensuring that

smaller trades, which do not qualify as block transactions, are

executed on the trading system where there is pre-trade and post-trade

transparency and where buyers and sellers may make informed trading

decisions based on the market's transparency.

d. Sound Risk Management Practices

The Commission anticipates that the criteria will likely result in

enhanced price discovery as discussed above. With better and more

accurate data, swap market participants will likely be better able to

measure and manage risk. The Commission believes that if the

prohibition of aggregation of trades was not adopted, swap transactions

may not be reported to an SDR ``as soon as technologically

practicable.'' The Commission also believes that by preventing this

delay in the reporting period of a swap transaction to an SDR, the

Commission will possess the information it needs to monitor the

transfer and positions of risk among counterparties in the swaps

market.

e. Other Public Interest Considerations

The Commission has not identified any other public interest

considerations regarding the rule.

G. Costs and Benefits Relevant to Sec. 43.6(i)--Eligible Block Trade

Parties

1. Overview of Comments Received

The Commission received few comments with respect to the eligible

block trade parties rule. As discussed above, similar comments

regarding the exceptions to the prohibitions against aggregation for

certain persons were submitted with respect to the exception to certain

persons transacting blocks on a DCM on behalf of non-ECPs. For example,

ICI opposed the minimum assets under management requirement in proposed

Sec. 43.6(i)(1) and similarly argued that the Commission did not

articulate a rationale or policy reason for this requirement.\700\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\700\ CL-ICI at 3.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission received one specific comment related to costs on

proposed Sec. 43.6(i)(2). SIFMA commented that proposed Sec.

43.6(i)(2) may require asset managers to obtain consent from each

client for whom they will engage in block trades.\701\ SIFMA contended

that this requirement would be costly and unnecessary, and that notice

to the customers \702\ or a general grant of investment discretion in

the investment management agreement, power of attorney, or similar

document should be sufficient.\703\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\701\ CL-SIFMA at 1.

\702\ Id. at 2.

\703\ Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission disagrees with SIFMA's contention regarding the

burdens of obtaining consent. This burden consent will be minimal

because Sec. 43.6(i)(2) states that the instruction or consent may be

provided through a power of attorney or similar document that provides

discretionary trading authority or the authority to direct trading in

the account. The consent may therefore be included in existing and

future customer agreements. The Commission further disagrees that a

general grant of investment discretion or notice to the customer should

satisfy Sec. 43.6(i)(2). A customer's written instruction or consent

is necessary because a customer potentially may not receive the best

terms for an individual swap transaction that is part of an

aggregation. The written instruction or consent makes the customer

aware that block trades may be used on its behalf, allowing the

customer to decide whether to allow these transactions, through which

the rule has the added benefit of protection of market participants and

public. The Commission also would like to point out that a cost

estimate for that burden has already been presented in the proposed

rule and received no direct comments on that cost estimate.

2. Costs

Section 43.6(i)(1) requires that parties to a block trade must be

eligible contract participants, as defined under the CEA and Commission

regulations, except that a DCM may allow: (i) A CTA registered pursuant

to Section 4n of the Act or exempt from registration under the Act, or

a principal thereof, and who has discretionary trading authority or

directs client accounts, (ii) an investment adviser who has

discretionary trading authority or directs client accounts and

satisfies the criteria of Sec. 4.7(a)(2)(v) of the Commission's

regulations, or (iii) a foreign person who performs a similar role or

function to the persons described in (i) or (ii) and is subject as such

to foreign regulation, to transact block trades for customers who are

not eligible contract participants, if such CTA, investment adviser or

foreign person has more than $25,000,000 in total AUM. This rule

codifies, in part, the requirement under Section 2(e) of the CEA, which

requires that ``[i]t shall be unlawful for any person, other than an

eligible contract participant, to enter into a swap unless the swap is

entered into on, or subject to the rules of[hellip].a designated

contract market.'' In addition, the provisions allowing certain

entities (as described in this release) to enter into block trades on

behalf of their non-ECP customers on DCMs is substantially similar to

the existing DCM rules that allow block trading in the futures market.

Section 43.6(i)(2) further provides that no person may conduct a

block trade on behalf of a customer unless the person receives prior

written instruction or consent to do so. The rule further provides that

such instruction or consent may be provided in the power of attorney or

similar document by which the customer provides the person with

discretionary trading authority or the authority to direct the trading

in its account. The Commission is of the view that the cost associated

with the written instruction or consent is minimal. The Commission

estimates that a prior written instruction or consent requirement would

impose an initial non-recurring burden of approximately 2 personnel

hours at an approximate cost of $155.54 for each CTA, investment

adviser or foreign person.\704\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\704\ The estimate is calculated as follows: Compliance manager

at 2 hours. A compliance manager's adjusted hourly wage is $77.77.

See note 521 supra.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. Benefits

The Commission has determined that the benefits of Sec. 43.6(i)

are significant. The rule allows customers who are not ECPs to engage

in block trade transactions through certain entities as outlined in the

rule. By permitting certain CTAs, investment advisers and foreign

persons to transact swaps on behalf of non-ECP customers, the rule

provides important safeguards for non-ECPs when entering into block

transactions in swaps. The Commission believes that access to block

trades will allow customers who are not ECPs to diversify their risk or

improve their investment strategies. In addition, the Commission also

anticipates the access to block trades for non-ECPs to increase their

participation in swap markets, increasing liquidity in the markets for

everyone.

The Commission acknowledges that Sec. 43.6(i)(2) has the added

benefit of protection of market participants and public since the

written instruction or consent required in Sec. 43.6(i)(2) of the rule

makes the customer aware that block trades may be used on its behalf,

allowing the customer to decide whether to allow these transactions.

[[Page 32934]]

4. Section 15(a) Factors

a. Protection of Market Participants and the Public

As discussed above, Sec. 43.6(i)(2), by requiring that no person

may conduct a block trade on behalf of a customer unless the person

receives prior written instruction or consent to do so, protects the

customer by making sure the customer is aware that block trades may be

used on its behalf. This means better protection for market

participants and the public since no one will be able to conduct a

block trade on their behalf without their consent.

b. Efficiency, Competitiveness, and Financial Integrity of the Futures

Markets

The Commission expects the rule to improve competitiveness in the

markets by allowing customers who are not ECPs to have access to block

trades through certain CTAs, investment advisers and foreign persons.

The Commission anticipates an increase in competitiveness due to the

fact that more customers would use the swap markets as a result of this

rule. An increased participation in a market will also serve to

increase liquidity, as well as competition, in that market.

c. Price Discovery

The Commission does not anticipate the rule to have any significant

effect on price discovery in the market.

d. Sound Risk Management Practices

The Commission does not anticipate the rule to have any significant

effect on risk management practices.

e. Other Public Interest Considerations

The Commission has not identified any other public interest

considerations regarding the rule.

VI. Regulatory Flexibility Act

The Regulatory Flexibility Act (``RFA'') requires Federal agencies

to consider the impact of its rules on ``small entities.'' \705\ A

regulatory flexibility analysis or certification typically is required

for ``any rule for which the agency publishes a general notice of

proposed rulemaking pursuant to'' the notice-and-comment provisions of

the Administrative Procedure Act, 5 U.S.C. 553(b).\706\ With respect to

the Further Block Proposal, the Commission provided in its RFA

statement that the proposed rule would have a direct effect on a number

of entities, specifically DCMs, SEFs, SDs, MSPs, and certain single

end-users.\707\ In the Further Block Proposal, the Chairman, on behalf

of the Commission, certified that the rulemaking would not have a

significant economic effect on a substantial number of small entities.

Comments on that certification were sought.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\705\ See 5 U.S.C. 601 et seq.

\706\ See 5 U.S.C. 601(2), 603, 604, and 605.

\707\ As discussed more fully in the Further Block Proposal, the

Commission is of the view that registered entities such as SDs and

MSPs are not small businesses.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

In the Further Block Proposal, the Commission provided that it

previously had established that certain entities subject to its

jurisdiction are not small entities for purposes of the RFA.

Specifically, the Commission stated that it had previously determined

that SEFs and DCMs are not small businesses.\708\ The Commission also

stated that it is of the view that SDs and MSPs are not small

businesses.\709\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\708\ 77 FR at 15499. See 17 CFR part 40 Provisions Common to

Registered Entities, 75 FR 67282 (Nov. 2, 2010); see also 47 FR

18618, 18619, Apr. 30, 1982 and 66 FR 45604, 45609, Aug. 29, 2001.

\709\ 77 FR at 15499.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission recognized that the proposed rule could impose

direct burdens on parties to a swap, which the Commission has

determined previously may include a percentage of small end users that

are considered small businesses for the purposes of the RFA.\710\

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\710\ See 77 FR 1240 (``[T]he Commission recognized that the

proposed rule could have an economic effect on certain single end

users, in particular those end users that enter into swap

transactions with another end-user. Unlike the other parties to

which the proposed rulemaking would apply, these end users are not

subject to designation or registration with or to comprehensive

regulation by the Commission. The Commission recognized that some of

these end users may be small entities.''). The term reporting party

also includes swap dealers and major swap participants.

The Commission previously has determined that these entities do

fall within the definition of small business for the purpose of the

RFA. See 75 FR at 76170.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

Notwithstanding the imposition of this burden, however, the

determination to certify pursuant to Sec. 605(b) of the RFA that the

proposed rule would not have a significant economic effect on a

substantial number of small entities was based upon two major

considerations. First, Section 43.3 of the Commission's regulations

already requires these entities to report their swap transaction and

pricing data to an SDR.\711\ The Commission is of the view that

requiring these entities to include an additional notification or field

in conjunction with the reporting of such data would impose, at best, a

marginal and incremental cost. Second, the proposed rule was structured

so that most swaps that are expected to be executed by an end user

would not require notification of the election by the end user, but

rather by a party that is subject to Commission registration and

regulation.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

\711\ See 77 FR 1240.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Commission did not receive any comments respecting its RFA

certification. Accordingly, for the reasons stated in the Further

Proposal and set forth above, the Commission continues to believe that

the rulemaking will not have a significant impact on a substantial

number of small entities. Therefore, the Chairman, on behalf of the

Commission, hereby certifies, pursuant to 5 U.S.C. 605(b), that the

procedure to establish appropriate minimum block sizes adopted herein

will not have a significant economic impact on a substantial number of

small entities.

VII. Example of a Post-initial Appropriate Minimum Block Size

Determination Using the 67-percent Notional Amount Calculation

The example below describes the steps necessary for the Commission

to determine the post-initial appropriate minimum block size based on

Sec. 43.6(c)(1) for a sample set of data in ``Swap Category Z.'' For

the purposes of this example, Swap Category Z had 35 transactions over

the given observation period. The observations are described in table A

below and are ordered by time of execution (i.e., Transaction

1 was executed prior to Transaction 2).

Table A--Swap Category Z Transactions

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Transaction 1 i>2 i>3 i>4 i>5

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

5,000,000 25,000,000 50,000,000 1.05 3,243,571

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 32935]]

Transaction 6 i>7 i>8 i>9 i>10

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

100,000,000 525,000,000 10,000,000 15,000,000 25,000,000

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Transaction 11 i>12 i>13 i>14 i>15

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

100,000,000 265,000,000 25,000,000 100,000,000 100,000,000

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Transaction 16 i>17 i>18 i>19 i>20

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

100,000,000 150,000,000 50,000,000 100,000,000 50,000,000

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Transaction 21 i>22 i>23 i>24 i>25

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

75,000,000 82,352,124 100,000,000 1,235,726 60,000,000

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Transaction 26 i>27 i>28 i>29 i>30

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

100,000,000 50,000,000 50,000,000 100,000,000 100,000,000

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Transaction 31 i>32 i>33 i>34 i>35

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

100,000,000 100,000,000 32,875,000 50,000,000 440,000,000

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Step 1: Remove the transactions that do not fall within the

definition of ``publicly reportable swap transactions'' as described in

Sec. 43.2.

In this example, assume that five of the 35 transactions in Swap

Category Z do not fall within the definition of ``publicly reportable

swap transaction.'' These five transactions, listed in table B below

would be removed for the data set that will be used to determine the

post-initial appropriate minimum block size.

Table B--Transactions That Do Not Fall Within the Definition of ``Publicly Reportable Swap Transaction''

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Transaction 4 i>13 i>16 i>20 i>21

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

1.05 25,000,000 100,000,000 50,000,000 75,000,000

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Step 2A: Convert the publicly reportable swap transactions in the

swap category to the same currency or units.

In order to accurately compare the transactions in a swap category

and apply the appropriate minimum block size calculation, the

transactions must be converted to the same currency or unit.

In this example, the publicly reportable swap transactions were all

denominated in U.S. dollars, so no conversion was necessary. If the

notional amounts of any of the publicly reportable swap transactions in

Swap Category Z had been denominated in a currency other than U.S.

dollars, then the notional amounts of such publicly reportable swap

transactions would have been adjusted by the daily exchange rates for

the period to arrive at the U.S. dollars equivalent notional amount.

Step 2B: Examine the remaining data set for any outliers and remove

any such outliers, resulting in a trimmed data set.

The publicly reportable swap transactions are examined to identify

any outliers. If an outlier is discovered, then it would be removed

from the data set. To conduct this analysis, the notional amounts of

all of the publicly reportable swap transactions remaining after step 1

and step 2A are transformed by Log10. The average and

standard deviation (``STDEV'') of these transformed notional amounts

would then be calculated. Any transformed notional amount of a publicly

reportable swap transaction that is larger than the average of all

transformed notional amounts plus four times the standard deviation

would be omitted from the data set as an outlier.

In the data set used in this example, none of the observations were

large enough to qualify as an outlier, as shown in the calculations

described in Table C.

Table C--Testing for Outliers in the Publicly Reportable Swap Transaction Data Set

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Log10 Average............................... 7.75 4*STDEV+Average............... 10.2

Log10 STDEV................................. 0.611359 Omitted Values................ None

-------------------------------------------------

4* STDEV.................................... 2.45

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Step 3: Sum the notional amounts of the remaining publicly

reportable swap transactions in the data set resulting after step 2B.

Note: The notional amounts being summed in this step are the original

amounts following step 2A and not the Log10 transformed

amounts used for the process in step 2B used to identify and omit any

outliers.

Using the equation described immediately below, the notional

amounts are added to determine the

[[Page 32936]]

sum total of all notional amounts remaining in the data set for a

particular swap category. In this example, the notional amounts of the

30 remaining publicly reportable swap transactions in Swap Category Z

are added together to come up with a net value of 2,989,706,421.

[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TR31MY13.000

30 = Notional amount of swap transaction

i = Index variable of summation for the set

Ti = Indicator for publicly reportable swap transactions

PRSTNV = Sum total of the notional amounts of all remaining publicly

reportable swap transactions in the set

PRSTNV = 2,989,706,421

Step 4: Calculate the 67 Percent Notional Amount.

Using the resulting amount from step 2B, a 67-percent notional

amount value would be calculated by using the equation:

PRSTNV * 0.67 = G

G = 67 percent of the sum total of the notional amounts of all

remaining publicly reportable swap transactions in the set.

G = 2,003,103,302

Step 5: Order and rank the observations based on notional amount of

the publicly reportable swap transaction from least to greatest.

The remaining publicly reportable swap transactions having

previously been converted to U.S. dollar equivalents must be ranked,

based on the notional sizes of such transactions, from least to

greatest. The resulting ranking yields the PRSTi[squ]. Table D below

reflects the ranking of the remaining publicly reportable swap

transactions based on their notional amount sizes for this example.

PRSTi = a publicly reportable swap transaction in the data set

ranked from least to greatest based on the notional amounts of such

transactions.

Step 6A: Calculate the running sum of all PRSTi.

A running sum would be calculated by adding together the ranked and

ordered publicly reportable swap transactions from step 5 (PRSTi) in

least to greatest order. The calculations of running sum values with

respect to this example are reflected in Table D below.

RS Values = Running sum values

Table D--PRSTi Values and RS Values

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Rank Order 1 i>2 i>3 i>4 i>5

PRSTi Values........................................ 1,235,726 3,243,571 5,000,000 10,000,000 15,000,000

RS Values........................................... 1,235,726 4,479,297 9,479,297 19,479,297 34,479,297

Rank Order 6 i>7 i>8 i>9 i>10

PRSTi Values........................................ 25,000,000 25,000,000 32,875,000 50,000,000 50,000,000

RS Values........................................... 59,479,297 84,479,297 117,354,297 167,354,297 217,354,297

Rank Order 11 i>12 i>13 i>14 i>15

PRSTi Values........................................ 50,000,000 50,000,000 50,000,000 60,000,000 82,352,124

RS Values........................................... 267,354,297 317,354,297 367,354,297 427,354,297 509,706,421

Rank Order 16 i>17 i>18 i>19 i>20

PRSTi Values........................................ 100,000,000 100,000,000 100,000,000 100,000,000 100,000,000

RS Values........................................... 609,706,421 709,706,421 809,706,421 909,706,421 1,009,706,421

Rank Order 21 i>22 i>23 i>24 i>25

PRSTi Values........................................ 100,000,000 100,000,000 100,000,000 100,000,000 100,000,000

RS Values........................................... 1,109,706,421 1,209,706,421 1,309,706,421 1,409,706,421 1,509,706,421

Rank Order 26 i>27 i>28 i>29 i>30

PRSTi Values........................................ 100,000,000 150,000,000 265,000,000 440,000,000 525,000,000

RS Values........................................... 1,609,706,421 1,759,706,421 2,024,706,421 2,464,706,421 2,989,706,421

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Step 6B: Select first RS Value that is greater than or equal to G.

In this example, G is equal to 2,003,103,302, meaning that the RS

Value that must be selected would have to be greater than that number.

The first RS Value that is greater than or equal to G can be found in

the observation that corresponds to Rank Order 28 (see Table

D). The RS Value of the Rank Order 28 observation is

2,024,706,421.

Step 7: Select the PRSTt that corresponds to the observation

determined in step 6B.

In this example, the PRSTt that corresponds to the RS Value

determined in step 6B (Rank Order 28) is 265,000,000.

Step 8: Determine the rounded notional amount.

Calculate the rounded notional amount under the process described

in the proposed amendment to Sec. 43.2. The 265,000,000 amount would

be rounded to the nearest 10 million for public dissemination, or

270,000,000.

Step 9: Set the appropriate minimum block size at the amount

calculated in step 8.

In this example, the appropriate minimum block size for swap

category Z would be 270,000,000 for the observation period.

Post-Initial Appropriate Minimum Block Size = $270,000,000

VIII. List of Commenters Who Responded to the Further Block Proposal

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Acronym/Abbreviation Commenter

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Abbott.................................... Abbott, Robert.

AFR....................................... Americans for Financial

Reform.

ABC....................................... American Benefits Counsel.

Arbor..................................... Arbor Research & Trading,

Inc.

AII....................................... Association of Institutional

Investors.

Barclays.................................. Barclays Bank PLC.

Barnard................................... Barnard, Chris.

Better Markets............................ Better Markets, Inc.

CIEBA..................................... Committee on the Investment

of Employee Benefit Assets.

CME Group................................. CME Group Inc.

[[Page 32937]]

CRT....................................... CRT Capital Group LLC.

Currenex.................................. Currenex, Inc.

EEI....................................... Edison Electric Institute.

FIA....................................... Futures Industry Association

Principle Traders Group.

Freddie................................... Freddie Mac.

GFMA...................................... Global Foreign Exchange

Division of the Global

Financial Markets

Association.

ICAP Energy............................... ICAP Energy LLC.

ICAP...................................... ICAP North America Inc.

ISDA/SIFMA................................ International Swaps and

Derivatives Association and

the Securities Industry and

Financial Markets

Association.

ICI....................................... Investment Company

Institute.

Javelin................................... Javelin Capital Markets,

LLC.

Jefferies................................. Jefferies & Co., Inc.

JPM....................................... J.P. Morgan.

Kearney................................... Kearney, Timothy.

Kinetix................................... Kinetix Trading Solutions.

MFA....................................... Managed Funds Association.

Morgan Stanley............................ Morgan Stanley.

ODEX...................................... ODEX Group.

Parascandola.............................. Parascandola, James.

Parity.................................... Parity Energy, Inc.

Pierpont.................................. Pierpont Securities Holdings

LLC.

R.J. O'Brien.............................. R.J. O'Brien & Associates,

Inc.

SIFMA..................................... Asset Management Group of

the Securities Industry and

Financial Markets

Association.

SDMA...................................... Swaps & Derivatives Market

Association.

Spring Trading............................ Spring Trading, Inc.

Vanguard.................................. Vanguard.

WMBAA..................................... Wholesale Market Brokers'

Association, Americas.

Wolkoff................................... Wolkoff Consulting Services

LLC.

------------------------------------------------------------------------

List of Subjects in 17 CFR Part 43

Real-time public reporting, Block trades, Large notional off-

facility swaps, Reporting and recordkeeping requirements.

Accordingly, for the reasons discussed in the preamble, the

Commodity Futures Trading Commission amends 17 CFR part 43 as follows:

PART 43--REAL-TIME PUBLIC REPORTING

0

1. The authority citation for part 43 is revised to read as follows:

Authority: 7 U.S.C. 2(a), 12a(5) and 24a, as amended by Pub. L.

111-203, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010).

0

2. Amend Sec. 43.2 by adding the following definitions in alphabetical

order to read as follows:

Sec. 43.2 Definitions.

* * * * *

Cap size means, for each swap category, the maximum notional or

principal amount of a publicly reportable swap transaction that is

publicly disseminated.

* * * * *

Economically related means a direct or indirect reference to the

same commodity at the same delivery location or locations, or with the

same or a substantially similar cash market price series.

* * * * *

Futures-related swap means a swap (as defined in section 1a(47) of

the Act and as further defined by the Commission in implementing

regulations) that is economically related to a futures contract.

* * * * *

Major currencies means the currencies, and the cross-rates between

the currencies, of Australia, Canada, Denmark, New Zealand, Norway,

South Africa, South Korea, Sweden, and Switzerland.

Non-major currencies means all other currencies that are not super-

major currencies or major currencies.

* * * * *

Physical commodity swap means a swap in the other commodity asset

class that is based on a tangible commodity.

* * * * *

Reference price means a floating price series (including

derivatives contract prices and cash market prices or price indices)

used by the parties to a swap or swaption to determine payments made,

exchanged or accrued under the terms of a swap contract.

* * * * *

Super-major currencies means the currencies of the European

Monetary Union, Japan, the United Kingdom, and United States.

Swaps with composite reference prices means swaps based on

reference prices that are composed of more than one reference price

from more than one swap category.

* * * * *

Trimmed data set means a data set that has had extraordinarily

large notional transactions removed by transforming the data into a

logarithm with a base of 10, computing the mean, and excluding

transactions that are beyond four standard deviations above the mean.

* * * * *

0

3. Amend Sec. 43.4 as follows:

0

A. Revise paragraph (d)(4)(i);

0

B. Revise paragraph (d)(4)(ii)(B);

0

C. Add paragraph (d)(4)(iii);

0

D. Revise paragraph (h).

The revisions and addition read as follows:

Sec. 43.4 Swap transaction and pricing data to be publicly

disseminated in real-time.

* * * * *

(d) * * *

(4) * * *

(i) A registered swap data repository shall publicly disseminate

swap transaction and pricing data for publicly reportable swap

transactions in the other commodity asset class in the manner described

in paragraphs (d)(4)(ii) and (d)(4)(iii) of this section.

(ii) * * *

(B) Any publicly reportable swap transaction that is economically

related to one of the contracts described in Appendix B of this part;

or

* * * * *

[[Page 32938]]

(iii) The underlying assets of swaps in the other commodity asset

class that are not described in paragraph (d)(4)(ii) of this section

shall be publicly disseminated by limiting the geographic detail of the

underlying assets. The identification of any specific delivery point or

pricing point associated with the underlying asset of such other

commodity swap shall be publicly disseminated pursuant to Appendix E of

this part.

* * * * *

(h) Cap sizes.

(1) Initial cap sizes. Prior to the effective date of a Commission

determination to establish an applicable post-initial cap size for a

swap category as determined pursuant to paragraph (h)(2) of this

section, the initial cap sizes for each swap category shall be equal to

the greater of the initial appropriate minimum block size for the

respective swap category in Appendix F of this part or the respective

cap sizes in paragraphs (h)(1)(i) through (h)(1)(v) of this section. If

Appendix F of this part does not provide an initial appropriate minimum

block size for a particular swap category, the initial cap size for

such swap category shall be equal to the appropriate cap size as set

forth in paragraphs (h)(1)(i) through (h)(1)(v) of this section.

(i) For swaps in the interest rate asset class, the publicly

disseminated notional or principal amount for a swap subject to the

rules in this part shall be:

(A) USD 250 million for swaps with a tenor greater than zero up to

and including two years;

(B) USD 100 million for swaps with a tenor greater than two years

up to and including ten years; and

(C) USD 75 million for swaps with a tenor greater than ten years.

(ii) For swaps in the credit asset class, the publicly disseminated

notional or principal amount for a swap subject to the rules in this

part shall be USD 100 million.

(iii) For swaps in the equity asset class, the publicly

disseminated notional or principal amount for a swap subject to the

rules in this part shall be USD 250 million.

(iv) For swaps in the foreign exchange asset class, the publicly

disseminated notional or principal amount for a swap subject to the

rules in this part shall be USD 250 million.

(v) For swaps in the other commodity asset class, the publicly

disseminated notional or principal amount for a swap subject to the

rules in this part shall be USD 25 million.

(2) Post-initial cap sizes. Pursuant to the process described in

Sec. 43.6(f)(1), the Commission shall establish post-initial cap sizes

using reliable data collected by registered swap data repositories, as

determined by the Commission, based on the following:

(i) A one-year window of swap transaction and pricing data

corresponding to each relevant swap category recalculated no less than

once each calendar year; and

(ii) The 75-percent notional amount calculation described in Sec.

43.6(c)(3) applied to the swap transaction and pricing data described

in paragraph (h)(2)(i) of this section.

(3) Commission publication of post-initial cap sizes. The

Commission shall publish post-initial cap sizes on its Web site at

http://www.cftc.gov.

(4) Effective date of post-initial cap sizes. Unless otherwise

indicated on the Commission's Web site, the post-initial cap sizes

shall be effective on the first day of the second month following the

date of publication.

0

4. Add Sec. 43.6 to read as follows:

Sec. 43.6 Block trades and large notional off-facility swaps.

(a) Commission determination. The Commission shall establish the

appropriate minimum block size for publicly reportable swap

transactions based on the swap categories set forth in paragraph (b) of

this section in accordance with the provisions set forth in paragraphs

(c), (d), (e), (f) or (h) of this section, as applicable.

(b) Swap categories. Swap categories shall be established for all

swaps, by asset class, in the following manner:

(1) Interest rates asset class. Interest rate asset class swap

categories shall be based on unique combinations of the following:

(i) Currency by:

(A) Super-major currency;

(B) Major currency; or

(C) Non-major currency; and

(ii) Tenor of swap as follows:

(A) Zero to 46 days;

(B) Greater than 46 days to three months (47 to 107 days);

(C) Greater than three months to six months (108 to 198 days);

(D) Greater than six months to one year (199 to 381 days);

(E) Greater than one to two years (382 to 746 days);

(F) Greater than two to five years (747 to 1,842 days);

(G) Greater than five to ten years (1,843 to 3,668 days);

(H) Greater than ten to 30 years (3,669 to 10,973 days); or

(I) Greater than 30 years (10,974 days and above).

(2) Credit asset class. Credit asset class swap categories shall be

based on unique combinations of the following:

(i) Traded Spread rounded to the nearest basis point (0.01) as

follows:

(A) 0 to 175 points;

(B) 176 to 350 points; or

(C) 351 points and above;

(ii) Tenor of swap as follows:

(A) Zero to two years (0-746 days);

(B) Greater than two to four years (747-1,476 days);

(C) Greater than four to six years (1,477-2,207 days);

(D) Greater than six to eight-and-a-half years (2,208-3,120 days);

(E) Greater than eight-and-a-half to 12.5 years (3,121-4,581 days);

and

(F) Greater than 12.5 years (4,582 days and above).

(3) Equity asset class. There shall be one swap category consisting

of all swaps in the equity asset class.

(4) Foreign exchange asset class. Swap categories in the foreign

exchange asset class shall be grouped as follows:

(i) By the unique currency combinations of one super-major currency

paired with one of the following:

(A) Another super major currency;

(B) A major currency; or

(C) A currency of Brazil, China, Czech Republic, Hungary, Israel,

Mexico, Poland, Russia, and Turkey; or

(ii) By unique currency combinations not included in paragraph

(b)(4)(i) of this section.

(5) Other commodity asset class. Swap contracts in the other

commodity asset class shall be grouped into swap categories as follows:

(i) For swaps that are economically related to contracts in

Appendix B of this part, by the relevant contract as referenced in

Appendix B of this part; or

(ii) For swaps that are not economically related to contracts in

Appendix B of this part, by the following futures-related swaps--

(A) CME Cheese;

(B) CBOT Distillers' Dried Grain;

(C) CBOT Dow Jones-UBS Commodity Index;

(D) CBOT Ethanol;

(E) CME Frost Index;

(F) CME Goldman Sachs Commodity Index (GSCI), (GSCI Excess Return

Index);

(G) NYMEX Gulf Coast Sour Crude Oil;

(H) CME Hurricane Index;

(I) CME Rainfall Index;

(J) CME Snowfall Index;

(K) CME Temperature Index;

(L) CME U.S. Dollar Cash Settled Crude Palm Oil; or

(iii) For swaps that are not covered in paragraphs (b)(5)(i) and

(b)(5)(ii) of this section, the relevant product type as referenced in

Appendix D of this part.

[[Page 32939]]

(c) Methodologies to determine appropriate minimum block sizes and

cap sizes. In determining appropriate minimum block sizes and cap sizes

for publicly reportable swap transactions, the Commission shall utilize

the following statistical calculations--

(1) 50-percent notional amount calculation. The Commission shall

use the following procedure in determining the 50-percent notional

amount calculation:

(i) Select all of the publicly reportable swap transactions within

a specific swap category using a one-year window of data beginning with

a minimum of one year's worth of data;

(ii) Convert to the same currency or units and use a trimmed data

set;

(iii) Determine the sum of the notional amounts of swaps in the

trimmed data set;

(iv) Multiply the sum of the notional amount by 50 percent;

(v) Rank order the observations by notional amount from least to

greatest;

(vi) Calculate the cumulative sum of the observations until the

cumulative sum is equal to or greater than the 50-percent notional

amount calculated in paragraph (c)(1)(iv) of this section;

(vii) Select the notional amount associated with that observation;

(viii) Round the notional amount of that observation to two

significant digits, or if the notional amount associated with that

observation is already significant to two digits, increase that

notional amount to the next highest rounding point of two significant

digits; and

(ix) Set the appropriate minimum block size at the amount

calculated in paragraph (c)(1)(viii) of this section.

(2) 67-percent notional amount calculation. The Commission shall

use the following procedure in determining the 67-percent notional

amount calculation:

(i) Select all of the publicly reportable swap transactions within

a specific swap category using a one-year window of data beginning with

a minimum of one year's worth of data;

(ii) Convert to the same currency or units and use a trimmed data

set;

(iii) Determine the sum of the notional amounts of swaps in the

trimmed data set;

(iv) Multiply the sum of the notional amount by 67 percent;

(v) Rank order the observations by notional amount from least to

greatest;

(vi) Calculate the cumulative sum of the observations until the

cumulative sum is equal to or greater than the 67-percent notional

amount calculated in paragraph (c)(2)(iv) of this section;

(vii) Select the notional amount associated with that observation;

(viii) Round the notional amount of that observation to two

significant digits, or if the notional amount associated with that

observation is already significant to two digits, increase that

notional amount to the next highest rounding point of two significant

digits; and

(ix) Set the appropriate minimum block size at the amount

calculated in paragraph (c)(2)(viii) of this section.

(3) 75-percent notional amount calculation. The Commission shall

use the following procedure in determining the 75-percent notional

amount calculation:

(i) Select all of the publicly reportable swap transactions within

a specific swap category using a one-year window of data beginning with

a minimum of one year's worth of data;

(ii) Convert to the same currency or units and use a trimmed data

set;

(iii) Determine the sum of the notional amounts of swaps in the

trimmed data set;

(iv) Multiply the sum of the notional amount by 75 percent;

(v) Rank order the observations by notional amount from least to

greatest;

(vi) Calculate the cumulative sum of the observations until the

cumulative sum is equal to or greater than the 75-percent notional

amount calculated in paragraph (c)(3)(iv) of this section;

(vii) Select the notional amount associated with that observation;

(viii) Round the notional amount of that observation to two

significant digits, or if the notional amount associated with that

observation is already significant to two digits, increase that

notional amount to the next highest rounding point of two significant

digits; and

(ix) Set the appropriate minimum block size at the amount

calculated in paragraph (c)(3)(viii) of this section.

(d) No appropriate minimum block sizes for swaps in the equity

asset class. Publicly reportable swap transactions in the equity asset

class shall not be treated as block trades or large notional off-

facility swaps.

(e) Initial appropriate minimum block sizes. Prior to the

Commission making a determination as described in paragraph (f)(1) of

this section, the following initial appropriate minimum block sizes

shall apply:

(1) Prescribed appropriate minimum block sizes. Except as otherwise

provided in paragraph (e)(1) of this section, for any publicly

reportable swap transaction that falls within the swap categories

described in paragraphs (b)(1), (b)(2), (b)(4)(i), (b)(5)(i) or

(b)(5)(ii) of this section, the initial appropriate minimum block size

for such publicly reportable swap transaction shall be the appropriate

minimum block size that is in Appendix F of this part.

(2) Certain swaps in the foreign exchange and other commodity asset

classes. All swaps or instruments in the swap categories described in

paragraphs (b)(4)(ii) and (b)(5)(iii) of this section shall be eligible

to be treated as a block trade or large notional off-facility swap, as

applicable.

(3) Exception. Publicly reportable swap transactions described in

paragraph (b)(5)(i) of this section that are economically related to a

futures contract in Appendix B of this part shall not qualify to be

treated as block trades or large notional off-facility swaps (as

applicable), if such futures contract is not subject to a designated

contract market's block trading rules.

(f) Post-initial process to determine appropriate minimum block

sizes.

(1) Post-initial period. After a registered swap data repository

has collected at least one year of reliable data for a particular asset

class, the Commission shall establish, by swap categories, the post-

initial appropriate minimum block sizes as described in paragraphs

(f)(2) through (f)(5) of this section. No less than once each calendar

year thereafter, the Commission shall update the post-initial

appropriate minimum block sizes.

(2) Post-initial appropriate minimum block sizes for certain swaps.

The Commission shall determine post-initial appropriate minimum block

sizes for the swap categories described in paragraphs (b)(1), (b)(2),

(b)(4)(i) and (b)(5) of this section by utilizing a one-year window of

swap transaction and pricing data corresponding to each relevant swap

category reviewed no less than once each calendar year, and by applying

the 67-percent notional amount calculation to such data.

(3) Certain swaps in the foreign exchange asset class. All swaps or

instruments in the swap category described in paragraph (b)(4)(ii) of

this section shall be eligible to be treated as a block trade or large

notional off-facility swap, as applicable.

(4) Commission publication of post-initial appropriate minimum

block sizes. The Commission shall publish the appropriate minimum block

sizes determined pursuant to paragraph (f)(1) of this section on its

Web site at http://www.cftc.gov.

(5) Effective date of post-initial appropriate minimum block sizes.

Unless otherwise indicated on the Commission's Web site, the post-

initial appropriate minimum block sizes described in paragraph (f)(1)

of this

[[Page 32940]]

section shall be effective on the first day of the second month

following the date of publication.

(g) Required notification.

(1) Block trade election.

(i) The parties to a publicly reportable swap transaction that has

a notional amount at or above the appropriate minimum block size shall

notify the registered swap execution facility or designated contract

market, as applicable, pursuant to the rules of such registered swap

execution facility or designated contract market, of its election to

have the publicly reportable swap transaction treated as a block trade.

(ii) The registered swap execution facility or designated contract

market, as applicable, pursuant to the rules of which a block trade is

executed shall notify the registered swap data repository of such a

block trade election when transmitting swap transaction and pricing

data to such swap data repository in accordance with Sec. 43.3(b)(1).

(2) Large notional off-facility swap election. A reporting party

who executes an off-facility swap that has a notional amount at or

above the appropriate minimum block size shall notify the applicable

registered swap data repository that such swap transaction qualifies as

a large notional off-facility swap concurrent with the transmission of

swap transaction and pricing data in accordance with this part.

(h) Special provisions relating to appropriate minimum block sizes

and cap sizes. The following special rules shall apply to the

determination of appropriate minimum block sizes and cap sizes--

(1) Swaps with optionality. The notional amount of a swap with

optionality shall equal the notional amount of the component of the

swap that does not include the option component.

(2) Swaps with composite reference prices. The parties to a swap

transaction with composite reference prices may elect to apply the

lowest appropriate minimum block size or cap size applicable to one

component reference price's swap category of such publicly reportable

swap transaction.

(3) Notional amounts for physical commodity swaps. Unless otherwise

specified in this part, the notional amount for a physical commodity

swap shall be based on the notional unit measure utilized in the

related futures contract market or the predominant notional unit

measure used to determine notional quantities in the cash market for

the relevant, underlying physical commodity.

(4) Currency conversion. Unless otherwise specified in this part,

when the appropriate minimum block size or cap size for a publicly

reportable swap transaction is denominated in a currency other than

U.S. dollars, parties to a swap and registered entities may use a

currency exchange rate that is widely published within the preceding

two business days from the date of execution of the swap transaction in

order to determine such qualification.

(5) Successor currencies. For currencies that succeed a super-major

currency, the appropriate currency classification for such currency

shall be based on the corresponding nominal gross domestic product

classification (in U.S. dollars) as determined in the most recent World

Bank, World Development Indicator at the time of succession. If the

gross domestic product of the country or nation utilizing the successor

currency is:

(i) Greater than $2 trillion, then the successor currency shall be

included among the super-major currencies;

(ii) Greater than $500 billion but less than $2 trillion, then the

successor currency shall be included among the major currencies; or

(iii) Less than $500 billion, then the successor currency shall be

included among the non-major currencies.

(6) Aggregation. Except as otherwise stated in this paragraph, the

aggregation of orders for different accounts in order to satisfy the

minimum block trade size or the cap size requirement is prohibited.

Aggregation is permissible on a designated contract market or swap

execution facility if done by a person who:

(i) (A) Is a commodity trading advisor registered pursuant to

Section 4n of the Act, or exempt from registration under the Act, or a

principal thereof, who has discretionary trading authority or directs

client accounts,

(B) Is an investment adviser who has discretionary trading

authority or directs client accounts and satisfies the criteria of

Sec. 4.7(a)(2)(v) of this chapter, or

(C) Is a foreign person who performs a similar role or function as

the persons described in paragraphs (h)(6)(i)(A) or (h)(6)(i)(B) of

this section and is subject as such to foreign regulation; and,

(ii) Has more than $25,000,000 in total assets under management.

(i) Eligible Block Trade Parties.

(1) Parties to a block trade must be ``eligible contract

participants,'' as defined in Section 1a(18) of the Act and the

Commission's regulations. However, a designated contract market may

allow:

(i) A commodity trading advisor registered pursuant to Section 4n

of the Act, or exempt from registration under the Act, or a principal

thereof, who has discretionary trading authority or directs client

accounts,

(ii) An investment adviser who has discretionary trading authority

or directs client accounts and satisfies the criteria of Sec.

4.7(a)(2)(v) of this chapter, or

(iii) a foreign person who performs a similar role or function as

the persons described in paragraphs (i)(1)(i) or (ii) of this section

and is subject as such to foreign regulation, to transact block trades

for customers who are not eligible contract participants if such

commodity trading advisor, investment adviser or foreign person has

more than $25,000,000 in total assets under management.

(2) A person transacting a block trade on behalf of a customer must

receive prior written instruction or consent from the customer to do

so. Such instruction or consent may be provided in the power of

attorney or similar document by which the customer provides the person

with discretionary trading authority or the authority to direct the

trading in its account.

0

5. Add Sec. 43.7 to read as follows:

Sec. 43.7 Delegation of authority.

(a) Authority. The Commission hereby delegates, until it orders

otherwise, to the Director of the Division of Market Oversight or such

other employee or employees as the Director may designate from time to

time, the authority:

(1) To determine whether swaps fall within specific swap categories

as described in Sec. 43.6(b);

(2) To determine and publish post-initial, appropriate minimum

block sizes as described in Sec. 43.6(f); and

(3) To determine post-initial cap sizes as described in Sec.

43.4(h).

(b) Submission for Commission consideration. The Director of the

Division of Market Oversight may submit to the Commission for its

consideration any matter that has been delegated pursuant to this

section.

(c) Commission reserves authority. Nothing in this section

prohibits the Commission, at its election, from exercising the

authority delegated in this section.

0

6. Amend Appendix B to Part 43 to add the following contracts under the

heading ``Energy'' after the existing listing for ``New York Mercantile

Exchange New York Harbor Heating Oil'':

Appendix B to Part 43--Enumerated Physical Commodity Contracts and

Other Contracts

* * * * *

[[Page 32941]]

Energy

* * * * *

ICE Futures SP-15 Day-Ahead Peak Fixed Price

ICE Futures SP-15 Day-Ahead Off-Peak Fixed Price

ICE Futures PJM Western Hub Real Time Peak Fixed Price

ICE Futures PJM Western Hub Real Time Off-Peak Fixed Price

ICE Futures Mid-Columbia Day-Ahead Peak Fixed Price

ICE Futures Mid-Columbia Day-Ahead Off-Peak Fixed Price

Chicago Basis

HSC Basis

Socal Border Basis

Waha Basis

ICE Futures AB NIT Basis

NWP Rockies Basis

PG&E Citygate Basis

* * * * *

0

7. Add Appendix D to Part 43 to read as follows:

Appendix D to Part 43--Other Commodity Swap Categories

Other Commodity Group

Individual Other Commodity

Grains

Oats

Wheat

Corn

Rice

Grains--Other

Livestock/Meat Products

Live Cattle

Pork Bellies

Feeder Cattle

Lean Hogs

Livestock/Meat Products--Other

Dairy Products

Milk

Butter

Cheese

Dairy Products--Other

Oilseed and Products

Soybean Oil

Soybean Meal

Soybeans

Oilseed and Products--Other

Fiber

Cotton

Fiber--Other

Foodstuffs/Softs

Coffee

Frozen Concentrated Orange Juice

Sugar

Cocoa

Foodstuffs/Softs--Other

Petroleum and Products

Jet Fuel

Ethanol

Biodiesel

Fuel Oil

Heating Oil

Gasoline

Naphtha

Crude Oil

Diesel

Petroleum and Products--Other

Natural Gas and Related Products

Natural Gas Liquids

Natural Gas

Natural Gas and Related Products--Other

Electricity and Sources

Coal

Electricity

Uranium

Electricity and Sources--Other

Precious Metals

Palladium

Platinum

Silver

Gold

Precious Metals--Other

Base Metals

Steel

Copper

Base Metals--Other

Wood Products

Lumber

Pulp

Wood Products--Other

Real Estate

Real Estate

Chemicals

Chemicals

Plastics

Plastics

Emissions

Emissions

Weather

Weather

Multiple Commodity Index

Multiple Commodity Index

Other Agricultural

Other Agricultural

Other Non-Agricultural

Other Non-Agricultural

0

8. Add Appendix E to Part 43 to read as follows:

Appendix E to Part 43--Other Commodity Geographic Identification for

Public Dissemination Pursuant to Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii)

Registered swap data repositories are required by Sec.

43.4(d)(4)(iii) to publicly disseminate any specific delivery point

or pricing point associated with publicly reportable swap

transactions in the ``other commodity'' asset class pursuant to

Tables E1 and E2 in this appendix. If the underlying asset of a

publicly reportable swap transaction described in Sec.

43.4(d)(4)(iii) has a delivery or pricing point that is located in

the United States, such information shall be publicly disseminated

pursuant to the regions described in Table E1 in this appendix. If

the underlying asset of a publicly reportable swap transaction

described in Sec. 43.4(d)(4)(iii) has a delivery or pricing point

that is not located in the United States, such information shall be

publicly disseminated pursuant to the countries or sub-regions, or

if no country or sub-region, by the other commodity region,

described in Table E2 in this appendix.

Table E1. U.S. Delivery or Pricing Points

Other Commodity Group

Region

Natural Gas and Related Products

Midwest

Northeast

Gulf

Southeast

Western

Other--U.S.

Petroleum and Products

New England (PADD 1A)

Central Atlantic (PADD 1B)

Lower Atlantic (PADD 1C)

Midwest (PADD 2)

Gulf Coast (PADD 3)

Rocky Mountains (PADD 4)

West Coast (PADD 5)

Other--U.S.

Electricity and Sources

Florida Reliability Coordinating Council (FRCC)

Midwest Reliability Organization (MRO)

Northeast Power Coordinating Council (NPCC)

Reliability First Corporation (RFC)

SERC Reliability Corporation (SERC)

Southwest Power Pool, RE (SPP)

Texas Regional Entity (TRE)

Western Electricity Coordinating Council (WECC)

Other--U.S.

All Remaining Other Commodities (Publicly disseminate the region. If

pricing or delivery point is not region-specific, indicate ``U.S.'')

Region 1--(Includes Connecticut, Maine, Massachusetts, New

Hampshire, Rhode Island, Vermont)

Region 2--(Includes New Jersey, New York)

Region 3--(Includes Delaware, District of Columbia, Maryland,

Pennsylvania, Virginia, West Virginia)

Region 4--(Includes Alabama, Florida, Georgia, Kentucky,

Mississippi, North Carolina, South Carolina, Tennessee)

Region 5--(Includes Illinois, Indiana, Michigan, Minnesota,

Ohio, Wisconsin)

Region 6--(Includes Arkansas, Louisiana, New Mexico, Oklahoma,

Texas)

Region 7--(Includes Iowa, Kansas, Missouri, Nebraska)

Region 8--(Includes Colorado, Montana, North Dakota, South

Dakota, Utah, Wyoming)

Region 9--(Includes Arizona, California, Hawaii, Nevada)

Region 10--(Includes Alaska, Idaho, Oregon, Washington)

Table E2. Non-U.S. Delivery or Pricing Points

Other Commodity Regions

Country or Sub-Region

North America (Other than U.S.)

Canada

Mexico

Central America

South America

Brazil

Other South America

Europe

Western Europe

Northern Europe

Southern Europe

Eastern Europe (excluding Russia)

Russia

Africa

Northern Africa

Western Africa

Eastern Africa

Central Africa

Southern Africa

Asia-Pacific

Northern Asia (excluding Russia)

[[Page 32942]]

Central Asia

Eastern Asia

Western Asia

Southeast Asia

Australia/New Zealand/Pacific Islands

0

9. Add Appendix F to Part 43 to read as follows:

Appendix F to Part 43--Initial Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes by Asset

Class for Block Trades and Large Notional Off-Facility Swaps

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Currency group Currencies

------------------------------------------------------------------------

Super-Major Currencies.......................... United States dollar

(USD), European Union

Euro Area euro (EUR),

United Kingdom pound

sterling (GBP), and

Japan yen (JPY).

Major Currencies................................ Australia dollar

(AUD), Switzerland

franc (CHF), Canada

dollar (CAD),

Republic of South

Africa rand (ZAR),

Republic of Korea won

(KRW), Kingdom of

Sweden krona (SEK),

New Zealand dollar

(NZD), Kingdom of

Norway krone (NOK),

and Denmark krone

(DKK).

Non-Major Currencies............................ All other currencies.

------------------------------------------------------------------------

INTEREST RATE SWAPS

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Tenor less than or equal 50% Notional (in

Currency group Tenor greater than to millions)

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Super-Major............................ .......................... 46 days.................. 6,400

Super-Major............................ 46 days................... Three months (107 days).. 2,100

Super-Major............................ Three months (107 days)... Six months (198 days).... 1,200

Super-Major............................ Six months (198 days)..... One year (381 days)...... 1,100

Super-Major............................ One year (381 days)....... Two years (746 days)..... 460

Super-Major............................ Two years (746 days)...... Five years (1,842 days).. 240

Super-Major............................ Five years (1,842 days)... Ten years (3,668 days)... 170

Super-Major............................ Ten years (3,668 days).... 30 years (10,973 days)... 120

Super-Major............................ 30 years (10,973 days).... ......................... 67

Major.................................. .......................... 46 days.................. 2,200

Major.................................. 46 days................... Three months (107 days).. 580

Major.................................. Three months (107 days)... Six months (198 days).... 440

Major.................................. Six months (198 days)..... One year (381 days)...... 220

Major.................................. One year (381 days)....... Two years (746 days)..... 130

Major.................................. Two years (746 days)...... Five years (1,842 days).. 88

Major.................................. Five years (1,842 days)... Ten years (3,668 days)... 49

Major.................................. Ten years (3,668 days).... 30 years (10,973 days)... 37

Major.................................. 30 years (10,973 days).... ......................... 15

Non-Major.............................. .......................... 46 days.................. 230

Non-Major.............................. 46 days................... Three months (107 days).. 230

Non-Major.............................. Three months (107 days)... Six months (198 days).... 150

Non-Major.............................. Six months (198 days)..... One year (381 days)...... 110

Non-Major.............................. One year (381 days)....... Two years (746 days)..... 54

Non-Major.............................. Two years (746 days)...... Five years (1,842 days).. 27

Non-Major.............................. Five years (1,842 days)... Ten years (3,668 days)... 15

Non-Major.............................. Ten years (3,668 days).... 30 years (10,973 days)... 16

Non-Major.............................. 30 years (10,973 days).... ......................... 15

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Credit Swaps

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Traded tenor less than or 50% Notional (in

Spread group (Basis Points) Traded tenor greater than equal to Millions)

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Less than or equal to 175.............. .......................... Two years (746 days)..... 320

Less than or equal to 175.............. Two years (746 days)...... Four years (1,477 days).. 200

Less than or equal to 175.............. Four years (1,477 days)... Six years (2,207 days)... 110

Less than or equal to 175.............. Six years (2,207 days).... Eight years and six 110

months (3,120 days).

Less than or equal to 175.............. Eight years and six months Twelve years and six 130

(3,120 days). months (4,581 days).

Less than or equal to 175.............. Twelve years and six ......................... 46

months (4,581 days).

Greater than 175 and less than or equal .......................... Two years (746 days)..... 140

to 350.

Greater than 175 and less than or equal Two years (746 days)...... Four years (1,477 days).. 82

to 350.

Greater than 175 and less than or equal Four years (1,477 days)... Six years (2,207 days)... 32

to 350.

Greater than 175 and less than or equal Six years (2,207 days).... Eight years and six 20

to 350. months (3,120 days).

Greater than 175 and less than or equal Eight years and six months Twelve years and six 26

to 350. (3,120 days). months (4,581 days).

Greater than 175 and less than or equal Twelve years and six ......................... 63

to 350. months (4,581 days).

Greater than 350....................... .......................... Two years (746 days)..... 66

[[Page 32943]]

Greater than 350....................... Two years (746 days)...... Four years (1,477 days).. 41

Greater than 350....................... Four years (1,477 days)... Six years (2,207 days)... 26

Greater than 350....................... Six years (2,207 days).... Eight years and six 13

months (3,120 days).

Greater than 350....................... Eight years and six months Twelve years and six 13

(3,120 days). months (4,581 days).

Greater than 350....................... Twelve years and six ......................... 41

months (4,581 days).

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Foreign Exchange Swaps

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Super-major currencies

-----------------------------------------------------------------------

GBP (British JPY (Japanese USD (U.S.

EUR (Euro) pound) yen) dollar)

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Super-major currencies......................... EUR............................ 6,250,000 6,250,000 18,750,000

GBP............................ 6,250,000* 6,250,000 6,250,000

JPY............................ 6,250,000* 6,250,000* 1,875,000,000

USD............................ 18,750,000* 6,250,000* 1,875,000,000*

Major currencies............................... AUD............................ 6,250,000* 0 10,000,000 10,000,000

CAD............................ 6,250,000* 0 10,000,000 10,000,000

CHF............................ 6,250,000* 6,250,000* 12,500,000 12,500,000

DKK............................ 0 0 0 0

KRW............................ 0 0 0 6,250,000,000

SEK............................ 6,250,000* 0 0 10,000,000

NOK............................ 6,250,000* 0 0 10,000,000

NZD............................ 0 0 0 5,000,000

ZAR............................ 0 0 0 25,000,000

Non-major currencies........................... BRL............................ 0 0 0 5,000,000

CZK............................ 200,000,000 0 0 200,000,000

HUF............................ 1,500,000,000 0 0 1,500,000,000

ILS............................ 0 0 0 50,000,000

MXN............................ 0 0 0 50,000,000

PLN............................ 25,000,000 0 0 25,000,000

RMB............................ 50,000,000 0 50,000,000 50,000,000

RUB............................ 0 0 0 125,000,000

TRY............................ 6,250,000* 0 0 10,000,000*

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

All values that do not have an asterisk are denominated in the currency of the left hand side.

All values that have an asterisk (*) are denominated in the currency indicated on the top of the table.

Other Commodity Swaps

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Initial appropriate minimum

Related futures contract block size Units

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

............................ .......................................

AB NIT Basis (ICE)....................... 62,500...................... MMBtu

Brent Crude (ICE and NYMEX).............. 25,000...................... bbl.

Cheese (CME)............................. 400,000..................... lbs.

Class III Milk (CME)..................... NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

Cocoa (ICE and NYSE LIFFE and NYMEX)..... 1,000....................... metric tons

Coffee (ICE and NYMEX)................... 3,750,000................... lbs.

Copper (COMEX)........................... 625,000..................... lbs.

Corn (CBOT).............................. NO BLOCKS................... bushels

Cotton No. 2 (ICE and NYMEX)............. 5,000,000................... lbs.

Distillers' Dried Grain (CBOT)........... 1,000....................... short tons

Dow Jones-UBS Commodity Index (CBOT)..... 30,000 times index.......... dollars

Ethanol (CBOT)........................... 290,000..................... gallons

Feeder Cattle (CME)...................... NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

Frost Index (CME)........................ 200,000 times index......... euros

Frozen Concentrated Orange Juice (ICE)... NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

Gold (COMEX and NYSE Liffe).............. 2,500....................... troy oz.

Goldman Sachs Commodity Index (GSCI), 5,000 times index........... dollars

GSCI Excess Return Index (CME).

Gulf Coast Sour Crude Oil (NYMEX)........ 5,000....................... bbl.

Hard Red Spring Wheat (MGEX)............. NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

Hard Winter Wheat (KCBT)................. NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

Henry Hub Natural Gas (NYMEX)............ 500,000..................... MMBtu

HSC Basis (ICE and NYMEX)................ 62,500...................... MMBtu

Hurricane Index (CME).................... 20,000 times index.......... dollars

Chicago Basis (ICE and NYMEX)............ 62,500...................... MMBtu

[[Page 32944]]

............................ .......................................

Lean Hogs (CME).......................... NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

Light Sweet Crude Oil (NYMEX)............ 50,000...................... bbl.

Live Cattle (CME)........................ NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

Mid-Columbia Day-Ahead Off-Peak Fixed 250......................... MW/Hr.

Price (ICE).

Mid-Columbia Day-Ahead Peak Fixed Price 4,000....................... MW/Hr.

(ICE).

New York Harbor RBOB (Blendstock) 1,050,000................... gallons

Gasoline (NYMEX).

New York Harbor No. 2 Heating Oil (NYMEX) 1,050,000................... bbl.

NWP Rockies Basis (ICE and NYMEX)........ 62,500...................... MMBtu

Oats (CBOT).............................. NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

Palladium (NYMEX)........................ 1,000....................... troy oz.

PG&E Citygate Basis (ICE and NYMEX)...... 62,500...................... MMBtu

PJM Western Hub Real Time Off-Peak Fixed 3,900....................... MW/Hr.

Price (ICE).

PJM Western Hub Real Time Peak Fixed 8,000....................... MW/Hr.

Price (ICE).

Platinum (NYMEX)......................... 500......................... troy oz.

Rainfall Index (CME)..................... 10,000 times index.......... dollars

Rough Rice (CBOT)........................ NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

Silver (COMEX and NYSE Liffe)............ 125,000..................... troy oz.

Snowfall Index (CME)..................... 10,000 times index.......... dollars

Socal Border Basis (ICE and NYMEX)....... 62,500...................... MMBtu

Soybean (CBOT)........................... NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

Soybean Meal (CBOT)...................... NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

Soybean Oil (CBOT)....................... NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

SP-15 Day-Ahead Peak Fixed Price (ICE)... 4,000....................... MW/Hr.

SP-15 Day-Ahead Off-Peak Fixed Price 250......................... MW/Hr.

(ICE).

Sugar 11 (ICE and NYMEX) 5,000....................... metric tons

(futures).

Sugar 16 (ICE) (futures)........ NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

Temperature Index (CME).................. 400 times index............. currency units

U.S. Dollar Cash Settled Crude Palm Oil 250......................... metrics tons

(CME).

Waha Basis (ICE and NYMEX)............... 62,500...................... MMBtu

Wheat (CBOT)............................. NO BLOCKS................... .......................................

----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Issued in Washington, DC, on May 16, 2013, by the Commission.

Christopher J. Kirkpatrick,

Deputy Secretary of the Commission.

Appendices to Procedures To Establish Appropriate Minimum Block Sizes

for Large Notional Off-Facility Swaps and Block Trades--Commission

Voting Summary and Statements of Commissioners

Note: The following appendices will not appear in the Code of

Federal Regulations.

Appendix 1--Commission Voting Summary

On this matter, Chairman Gensler and Commissioners Chilton and

Wetjen voted in the affirmative; Commissioners Sommers and O'Malia

voted in the negative.

Appendix 2--Statement of Chairman Gary Gensler

I support the final block rule for swaps, which is critical to

promoting transparency in this once opaque market. With this rule,

the public will benefit from seeing the price and volume of the

majority of swaps transactions in real time--as soon as

technologically practicable--after a trade is executed. Further,

with this rule the public will benefit from the competition that

will arise as buyers and sellers must transact on transparent

trading platforms.

The methodology for determining block sizes is appropriately

tailored to vary by asset class and by underlying referenced product

or rate.

The Commission also has established a phased-in approach for

setting and implementing appropriate minimum block sizes. During an

initial one-year period, block sizes in the interest rate and credit

asset classes will be set such that 50 percent of the notional

amount of a particular swap category will benefit from pre-trade and

post-trade transparency. Also during this initial period, the block

sizes for foreign exchange and other commodity asset classes will be

based upon the block sizes that designated contract markets have set

for economically related futures contracts.

After the initial period, the Commission will determine block

sizes using a methodology that relies on the data collected by swap

data repositories. Block sizes will be set such that 67 percent of

the notional amount of a particular swap category will benefit from

pre-trade transparency and enhanced post-trade transparency.

The rule also includes measures to protect the identities,

market positions and business transactions of swap counterparties

when their swap transactions and pricing are reported to the public.

[FR Doc. 2013-12133 Filed 5-30-13; 8:45 am]

BILLING CODE 6351-01-P

Last Updated: May 31, 2013